Framing Effects The first step in making a decision is to frame the question. It's also one of the most dangerous steps. Question: Which English county is surrounded by water? The way a problem is framed can profoundly influence the Answer: Isle of Wight – in 1974 it was choices you make. reconstituted as a non-metropolitan ceremonial county which gave it its own Lord Lieutenant and A frame can establish the status quo (recall lecture 3.44) was recognised as a postal county. or introduce an anchor (recall lecture 1.101). It can highlight investment costs or lead you toward confirming evidence. 4.11 Saturday, 12 March 2016 11:21 AM Framing Effects How a question is posed can be crucial, for instance. Have you stopped beating your wife? 4.22 Framing Effects This discussion closely follows that of Kahneman (2011). Not all frames are equal, and some frames are clearly better than alternative ways to describe (or to think about) the same thing. Consider the following pair of problems: 4.33 Framing Effects A woman has bought two $80 tickets to the theatre. When she arrives at the theatre, she opens her wallet and discovers that the tickets are missing. Will she buy two more tickets to see the play? A woman goes to the theatre, intending to buy two tickets that cost $80 each. She arrives at the theatre, opens her wallet, and discovers to her dismay that the $160 with which she was going to make the purchase is missing. She could use her credit card. Will she buy the tickets? In each scenario, what would you do? 4.44 Framing Effects Respondents who see only one version of this problem reach different conclusions, depending on the frame. Most believe that the woman in the first story will go home without seeing the show if she has lost tickets, and most believe that she will charge tickets for the show if she has lost money. 4.55 Framing Effects The explanation should already be familiar - this problem involves mental accounting and the sunk-cost fallacy. The different frames evoke different mental accounts, and the significance of the loss depends on the account to which it is posted. When tickets to a particular show are lost, it is natural to post them to the account associated with that play. The cost appears to have doubled and may now be more than the experience is worth. 4.66 Framing Effects In contrast, a loss of cash is charged to a “general revenue” account - the theatre patron is slightly poorer than she had thought she was, and the question she is likely to ask herself is whether the small reduction in her disposable wealth will change her decision about paying for tickets. Most respondents thought it would not. 4.77 Framing Effects The version in which cash was lost leads to more reasonable decisions. It is a better frame because the loss, even if tickets were lost, is “sunk,” and sunk costs should be ignored. History is irrelevant and the only issue that matters is the set of options the theatre patron has now, and their likely consequences. Whatever she lost, the relevant fact is that she is less wealthy than she was before she opened her wallet. 4.88 Framing Effects If the person who lost tickets were to ask for my advice, this is what I would say: “Would you have bought tickets if you had lost the equivalent amount of cash? If yes, go ahead and buy new ones.” Broader frames and inclusive accounts generally lead to more rational decisions. 4.99 Framing Effects In the next example (Larrick and Soll 2008), two alternative frames evoke different mathematical intuitions, and one is much superior to the other. The paper identified a case in which passive acceptance of a misleading frame has substantial costs and serious policy consequences. Most car buyers list petrol consumption as one of the factors that determine their choice; they know that high-mileage cars have lower operating costs. But the frame that has traditionally been used in the United States - miles per gallon - provides very poor guidance to the decisions of both individuals and policy makers. Consider two car owners who seek to 4.10 10 reduce their costs: Framing Effects Adam switches from a gas-guzzler of 12 mpg to a slightly less voracious guzzler that runs at 14 mpg. The environmentally virtuous Beth switches from a 30 mpg car to one that runs at 40 mpg. Suppose both drivers travel equal distances over a year (say 10,000 miles). Who will save more fuel by switching? 4.11 11 Framing Effects You almost certainly share the widespread intuition that Beth's action is more significant than Adam's: she reduced mpg by 10 miles rather than 2, and by a third (from 30 to 40) rather than a sixth (from 12 to 14). If the two car owners both drive 10,000 miles, Adam will reduce his consumption from a scandalous 833 gallons to a still shocking 714 gallons, for a saving of 119 gallons. Beth's use of fuel will drop from 333 gallons to 250, saving only 83 gallons. The mpg frame is wrong, and it should be replaced by the gallons-per-mile frame (or litres-per-100 kilometres, which is used in most other countries). As Larrick and Soll (2008) point out, the misleading intuitions fostered by the mpg frame are likely to mislead policy makers as well as car buyers. Hyundai and Kia settle US mileage claims - FT - 3 Nov 2014 Groups hit with $300m penalties for overstating fuel economy. The businesses will pay $100m, the largest civil penalty in the history of the US Clean Air Act and will forfeit greenhouse gas 4.12 12 emission credits with an estimated value of more than $200m. Framing Effects A directive about organ donation in case of accidental death is noted on an individual's driver license in many countries. The formulation of that directive is another case in which one frame is clearly superior to the other. Few people would argue that the decision of whether or not to donate one's organs is unimportant, but there is strong evidence that most people make their choice thoughtlessly. The evidence comes from a comparison of the rate of organ donation in European countries, which reveals startling differences between neighbouring and culturally similar countries. 4.13 13 Framing Effects Johnson and Goldstein (2003) noted that the rate of organ donation was close to 100% in Austria but only 12% in Germany, 86% in Sweden but only 4% in Denmark. 4.14 14 Framing Effects These enormous differences are a framing effect, which is caused by the format of the critical question. The highdonation countries have an opt out form, where individuals who wish not to donate must check an appropriate box. Unless they take this simple action, they are considered willing donors. The low-contribution countries have an opt-in form: you must check a box to become a donor. That is all. The best single predictor of check a box to become a donor. That is all. The best single predictor of whether or not people will donate their organs is the designation of the default 4.15 15 option that will be adopted without having to check a box. Framing Effects People will check the box if they have already decided what they wish to do. If they are unprepared for the question, they have to make the effort of thinking whether they want to check the box. I imagine an organ donation form in which people are required to solve a mathematical problem in the box that corresponds to their decision. One of the boxes contains the problem 2 + 2 = ?4 The problem in the 491 The rate of donations other box is 13 × 37 = ??? would surely be swayed. 4.16 16 Framing Effects When the role of formulation is acknowledged, a policy question arises: Which formulation should be adopted? In this case, the answer is straight forward. If you believe that a large supply of donated organs is good for society, you will not be neutral between a formulation that yields almost 100% donations and another formulation that elicits donations from 4% of drivers. 4.17 17 Framing Effects Reference Point People’s trading decisions are affected by reference points, which act as performance benchmarks. Suppose you are asked the question: Primus owns 100 shares of an asset, originally bought at 100. Secunda owns 100 shares of the same asset, originally bought at 200. The price of the share was 160 yesterday and it is 150 today. Who is more upset? It is the initial price, which determines how the stock is doing. 4.18 18 Framing Effects Reference Point A consequence of this is the disposition effect: an investor who needs cash and owns two stocks is much more likely to sell the stock whose price has gone up; see Odean (1998a). 4.19 19 Framing Effects - The Disposition Effect This discussion closely follows that of Kahneman (2011). A mistake that afflicts individual investors when they sell stocks from their portfolio: 4.20 20 Framing Effects - The Disposition Effect You need money to cover the costs of your daughter’s wedding and will have to sell some stock. You remember the price at which you bought each stock and can identify it as a “winner,” currently worth more than you paid for it, or as a loser. Among the stocks you own, Blueberry Tiles is a winner; if you sell it today you will have achieved a gain of $5,000. You hold an equal investment in Tiffany Motors, which is currently worth $5,000 less than you paid for it. The value of both stocks has been stable in recent weeks. Which are you more likely to sell? What would you do? 4.21 21 Framing Effects - The Disposition Effect A plausible way to formulate the choice is this: “I could close the Blueberry Tiles account and score a success for my record as an investor. Alternatively, I could close the Tiffany Motors account and add a failure to my record. Which would I rather do?” If the problem is framed as a choice between giving yourself pleasure and causing yourself pain, you will certainly sell Blueberry Tiles and enjoy your investment prowess. As might be expected, finance research has documented a massive preference for selling winners rather than losers — a bias that has 4.22 22 been given an opaque label: the disposition effect. Framing Effects - The Disposition Effect The disposition effect is an instance of narrow framing. The investor has set up an account for each share that she bought, and she wants to close every account as a gain. A rational agent would have a comprehensive view of the portfolio and sell the stock that is least likely to do well in the future, without considering whether it is a winner or a loser. 4.23 23 Framing Effects Reference Point Selling losers and buying winners is referred to as a momentum investment strategy (Hong and Stein, 1998). It is believed to outperform the contrarian investment strategy, that is selling winners and buying losers. Yet, investors will be “disposed” to sell winners too soon and hold losers too long. Shefrin and Statman (1985) accordingly labeled this the disposition effect. 4.24 24 Review It is remarkably difficult to consistently outperform passive index returns with active strategies for trading and investing. A review by Barber and Odean (2011) found that individual investors routinely underperform relevant benchmarks. This is due in part to biases in perception and decision-making. For example, investors tend to overweight recent performance, allowing that to colour subsequent decisions. Investors also tend to hold losing trades while disposing of winners, creating negatively skewed tails of returns. They commonly engage in strategies that bring pleasure and avoid those that are associated with pain. That turns out to be unhelpful when a prompt taking of losses is a prudent 4.25 25 course of action. Review Interestingly, the authors also found that individual investors suffer from a lack of diversification in their portfolios – a failure to generate a rich array of different trading ideas. Investors also trade quite actively on average, with returns notably hurt by transaction costs. Indeed, evidence suggests that active trading actually diminishes financial returns. Summarising this evidence, Barber and Odean express wonder as to “why investors trade so much and to their detriment” (p. 15). The Greatest Psychological Hurdle To Trading And Investment Performance - Forbes - 12 April 2015 4.26 26 Review Barber and Odean (2011) provide an overview of research on the stock trading behaviour of individual investors. This research documents that individual investors 1 underperform standard benchmarks (e.g., a low cost index fund), 2 sell winning investments while holding losing investments (the “disposition effect”), 3 are heavily influenced by limited attention and past return performance in their purchase decisions, 4 engage in naïve reinforcement learning by repeating past behaviours that coincided with pleasure while avoiding past behaviours that generated pain 5 tend to hold undiversified stock portfolios. These behaviours deleteriously affect the financial well being of individual investors. 4.27 27 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Research shows the pervasiveness of framing effects: two logically equivalent statements of a problem lead decision-makers to choose different options. 4.28 28 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Framing effects typically involve differing frames whose logical equivalence is neither totally transparent nor terribly obscure, and the ways in which decisions are influenced is typically predictable by the features emphasized by the frames. The most predictable influences of framing on choice relate to loss aversion and diminishing sensitivity, as outlined above. Because losses resonate with people more than gains, a frame that highlights the losses associated with a choice, makes that choice less 4.29 29 attractive. Framing Effects Pervasiveness Similarly, a frame that exploits diminishing sensitivity by making losses appear small relative to the scales involved makes that choice more attractive (£ or £,000). Kahneman and Tversky (1979) introduced framing by means of the observation that a reference point may shift in such a way that a gain appears to be a loss or a loss appears to be a gain. 4.30 30 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Verbal labels may make a reference point salient, for instance, the content of meat products may be framed either as P% fat-free (making 0% fat-free the reference point) or (100-P)% fat (making 100% fat the reference point). P% fat-free will then appear to be a gain and be more positively evaluated than (100-P)% fat which appears to be a loss. Dehydration 4.31 31 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Levin and Gaeth (1988) found that whether fat content of meat was described as percentage fat or percentage fat-free even affected the taste of the meat. 4.32 32 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Tversky and Kahneman (1986, p. S254-5) give the following example of framing effects, taken from a study of medical decisions by McNeil et al. (1982): 4.33 33 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Respondents were given statistical information about the outcomes of two treatments of lung cancer. The same statistics were presented to some respondents in terms of mortality rates and to others in terms of survival rates. The respondents then indicated their preferred treatment. The information was presented exactly as follows. 4.34 34 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Problem (Survival frame) Surgery: Of 100 people having surgery 90 live through the post-operative period, 68 are alive at the end of the first year and 34 are alive at the end of five years. Radiation Therapy: Of 100 people having radiation therapy all live through the treatment, 77 are alive at the end of one year and 22 are alive at the end of five years. Please note down the key figures. 4.35 35 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Problem (Mortality frame) Surgery: Of 100 people having surgery 10 die during surgery or the post-operative period, 32 die by the end of the first year and 66 die by the end of five years. Radiation Therapy: Of 100 people having radiation therapy, none die during treatment, 23 die by the end of one year and 78 die by the end of five years. Please note down the key figures. 4.36 36 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Survival Mortality Surgery Radiation Surgery Radiation Initial After treatment 100 90 100 100 100 100-90 100 100-100 Year 1 68 77 100-68 100-77 Year 5 34 22 100-34 100-22 4.37 37 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Survival Mortality Surgery Radiation Surgery Radiation Initial After treatment 100 90 100 100 100 10 100 0 Year 1 68 77 32 23 Year 5 34 22 66 78 4.38 38 Framing Effects Pervasiveness The inconsequential difference in formulation produced a marked effect. The overall percentage of respondents who favoured radiation therapy rose from 18% in the survival frame (n = 247) to 44% in the mortality frame (n = 336). The advantage of radiation therapy over surgery evidently looms larger when stated as a reduction of the risk of immediate death from 10% to 0% rather than as an increase from 90% to 100% in the rate of 4.39 39 survival. Framing Effects Pervasiveness The framing effect was not smaller for experienced physicians or for statistically sophisticated business students than for a group of clinic patients. This question is hypothetical, and real stakes might change the level of care that subjects give to the problem. Controlled experiments of the issues above would be problematic. 4.40 40 Framing Effects Pervasiveness But the fact that experienced physicians make the same mistakes suggests that similar patterns might play out in the real world. Similar framing effects were found in choices over lotteries with small monetary stakes. More generally, it would be wrong to think that framing effects only matter when stakes are small, when the framing of the choices obscures the appropriate choice in an exceedingly subtle way, or when the decision context is hypothetical or noneconomic. 4.41 41 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Tversky and Kahneman (1986, S251-278) cite some important real-world examples of framing effects. As an illustration they approached respondents in a telephone interview who evaluated the fairness of the action described in the following vignette, which was presented in two versions that differed only in the bracketed clauses. 4.42 42 Framing Effects Pervasiveness A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment [but no inflation]. The company decides to [decrease wages and salaries 7%] this year. Is this fair? 4.43 43 Framing Effects Pervasiveness A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment [and inflation of 12%]. The company decides to [increase salaries only 5%] this year. Is this fair? 4.44 44 Framing Effects Pervasiveness A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment [but no inflation]. The company decides to [decrease wages and salaries 7%] this year. A company is making a small profit. It is located in a community experiencing a recession with substantial unemployment [and inflation of 12%]. The company decides to [increase salaries only 5%] this year. 4.45 45 Framing Effects Pervasiveness Although the loss of real income is very similar in the two versions, the proportion of respondents who judged the action of the company "unfair" or "very unfair" was 62% for a nominal reduction (first case) but only 22% for a nominal increase (second case). 4.46 46 Framing Effects Compartmentalization People often fail to take into account the joint effect of their decisions. Suppose you are asked the question: You face two concurrent decisions. Examine both decisions and state the options you prefer for each decision (note your choice for both A and B). Decision A: choose between a sure gain of 2,400 and a 25% chance of a gain of 10,000 (75% for no gain). Record your choices Decision B: choose between a sure loss of 7,500 and 4.47 47 a 75% chance of a loss of 10,000 (25% for no loss). Framing Effects Compartmentalization In accord with loss aversion, most people tend to choose the sure gain in A and the gamble in B. Now, consider the following question: Choose between a 25% chance to win 2,400 and a 75% chance to lose 7,600 versus a 25% chance to win 2,500 and a 75% chance to lose 7,500. Record your choice There is no doubt about the right choice: the second 4.48 48 option dominates the first one. Framing Effects Compartmentalization However, note that the pair chosen in the first question amounts to the inferior option, while the pair rejected is equivalent to the dominating choice in the A/B problem. As detailed in the following slides. People find it easier to deal with decisions one at a time and tend to forget the overall picture. 4.49 49 Framing Effects Compartmentalization In case you missed the link, most people tend to choose the sure gain in A and the gamble in B. Decision A: sure gain of 2,400 Decision B: 75% chance of a loss of 10,000 (So 2,400 plus either 0 at 25% or -10,000 at 75%. That is 2,400 at 25% or (2,400-10,000) at 75%.) That is 25% chance to win 2,400 and a 75% chance to lose 7,600 . The first combined option. 4.50 50 Framing Effects Compartmentalization In case you missed the link, most people tend to reject the gamble in A and the sure loss in B. Decision A: 25% chance of a gain of 10,000 Decision B: sure loss of 7,500 (So -7,500 plus either 10,000 at 25% or 0 at 75%. That is 2,500 at 25% or (0-7,500) at 75%.) That is 25% chance to win 2,500 and a 75% chance to lose 7,500. The second combined option. 4.51 51 Framing Effects Compartmentalization A common effect is the use of a “mental accounting” strategy by which people classify their savings (or expenses) in different segments and deal with them in different ways; for instance, a windfall rise in income rarely finds its way in the (mentally separated category of) retirement savings or health insurance. 4.52 52 Framing Effects Compartmentalization Mental accounting refers to how people categorize and evaluate financial outcomes (Henderson and Peterson, 1992). Shefrin and Thaler (1988) assume that people categorize wealth in three mental accounts: current income, current wealth and future income. It is further more assumed that the propensity to consume is greatest from the current income account and smallest from the future-income account. 4.53 53 Framing Effects Framing refers to the way our decisions are affected by the way information is presented. For instance, framing can influence whether we see a glass as half empty or half full. The same glass framed different ways can be perceived differently depending on the context. In the strip, Dogbert and his client describe as "dumb" those shoppers who think something labelled as "50 percent off" must be a bargain. Yet the client considers himself a "genius" when he falls victim to the same bias. Cartoon (Kramer 2014) Framing shows up again in the strip when Dilbert's boss frames Dilbert's lack of a salary raise relative to the alternative of being attacked by bears, which 4.54 54 Dilbert finds compelling. Cartoon (Kramer 2014) Framing Effects - Avoidance Hammond et al., 2006 1. Don't automatically accept the initial frame, whether it was formulated by you or by someone else. Always try to reframe the problem in various ways. Look for distortions caused by the frames. 2. Try posing problems in a neutral, redundant way that combines gains and losses or embraces different reference points. For example: Would you accept a fifty-fifty chance of either losing $300, resulting in a bank balance of $1,700, or winning $500, resulting in a bank balance of $2,500? 4.55 55 Framing Effects - Avoidance 3. Think hard throughout your decision-making process about the framing of the problem. At points throughout the process, particularly near the end, ask yourself how your thinking might change if the framing changed. 4. When others recommend decisions, examine the way they framed the problem. Challenge them with different frames. 4.56 56 A “Real” World Application In his booklet (Lynn 2010) provides instruction for servers’ in the psychology of tipping as well as specific techniques that can be used to earn larger tips. All the suggested techniques have been scientifically tested and the evidence of their effectiveness is described along with the techniques. Using even a few of these techniques should increase servers' tips by 10% to 30%. As an aside Does Weather Actually Affect Tipping? An Empirical No! Analysis of Time-Series Data Sean Masaki Flynn And Adam Eric Greenberg Journal of Applied Social Psychology Volume 42, Issue 3, pages 702–716, March 2012 DOI: 10.1111/j.1559-1816.2011.00813.x 4.57 57 A “Real” World Application What’s in it for the employer? Managers might expect 1 2 3 Increased sales Greater Customer Satisfaction Lower labour costs due to reduced server turnover 4.58 58 A “Real” World Application The methods Tipping Expert Lynn 2010 1. Wear Something Unusual 2. Introduces Yourself By Name 3. Sell, Sell, Sell – increased sales means increased tips 4. Crouch Next To The Table (crouch – bend down) 5. Touch Your Customers 6. Entertain Your Customers 7. Repeat Customers’ Orders 8. Call Your Customers By Name 9. Draw On The Bill () 10. Use Credit Card Insignia (On The Trays And Bill Folders) - as we see in the group case study 5 11. Smile 12. Write “Thank You” On The Bill 13. Forecast Good Weather 14. Give Customers Sweets (Mints) 4.59 59 A “Real” World Application Parrett (2015) looks at the effect of beauty on earnings using restaurant tipping data. Customers were surveyed as they left a set of five Virginia restaurants about the dining experience, their server, and themselves, including about their tip and their server’s beauty and productivity. It is found that attractive servers earn approximately $1261 more per year in tips than unattractive servers, the primary driver of which is female customers tipping attractive females more than unattractive females. Potential explanations of this earnings gap are drawn from both the labour and experimental economics literatures, the most compelling of which is customer taste-based discrimination. • • • • Attractive servers earn roughly $1261 more per year than unattractive servers. Beauty has a larger impact on female than male server earnings. Beauty matters more for female than male customers. Findings attributable to customer taste-based discrimination. 4.60 60 A “Real” World Application Azar et al. (2015) consider tipping behaviour which is analysed in a field experiment where restaurant customers received excessive change, either 10 or 40 Shekels (about $3 versus $12). One third of the tables reported the extra change to the server and returned it. Tips were higher with the higher level of extra change. Returning the extra change was negatively correlated with tips. The interaction between the level of extra change and whether it was returned had no effect. Possible explanations that tips are higher when the excessive change is not returned due to a positive income effect or perceiving paying a tip out of excessive change as less costly, because it is a forgone gain and not a loss, are not supported by the data. 4.61 61 A “Real” World Application Subjects may have exhibited moral licensing and moral cleansing effects. These effects, however, were possibly mitigated by a self-selection effect going in the opposite direction: those who are more generous or altruistic by their nature are more likely to return the extra change and also more likely to tip generously. Receiving the larger amount of extra change may result in feelings of good mood, perceived luckiness, or individuation and unconscious fear of being observed, which increase tips. Interestingly, these feelings seem to remain even if the extra change was returned. • • • • A field experiment on how excessive change to restaurant customers affects tipping. Customers tipped more when the excessive change was higher (40 versus 10 Shekels). Tips were higher when the excessive change was not returned. The interaction between the extra change and whether it 4.62 62 was returned had no effect. Persuasion by Way of Example An additional study examined the role of gratuity guidelines on tipping behaviour in restaurants. When diners were finished with their meals, they were given bills that either did or did not include calculated examples, informing them what various percentages of their bill would amount to. Results indicated that parties who received the gratuity examples left significantly higher tips than did those receiving no examples. Seiter et al. 2011 “Persuasion by Way of Example: Does Including Gratuity Guidelines on Customers' Checks Affect Restaurant Tipping Behaviour?” Journal of Applied Social Psychology 41 150-159. 4.63 63 Tipping in the UK New research in the UK has revealed that the average tip on top of the bill is £4.18, and the average percentage is nine per cent. And it's no longer only for exceptional service, with 87 per cent of adults always leaving a tip - but men are much less likely to tip in a restaurant than women. The survey of 2,000 adults, released by restaurant booking service OpenTable, found that 17 per cent of men never leave a gratuity compared to just 10 per cent of women. The research also uncovered differences across the country, with Londoners tipping the most, but Scots 4.64 64 being the most likely to leave a tip. Tipping in the UK The average tipping spend in the capital comes to £5.68. The Scots are the most likely to tip (91 per cent) - with half of Aberdeen's diners always leaving a tip and 47 per cent of Glaswegians still leaving a tip even if they receive less than perfect service. Yorkshire was revealed as the region most likely to never leave a tip, with only 1 in 5 (20 per cent) saying they would leave a gratuity. Women make the most generous tippers as London leaves biggest tips - Daily Mail 13 May 2015 Scots are most likely to tip, Londoners are very generous, and half of Yorkshire diners ask for service charges to be REMOVED: Tipping habits across the UK revealed - Daily Mail - 13 May 2015 4.65 65 Clothing Colour and Tipping Gentlemen Patrons Give More Tips to Waitresses With Red Clothes Red, relative to other achromatic or chromatic colours, led men to view women presented on a photograph as more attractive. The effect of colour on behaviour was tested in a tipping context. Eleven waitresses in five restaurants were instructed to wear the same tee shirt with different colours. The effect of colour on tipping according to patron’s gender was measured. 4.66 66 Clothing Colour and Tipping It was found that waitresses wearing red received more tips but only with male patrons. Waitresses colour had no effect on female patrons’ tipping behaviour. The relation between red and sexual attractiveness are used to explain the results. Managerial interests related with clothing appearance were discussed. N. Guéguen and C. Jacob, 2014 “Clothing colour and tipping: gentlemen patrons give more tips to waitresses with red clothes” Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Research 38(2) 275-280. 4.67 67 Tipping is more prevalent in countries that are more corrupt Using data on tipping behaviour in 32 countries (collected from The International Guide to Tipping) and comparing this against the Corruption Perception Index, researchers found that rates of corruption are higher in countries that tip more (the correlation was 0.6 where 1 would be a perfect match). This may strike some as odd - tipping is often seen as altruistic, whereas corruption is immoral. Yet, the researchers propose that tipping to ensure future good service is comparable to a bribe and this could explain the puzzling association (Torfason et al. 2012). 4.68 68 Tipping is more prevalent in countries that are more corrupt In a final study, researchers primed 40 US undergraduates with either a future-oriented or past-oriented approach to tipping. For this they used two versions of text ostensibly taken from the Emily Post etiquette guide. After reading that tipping should be performed as a way to ensure good service in the future (as opposed to rewarding past good service), the students tended to view two accounts of political and legal bribery more leniently. 4.69 69 Tipping is more prevalent in countries that are more corrupt "The studies reported here highlight a psychological mechanism that may help explain the surprising association between tipping and bribery both within and across countries," the researchers said. They added that the findings raise some intriguing possibilities - for example, might encouraging people to give tips specifically as a reward for past good service act to reduce the tolerance of bribery in society? Magnus Thor Torfason, Francis J. Flynn, and Daniella Kupor (2012). Here Is a Tip: Prosocial Gratuities Are Linked to Corruption. Social Psychological and Personality Science. Tipping is more prevalent in countries that are more corrupt - BPS Research Digest 4.70 70 Is Tipping Dead? New York restaurateur Danny Meyer hits tipping point - FT - 15 Oct 2015 Danny Meyer, the man behind some of New Yorks best-known restaurants such as Gramercy Tavern and The Modern, is ending the practice of tipping across all his premises in a move that will be watched closely by other restaurateurs. Mr. Meyer, who also founded Shake Shack, said in an open letter on Wednesday that he had found that the main obstacle to providing career opportunities for his 1,800 staff at Union Square Hospitality Group was the practice of tipping. Shake Shack's founder is banning tips at all his restaurants - Yahoo Finance 4.71 71 Technology? Future restaurant waiters will respond to taps instead of tips - FT 10 Sept 2015 Service has always been labour intensive but the technological barriers to automating it are falling. The restaurant Eatsa in San Francisco is a restaurant without employees, to be more precise no visible ones. There is a staff of five or six cooks assembling the bowls, but they work completely behind the scenes. The typical customer interacts with zero Eatsa employees on a typical visit: they order and pay via a smartphone or tablet, then pick up their food from a cubbyhole displaying their name. Prices are low, and initial reviews are quite good. Mark Oleynik, Moley Robotics: The Russian scientist who wants to replace chefs with robots 4.72 72 Technology? Why bartenders have to ignore some signals: Research into pub communication with robot James continues -ScienceDaily -- 25 Nov 2015 A robotic bartender has to do something unusual for a machine: It has to learn to ignore some data and focus on social signals. Researchers recently investigated how a robotic bartender can understand human communication and serve drinks socially appropriately. Ghost-in-the-Machine reveals human social signals for human– robot interaction Sebastian Loth, Katharina Jettka, Manuel Giuliani, Jan P. de Ruiter Frontiers in Psychology, 2015; 6 DOI: 10.3389/fpsyg.2015.01641 Test persons put themselves in the role of bartender robot James at the computer. 4.73 73 Technology? Dining technology use is no measure of value, Clemson researchers find - Clemson University - 25 Sept 2015 Have you ever been dissatisfied with a restaurant experience because the customer-service technology you had to use to reserve a table, order your food or pay for the meal wasn't up to par? Researchers aren't surprised. According to their findings, organizations often gauge the effectiveness and value of a customer service technology based solely on its use, which could be a costly mistake when they decide where to invest their technology dollars. Dining technology use is no measure of value, 4.74 74 researchers find -- ScienceDaily -- 25 Sept 2015 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Cynical tricks restaurants use to make you spend more revealed - Daily Mail - 18 Aug 2014 By Vincent Graff Why that “special” on the menu is a recipe for taking your cash: Revealed, the cynical tricks restaurants use to make you spend more What’s so special about a restaurant’s “daily special”? It’s a familiar ritual. You’re sitting down, you’ve been handed the menu and the waitress launches into a florid description of an item that isn’t printed on the sheet she gave you. 4.75 75 Restaurants Are A Mine Field If you’re lucky, the “special” is just that, something delicious that the chef has whipped up from fresh ingredients that caught his eye at the market this morning. But very often the special — or “chef’s recommendation”, or “dish of the day” — is special only because it’s the most profitable item on sale, and the restaurant knows it will sell many more if the waitress singles it out for attention. 4.76 76 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Restaurants also know that most diners are too shy or embarrassed to ask for the price of the special — and, guess what, the waitress “forgot” to mention what the dish will cost you. The fake special is just one of the secret weapons restaurants deploy to make us spend more than we intend to when we go out to eat. In fact, the tricks begin as soon as you’re handed the menu (Poundstone 2014). Priceless | William Poundstone | Macmillan 4.77 77 Restaurants Are A Mine Field And because we don’t know they’re doing it, they’re nearly always successful. For, whether we like it or not, every time we go out to eat, the restaurants are playing mind games with us — while we remain, mostly, innocently oblivious. “People rarely go into restaurants knowing exactly what they want to order or how much they want to spend,” explains Poundstone. “And we can be influenced by all sorts of things that we’re not aware of.” 4.78 78 Restaurants Are A Mine Field At the centre of all this is the humble menu. You might think that the restaurant menu merely tells you what items are available in a certain establishment. Actually, it is a very sophisticated piece of advertising. In fact, it’s the only piece of advertising that restaurant owners can be certain their customers will read. As a result, restaurants invite in “menu consultants” whose job it is to lay out a menu that will persuade you to spend more money than you’d expected. 4.79 79 Restaurants Are A Mine Field You may, for instance, have noticed that increasingly the prices on menus no longer employ the pound sign — or even any evidence of pence. Where once a steak might have cost you “£16.00” now its price is stated as “16”. Pound signs are disappearing from menus as quickly as cod are vanishing from the oceans. And not just at fashionable restaurants. There are no pound signs at Carluccio’s, Byron, Giraffe or Cafe Rouge either. 4.80 80 Restaurants Are A Mine Field This is not a coincidence. A study (Yang et al. 2009) found that when, in a similar move, dollar signs were left off a menu, sales increased by eight per cent. Why so? $ or Dollars: Effects of Menu-price Formats on Restaurant Checks - Cornell School of Hotel Administration 4.81 81 Restaurants Are A Mine Field When eating out in a restaurant, consider the sounds around you. Is there music playing? Just the gentle hum of other people’s conversations? Maybe it’s loud and booming, maybe it’s relatively quiet. Whatever the acoustic atmosphere, it could be affecting how you experience the flavour of the food and drink you’re consuming, according to a growing body of research (Yan and Dando R. 2015). Simple, says Poundstone. “the more space you devote to something on a menu, the more people pay attention to it.” 4.82 82 Restaurants Are A Mine Field “so if you have a pound sign and the number of pence, it takes up more space on the page — and more space in your mental attention.” “And obviously the restaurant does not want you to choose your food on the basis of price.” That’s also the reason why menus very often feature the items and their prices centred on the page, rather than having the prices all lined up in a tidy column on the right-hand side. If all the prices appear neatly one above another, says Poundstone, that just invites us to compare one against the other — which is the last thing the restaurant wants us to do. 4.83 83 Restaurants Are A Mine Field For that same reason, you now never see dots leading the eye from the description of the item to the price. Another key trick is known as “anchoring”. This is where a restaurant places a highly expensive dish prominently on the menu — solely in order to make the other dishes nearby appear relatively cheap. At Marco Pierre White’s Marco Grill in London, there’s a 35oz Tomahawk steak on sale for £70. Restaurants do not expect to sell many of these costly “anchor” items, says Poundstone. 4.84 84 Restaurants Are A Mine Field That is not their job — instead they are simply there to make the other dishes look like good value. Suddenly spending £21 on a plate of Marco’s grilled Dorset lemon sole doesn’t seem so outlandish. A lot of research has also gone into where we look when we first open a menu. It’s estimated that we read a menu for 109 seconds on average. Studies have shown that when presented with a list we remember best the item at the very start, and the one at the end — it’s the way our memories work. 4.85 85 Restaurants Are A Mine Field We will also turn our eyes first to the top right-hand corner of a page in front of us, whether it be a doublepage or single-sheet menu. So that corner, of course, is usually where the most profitable items are placed. Poundstone says some of the other techniques are so commonplace, they seem unremarkable. Why might an item on the menu have a box around it? It’s not because it’s a dish the chef is particularly proud of, it’s because it earns a high profit for the restaurant. 4.86 86 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Alternatively, the menu might use other methods to draw our attention: an item in a different colour; an accompanying illustration; a different typeface. Spence and Piqueras-Fiszman (2014) are alert to the techniques in play. Wiley: The Perfect Meal: The Multisensory Science of Food and Dining - Charles Spence, Betina PiquerasFiszman 4.87 87 Restaurants Are A Mine Field “I was in the burger restaurant Byron the other day,” he says. “the menu is all in black and white, except for one item, which is highlighted in bright red. And it’s their most expensive item.” Spence and Piqueras-Fiszman (2014) say that people are also likely to spend more if menus — and especially wine lists — are heavy to handle. And of course, even the words that menus use can persuade us to splash out. 4.88 88 Restaurants Are A Mine Field At the restaurant chain Giraffe — which was bought last year for £49 million by Tesco, a company that knows all about parting us from our cash — the toast is “artisan sourdough toast”, the chicken nuggets have a “sesame crunch coating” and the salsa is “fiery red roasted chipotle salsa”. Meanwhile the bresaola at Jamie Oliver’s, Jamie’s Italian, is “elegant slices of cured beef” and at West End eaterie The Ivy, in London, there’s an “heirloom tomato salad” and the carrots and beetroots are both labelled “heritage”. 4.89 89 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Spence and Piqueras-Fiszman (2014) say: “there’s research that demonstrates that if you give food a more descriptive label, people will enjoy it more — and they’ll also pay more for it.” One common example of this is to attach somebody’s name to a dish. At Randall & Aubin restaurant in London’s Soho, they serve “slow roast Aubrey Allen pork belly”. Few, if any, of the punters will realise who Aubrey Allen is. For all anyone knows, it could be the name of the boy who sweeps up the pork fat in the abattoir. In fact, it’s the name of the butcher — based in a Coventry business park — who supplied the meat. 4.90 90 Restaurants Are A Mine Field The “chef’s recommendation” or “dish of the day” is special because it is the most profitable item on sale and the restaurant knows it will sell more if the waitress singles it our for attention “this is a classic technique,” say Spence and PiquerasFiszman (2014) . “It could be any name there at all. But attaching the words “Aubrey Allen” makes the dish feel like it’s more carefully chosen. It’s not just any old pork belly. And that allows them to put a premium on it.” If it’s any comfort, it’s not just us poor punters who are victims of these mean tricks. 4.91 91 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Restaurateur Russell Norman is the owner of a string of successful restaurants in London, including Polpo in Notting Hill. He is also innocent of all the sales ploys detailed here (except one: his menus do not use pound signs). “My pet hate is the use of hyperbole on menus,” he says. “When chefs or restaurateurs describe dishes as “delicious”, “mouth-watering” or “gorgeous”, I always think: “How dare you! I will be the judge of that, thank you very much.” ” But the other day, while on holiday in New York, even he fell victim to “anchoring”. 4.92 92 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Visiting a restaurant, he was mulling over which wine to choose from a list which featured several bottles that cost $2,500 (£1,500). “And because they had so many bottles that cost so much, I ended up buying a bottle of wine for $90 (£54). That’s nearly double what I’d normally spend. But they’d made it look cheap by comparison. “I’m a restaurateur — and I was still suckered!” 4.93 93 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Rotating your plate as it is placed on the table may improve the taste of your food, psychologists claim. People have a subconscious preference for food that points away from them, according to Oxford University experts, to the extent that it can affect the flavour. An experiment involving 12,000 people, carried out at London’s Science Museum, suggests that most people prefer their meal to be aligned facing away from them, and marginally to the right. Rotating plates: How orientation can make your food taste better | Inside the Red Onions, Science Museum Tapioca, Sugar Cane Vinegar, Peanut and Want a tasty meal? Try rotating your plate!Cream Diners prefer meals facing away from Fermented them and pointing marginally to the right - Daily Mail - 11 May 2015 4.94 94 Restaurants Are A Mine Field The perfect orientation, the scientists discovered, is for food to point at 3.2 degrees clockwise, a tiny fraction to the right of the vertical axis of the plate. The effect is so pronounced that people actually experience an improved taste when the alignment is correct, the psychologists claim. Rotating plates: Online study demonstrates the importance of orientation in the plating of food Charles Michel, Andy T. Woods, Markus Neuhäeuser, Alberto Landgraf and Charles Spence Food Quality and Preference 2015 DOI: 10.1016/j.foodqual.2015.04.015 4.95 95 Restaurants Are A Mine Field Why eating off a red plate makes you less hungry: An Oxford professor's astonishing tips on how to make food taste better - Daily Mail - 1 June 2015 Prof. Charles Spence (Oxford University) is championing the new science of gastrophysics. We all know that fish and chips taste best when you’re sitting on a harbour wall looking out to sea. And most of us would agree that music and lighting affects the overall enjoyment of a meal. But did you realise that ordering first when dining with friends will make your food taste better? Or that eating from a red plate is a good way to lose weight? Or that the heavier the cutlery, the more likely you are to think your meal is delicious? Study Finds A Good Appetizer Could Make Your Main Course Less Enjoyable A good or mediocre appetizer has the potential to significantly change how the main course is enjoyed, according to one Drexel food science professor. Jacob Lahne 2015 How ordering a starter could spoil your main meal - Daily Mail - 27 June 2015 A good appetizer could make your main course less enjoyable - ScienceDaily - 25 June 2015 4.96 96 A Test of Intuition Frederick (2005) introduces a three-item "Cognitive Reflection Test" (CRT) as a simple measure of one type of cognitive ability - the ability or disposition to reflect on a question and resist reporting the first response that comes to mind. He shows that CRT scores are predictive of the types of choices that feature prominently in tests of decision-making theories, like expected utility theory and prospect theory. Frederick S. 2005 “Cognitive reflection and decision making” American Economic Association 19 25-42. 4.97 97 A Test of Intuition Indeed, the relation is sometimes so strong that the preferences themselves effectively function as expressions of cognitive ability - an empirical fact begging for a theoretical explanation. The author examines the relation between CRT scores and two important decision-making characteristics: time preference and risk preference. The CRT scores are then compared with other measures of cognitive ability or cognitive “style.” 4.98 98 A Test of Intuition Despite the diversity of phenomena related to IQ, few have attempted to understand - or even describe - its influences on judgment and decision making. Studies on time preference, risk preference, probability weighting, ambiguity aversion, endowment effects, anchoring and other widely researched topics rarely make any reference to the possible effects of cognitive abilities (or cognitive traits). 4.99 99 A Test of Intuition The Cognitive Reflection Test (CRT) 1. A bat and a ball cost $1.10 in total. The bat costs $1.00 $0.05 more than the ball. How much does the ball cost ______ $0.90 cents. 2. If it takes 5 machines 5 minutes to make 5 widgets, how long would it take 100 machines to make 100 widgets 5 ______ minutes. 5 3. In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to 47 cover half of the lake ______ days. 47 4.100 100 A Test of Intuition The CRT was administered to 3,428 respondents in 35 separate studies over a 26-month period beginning in January 2003. Most respondents were undergraduates at various universities in the midwest and northeast of America. The CRT scores exhibit considerable difference between men and women and the article explores how this relates to sex differences in time and risk preferences. The final section addresses the interpretation of correlations between cognitive abilities and decision-making characteristics. In short respondents who score differently on the CRT made different choices. Frederick S. 2005 “Cognitive reflection and decision making” American Economic Association 19 25-42. 4.101 101 Where Should You Invest? The Observer portfolio challenge pitted professionals Justin Urquhart Stewart of wealth managers Seven Investment Management, Paul Kavanagh of stockbrokers Killick and Co, and Schroders fund manager Andy Brough against students from John Warner School in Hoddesdon, Hertfordshire – and Orlando. While the professionals used their decades of investment knowledge and traditional stock-picking methods, the cat (Orlando) selected stocks by throwing his favourite toy mouse on a grid of numbers allocated to different companies. Investments: Orlando is the cat's whiskers of stock picking The Observer - Sunday 13 January 2013 4.102 102 Where Should You Invest? Each team invested a notional £5,000 in five companies from the FTSE All-Share index at the start of the year. After every three months, they could exchange any stocks, replacing them with others from the index. By the end of September the professionals had generated £497 of profit compared with £292 managed by Orlando. But an unexpected turnaround in the final quarter has resulted in the cat's portfolio increasing by an average of 4.2% to end the year at £5,542.60, compared with the professionals' £5,176.60. Investments: Orlando Is The Cat's Whiskers Of Stock Picking The Observer, 13 January 2013 4.103 103 Its Not Just The Share Price The fifteen years since the FTSE 100 hit its all-time high have been a lesson in why dividends matter. When that anniversary rolled round last week, the leading UK stock market index was down 4.3 per cent on the 6,930.2 points it reached as we prepared to celebrate the millennium. Yet take into account dividends, as the FTSE 100 Total Return index does, and investors were up 58%. That’s not much to write home about – an average of just 3% a year - but it’s considerably better than losing money. THE MINOR INVESTOR: If you want to make money long-term put your trust in dividends - the Rolling Stones of investing Daily Mail - 8 January 2015 4.104 104 Where Should You Invest? One would think that professional investors, such as mutual funds, hedge funds and institutional managers, would be behavioural-data investors. And indeed, the analysts within such organizations are most often behavioural-data investors. But the further up one goes in the organization and the larger the fund, the more like the crowd it becomes. This is because in order to grow assets under management, funds must attract and retain emotional investors, which means catering to client emotions and taking on the features of the crowd. As the fund grows in size, it increasingly invests in those stocks favoured by the crowd, since it is easier to attract and retain clients by investing in stocks to which clients are emotionally attached. A fund might also mimic the index to lock in a past alpha or become a closet indexer to avoid style drift and tracking error. Each of these represents a different way of catering to investor 4.105 105 emotions (Howard 2013). Where Should You Invest? So, what may start out as a fund managed by behavioural-data investors taking positions opposite the crowd often ends up morphing into something that is acceptable to the crowd. As argued by Berk and Green (2004), such behaviour is rational on the part of the fund, as revenues are based on assets under management. Consistent with this argument, others have found that returns decline as funds grow large (Howard 2013). 4.106 106 Where Should You Invest? In three studies on predicting the stock market, Ortmann et al. (2008) reported that recognition-based portfolios (the set of most-recognized options), on average, outperformed managed funds such as the Fidelity Growth Fund, the market (Dow or Dax), chance portfolios, and stock experts. In contrast, Boyd (2001) found no such advantage when he used college students’ recognition of stocks rather than that of the general public. It is imperative to understand why and under what conditions this simple heuristic can survive in financial markets without making a systematic market analysis. This remains an open question. 4.107 107 Next Week Asset Pricing 4.108 108