Trade and industrial policy Table of Contents 1 General principles ............................................................................................................................. 2 1.1 The evolution of the multilateral trading system ....................................................................... 2 1.2 Most-favored nation and national treatment principles ............................................................. 2 Non discrimination....................................................................................................................... 2 Minimisation of distorsions (disciplines on specific instruments) .............................................. 3 2. The instruments of trade policy ....................................................................................................... 4 2.1 Tariffs and non-tariff measures .................................................................................................. 4 2.2 Why are quantitative restrictions (QR) bad ? ............................................................................ 4 2.3 Trade-defense instruments and anti-dumping regulations ......................................................... 6 2.4 Measuring the restrictiveness of trade policy ............................................................................ 7 Tarifs moyens............................................................................. Error! Bookmark not defined. Le TTRI et l’OTRI ....................................................................................................................... 8 Mesurer la restrictivité des mesures non tarifaires ...................................................................... 9 3. La politique industrielle ................................................................................................................. 14 4. Le régionalisme .............................................................................................................................. 18 4.1 Les déterminants du commerce bilatéral ................................................................................. 18 4.2 Les accords régionaux.............................................................................................................. 20 4.3 Création et détournement de commerce .................................................................................. 22 4.4 Gains non traditionnels ............................................................................................................ 26 Références .......................................................................................................................................... 27 1 1 General principles 1.1 The evolution of the multilateral trading system The WTO is the guardian of the treaties that form the basis of the multilateral trading system (MTS). Its growing importance relates to its capacity to settle disputes between sovereign states and to its sanction system. A few things to remember: o o o o From Bretton Woods to the WTO Negotiation « rounds » « Mission creep » : from tariffs to NTBs and regulations Dispute settlement: From the first panels to the Appellate body 1.2 Most-favored nation and national treatment principles The MTS’s overarching principles are non discrimination and the minimization of policy-induced distortions. Non discrimination Article I of the GATT (most-favored nation principle) states that all partners should be treated alike: PART I Article I General Most-Favoured-Nation Treatment 1. With respect to customs duties and charges of any kind imposed on or in connection with importation or exportation or imposed on the international transfer of payments for imports or exports, and with respect to the method of levying such duties and charges, and with respect to all rules and formalities in connection with importation and exportation, and with respect to all matters referred to in paragraphs 2 and 4 of Article III,* any advantage, favour, privilege or immunity granted by any contracting party to any product originating in or destined for any other country shall be accorded immediately and unconditionally to the like product originating in or destined for the territories of all other contracting parties. Article III (national treatment) states that “like products” should be treated alike (whether imported or produced domestically) PART II Article III* National Treatment on Internal Taxation and Regulation 1. The contracting parties recognize that internal taxes and other internal charges, and laws, regulations and requirements affecting the internal sale, offering for sale, purchase, transportation, 2 distribution or use of products, and internal quantitative regulations requiring the mixture, processing or use of products in specified amounts or proportions, should not be applied to imported or domestic products so as to afford protection to domestic production. 2. The products of the territory of any contracting party imported into the territory of any other contracting party shall not be subject, directly or indirectly, to internal taxes or other internal charges of any kind in excess of those applied, directly or indirectly, to like domestic products. Moreover, no contracting party shall otherwise apply internal taxes or other internal charges to imported or domestic products in a manner contrary to the principles set forth in paragraph 1. However there are exceptions. The architecture of WTO agreements with respect to national treatment and acceptable exceptions is shown in Figure 1: Figure 1: The architecture of WTO agreements on national treatment Article III (national treatment) Overarching principle Article XX (exceptions) SPS agreement TBT agreement Licensing agreement Trade-facilitation agreement General exceptions Disciplines on specific instruments Procedures Minimisation of distorsions (disciplines on specific instruments) Regulations that can affect international trade are covered by the disciplines of the TBT (Technical Barriers to Trade) and SPS (Sanitary and Phyto-Sanitary measures) agreements. The SPS agreement imposes that measures be based on science : 5.2. In the assessment of risks, Members shall take into account available scientific evidence; relevant processes and production methods; relevant inspection, sampling and testing methods; prevalence of specific diseases or pests; existence of pest — or disease — free areas; relevant ecological and environmental conditions; and quarantine or other treatment. 5.4. Members should, when determining the appropriate level of sanitary or phytosanitary protection, take into account the objective of minimizing negative trade effects. 5.7. In cases where relevant scientific evidence is insufficient, a Member may provisionally adopt sanitary or phytosanitary measures on the basis of available pertinent information, including that from the relevant international organizations as well as from sanitary or phytosanitary measures applied by other Members. In such circumstances, Members shall seek to obtain the additional information necessary for a more objective assessment of risk and review the sanitary or phytosanitary measure accordingly within a reasonable period of time. 3 2. The instruments of trade policy 2.1 Tariffs and non-tariff measures The rise in importance of NTMs reflects partly the proliferation of regulation and partly the fact that tariffs (the other major trade-policy instrument) have come down substantially over the last thirty years, as shown in Figure 2. Figure 2: Average tariffs at the country level against GDP/capita, 1980-2010 30 20 0 10 Tariffs(%) 40 50 MFN Applied Tariff Rates versus GDP per Capita 0 2000 4000 GDP per capita(US dollars) 1980s 2000s 6000 8000 1990s Source : World Bank, 2011 The term « Non-tariff measures » (NTMs) covers all regulations other than tariffs that can affect international trade : o o o o o Taxes Quantitative restrictions (prohibitions, quotas) Technical and SPS regulations Anti-dumping regulations Restrictive commercial practices 2.2 Why are quantitative restrictions (QR) bad ? Article XI of the GATT specifically prohibits QRs: Article XI* General Elimination of Quantitative Restrictions 1.No prohibitions or restrictions other than duties, taxes or other charges, whether made effective through quotas, import or export licences or other measures, shall be instituted or maintained by any contracting party on the importation of any product of the territory of any other contracting party or on the exportation or sale for export of any product destined for the territory of any other contracting party. 4 Why is this? Under perfect competition at home, there is a basic tariff-quota equivalence theorem: For every tariff, one can find a quota that has exactly the same effect on welfare. Figure 3: Tariff-quota equivalence under perfect competition (a) Tarif (b) Quota Prices Prices Domestic demand Domestic demand Residual (after-quota) demand Marginal cost Marginal cost World price plus tariff Tariff A B C D Domestic price A World price B C Quantities D World price Quantities Quantity imported Quota However, when the assumption of perfect competition on the home market is relaxed, a quota is much worse than a tariff. To see this, let us consider the case of a monopoly on the home (importing) market. The way we will proceed is in four steps 1. 2. 3. 4. Monopoly in a closed economy Monopoly under free trade Monopoly with a tariff Monopoly with a quota. The argument is essentially this: In the closed economy, the home firm in a monopoly situation holds back output in order to raise price (standard story). Free trade strips the home firm of its monopoly power. Imposing a tariff allows the home firm to raise its price somehow, but not all the way back to its closed-economy level. That is, a tariff does not hand back monopoly power to the home firm. By contrast, a quota hands it back monopoly power on a silver plate. As a result, the home firm again holds back output (that is, does not create jobs) and jacks up prices, the worst of both worlds (high prices but no jobs!) Figure 4: Non-equivalence in the presence of a monopoly on the importer market (a) Tariff (b) Quota 5 Prices Prices Domestic demand Domestic demand Residual (after-quota) domestic demand Marginal revenue (irrelevant) Marginal cost Domestic price Marginal cost World price plus tariff Tariff A B C D C A D World price World price Quantities Quantities Quota Quantity imported B Upshot of the discussion : When there is market power in the importing country (not necessarily a pure monopoly, but anything that deviates from competition), a quota is the worst way of protecting the home producer from foreign competition. 2.3 Trade-defense instruments and anti-dumping regulations Anti-dumping (AD) regulations allow a country’s producers to complaint to their government about unfair pricing practices by their foreign competitors. The WTO AD agreement allows the importing government to conduct an investigation in order to determine 1. Whether there was dumping in the form of either pricing below cost or pricing exports below the domestic price (see below) 2. Whether there was injury in the importing country (for its domestic producers) 3. Whether the dumping caused the injury. If the answer is yes to all three questions, the government is entitled to impose AD duties on all firms in the exporting country (not just those that actually dumped). After five years, the duties must be re-examined and can be extended only upon justification In reality, AD regulations are a mess. Dumping is defined by the AD agreement as follows: Article 2 Determination of Dumping 2.1 For the purpose of this Agreement, a product is to be considered as being dumped, i.e. introduced into the commerce of another country at less than its normal value, if the export price of the product exported from one country to another is less than the comparable price, in the ordinary course of trade, for the like product when destined for consumption in the exporting country. 2.2 When there are no sales of the like product in the ordinary course of trade in the domestic market of the exporting country or when, because of the particular market situation or the low volume of the 6 sales in the domestic market of the exporting country, such sales do not permit a proper comparison, the margin of dumping shall be determined by comparison with a comparable price of the like product when exported to an appropriate third country, provided that this price is representative, or with the cost of production in the country of origin plus a reasonable amount for administrative, selling and general costs and for profits. Thus, standard business practices, like introducing new products on export markets at a discount, can easily qualify as dumping. Moreover, the calculation of dumping margins is fraught with weird practices. For instance, « zeroing » is a cute way of biasing the result. Here is an example: Exporter’s domestic market (Turkey) Exporter’s foreign market (EU) Prices Prices Dumping margins Transaction 1 120 n/a Transaction 2 95 5 Transaction 3 85 15 ______________________________ Average dumping margin 10 Transaction 1 120 Transaction 2 95 Transaction 3 85 __________________ Normal value 100 In this case, under zeroing the firm is dumping even though it charges the exact same prices on its domestic and export markets. 2.4 Measuring the restrictiveness of trade policy Measuring the overall restrictiveness of a trade-policy stance involves two challenges : o Combining the effects of several types of measures o Aggregating their effects on all goods. This is however very important, because assessments of how restrictive is a country’s policy enter scoring systems used by donors to determine their aid commitments. Average tariffs Overall tariff restrictiveness can be measured by either simple or import-weighted average tariffs. Unfortunately both are biased: o The simple average over-weighs small items o The weighted average under-weighs items with the most restrictive tariffs In addition, neither takes into account the effect of tariff variability, which is a factor of inefficiency in itself from a welfare perspective. To see this, consider the following approximation of the deadweight loss: 7 The TTRI and OTRI The tarif trade restrictiveness index (TTRI) is the rate of a (fictitious) uniform tariff that would give the same welfare level (i.e. that would generate the same deadweight loss) as the current array of tariffs at different rates. It is calculated as follows: The Overall Trade Restrictiveness Index (OTRI) is the rate of a (fictitious) uniform tariff that would give the same aggregate import level (all goods together) as the current array of tariffs at different rates: 8 The MA-OTRI is an export-weighted average of the OTRIs a country faces on its destination markets : It is an inverse measure of a country’s market access; i.e. the higher it is, the more protection a country faces on its export markets. Figure 5 shows that both OTRI and MA-OTRI correlate negatively with income levels ; thus o Poor countries are more protectionist o They face higher barriers on their export markets. Figure 5: Correlation of OTRI and MA-OTRI with income level Source: Kee, Nicita and Olarreaga 2009 However, this is partly a statistical illusion created by the way the OTRI and MA-OTRI are constructed. A country can have a high OTRI and yet grant deep tariff preferences to LDCs. For instance, most industrial countries grant tariff-free, quota-free access to products from sub-Saharan Africa. Thus, E.U. and U.S. MFN tariffs do not concern Africa, even though they enter in the calculation of the E.U. and U.S. OTRI. When calculating the MA-OTRI of an African country, the use of E.U. and U.S. OTRIs is thus misleading. Measuring the restrictiveness of non-tariff measures One can measure the restrictiveness of non-tariff measures (NTMs) in an « artisanal » way by calculating the price gap, i.e. the difference of a given good’s price in an NTM-ridden market vs. a market where no NTM is imposed. For instance, Table 1 shows a price gap calculation for goods 9 affected by import prohibitions in Nigeria. The market affected by the NTM (the import prohibition) is Lagos, Nigeria’s port city, and the comparator market is Nairobi. Cotonou, Benin’s capital, would have been a much better comparator, but there is no price data for Cotonou. Table 1: Price gap calculation for Nigerian import bans Table 1 Price-gap calculations, Lagos vs. Nairobi (percent) Staples Protein Beverages Household supplies 178 61 30 -24 -7 -26 67 -12 Banned products Other Personal care products 194 -17 Total 92 15 Source : EIU, PRMTR calculations On average, goods not affected by import prohibitions are 15% more expensive in Lagos than Nairobi (second line of the table). However, goods affected by prohibitions are 92% more expensive. Thus, the price gap is 92% - 15% = 77%. That is, import prohibitions raise the price of affected products by 77%. This price increase can be fed into household survey data in order to assess the effect on the cost of living at each level of income. Formally, let k be a good and pk the estimated price gap: pk pk pk* (1) Let i be a household and ik the weights of producst k = 1,…, K that this household consumes. The change in real income (here the increase in the cost of living) generated by the NTM for household i is : I i k ik pk (2) In the next step, we calculate the average I i by income bracket; say for each income quartile (bottom 25%, next 25%, and so on). This gives a picture like Figure 6, which shows a regressive effect (a stronger increase in the cost of living, i.e. a deeper cut in real income, for the bottom quartile of the income distribution). Figure 6: Effect of import bans by income quartile 10.0% 9.0% 8.0% 7.0% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% Total 1st Quartile 2nd Quartile 10 3rd Quartile 4th Quartile Source : Treichel et al. 2012 Figure 7 shows the effect of a cash grant equivalent fully compensating the prohibitions’ effect on real income on the distribution of income. The effect looks small on the picture, but given the size of Nigeria’s population, is sufficient to lift three million out of poverty (out of a population of 140 million people). 0 .00001 .00002 .00003 Figure 7: Actual and simulated income distribution 0 20000 40000 60000 80000 100000 x Baseline Simulated Note : Actual income distribution is while import prohibitions are in force. Simulated distribution is as if each household received a cash grant equivalent to the real-income loss generated by the prohibitions; so the first quartile receives a cash grant of 9.1%, the next one 8.9%, and so on. More generally, one can analyze the effect of NTMs by using the variation of prices (or of quantities traded) as the identification mechanism. Using prices, the estimation equation is as follows. Let pij be the price of a good exported from country i to country j and t j the tariff imposed by j. Let n be a type of NTM (n = A for SPS measures, n = B for a TBT measure, etc.). Let x ij be a vector of characteristics of country pair (i,j) including, inter alia, their distance. Let 1 if country j imposes measure n on the product in question otherwise 0 jn And i and j country fixed effects by exporter and importer. The estimation equation is ln pij ln 1 t j n n jn NTMs j n n j jn NTMs interagies avec importateur xij γ i j uij bilateral The ad-valorem equivalent (AVE) of NTM n is1 an e n jn n j jn 1. This expression is obtained by exponentiating the equation above, evaluating it at 1 and at 0 jn jn respectively, dividing the first by the second and subtracting one to get the rate of change of the price. Try it! 1 11 An example of regression results is shown in Table 2. Table 2: Estimated price effect (AVE) of NTMs in sub-Saharan Africa Estimator ln (price gap) (1) Dep. Var.: Within-product Percent Tariff-corrected price gap price gap (2) (3) (4) -0.111 -11.495 -7.999 (0.99) (1.31) (0.60) 0.002 0.210 (0.14) (0.17) 1.272 1.073 (15.54)***(13.48)*** SSA dummy Ln (1 + tariff) COL adjustment Frequency ratios SPS NTM A × SSA TBT NTM B × SSA PSI & Formalities NTM C × SSA Price measures NTM D × SSA QRs NTM E × SSA Observations Number of products Fixed effects Products Countries R-squared (within) 0.113 (2.53)** -0.021 (0.37) 0.018 (0.29) -0.028 (0.29) 0.060 (0.43) 8.619 (2.22)** -0.623 (0.13) 0.466 (0.09) -2.304 (0.24) 7.061 (0.53) 14.002 (2.98)*** -6.934 (1.24) 1.963 (0.38) 4.128 (0.37) 17.794 (1.17) 12.951 (2.16)** 2.596 (0.50) 6.989 (0.97) -1.393 (0.12) 17.937 (1.01) 1'260 42 1'260 42 1'260 42 1'260 42 yes no yes no yes no yes yes 0.34 0.31 0.09 0.12 However, restrictiveness is not the whole story : NTMs address a need for regulatory intervention in order to correct market failures. Figure 8: Effect of a regulation on consumption with a negative externality (a) Avant règlementation (b) Après règlementation 12 Prices & monetary valuations Prices & monetary valuations Domestic demand Domestic demand Consumer surplus NTM compliance cost Foreign supply Foreign supply Consumer surplus reduced Quantities consumed Negative externality reduced (directly and indirectly) Negative externality One should therefore strive to improve them through a logical process rather than eliminate them (Figure 9) : Figure 9: Logical workflow of an NTM review PRIVATE-SECTOR INTERVIEW TRIGGER QUESTIONNAIRE Issue is substantial? No Yes WTO tests o Drop case REGULATOR INTERVIEW FACT-FINDING QUESTIONNAIRE Necessity Market failure? o Propose regulation phase-out No Yes Regulation correctly targets market failure? Proportionality No Yes o Propose regulation redesign Regulatory benefits clearly outweigh its costs? Yes Tradefacilitation team o Debate reglation justification No o Regulation should be kept o Look for ways to redesign it in a cost-minimizing way 13 3. Industrial policy Many governments regularly sollicit advice on how to put in place an industrial policy. How should one justify using taxpayer resources to affect the allocation of resources, given the basic premise that the “invisible hand” does it right? Clearly, like in the case of regulatory interventions in the previous section, the justification must be grounded in the identification of a market failure. The nature of the market failure, however, is likely to be different, having more to do with economies of scale, learning etc. (Figure 10). Figure 10: Non-concave production possibility frontier with economies of scale Sector 1 (traditional) Home relative producer prices at E1 (sector 2 inefficient) International relative prices E1 PPF E2 Sector 2, subject to IRS (to be targeted by IP) Region where sector 2 dispays increasing returns to scale Most governments do it through special economic zones (SEZs) designed to attract FDI (there are over 130 in the world). SEZs typically offer « tax holidays » by which is meant a grace period (usually ten years) during which companies established in the SEZ do not pay any profit or corporate income tax. They also typically have exemptions from duties on their intermediate inputs, have access to simplified administrative procedures, and a special, dedicated infrastructure (energy at less than market rates, special transportation infrastructure like port installations, dedicated telecom infrastructure, and so on). What do governments get out of these costly concessions? 2 They expect to get “good” (highpaying) jobs, export revenue, a better visibility with foreign investors, and a “growth engine” with backward linkages in the local economy. However, apart from big successes (Mauritius, China’s Shenzhen, or Masan in Korea) the evidence so far is not terribly encouraging 2 The tax concessions and dedicated infrastructure can be very costly. Some countries forsake close to half their potential fiscal revenue, which cripples their ability to provide public goods (health, education) to the population at large. Electricity is sometimes sold at half price to large multinational companies which therefore waste it, while the population at large is denied electricity access for very basic needs and hospitals put up with multiple power outages each day. 14 For instance, backward linkages are, in many cases, virtually nonexistent (Figure 11). Figure 11: Backward linkages 45 Percent sourced locally 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Source : World Bank 2013 Salaries do not seem much higher than those offered in the domestic economy (Figure 12) Figure 12: SEZ wage premium relative to average manufacturing wage 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 -50 Source : World Bank 2013 And the jobs do not seem to leverage much the local skills (Figure 13). 15 Figure 13: Percentage of SEZ employees trained in local vocational schools 16.0 14.0 12.0 Percent of workers trained in local vocational training programs 10.0 8.0 6.0 4.0 2.0 - Source : World Bank 2013 Worse, the tax incentives have been driving down average tax rates in developing countries, in particular in sub-Saharan Africa, where they are heading toward zero (Figure 14). Figure 14: Average corporate income tax rates in the world Source: Abbas, Ali; A. Klemm, S. Bedi and J. Park (2012), “A Partial Race to the Bottom: Corporate tax Developments in Emerging and Developing Countries; IMF working paper WP/12/28 This is particularly bad given that FDI seems to be only weakly sensitive to tax incentives. There are spectacular examples of reactivity like when Antigua, a Caribbean island, eliminated the tax on hotels (Figure 15), but this was largely a « beggar-thy-neighbor » policy as it diverted investment away from other Caribeean islands. 16 Figure 15: Tourism investiment in Antigua vs. Windward Islands In general, tax incentives do not compensate for poor business environments (Africa’s problem). Figure 16 distinguishes between recipient countries with poor investment climates (IC), with the orange regression line, and countries with good investment climates, those with the dark blue line. The first line is almost flat and indeed its slope is not significantly different from zero. Figure 16: FDI and the marginal tax rate on corporations Source: James, Sebastian, 2007, “The Effect of Tax Rates on Declared Income: An Analysis of Indian Taxpayer Response to Changes in Income Tax Rates,” Ph.D. diss., Harvard University, quoted in James (2009) Figure 16’s results are confirmed by a panel regression on 47 countries (Table 3: FDI and effective tax rates: Panel regression results). Table 3: FDI and effective tax rates: Panel regression results 17 (lagged) Source: Abbas et al. (2011) Notes: METR: Marginal effective tax rate; EATR: Average effective tax rate. EATR for special regime: régimes miniers ou zones franches. Thus, while the idea that an SEZ could provided a sheltered environment in which the country’s overall governance problems (poor infrastructure, inefficient and corrupt administration, heavy bureaucratic procedures, uncertain investment climate) could be overcome on a limited scale, while appealing, does not seem to work out in practice. If the country is a mess, so will be the SEZ. The only argument that seems to have some reality is that for a government that wants to implement reforms (e.g. lightening labor regulations when they are too heavy, liberalizing imports of intermediates, etc.) but not attack lobbies frontally, an SEZ can provide a way to do it in a limited way and avoid a big political battle. This is what happened in Mauritius and in China. 4. Regionalism 4.1 Determinants of bilateral trade : The gravity equation The gravity equation is the basic workhorse in terms of empirical trade analysis. The analogy with gravity comes from the fact that gravity can be expressed as F gm1m2 / r 2 where F is “the Force”, g is the gravitational constant, m1 and m2 are masses of the two bodies, and r is their bilateral distance . Economic gravity is very similar: Trade between two countries depends on the product of 18 their GDPs (their economic mass) divided by the cost of trade, itself roughly proportional to distance (inter alia). The key difference is that in economics the equivalent of g is not a constant. The gravity equation can be derived in a simple framework where consumer preferences are CES (constant elasticity of substitution) in each country. 3 Let i be the exporting country and j the importing one. Consider a variety produced in country i. Let xij be the quantity exported from i to j (in tons), pij the CIF price of variety i, and E j total expenditure in country j. The share of the variety exported by i in the expenditure of country j is sij , so we can write pij xij sij E j (3) Because of CES preferences, it can be shown (I spare you the proof) that if Pj is a composite price index for country j and is the elasticity of substitution between varieties, 1 p sij ij P j (4) The variable (ad valorem) trade cost is ij and the producer price in i is pi . Suppose that this producer price is the same irrespective of the destination of exports (this is actually a property of the model, not an assumption; it is called « mill pricing »). Then we have pij ij pi (5) Let Vij be the total value of export from i to j, and suppose that i exports ni varieties. Bilateral trade between i and j, all varieties together, is thus 1 p Vij ni pij xij ni sij E j ni ij P j Ej 1 p ni ij i P j (6) Ej Country i’s GDP is the sum of all that it sells or exports, including to itself: 1 p Yi Vij ni ij i P j 1 j 1 j m m Ej (7) Let us now invert this to solve as a function of ni pi1 : ni pi1 Yi i where 3 Le traitement dans cette section suit Baldwin et Taglioni (2006). 19 (8) m E i ij1 1j P j 1 j (9) where the term in the summation is a weighted average of the trade costs i faces. Substituting (9) into (6) gives YE Vij ij1 i 1j P i j (10) Finally, noting that E j Y j (income equals expenditure) we get an expression that looks very much like gravity : Vij ij1 1 YY i j i Pj1 (11) or, in logs and adding control variables and an error term, lnVij 1 ln ij coût du commerce 2 ln Yi 3 ln Y j xi γ1 x j γ 2 uij PIB export. PIB import. (12) controles With importer and exporter fixed effects, the equation drastically simplifies to ln Vij 1 ln ij coût du commerce i j uij (13) EF export. & import. When the gravity equation is estimated on a panel of countries (i.e when several years of data are available), the term 1 / i Pj1 —equivalent to the gravitational constant, called in a trade context the « multilateral resistance term » and measuring a country’s difficulty to trade with all its trade partners—varies over time, so the fixed effects in equation (12) should also be made timedependent (i.e. they should be country×year fixed effects). If the bilateral trade cost ij also varies over time (e.g. with investments in transport infrastructure), the correct estimation equation is: ln Vijt 1 ln ijt it jt uijt (14) Typically, the bilateral trade cost is itself expressed in terms of fundamentals including the possible presence of a common land border, a common language or religion, a common colonial past, and so on. The gravity equation predicts bilateral trade flows in a very reliable way and is used both in order to predict them and to identify the gap between predicted and actual trade flows (« under-trading » ). It can also be used to assess the effect of various trade policy instruments, in particular regional trade agreements, to which we now turn. 4.2 Regional trade agreements « Regionalism » can facilitate trade negotiations within a club of neighboring countries that share other policy objectives (like common security etc.) and have more to share and to gain from an 20 agreement than all countries together in a multilateral round. It thus offers a limited alternative to multilateral (WTO) trade negotiations. It is also very much in fashion, as shown by the growth in the number of trade agreements around the world (Figure 17). Figure 17: Number of trade agreements in force The result of this proliferation is to create very complicated preference structures (a « spaghetti bowl » of agreements, as shown for Bangladesh in Figure 18). Figure 18: Bangladesh’s preferential trade agreements Germany Poland Ukraine Hungary Romania Belarus Former Yugoslavia SAFTA Uzbekistan BIMSTEC Former Czekoslovakia Bulgaria Albania Nepal Afghanistan TPS-PRETAS Uganda Jordan Cameroon Lebanon Guinea Syria Tunisia Lybia UAE Senegal Algeria Sudan Iran Philippines Bhutan Malaysia Pakistan Nigeria Indonesia Turkey Egypt Bangladesh D-8 Lao PDR Korea APTA India Kuweit Sri Lanka Zimbabwe Kenya Mali Maldives Brazil Zambia Source : World Bank (2012) These agreements typically include o Trade liberalization within the bloc 21 Myanmar Cambodia Thailand Vietnam o Cooperation in limited other areas (harmonization of regulations, security, management of water resources, …) It is customary to distinguish four broad type of agreements, in increasing order of deep integration : o o o o Free-trade agreements (FTAs ; example : NAFTA) Customs unions (Mercosur, Russia-Kazakhstan, E.U.-Turkey) Common markets (European Community before Maastricht Treaty) Monetary unions (Eurozone, West Africa). While preferential trade agreements are likely to generate more trade because they entail withinbloc trade liberalization, this trade expansion is not necessarily welfare enhancing. This is a fundamental result derived by Jacob Viner in 1951, to which we now turn. 4.3 Trade creation and trade diversion Trade creation in an FTA generates welfare gains, while trade diversion generates welfare losses. In order to understand the mechanics, let us assume the following 3-country trade structure: Figure 19: Basic trade structure for Vinerian effects Home production competes with imports from B and C imports Country A Country B FTA imports Country C Table 4: Trade creation and trade diversion Case 1: Neither creation nor diversion Producers Domestic price Duty-paid price in A With 20% MFN tariff With tariff only on C A 15.0 B 18.0 C 20.0 15.0 15.0 21.6 18.0 24.0 24.0 A 17.0 B 15.0 C 16.0 17.0 17.0 18.0 15.0 19.2 19.2 A 13.0 B 11.0 C 10.0 13.0 13.0 13.2 11.0 12.0 12.0 Case 2: Trade creation Imports from partner displace inefficient domestic production Producers Domestic price Duty-paid price in A With 20% MFN tariff With tariff only on C Case 3: Trade diversion Imports from partner displace efficient imports from rest of the world Producers Domestic price Duty-paid price in A With 20% MFN tariff With tariff only on C 22 Empirically, the presence of trade creation or diversion can be tested using the gravity equation (which is why I introduced it in this chapter). The first step is to create two dummy variables o The first is equal to one if both importer and exporter are in the preferential bloc, zero otherwise; o The second is equal to one if the importer is in the bloc but not the exporter. If the first has a positive and significant coefficient, case 1 in Table 4 can be ruled out, but one cannot discriminate between cases 2 and 3. If the second comes out with a negative (and significant) coefficient, case 2 can be ruled out and we are in a case of trade diversion. Table 5 gives an illustration using trade data from the East African Community (EAC), which was an FTA until 2004 and a CU from 2005 on. The first dummy is positive and significant, so intrabloc trade was encouraged (see also Figure 20: EAC’s intra-bloc trade rose with out-of-bloc exports), while the second is negative and significant, suggesting Case 3 (trade diversion). Figure 20: EAC’s intra-bloc trade rose with out-of-bloc exports Table 5: Trade creation and diversion in the EAC 23 Dep. Var. Estimator Exporter GDP Importer GDP Distance Common border Common language Common colonial past Exporter real ER Importer real ER Both in EAC, 2001-4 Both in EAC, 2005Importer in EAC, exporter out, 2001-4 Importer in EAC, exporter out, 2005Inverse Mills ratio Constant Observations R-squared Log (trade) Log (trade) OLS (1) Heckman PPML (2) (3) 0.865)*** (15.13) 1.176*** (23.96) -1.582*** (92.09) 0.750*** (8.13) 0.793*** (22.00) 0.829*** (9.33) 0.000** (2.26 -0.000*** (5.37) 1.356*** (3.78) 1.478*** (4.22) -0.211*** (3.47) -0.167** (2.32) 0.72*** (0.07) 1.24*** (0.06) -1.60*** (0.02) 0.75*** (0.10) 0.81*** (0.04) 0.78*** (0.09) 0.00 (0.00) -0.00*** (0.00) n.a. Trade Trade ZIP (4) 1.31*** (0.10) 1.29*** (0.10) -0.86*** (0.03) 0.48*** (0.07) 0.31*** (0.06) -0.03 (0.10) -0.00 (0.00) -0.00*** (0.00) 2.14*** (0.38) n.a. 1.99*** (0.31) -0.20*** -0.17*** (0.06) (0.06) -0.16** 0.00 (0.08) (0.08) 0.03 (0.03) 11.200 11.41*** 6.15*** (37.70)***(0.35) (0.65) 1.30*** (0.10) 1.28*** (0.10) -0.87*** (0.03) 0.48*** (0.07) 0.31*** (0.06) -0.03 (0.10) -0.00** (0.00) 0.00*** (0.00) 2.09*** (0.38) 1.94*** (0.32) -0.19*** (0.07) -0.01 (0.08) 336588 0.76 520,596 283,338 0.758 520,596 6.35*** (0.66) If one wants to go beyond a mere gravity analysis, firm-level data suggests that firms in the region are heavily specialized between those that sell on the regional market and those that sell outside (Figure 21). Figure 21: Distribution of regional shares in firm exports, average 2009-2011 (a) EAC (b) EAC + DRC 24 40 50 40 Percent 30 30 0 0 10 10 20 20 Percent 0 .2 .4 .6 EAC share in firm exports .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 Region's share in firm exports .8 1 Note: The horizontal axis measures the proportion of sales going to the EAC (panel a) or to the region inclusive of the DRC (panel b), in “bins” of 5% each. The vertical axis measures the percentage of firms in each bin. That is, for instance, almost 40% of Tanzania’s exporters were sending over 95% of their exports to the region on average over 2009-2011. Source: Mission calculations using TRA data. Moreover, products exported to regional markets are slightly more intensive in capital and human capital (Figure 22). Figure 22 Factor content of Tanzania’s regional and out-of-region exports, average 2009-2011 (b) Capital intensity 0 0 .1 Frequency .2 Frequency 5.000e-06 .00001 .3 .000015 (a) Human-capital intensity 2 4 6 8 Human-capital intensity Regional exports 10 12 0 Out-of-region exports 50000 100000 150000 200000 Capital intensity (dollars per worker) Regional exports 250000 Out-of-region exports Source: Mission calculations using TRA data and UNCTAD revealed factor intensity database. All this suggests that the regional market acts like a protected market for « infant exporters ». However, the learning does not seem to translate to a migration flow from the group of regional exporters to the group of out-of-region exporters, as transitions are very small (Table 6) 25 Table 6: Annual transition probabilities between exporter categories Non-OECD In between OECD 0.941 0.057 0.014 0.044 0.904 0.039 0.015 0.039 0.947 Non-OECD In between OECD Source: Mission calculations using TRA data. 4.4 Non traditional gains Beyond trade gains, regionalism encourages o More predictability and stability of trade policies o More independence from lobbies, especially in the presence of supranational institutions like the EU Commission. It also encourages cooperation in non-trade areas. 26 References (complete) Abbas, Ali, A. Klemm, S. Bedi and J. Park (2012), “A Partial Race to the Bottom: Corporate Tax Developments in Emerging and Developing Economies”; IMF working paper WP/12/28; Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Baldwin, Richard, and D. Taglioni (2006), ‘Gravity for Dummies and Dummies for Gravity; NBER Working Paper 12516. Carrère, Céline (2006), “Revisiting the effects of regional trade agreements on trade flows with proper specification of the gravity model”; European Economic Review 50, 223-247. Farole, Thomas (2011), Special Economic Zones in Africa: Comparing performance and learning from experience; Washington, DC: The World Bank. Kee, Hiau Looi, A. Nicita, and M. Olarreaga (2009), “Estimating Trade Restrictiveness Indices”; Economic Journal 119, 172-199. Klemm, Alexander, and S. Van Parys (2009), “Empirical Evidence on the Effect of Tax Incentives”; IMF Working Paper 09/136; Washington, DC: IMF. 27