The Price of Renewable Energy Policy Risk Empirical Insights from Choice Experiments with European Solar Energy Project Developers Rolf Wüstenhagen (joint work with Sonja Lüthi) U Minnesota, April 29, 2010 Good Energies Chair for Management of Renewable Energies at the University of St. Gallen (IWÖ-HSG) • Established in 2009 with support from Good Energies • Part of one of Europe‘s leading business schools • Dedicated team (9 people) • 30+ Bachelor/Master Theses, ≈ 3-4 PhD dissertations p.a. • Research and teaching on... • • • • • • Investment Decisions and Venture Capital Consumer Decisions and Marketing RE Business Models for Renewable Energy Energy Policy Forthcoming Energy Policy Special Issue: „Strategic Choices in Renewable Energy Investment“ Handbook of Research on Energy Entrepreneurship Vision of our Chair – The Road from 20:80 to 80:20 100% Non-Renewable Energies 80% 60% 40% 20% Renewable Energies 0% 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 Berlin, 24.10.2009 (...) The new German government‘s objective is „a consistent energy policy, which leads into a new age of renewable energies“, said Chancellor Angela Merkel when she presented the coalition agreement. „Renewable energy shall account for the major part of German energy supply“, and conventional energy sources shall continuously be replaced. (Source: dpa) The paper in a nutshell • • • • • Recent growth of renewable energies in Europe, particular solar photovoltaics (PV), largely driven by public policy Seemingly similar policies (e.g. feed-in tariff of similar level) lead to different results in different countries Vivid debate about what constitutes efficient and effective renewable energy policies, recently highlighting importance of both sides of the risk-return equation Consensus that policy risk matters. BUT: Which risk factors are relevant, and how should policy makers prioritize them? Two approaches to understanding investor behavior: • Revealed preferences (installed capacities). Limitation: Few cases, retrospective. • Stated preferences (choice experiments). • Result: Empirically measuring the price of policy risk, leading to specific policy recommendations. Solar Energy: Small market share today, large future potential 2100 64% EJ/a Geothermal 1600 Other renewables Solar Thermal (Heat) 1400 1200 Solar electricity (PV and Solar Thermal) 1000 2007 0.1% 800 Wind 600 Biomass (modern) Biomass (traditional) Hydroelectricity Nuclear Gas Coal Oil 400 200 0 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2100 Global primary energy scenario: Renewables 80% of primary energy by 2100 Source: German Advisory Council on Global Change WBGU Berlin 2003 www.wbgu.de Share of newly installed capacity in 2009 [MW] Change we can believe in: New power plant investments in Europe 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Guess Who Solar Coal is Who: Oil Nuclear Hydro Oil, Gas, Coal, (PV) Nuclear, Hydro, Wind, Solar (PV) Wind Gas Source: Platts, EWEA Solar Photovoltaics: Towards „Grid Parity“ R&D Pilot Political Market Self-Sustaining Market 2010 Grid parity European countries Average household electricity price [€/kWh] 0,40 Grid Parity 0,35 0,30 Denmark Italy 0,25 Netherlands Germany 0,20 Portugal France Sweden 0,15 Spain Hungary 0,10 Greece 0,05 0,00 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200 1300 1400 1500 Solar Irradiation [kWh/m2*a] Source: Centrotherm May 2008 1600 1700 1800 1900 2000 Greening Goliaths vs. Emerging Davids Environmental & Social Performance Sustainability Niche Emerging Davids high Sustainability Start-up Sustainability Transformation of an Industry Greening Goliaths low Market Incumbent low Source: Hockerts and Wüstenhagen (2010) high Market Share 9 Solar industry growth so far driven by Technology & Policy, increasing importance of Business Models η § € Source: Klein et al. (2006) Increasing number of countries with feed-in tariffs for renewable energy Influence of policy design on the deployment of renewable energy technologies - Sufficient and secure support is essential for increasing solar capacity (Mendonça, 2007; Jacobsson & Lauber, 2006; Butler & Neuhoff, 2005; Lauber & Toke, 2005; Rowlands, 2005; Wiser et al. 1997): – Provide financial security: A guaranteed level of tariffs for a sufficiently long duration (e.g. 20 years) ensures planning security and makes the investment in solar electricity systems attractive – Level of tariff higher than the marginal costs of generation (in order to ensure a sufficient return on investments) – Solar policy stability: A stable and foreseeable solar policy allows investors to plan their activities. - For efficient policy design, the project development and financing processes need to be understood (Wiser & Pickle, 1998, Langniss 1999) Empirical Puzzle: Why do similar policies (PV feed-in tariffs) lead to different outcomes across countries? Empirical Puzzle: Level of return fails to explain level of installed PV capacity Germany Spain Greece Return + (++) ? ++ - Level of tariff + (+) ? ++ - Duration of support + ++ + - Solar radiation O ++ ++ Risk ++ (+) – – (– –) – - Funding stability ++ (+) – – O - Promotion cap ++ –– ++ - Administrative process ++ + (– –) – Level of diffusion High Medium Low ++ = very favorable; + = favorable; O = medium; – = unfavorable; – – = very unfavorable; ( ) = situation in 2006 Source: Lüthi (2010) 1. Objectives – Empirically measure the price of energy policy risk in the case of support policies for photovoltaics, in order to… – provide recommendations for design of effective PV policies. 2. Research Questions – How important are various attributes of solar energy policies in influencing the decision of a PV project developer to invest in a given country? – What is investors' willingness-to-accept specific policy risks? ? Empirical Research Design, Data and Sample • • • • Stated preference survey among international solar energy project developers from Germany, Italy, Spain, Greece and Switzerland, conducted in October-November 2008. Participation solicited by phone, e-mail, at a solar industry trade fair, through the University of St. Gallen website and a leaflet in a solar industry journal. 135 respondents logged on to the survey website, 63 questionnaires were completed. Each respondent completed 25 choice tasks, resulting in a total dataset of N=1575 decisions. Methodology: Adaptive Conjoint Analysis (ACA) Simulation of a “real” investment choice situation Utility function and decision rule: U jk U jk v jk , jk max! Ujk = utility of policy k for investor j vjk = vector of deterministic relevant decision attributes which subsumes feasible attributes of policy k for investor j (zjk) jk = stochastic random variable which comprises unobservable policy attributes zjk*, unobservable personal attributes sj* and measurement errors jk. Choice Analysis: Pjk Pr obU jk U jn ; k n; k , n X t Pjk = probability that investor j chooses policy k Multinominal logit model (MNL) Maximum likelihood estimation Choice Experiments in Marketing Research: Sample Choice Task from Sammer/Wüstenhagen 2006 If you would buy a washing machine today, which product would you choose? (assuming 5 kg wash load capacity) If you would buy a washing machine today, which product would you choose? Miele V-Zug V-Zug (assuming 5 kg wash load capacity) If you would buy a washing machine today, which product would you choose? Equipment Version: Equipment Version: Miele V-Zug V-Zug (assuming 5 kg wash load capacity) Equipment Version: Simple* Middle* Middle* The 5-6 most important attributes of the buying decision – preferably independent of each other Miele V-Zug V-Zug Equipment Version: Equipment Version: Consumption Water Consumption Water Consumption EquipmentWater Version: Simple* Middle* Middle* 39 l/Wash Cycle 39 l/Wash Cycle 58 l/Wash Cycle Equipment Version: Equipment Version: Consumption Water Consumption Water Consumption EquipmentWater Version: Simple* Electricity Consumption Middle* Electricity ConsumptionMiddle* Electricity Consumption 39 l/Wash Cycle 39 l/Wash Cycle 58 l/Wash Cycle 0.85 kWh/Wash Cycle 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle Water Consumption Water Consumption Water Consumption Electricity Consumption Electricity Consumption Electricity Consumption ’A’ Class Energy ’B’ Class Energy 39 l/Wash Cycle 39 l/Wash Cycle 58 l/Wash Cycle Class Energy 0.85’C’ kWh/Wash CycleEfficiency 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle Efficiency Efficiency Electricity Consumption Electricity Consumption Electricity Consumption ’A’ Class Energy ’B’ Class Energy Class Energy 0.85’C’ kWh/Wash CycleEfficiency 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle 1.3 kWh/Wash Cycle 1890 CHF 3780 CHF 2650 CHF Efficiency Efficiency ’A’ Class Energy 3780 CHF Efficiency ’C’ Class Energy Efficiency 1890 CHF 1890 CHF 3-5 levels per attribute ’B’ Class Energy 2650 CHF Efficiency 3780 CHF 2650 CHF Which of these three models would you buy? Please mark with a cross! Which of these three models would you buy? Please mark with a cross! 1 Respondent chooses preferred product 2 3 Which of these three models would you buy? Please mark with a cross! 1 1 2 2 3 3 e.g. 20 Choice Tasks with varying attribute levels Design of the Choice Experiments Based on qualitative pre-study, the following attributes were selected for the ACA: Attributes Attribute levels Level of the feed-in-tariff 31; 35; 38; 41; 45 ct/kWh Duration of support 15, 20, 25 years Expected time until support cap will be reached No cap; reached in 4 years; reached in 1 y. Duration of the administrative process 1-2; 3-6; 6-12; 13-18; 19-24 months Solar policy stability 0, 1, 3 abrupt policy changes Predefined framework conditions: solar radiation: 1500 kWh/m2 size of the installation: 500 kW Sample Choice Task from ACA questionnaire (paired comparison) Sample Choice Task from ACA questionnaire (calibration task) Relative Importance of Attributes How important are various attributes of solar energy policies in influencing project developers' decision to invest in a given country? 30% 25.56% 25% 24.37% 18.72% 20% 17.74% 13.61% 15% 10% 5% 0% Duration admin. process Feed-in Tariff level Cap Solar policy changes Feed-in Tariff duration Normalized Part Worth Utilities of Attribute Levels 30 Number of Duration of Policy Changes Support Level of Feed-in Tariff 20 19.15 18.19 17.74 15 13.61 Cap 25.56 24.37 25 Part Worth Utilities Duration of Admin. Process 18.72 13.08 12.47 10.59 10.57 10 7.59 7.05 6.66 5 0 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 9 6 3 0 0 6 12 18 24 Duration of Admin Process [in months] 15 12 9 6 3 0 No Cap Loose Cap Tight Cap (unltd.) (4 y.) (1 y.) Implicit Willingness to Accept [ct/kWh] 12 Implicit Willingness to Accept [ct/kWh] 15 Implicit Willingness to Accept [ct/kWh] Implicit Willingness to Accept [ct/kWh] Implications for Policy Makers: The "Price Tag" of Poor Policies 15 12 9 6 3 0 0 1 2 Number of Policy Changes 3 15 12 9 6 3 0 25 20 15 Duration of Support [in years] Interpretation of Results • • • Solar energy investors are particularly sensitive to duration of administrative procedures, followed by other policy risks (policy changes, existence of cap). Duration of support is relatively less important. For every half-year increase in the duration of the administrative process, a government has to pay investors a premium of about 4 ct/kWh (all else being equal). Removing a loose (tight) cap will allow governments to attract the same level of investment at a feed-in tariff that is about 5 (10) ct/kWh lower. Limitations and further research • • • • • Sample size > should be increased in future studies (without compromising on quality of respondents) Stated preferences > validation of implicit willingness-toaccept by cross-checking with revealed preferences (especially as longer time series become available) Relevance of unobserved factors (e.g. language, country size) and social interaction (e.g. "hype") Transfer to private investors (e.g. residential homeowners buying solar panels) Transfer to corporate finance decisions and explore role of policy aversion bias Conclusions • • • • Ultimately, the achievement of energy policy objectives hinges on whether policy instruments effectively influence investor behavior. Applying a sophisticated research method from another field (marketing), the research presented here is one of the first empirical contributions that investigates the influence of renewable energy policies on investor decisions. We confirm prior research that points to the importance of "non-economic" barriers to deployment of renewables, such as policy instability. Based on a solid empirical basis, we develop specific recommendations that enable policy makers to assess the cost and benefit of reducing various elements of policy risk. Thank you! Prof. Dr. Rolf Wüstenhagen Director Institute for Economy and the Environment University of St. Gallen Tigerbergstrasse 2 CH-9000 St. Gallen / Switzerland Telephone: +41-71-224 25 87 Mobile: +41-76-306 43 13 E-mail: rolf.wuestenhagen@unisg.ch http://goodenergies.iwoe.unisg.ch Further Reading Lüthi, S. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2010): The Price of Policy Risk – Empirical Insights from Choice Experiments with European Photovoltaic Project Developers (under review). Hockerts, K. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2010): Greening Goliaths versus Emerging Davids – Theorizing about the Role of Incumbents and New Entrants in Sustainable Entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, forthcoming. Känzig, J. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2010): The effect of life-cycle cost information on consumer investment decisions for eco-innovation. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 1 (14), 121-136. Bürer, M.J. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2009): Which renewable energy policy is a venture capitalist's best friend? Empirical evidence from a survey of international cleantech investors. Energy Policy, 37 (12), 4997-5006. Wüstenhagen, R., Wolsink, M., Bürer, M.J. (2007): Social acceptance of renewable energy innovation: An introduction to the concept. Energy Policy 35 (5): 2683-2691. Wüstenhagen, R. and Teppo, T. (2006): Do venture capitalists really invest in good industries? Risk-return perceptions and path dependence in the emerging European energy VC market. Int. J. Technology Management, 34 (1/2), 63-87. Sammer, K. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2006): The Influence of Eco-Labelling on Consumer Behaviour – Results of a Discrete Choice Analysis for Washing Machines. Business Strategy and the Environment, 15, 185-199. Wüstenhagen, R. and Bilharz, M. (2006): Green Energy Market Development in Germany: Effective Public Policy and Emerging Customer Demand. Energy Policy, 34, 1681-1696. Moore, B. and Wüstenhagen, R. (2004): Innovative and Sustainable Energy Technologies: The Role of Venture Capital, Business Strategy and the Environment, 13, 235-245.