The Evolution of Initial Public Offerings in Italy Giovanni Sabatini Prague 3 -11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Agenda Introduction Reasons to go public/stay private The evolution of IPO’s in Italy Empirical evidence Final considerations Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Introduction The role of stock markets in financing investments, monitoring companies, reallocating corporate control varies greatly among developed capitalistic economies. Market-oriented Systems – In Anglo-Saxon countries the stock market plays a central role in those functions Bank-oriented Systems – In most Continental European countries and in Japan banks have played a major role in financing companies Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Introduction IPO stands for initial public offering, i.e. when a company sells its shares to the public for the first time. Initial Public Offerings (IPOs) have represented the traditional way of raising capital for high-growth firms. Until ’90 IPOs have been limited to US and UK, where capital markets are more developed In the ‘90s, large privatization programs in European markets led to a new wave of IPOs Internet boom created another wave of IPOs worldwide (late ’90s) Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Agenda Introduction Reasons to go public/stay private The evolution of IPO’s in Italy Empirical evidence Final considerations Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Reasons to go public Strategic – Growth: Raise capital - Investments too large to be provided by the founders – Diversify (dilution effect) - Share business risk among many owners Commercial – Enter Global competition – Acquisitions (cross-borders) become more feasible – Increase visibility – (e.g. listing on the NYSE) Financial – Rebalance capital structure – Cost of credit Increased bargaining power with banks – Exploit mispricing - If some stocks are mispriced, the entrepreneurs recognizing that other companies in the same industry are overvalued, have an incentive to go public Reputation – Transparency - Increase the accountability of the firm and improve the reputation by reducing information asymmetry – Improve Corporate Governance - listed companies have to comply with a Code of Discipline Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Reasons to stay private Maintain the control over the firm – in widely held companies, dispersed shareholders do not participate in the annual meetings (they “vote with their feet”, selling the shares) – the control of the firm is held by strong managers who act for their own interest Avoid outside control (eg. regulatory bodies, auditor, financial analysts) - Public firms must regularly report to the Authorities and to the investors Avoid underpricing - The IPO is expensive as the offer price is set at low levels to attract investors TAX opaqueness Direct and indirect costs of going public Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini The IPO process – Approval of the BoD and appointment of the advisory team – General meeting of the shareholders and appointment of the sponsor and legal advisors – Meeting between the management and the advisors – Due diligence – Preparation of the prospectus of the offer and application for approval (CONSOBB) – Application for listing at the Stock Exchange (Borsa Italiana SpA) Within two months the Stock Exchange informs the firm and the Authority and publishes the decision The firm has six months to make the offer – Roadshows to present the issuer to the institutional investors – Bookbuilding: institutional investors set their offers in terms of quantity and price of the shares – Start of trading (and stabilization of the price, where allowed) Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini The pricing Mechanisms to set the IPO price: – Auction – Fixed Price – Price range (binding) – Price range not binding Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Allotment The offer differs depending on the type of investor to whom it is addressed – Private placement (to institutional investors) – this implies that before the offering the underwriters contact potential IPO subscribers and collect indicative bids, with or without limit price (book building) – Retail offer (to the public) – there is no discrimination among investors The prospectus normally prescribes a minimum number of shares to be allotted to the public and a maximum number to institutional investors Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Special clauses Green shoe option – allows the underwriter to place a further Overallotment – the underwriters assign Lock-up agreement – controlling shareholders and other Bonus shares – additional Remedy share – commitment by the IPO promoters that fraction of IPO shares on the market (generally between 10-15% of the IPO shares within 30 days from the listing) an amount of shares to IPO subscribers that is larger than the IPO size; the short position is covered after the listing (by exercising the green shoe option or by repurchasing the shares) insiders commit not to sell their portfolio shares within a certain period of time after listing (signalling their positive expectation about the firm value) shares assigned for free to investors retaining IPO stock up to a certain deadline (used in privatization offerings) additional shares will be assigned for free to subscribers, in the event that the business targets declared in the prospectus will not be reached Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Agenda Introduction Reasons to go public/stay private The evolution of IPO’s in Italy Empirical evidence Final considerations Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini ITALIAN STOCK EXCHANGE Facts & Figures 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Capitalization Capitalization Turnover Euro/billion % GDP 20,3 30,2 44,8 64,4 67,8 47,3 35,7 36,6 42,2 Euro/billion 199 310 484 714 790 575 447 475 569 Capitalization Euro/billion 3 5 4 5 6 5 5 5 5 EXPANDI Turnover .. 1 2 1 1 .. .. .. .. 81 174 423 503 839 637 562 567 641 N. listed firms 31 26 20 17 15 12 13 11 13 MTA N. listed firms 213 209 219 241 237 232 231 219 219 14 14 25 28 16 13 11 9 7 N. delisted firms 18 18 15 6 20 18 12 21 7 NUOVO MERCATO Capitalization Turnover N. listed firms Euro/billion 7 22 13 6 8 7 Source: Relazione annuale 2004, Consob Prague, 3-11-2005 N. IPOs Giovanni Sabatini 4 30 21 10 14 19 6 39 44 44 41 37 Div/P Earnings/P 2,1 1,7 1,6 1,5 2,1 2,8 3,8 3,4 3,4 6,9 4,6 3,9 3,4 4,5 6 5,9 6,4 6 Characteristics of Italian Industral Structure Limited firms size Highly Concentrated Ownership Family- Owned Leverage Limited presence in high-technology business Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini The Italian IPO waves There are waves in the history of Italian IPOs: – 1985-1988 (bullish market): 69 IPOs firms, of which 32% financial, 58% industrial (mainly construction and electronics) and 10% services. Most were carve-outs – 1989-1994: only 19 IPOs (52% of which were financial companies) – 1995-1997: 34 IPO (76% of which were financial companies) most of them were small-medium companies taking advantage of the tax benefits granted by the “legge Tremonti”. No carve-outs – 1998-2000 (dot.com bubble): 85 IPOs, most were hightech firms in the services category (media, software, information technology) – 2001-2004 (slowdown): 35 firms, the majority of which the were public utilities – Today: 13 firms, of which 4 listing in the Expandi segment The pattern supports the evidence that firms tend to time the IPO when the moment is more convenient (“window opportunity”) Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Ipo filed in Italy from 1985 to 2004, by year of listing (Borsa Italiana, 2005) MTA (main market) Nuov o Mercato Mercato Ristretto/Expandi 35 32 30 30 25 21 20 17 15 15 11 10 11 12 10 9 7 5 13 12 6 3 4 4 3 2 1 1 6 5 4 2 1 0 1985 1986 1987 Prague, 3-11-2005 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Giovanni Sabatini 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 The evolution of Initial Public Offerings in Italy IPO firms in the recent years have different characteristics than the early IPOs: – Smaller and younger – Less concentrated ownership – More frequently participated by pre-IPO private equity investors IPO pricing in Italy has become more efficient Italian IPOs adopted several clauses of the going public process in the US (green shoes, lock-ups, book building) Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Features of the IPO firms: issue type Equity carve-outs have been frequent from 1985 to 1988 when listed companies took advantage of the bullish market momentum to spin-off subsidiaries (this is consistent with the evidence that carve-outs can time better the IPO). Independently newly listed firms are largely predominant from 1995 Privatizations have been frequent across the whole period (privatizing companies account for more than 15% of the IPO activity of the last 20 years in Italy) 1985-1988 1989-1994 1995-1997 1998-2000 2001-2004 69 19 34 85 35 of which carve outs 42% 26% 3% 7% 5% of which privatization 21% 26% 8% 9% 11% other 37% 48% 89% 84% 84% IPO sample Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Features of the IPO firms: age, total assets, net profits The average age of the IPO firms has reduced Total assets vary across the periods, with small firms alternating with large firms Net profits are always positive, as profitability is a listing requirement (contrary to US, where firms with negative earnings can go public) 1985-1988 1989-1994 1995-1997 1998-2000 2001-2004 48 38 48 37 32 Total assets (euro ML) 2593 8517 2327 2200 837 Gross revenues 406 1402 1804 429 323 Net profit 15 35 79 44 30 Firm age (yrs) Statistics about the accounting value of consolidated assets and revenues are very dispersed and reveal that large companies alternated to smaller firms during the period Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Median age of companies that made an IPO in Italy, USA, and in Europe (Belgium, France, Germany, the Netherlands, UK) (Borsa Italiana, 2005) Italy USA Europe 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1985-1988 Prague, 3-11-2005 1989-1994 1995-1997 Giovanni Sabatini 1998-2000 2001-2004 Fraction of IPO companies that reported zero or negative profits at the year before the listing, in Italy, USA, and in Europe (Belgium, France, Germany, the Netherlands, UK) (Borsa Italiana, 2005) Italy USA Europe 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1985-1988 Prague, 3-11-2005 1989-1994 1995-1997 Giovanni Sabatini 1998-2000 2001-2004 Features of the IPO firms: net proceeds and control The mean value of IPO proceeds is biased by large privatizations in the early 1990s The firms are generally closely held by large shareholders before the IPO, and they generally hold more than 50% after the IPO 1985-1988 1989-1994 1995-1997 1998-2000 2001-2004 74 421 195 379 223 before the IPO 89% 88% 80% 79% 79% after the IPO 69% 64% 55% 51% 51% IPO proceeds Equity capital held by controlling shareholders Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini LISTING REQUIREMENTS (Italian Stock Exchange) MTA (Large and medium size firms) firm’s ability of generating positive revenues in normal business conditions minimum floating of 25% of the equity capital publication of the previous three years’ financial statements with the last year’s financial statements audited minimum capitalization of € 5 million Nuovo Mercato (Small and growth firms) firm’s ability of generating positive revenues in normal business conditions (even with present negative earnings) minimum floating of 20% of the equity capital financial statements audited minimum capitalization of € 1,5 million lock- in clause (commitment of the management team to keep at least 80% of the shared owned at the time of the offer, for a period of minimum 1 year) For start-up firms (with life less than 1 year), the lock-in clause lasts for 2 years Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Agenda Basics Reasons to go public/stay private The evolution of IPO’s in Italy Empirical evidence Final considerations Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: the opinion of the financial community Survey on the IPO effects (Osservatorio M&A, Bocconi University, Milan) IPOs help growth: – after the IPO, the firms continue to grow (average of 18% revenues increase) – 79,6% of the interviewed firms stated that the growth rate without IPO would have been lower; 43% stated that without the IPO most investments would have been cut off IPOs sustain the acquisition process: – 76,4% of the interviewed firms made at least one acquisition after the IPO – the average acquisition number is 4 Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: the opinion of the financial community (continue) IPO helps capital structure optimization – Immediately after the IPO, the leverage decreases – In the following years the leverage increases and returns to previous levels after three years – 68% of the interviewed firms consider the re-leverage process the main reason for the IPO – The re-leverage is convenient because after the IPO the firm has increased its bargaining power with banks IPO improves the communication with the stakeholders – Institutional investors – Regulators – Shareholders Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: underpricing In the first day of the offer there is a positive return from the offer price to the closing market price (underpricing) The long-run performance shows different patterns across time Av. First Day Ret. and 3 yr Return (% ) - Loughran and Ritter, 2000 80 60 40 20 0 1980-1989 1990-1994 1995-1998 -20 First Day Return -40 3 yr Return Prague, 3-11-2005 -60 Giovanni Sabatini 1999-2000 2001 Av. First day Return (%) Average 3-year Buy-andHold Return (%) 1980-1989 7,4 20,8 1990-1994 11,2 44,7 1995-1998 18,1 36 1999-2000 65 -53,8 2001 14 na 18,7 22,6 Period 1980-2001 Underpricing (%) for 38 countries 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1984-2002 1983-2000 1978-1999 1985-2001 1991-1998 1986-1998 1980-1998 1959-2001 1960-2001 Austria France Prague, 3-11-2005 Germ any Italy Poland Giovanni Sabatini Spain Sw eden UK USA Underpricing and long term performance In the recent years the mean underpricing level in Italy has been decreasing One interpretation (Giudici, Paleari) is that the reduction is related to the adoption of book building as opposed to previously used practices of setting the price (i.e.: fixed price) and to greater involvement of institutional investors in the placement The long term underperformance is still present but less than in the past Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: money left on the table Money on the table is the number of shares sold times the difference between the first-day closing market price and the offer price (the average IPO leaves $9.1 million on the table) – This is approximately twice as large as the fees paid to investment bankers ($13 billion), and represents a substantial indirect cost to the issuing firm (Loughran and Ritter, 2000) In Netscape’s August 1995 initial public offering (IPO) with Morgan Stanley as the lead underwriter, 5 million shares were sold to investors at $28.00 per share. With a closing market price of $58.25, $151 million was left on the table Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table? – The discount is the condition imposed by financial intermediaries in order to ensure the success of the placement For 15 IPOs with first-day returns in excess of 60% that subsequently conducted follow-on offerings, all 15 retained the lead underwriter from the IPO (Krigman, Shaw, and Womack, 2001) Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Aggregate Money Left on the Table (m illions $) Av. First day Return (%) Average 3-year Buyand-Hold Return (%) 1980-1989 5409 7,4 20,8 1990-1994 9954 11,2 44,7 1995-1998 22436 18,1 36 1999-2000 65625 65 -53,8 2001 2973 14 na 106379 18,7 22,6 Period 1980-2001 Money Left on the Table (million $) - Loughran and Ritter, 2000 70000 60000 50000 40000 30000 20000 10000 0 1980-1989 Prague, 3-11-2005 1990-1994 1995-1998 Giovanni Sabatini 1999-2000 2001 Empirical evidence: valuation and ownership IPOs are typically valued using comparable multiples – For a sample of technology firms in the Internet boom period, Chanine (2002) finds that these firms are priced at a larger discount than non-tech firms, consistent with the higher first-day returns on tech IPOs The discount is larger if the incumbent shareholders do not lose the control after the IPO (Zingales, 1994) – This has been for decades the case of Italian IPOs, where the owners, typically families, maintain the control of the firm after the listing Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: IPO waves IPOs follows waves, with intense periods followed by periods of low activity – A first wave occurred in US in the 1990-1994 – A second wave occurred in US and in Europe in the late 1990s Historically, continental European IPO market has been dwarfed by the US IPO market. In 2000, however, in spite of high volume of IPOs in the USA, continental European IPO volume exceeded that of the USA One explanation is that in times when the market is over valuating certain industries, the firms in those industries will likely go public to exploit the mispricing Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Empirical evidence: size and age effect Large firms are more likely to go public as they can better afford high fixed costs of the IPO Large firms leave less money on the table as their offer price is normally higher due to less uncertainty in valuation – IPO firms in Italy are larger than IPO firms in US The size effect does not apply when the IPO regards a subsidiary of an holding company (carve-out) – fixed costs are indirectly borne by the holding company and the discount is lower as there is less uncertainty over the issue Younger firms should go public more often than older firms because they need capital to finance investments – IPO firms in Italy are older than IPO firms in US Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Agenda Basics Reasons to go public/stay private The evolution of IPO’s in Italy Empirical evidence Final considerations Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini Final considerations Italian IPOs in the past not driven by small high-growth firms; Successful IPOs require developed capital markets and good corporate governance systems; In recent periods the Italian IPOs adopted pricing strategies and arrangements (special clause) in line with US market practices; Whatever the reason to go public (finance growth, become more visible, exploit mispricing, etc.), IPOs help market development and improve firms’ accountability to investors. Prague, 3-11-2005 Giovanni Sabatini