Chapter 9 Slides

advertisement

Chapter 9

The Government and Fiscal Policy

CHAPTER OUTLINE

Government in the Economy

Government Purchases ( G ), Net Taxes ( T ), and

Disposable Income ( Y d

)

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)

Fiscal Policy at Work: Multiplier Effects

The Government Spending Multiplier

The Tax Multiplier

The Balanced-Budget Multiplier

The Federal Budget

The Budget in 2012

Fiscal Policy Since 1993: The Clinton, Bush, and

Obama Administrations

The Federal Government Debt

The Economy’s Influence on the Government

Budget

Automatic Stabilizers and Destabilizers

Full-Employment Budget

Appendix A: Deriving the Fiscal Policy Multipliers

Appendix B: The Case in Which Tax Revenues

Depend on Income

THE GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY fiscal policy The government’s spending and taxing policies.

monetary policy The behavior of the Federal Reserve concerning the nation’s money supply.

Government in the Economy discretionary fiscal policy Changes in taxes or spending that are the result of deliberate changes in government policy.

Government Purchases ( G ), Net Taxes ( T ), and Disposable Income ( Y d

) net taxes (T) Taxes paid by firms and households to the government minus transfer payments made to households by the government. disposable, or after-tax, income (Y

Total income minus net taxes: Y − T . d

) disposable income ≡ total income − net taxes

Y d

≡ Y − T

 FIGURE 9.1

Adding Net Taxes (T) and Government Purchases (G) to the Circular Flow of Income: A little more complicated

The disposable income ( Y d

) of households must end up as either consumption ( C ) or saving ( S ).

Thus, Y d

C

S

Because disposable income is Y d another identity:

≡ Y − T , we can write

Y T C S

By adding T to both sides:

Y C S T

Planned aggregate expenditure ( AE ) is the sum of consumption spending by households ( C ), planned investment by business firms ( I ), and government purchases of goods and services ( G ).

AE

C

I

G

budget deficit The difference between what a government spends and what it collects in taxes in a given period: G − T . budget deficit ≡ G − T

Which can also be written as the difference between what the government collects in taxes and what it spends in a given period: T − G : budget deficit ≡ T − G

Adding Taxes to the Consumption Function

To modify our aggregate consumption function to incorporate disposable income instead of before-tax income, instead of C = a + bY , we write

C = a + bY d or

C = a + b ( Y − T )

Our consumption function now has consumption depending on disposable income instead of before-tax income.

Planned Investment (

I

)

The government can affect investment behavior through its tax treatment of depreciation and other tax policies.

Planned investment depends on the interest rate.

For purposes of this chapter, as in chapter 8, we assume the interest rate and planned investment

( I ) are fixed..

- I is assumed to be autonomous.

Government (G) and Taxes (T)

We assume G is fixed, G is autonomous.

We initially assume T is fixed, T is autonomous.

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)

Y = C + I + G

TABLE 9.1 Finding Equilibrium for I = 100, G = 100, and T = 100

All Figures in Billions of Dollars

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Output

(Income)

Y

Net

Taxes

T

Disposable

Income

Y d

Y T

Consumption

Spending

C = 100 + .75 Y d

Saving

Y d

S

C

Planned

Investment

Spending

I

Government

Purchases

G

Planned

Aggregate

Expenditure

C + I + G

Unplanned

Inventory

Change

Y − (C + I + G)

Adjustment to Disequilibrium

300

500

100

100

700 100

900 100

1,100 100

1,300 100

1,500 100

200

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

250

400

550

700

850

1,000

1,150

− 50

0

50

100

150

200

250

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

100

450

600

750

900

1,050

1,200

1,350

− 150

− 100

− 50

0

+ 50

+ 100

+ 150

Output

Output

Output

Equilibrium

Output

Output

Output ↓

FIGURE 9.2

Finding

Equilibrium Output/Income

Graphically

Because G and I are both fixed at 100, the aggregate expenditure function is the consumption function displaced upward by

I + G = 200.

Equilibrium occurs at

Y = C + I + G = 900.

The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)

The Math

Equilibrium condition: Y = C + I + G

The sectors:

C = 100 + .75(Y – T)

I = 100

T = 100

G = 100

Substitute the sector information into equilibrium condition:

Y = 100+.75(Y – 100) + 100 + 100

.25Y = 100 – 75 + 100 + 100

.25Y = 225

Y = 225/.25

Y = 900

The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium saving/investment approach to equilibrium:

S + T = I + G

To derive this, we know that in equilibrium, aggregate output

(income) ( Y ) equals planned aggregate expenditure ( AE ).

By definition: AE = C + I + G and by definition Y = C + S + T.

Therefore, at equilibrium:

Y = AE

C + S + T = C + I + G

Subtracting C from both sides leaves:

S + T = I + G

Fiscal Policy at Work: Multiplier Effects

At this point, we are assuming that the government controls G and T . In this section, we will examine three multipliers:

Government spending multiplier

Tax multiplier

Balanced-budget multiplier

Fiscal Policy at Work: Multiplier Effects government spending multiplier The ratio of the change in the equilibrium level of output to a change in government spending =

Y

G government spending multiplier

1

1

MPC

1

MPS

Same as the investment spending multiplier

TABLE 9.2 Finding Equilibrium after a Government Spending Increase of 50 (G Has Increased from 100 in Table 9.1 to 150 Here) MPC =

0.75

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Output

(Income)

Y

Net

Taxes

T

300 100

Disposable

Income

Y d

Y T

200

Consumption

Spending

C = 100 + .75 Y d

250

500 100 400 400

Saving

Y d

S

C

50

0

Planned

Investment

Spending

I

100

Government

Purchases

G

150

Planned

Aggregate

Expenditure

C + I + G

Unplanned

Inventory

Change

Y − (C + I + G)

500

200

Adjustment to

Disequilibrium

Output

100 150 650

150 Output ↑

700

900

100

100

600

800

550

700

50

100

100

100

150

150

800

950

100

50

Output

Output

1,100

1,300

100

100

1,000

1,200

850

1,000

150

200

100

100

150

150

1,100

1,250

0

+ 50

Equilibrium

Output ↓

FIGURE 9.3

The Government Spending Multiplier

MPC = 0.75

Increasing government spending by 50 shifts the AE function up by

50.

As Y rises in response, additional consumption is generated.

Overall, the equilibrium level of Y increases by

200, from 900 to 1,100.

FISCAL POLICY AT WORK: MULTIPLIER EFFECTS

THE TAX MULTIPLIER

The multiplier for a change in taxes is not the same as the multiplier for a change in government spending.

tax multiplier The ratio of change in the equilibrium level of output to a change in taxes =

Y

T

FISCAL POLICY AT WORK: MULTIPLIER EFFECTS tax multiplier

MPC

1

MPC

MPC

MPS

The Balanced-Budget Multiplier

balanced-budget multiplier The ratio of change in the equilibrium level of output to a change in government spending where the change in government spending is balanced by a change in taxes so as not to create any deficit. The balanced-budget multiplier is equal to 1: The change in Y resulting from the change in G and the equal change in T are exactly the same size as the initial change in G or T . balanced-budget multiplier 

1

TABLE 9.3 Finding Equilibrium after a Balanced-Budget Increase in G and T of 200 Each (Both G and T

Have Increased from 100 in Table 9.1 to 300 Here)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

Output

(Income)

Y

500

700

Net

Taxes

T

300

Disposable

Y

Income d

Y T

200

Consumption

Spending

C = 100 + .75 Y d

250

Planned

Investment

Spending

I

100

Government

Purchases

G

300

Planned

Aggregate

Expenditure

C + I + G

650

Unplanned

Inventory

Change

Y − (C + I + G)

−150

300 400 400 100 300 800 −100

Adjustment to

Disequilibrium

Output ↑

Output ↑

900 300 600 550 100 300 950 −50 Output ↑

1,100

1,300

1,500

300

300

300

800

1,000

1,200

700

850

1,000

100

100

100

300

300

300

1,100

1,250

1,400

0

+ 50

+ 100

Equilibrium

Output

Output ↓

TABLE 9.4 Summary of Fiscal Policy Multipliers

Government spending multiplier

Policy Stimulus

Increase or decrease in the level of government purchases:

G

Multiplier

1

MPS

Final Impact on

Equilibrium Y

1

MPS

Tax multiplier Increase or decrease in the level of net taxes: ∆ T

Balancedbudget multiplier

Simultaneous balanced-budget increase or decrease in the level of government purchases and net taxes: ∆ G = ∆ T

MPC

MPS

1

MPC

MPS

G

A Warning

Although we have added government, the story told about the multiplier is still incomplete and oversimplified.

We have been treating net taxes ( T ) as a lump-sum, fixed amount, whereas in practice, taxes depend on income.

Appendix B to this chapter shows that the size of the multiplier is reduced when we make the more realistic assumption that taxes depend on income.

We continue to add more realism and difficulty to our analysis in the chapters that follow.

The Federal Budget

Receipts and Expenditures of the Federal

Government.

Also referred to as Revenues and Outlays of the Federal Government federal budget surplus (+) or deficit ( −):

Federal government receipts minus expenditures.

The Budget in 2012

TABLE 9.5 Federal Government Receipts and Expenditures, 2012 (Billions of Dollars)

Amount Percentage of Total

Current receipts

Personal income taxes

Excise taxes and customs duties

Corporate income taxes

Taxes from the rest of the world

Contributions for social insurance

Interest receipts and rents and royalties

Current transfer receipts from business and persons

Current surplus of government enterprises

Total

Current expenditures

Consumption expenditures

Transfer payments to persons

Transfer payments to the rest of the world

Grants-in-aid to state and local governments

Interest payments

Subsidies

Total

Net federal government saving: surplus (+) or deficit (−)

(Total current receipts − Total current expenditures)

1,137.8

116.1

373.7

17.3

934.8

53.4

59.2

− 17.8

2,674.5

1,059.6

1,773.2

76.4

468.0

318.5

60.4

3,756.1

− 1,081.6

42.5

4.3

14.0

0.6

35.0

2.0

2.2

− 0.7

100.0

28.2

47.2

2.0

12.5

8.5

1.6

100.0

federal surplus (+) or deficit ( −) Federal government receipts minus expenditures.

The Budget in 2015 – selected items

TABLE 9.5 Federal Government Receipts and Expenditures, 2012 (Billions of Dollars)

Amount Percentage of Total

Current receipts

Personal income taxes

Excise taxes and customs duties

Corporate income taxes

Taxes from the rest of the world

Contributions for social insurance

Interest receipts and rents and royalties

Current transfer receipts from business and persons

Other

Total

Current expenditures

Mandatory

Discretionary

1,541

344

1,065

299

3,249

2,299

1,165

47.4

10.6

32.7

9.2

100.0

70.0

24.0

Interest payments

Subsidies

Total

Net federal government saving: surplus (+) or deficit (−)

(Total current receipts − Total current expenditures)

223

3,687

− 438

6.0

100.0

federal surplus (+) or deficit ( −) Federal government receipts minus expenditures.

Federal Outlays and Revenue, 1965 –2025:

Expressed as percent of GDP

27

Budget Surplus or Deficit:1959 –2015, Expressed as percent of GDP

Deficits increase during recessions and decrease during expansions

28

The Economy’s Influence on the Government

Budget – Automatic Stabilizers

• Revenue and expenditure items in the federal budget that automatically change with the state of the economy in such a way as to stabilize

GDP.

• fiscal drag The negative effect on the economy that occurs when average tax rates increase because taxpayers have moved into higher income brackets during an expansion.

Automatic Stabilizers

• In a recession

– budget deficit automatically increases because transfers payments rise and tax revenue falls

(or the budget surplus decreases)

• In an expansion

– budget deficit automatically decreases because transfers decrease and tax revenue rises

(or the budget surplus increases)

30

Deficits and the National Debt

• Budget deficits need to be financed

– increase the public’s bond holdings

– increase the national debt

• Budget surpluses

– decrease the public’s bond holdings

– decrease the national debt

• Debt ratio

– national debt as a percentage of GDP

31

The U.S. Debt Ratio

Obama

Clinton

Bush

Reagan

Debt as a percentage of GDP soared during World War II, then fell steadily for several decades. It rose during the 1980s, fell in the 1990s, and then surged from 2009 –2011 due to recession and fiscal stimulus policies.

Federal Government Debt - National Debt

• The total national debt – what the government owes

– In Dec 2015, it was approaching $18.9 trillion

– Amount the government owed to the public was $13.6 trillion, privately held.

• This has a macroeconomic impact

– Amount that one government agency owed to another was about $5.3 trillion)

• No macroeconomic impact at all

33

Major Foreign Holders of US Gov’t Debt

http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/tic/Documents/mfh.txt

34

Full-Employment Budget full-employment budget What the federal budget would be if the economy were producing at the full-employment level of output. structural deficit The deficit that remains at full employment. cyclical deficit The deficit that occurs because of a downturn in the business cycle.

R E V I E W T E R M S A N D C O N C E P T S automatic destabilizers automatic stabilizers balanced-budget multiplier budget deficit cyclical deficit discretionary fiscal policy disposable, or after-tax, income ( Y d

) federal budget federal debt federal surplus (+) or deficit (−) fiscal drag fiscal policy full-employment budget government spending multiplier monetary policy net taxes ( T ) privately held federal debt structural deficit tax multiplier

Disposable income Y d

≡ Y − T

AE ≡ C + I + G

Government budget deficit ≡ G − T

Equilibrium in an economy with a government: Y = C + I + G

Saving/investment approach to equilibrium in an economy with a government: S + T = I + G

Government spending multiplier

1

MPS

1

1

MPC

MPC

7. Tax multiplier ≡

MPS

8. Balanced-budget multiplier ≡ 1

CHAPTER 9 APPENDIX A

Deriving the Fiscal Policy Multipliers

The Government Spending and Tax Multipliers

We can derive the multiplier algebraically using our hypothetical consumption function:

C a (

T )

The equilibrium condition is

Y

C I G

By substituting for C , we get

Y a (

T ) I G

Y a bY

 bT I G

This equation can be rearranged to yield

Y

 bY a I G

 bT

Y ( 1

 b )

  

G

 bT

Now solve for Y by dividing through by (1 − b ):

Y

1

1

 b

 ( a

I

G

 bT )

The Multipliers

Δ Y =

1

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐 x Δ

I Investment Spending Multiplier

Δ Y =

1

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐 x Δ G Government Spending Multiplier

Δ Y =

−𝑚𝑝𝑐

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐 x Δ

T Lump-sum Tax Multiplier

Δ Y =

−𝑚𝑝𝑐

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐 x Δ a Autonomous Spending Multiplier

CHAPTER 9 APPENDIX B

The Case in Which Tax Revenues Depend on Income

FIGURE 9B.1

The Tax Function

This graph shows net taxes

(taxes minus transfer payments) as a function of aggregate income.

Y d

Y

T

Y d

Y

(

200

1 / 3 Y )

Y d

Y

200

1 / 3 Y

C

100

.

75 Y d

C

100

.

75 ( Y

200

1 / 3 Y )

Y

C

I

G

Y

 

Y

 

Y

C

 

I G

Y

100

.

75 Y

150

25 Y

100

100

.

Y

5

450

.

5 Y

Y

450

FIGURE 9B.2

Different Tax

Systems

When taxes are strictly lump-sum

( T = 100) and do not depend on income, the aggregate expenditure function is steeper than when taxes depend on income.

The Government Spending and Tax Multipliers Algebraically

C a (

T )

C

 

(

 

0 tY )

C

  bY

 bT

0

 btY

We know that Y = C + I + G . Through substitution we get

Y

  bY

 bT

0

 btY

 

G

C

Solving for Y :

Y

1

1 b bt

( a I G

 bT

0

)

This means that a $1 increase in G or I (holding a and T

0 constant) will increase the equilibrium level of Y by

1

1 b bt

1

=

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐+(𝑚𝑝𝑐 𝑥 𝑡)

Holding a , I , and G constant, a fixed or lump-sum tax cut (a cut in T

0

) will increase the equilibrium level of income by

 b

1

 b

 bt

−𝑚𝑝𝑐

=

1−𝑚𝑝𝑐+(𝑚𝑝𝑐 𝑥 𝑡)

Download