Papua New Guinea: A Nation in Waiting The Dance of Traditional and Introduced Structures in a Putative State By Bruce M. Harris East Asia Environment and Social Division The World Bank May 2007 (The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the World Bank.) Contents Introduction .............................................................. 3 Part I: The Political Economy of Papua New Guinea ................... 4 A. An Explanatory Framework ...................................................................................... 4 B. The Physical Foundation ........................................................................................... 5 C. The Traditional Societies of Papua New Guinea: Diversity in Melanesia ................ 6 a. The Pre-History of New Guinea ............................................................................. 6 b. Social and Economic Structure of New Guinea ..................................................... 7 c. The Big Man Complex: Achieved Systems ............................................................ 8 d. The Chiefly Complex: Ascriptive Systems.......................................................... 12 e. Matrilineality in PNG ............................................................................................ 13 f. Societies with Extensive Trading Relations .......................................................... 14 g. Similarities and Differences among Traditional PNG Societies........................... 15 D. Modern Political Developments.............................................................................. 18 a. Early Colonial History .......................................................................................... 18 b. The Regional Reaction to Independence and Inclusion ....................................... 18 E. The Emergence of the Current System .................................................................... 21 a. The Westminster System and Traditional Institutional Rules............................... 21 i. The Structure of Government: A Majoritarian and Consensus Cocktail……..22 ii. Electorates, the Electoral System and Big Man Politics……………………...23 iii. Parties, Governments and the Fragility of Power……………… ………….24 F. Changes in the System ............................................................................................. 29 a. Introduction ........................................................................................................... 29 b. The Public Service (Management) Act ................................................................. 30 c. The Organic Law on Provincial Government and Local Level Government ....... 30 d. The Organic Law on the Integrity of Political Parties .......................................... 33 e. The Limited Preferential Electoral System ........................................................... 34 G. Identity and Nationhood.......................................................................................... 35 Part II: Ways Forward ................................................ 37 A. Introduction ........................................................................................................... 37 B. From Conflict to Consensus at the Local Level: From the Bottom Up ................. 37 a. Some Integrative Local Level Processes............................................................... 38 b. Some Lessons of Local Level Development Activities and Potential Areas of Inquiry ....................................................................................................................... 40 C. The State as Nurturer of National Identity: from the Top Down ............................ 43 a. Oversight Institutions ............................................................................................ 43 b. The Importance of Consistency and Reliability of State Support......................... 44 c. Different Strokes for Different Folks: Equity in Resource Transfers ................... 45 d. Assessing Provincial Differences ......................................................................... 47 D. Where the Top Meets the Bottom: The District as Entry Point for Improving Governance and Development Outcomes ..................................................................... 49 a. National Parliamentarians as Stakeholders ........................................................... 50 b. CDD in the Context of Trans-Local Groups ......................................................... 50 PART III: CONCLUSION ............................................ 52 2 Introduction This paper is a partial analysis and assessment of the political economy of Papua New Guinea. I take an encompassing view of political economy, as the study of the interrelationships between political and economic processes, with both political and economic seen in the context of social and cultural structures. This includes not only national level processes, but the relations among local, district, provincial and national levels, and interactions between the variety of pre-existent traditional forms and those introduced from outside the country. The analysis is not academic. It is intended to answer the basic question posed in this paper: why has the state of Papua New Guinea failed to consistently provide resources, services and good governance to the citizens of the country. Why has there been a failure of development; a failure of governance? That there has been a failure of governance, of development, is well accepted. Many characterize PNG as an example of a “failed” or “fragile” state. I think it more useful to think of PNG as a “putative” state. The geopolitical structure of the country is an accident of its colonial history; there is little sense of nation, centrifugal tendencies remain strong among the regions, and there is little feeling among citizens that membership in the “state” of PNG is of benefit to people at the grassroots level. PNG is a state, a nation, that may develop in future, but at present is only a state in prospect. This is an important distinction. If the state has never been fully viable, the question is not how to reinvigorate state institutions and processes, but how to create them1; how to allow them to emerge. Reasonably, then, we need to understand why the state has not fully emerged; what are the factors that have worked against establishment of a viable state? Once we understand the reasons for the failure of state development, it should be possible to begin to identify strategies that will promote the development of a sound state. The paper is organized in two parts: Part I is an analysis of the political economy of Papua New Guinea arranged in several sections. In the first section I analyze the social and political structure and processes of the traditional societies of Papua New Guinea to understand the pre-existing situation in the country. I then look at the nature of the imported system and the rules by which it is intended to operate. Following this I look at how the two systems have interacted to produce the distinct political economy of Papua New Guinea today. Part II is a discussion of the way forward in which I try to draw the lessons of the analysis to outline some strategies for state building and the promotion of sustainable development outcomes. 1 This is not to say there has been no progress in the development of the state, only that it has been incomplete and there is much work remaining to be done. 3 Part I: The Political Economy of Papua New Guinea A. An Explanatory Framework There are a variety of explanatory frameworks available as heuristics to structure this analysis. I will make extensive use of the tools of the new institutional economics2 or exchange sociology to characterize traditional and imported systems and to conceptualize the interplay of the two and the implications of those interactions for the quality of governance. This framework is well suited to conceptualizing a situation in which preexisting traditional institutions come into contact with introduced institutions leading to potential ambiguity and mixed signals as well as opportunities on the part of the actors in the system to exploit those ambiguities. The approach distinguishes between institutions and organizations. Institutions are the shared and agreed “rules of the game” ordering interactions among actors and providing an incentive structure which establishes the preferences of those involved in the exchange under consideration, be it political, economic or social. They consist of formal constraints (including rules, laws, constitutions), informal constraints (such as norms of behavior, conventions, self-imposed codes of conduct), and their enforcement characteristics3. These rules determine those kinds of behavior that are culturally and socially appropriate in trying to achieve goals or objectives. As such they generate expectations about the rights and obligations of players within the context of a given interaction. While institutions consist of the rules of play, organizations are the “teams” people form in order to play the game. These may be political, economic or social groups, or some combination of the three. Organizations are established to achieve some objective; the ways in which those objectives may be attained are powerfully influenced by institutions, the rules for playing the game. The institutions define the opportunities available in any social arena; organizations emerge so groups of people can cooperate to take advantage of those opportunities. This framework suggests three basic questions we need to answer. First, what are the rules of the game that define the important institutions in traditional Papua New Guinea societies, and what is the nature of the organizations, the teams, that emerged to exploit those rules? Second, what are the institutions and organizations characterizing the introduced system and how did those institutions and organizations interact with the preexisting structures? Finally, how can adjustments be made in both sets of institutions so the organizations responding to the rules of the game are oriented towards objectives that will work to the benefit of the country as a whole, and lead to good governance and positive development outcomes? 2 See. E.g., North, D.C., The New Institutional Economics and Development, Washington University in St. Louis, also at www.econ.iastate.edu/tesfatsi/NewInstE.North 3 See Benham, Alexandra, A Glossary for the New Institutional Economics at http://www.coase.org/nieglossary.htm#REFInstitutions 4 B. The Physical Foundation Before I discuss the traditional societies of New Guinea, a brief word about the island itself is in order. The physical nature of the island is the underlying reality to which all human societies occupying the area have had to adapt and has fundamentally conditioned the nature of that adaptation. It is impossible to understand the reasons for the emergence of the particular kinds of traditional societies that came to populate the island without understanding this physical substrate. The sheer size and diversity of the island is infrequently appreciated. If superimposed on Europe the “island” would stretch from Portugal in the west to Romania in the east, and at its midsection would reach from the Mediterranean in the south to the English Channel in the north. The island is larger than Turkey, over twice the size of Zimbabwe. The country of Papua New Guinea alone, composing something more than half the island, is half again as large as Germany and nearly the size of France. The physical environment has been categorized into over forty distinct geographic and biodiversity areas4, ranging from montane and alpine wilderness in the higher elevations of the Highlands (with many permanently snow-capped mountains higher than any in Europe or the continental U.S.) to mid- and lower montane, heavily forested mixed growth regions, through old growth wet rainforest, savannah and riverine gallery forest, lowland alluvial forests, coastal swamps and plains and a variety of environments on the larger offshore islands. The island and country are huge; few countries on earth contain the range of environments of PNG. Though the country encompasses a stunning range of physical environments, in general it can be divided into at least four large and largely distinct regions: the Highlands, the south (Papuan) coast, the north (Momase) coast and the Islands. There is a good deal of variety within regions, but each region has nonetheless historically been relatively separate from the others and the societies in each region have greater similarities and more intense relations with one another than with societies and cultures outside the region. These physical factors have important consequences. Though technically an island, most of the population is not oriented towards the sea, but instead resides in a mountainous, rich and largely inaccessible interior, in lowland forest or savannah or in riverine/ lacustrine environments and traditionally lived their lives without ever seeing the sea. Problems of communication, transport and all other aspects of access are those of a large and rugged landmass with substantial offshore islands, not those of a small island or series of islands. At the same time the richness of the physical environment has meant local groups are able to be generally self-sufficient and insular. This brings us to the traditional societies of PNG and the sociocultural context. 4 See, e.g., J.F. Swartzendruber, Papua New Guinea Conservation Needs Assessment Synopsis Report at: www.worldwildlife.org/bsp/publications/asia/papua_synopsis/synopsis.html 5 C. The Traditional Societies of Papua New Guinea: Diversity in Melanesia a. The Pre-History of New Guinea The physical realities of the country are reflected in its sociocultural structure. Papua New Guinea is one of a set of Melanesian countries stretching roughly from Timor Leste and Halmahera in the west to Fiji in the east, and to Vanuatu and New Caledonia in the south. Melanesian societies are ancient. The most recent work (much of it based on mitochondrial DNA analysis)5 indicates much of Melanesia was peopled through an ongoing migration beginning in Africa about 150,000 years ago and moving through New Guinea and into Australia between 40,000 and 60,000 years ago. Most estimates are that these people had developed horticulture by at least 10,000 years ago, and some theorise they began practicing subsistence horticulture as early as 25,000 years ago, before any other human population6. These early groups were Australoid hunter-gatherers, but around 5 - 7,000 BC a secondary movement of Mongoloid horticulturalists began from mainland China and Formosa (Taiwan) that eventually moved along the coasts of New Guinea and into the Pacific7. These people brought both more advanced horticultural practices and the Austronesian group of languages8. The Austronesian languages are represented particularly in the larger offshore islands (New Britain, New Ireland and Bougainville) while the languages of the mainland are generally classed as Papuan or Trans-New Guinean. Both Papuan and Trans-New Guinean are language groups defined by exclusion – they are defined as all the languages of the area that are non-Austronesian languages, but do not actually represent linguistic phyla of their own. These are the languages that predated the arrival of the Austronesian speakers, and dominate the New Guinea mainland. In fact, they consist of hundreds of distinct languages; the latest estimate by Ethnologue is that there are 820 living languages in PNG alone, with at least another 270 in the 5 See Melanesian mtDNA Complexity, Jonathan S. Friedlaender, Françoise R. Friedlaender, Jason A. Hodgson, Matthew Stoltz, George Koki, Gisele Horvat, Sergey Zhadanov, Theodore G. Schurr, and D. Andrew Merriwether at http://www.pubmedcentral.nih.gov/articlerender.fcgi?tool=pubmed&pubmedid=17327912 6 See, e.g., Background to Pacific Archaeology and Prehistory by Patrick V. Kirch at http://sscl.berkeley.edu/~oal/background/background.htm 7 It is generally accepted that the original Australoid migrations penetrated as far as New Guinea and into Australia, but it was not until the later migrations originating in Formosa that Vanuatu, New Caledonia, and, eventually, Fiji were populated. 8 The Austroneisan group of languages has about ten primary branches, all but one of which are found on Formosa (modern Taiwan), thereby establishing Formosa as the most likely point of origin. All the Austronesian languages of southeast Asia and the Pacific are in the primary branch known as MalayoPolynesian. 6 Indonesian half of the island, for a total of over 1,000 languages on the island as a whole9. Human populations, then, have occupied New Guinea for probably 50,000 years, and for at least 10,000 years they have been primarily subsistence horticulturalists, supplemented by hunting and gathering. The richness and diversity of flora and fauna in New Guinea has allowed efficient subsistence (supplemented by hunting and gathering) without moving over large tracts of land. A given area could support a larger number of groups than in less rich environments, and this is one reason horticulture, or basic gardening, did not lead to more intensive settled agricultural practices, or large-scale field cropping, as occurred in other locations. Both the linguistic and anthropological evidence point to the likelihood that from an early time the societies of Melanesia, and particularly those of mainland New Guinea, took on a distinct structure. They were relatively constrained in the areas they occupied, relatively small scale, socially and culturally compartmentalized and fragmented and with modest levels of contact with groups at any distance from themselves. This is supported by the linguistic evidence indicating most of the languages of these groups developed locally, rather than representing imported language groups10. This small scale, compartmentalized social structure is an enduring feature of Melanesian life that flows as an unintended consequence from the richness of the environment in which these groups found themselves. b. Social and Economic Structure of New Guinea From the time of the earliest ethnographic work these basic features of Melanesian life were identified as underpinning the social and economic existence of the vast majority of New Guineans. Groups are arranged by a number of different social principles with respect to descent, inheritance and status. Descent groups range from patrilineal groups to matrilineal and cognatic (through both lines); inheritance may also be through the partiline, the matriline or both. Status and power may be achieved, as in the big man complex, or ascribed, as in inherited chiefly systems. However, overall there are some general similarities. To the extent that we can speak of “tribes” (or ethnic/cultural groups) such tribes generally consist of a series of residential groups related by kinship. Each of these groups is fairly independent and generally amounts to no more than several villages or a village and a group of associated hamlets. Perhaps the defining feature of these groups is that they are what Sahlins has called “segmental”11. That is, each of these relatively small groups of kin-related members is independent of other, surrounding groups, has independent control over its land and 9 This represents about one seventh of the total number of languages on earth, which Ethnologue now estimates at around 6,900. Ethnologue can be visited at http://www.ethnologue.com 10 See Papuan Pasts: Cultural, Linguistic and Biological Histories of Papuan-speaking Peoples, ed. by Andrew Pawley, Robert Attenborough, Jack Golson and Robin Hide in which it is argued that “The northern third of New Guinea is the most linguistically diverse part of the planet, containing a concentration of disparate language families consistent with in situ diversification in the late Pleistocene.” 11 See Sahlins, Marshall D. Poor Man, Rich Man, Big-Man, Chief: Political Types in Melanesia and Polynesia in Comparative Studies in Society and History, 1963, Cambridge University Press. 7 economic resources, and is the general equivalent of all others in the area in political power and status. The groups do not aggregate into any larger political entity – they are not, as in Polynesia, pyramidal, with smaller segments combining into larger segments that, in turn, come together in yet larger and more encompassing polities crowned by an overall political (and often religious) authority. In PNG, social interaction, trust and interdependence is intense within each group, but drops off precipitously between groups. Relations between groups are highly ritualized, revolving around such activities as marriage links, ceremonial exchanges and feasts, tribal war and other conflicts arising as a result of disagreements over land or other perceived slights or insults. This radical disjunction between the institutionalized rules of behavior within the group as opposed to between groups is perhaps the central aspect of PNG social life and constitutes, as we will see, both the greatest challenge and main opportunity in the process of nation building. c. The Big Man Complex: Achieved Systems It is in both intra- and inter-group exchanges that economic and, by extension, political power are built in most Melanesian societies. In most of mainland PNG a defining characteristic of Melanesian society is that political power and authority are achieved, not inherited. The “big man” of Melanesian society12 becomes such through his own efforts, not through ascription as a member of a chiefly lineage or as a result of a position in a feudal structure. To achieve the position of “big man” requires, above all, the creation of a group of followers, a faction. The larger the faction the more power accrues to the leader. However, not everyone is a potential big man – to be such requires demonstration of certain qualities such as oratorical ability, valor in tribal war (including, often, the ascription by his followers of supernatural abilities), and qualities of personal and social persuasion13. Probably the most critical skill is the ability to effectively utilize social reciprocity to one’s advantage, a process through which one gradually constructs a faction of supporters. The skilled big man above all has the ability to choose his spots for support of others by distributing to them things of value and articles of wealth, such as food, pigs, and shell money, in public arenas in which those on the receiving end of the big man’s “generosity” are publicly indebted to him. In order to do so he must start by mobilizing 12 The big man institution is characteristic of most of the Highlands of PNG, and extends along the major rivers (the Sepik, the Fly and the Purari) to the foothills and lowlands towards the shore. Along both the north and south shores, and into the main offshore islands the complex weakens and a variety of other institutions order society, including ascriptive societies as discussed below. 13 There is a lively discussion of the extent to which Highlands, and other, societies in New Guinea conform to the standard view of “big man” societies as egalitarian systems in which big men achieve status through skillfully playing the “reciprocity game”, and there are a number of nuanced interpretations of the system. See, e.g., Inequality in New Guinea Highlands Societies. Andrew Strathern, ed. Cambridge Papers in Social Anthropology, 11. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1982. However, it is safe to say there is general agreement that the outline of the picture presented in this paper is a real reflection of sociopolitical organization in much of Melanesia. 8 additional labor to generate economic goods. Initially this may be done by enlisting his own family in gardening and the raising of pigs. Sometimes aspiring big men adopt children from families who cannot fully support them or offer a home to social isolates in the village; this avails him of additional sets of hands to work in the garden to produce more food for distribution or as fodder for pigs. As he builds his wealth he may begin to provide resources for relatives for ceremonial purposes when required, thereby building obligations on their part to reciprocate when he demands it. Another strategy is to marry into several families in the immediate locality; increasing his access to land and labor. He may then begin to provide brideprice for promising younger men, adding to the group who are obligated to him and building his cadre of followers. As his wealth and the size of his faction grow he can provide support to wider groups for marriages, death ceremonies, other rites of passage and construction of public buildings such as a men’s house. All these exchanges bring the big man not only the indebtedness of those he has assisted, who must return to him at his request all he has provided in addition to what is effectively an interest payment, but also public reputation as a generous and powerful man. Once he achieves a certain level of wealth and has a core of followers, the big man on the move will turn his attention to building his reputation beyond the local group from which he emerged. He will then take primary responsibility for leading his faction in interactions with other groups, led by other big men in the area. These activities may include tribal war, ceremonial feasts during which negotiations are held and compensation paid following a tribal war, marriage ceremonies and exchange or other ceremonial occasions bringing separate groups together. In many areas of the Highlands large scale feasts are held that amount to little more than a challenge on the part of one big man to another to see who is able to provide the greatest amount of largesse for the greatest number of people. The genuine big man is, therefore, a compelling figure, in the full sense of the term. He has impressive oratorical skills, the instincts of a shrewd businessman able to manipulate the system of reciprocity and exchange to his own ends, and is, above all, a populist political leader with charismatic qualities who has gained the unquestioned allegiance of a large group of dedicated followers who have nearly unquestioned faith in him. The big man also stands astride the dividing line between the two social arenas, that of his lineage group and that of surrounding groups. But though his motivation for action in both arenas is ultimately personal power, his strategies differ depending on the arena. Within the arena of the lineage from which he sprang his strategies revolve around support in the provision of resources for those who require it, extension of key links (through marriage, adoption, and the like) to expand his base of support, frequent redistribution of resources to continually build support and provision of status to his group through his own rise in status. The big man also may serve as an adjudicator in cases of intra-group dispute, working always toward consensus through a process of negotiation and accommodation. 9 With respect to groups outside his own the strategies are more competitive (and often violent). His interest is to attempt to lead his supporters to victory in any conflicts, to shrewdly extract advantage in compensation negotiations, to shame other big men by eclipsing them in provision of resources for feasting and exchange and to establish dominance over others in the area through his own accumulation of wealth and social standing. As we will see below, both the constitution of these teams and the strategies by which they play the game have served as basic models for operating in the modern political arena. There is an essential contradiction at the core of the big man complex. As Sahlins and others have pointed out, the heart of the support for the big man is his “faction” of supporters, those who he has indebted through his redistributive practices. As the big man becomes a big man for an area exceeding his original lineage and supplants other big men, he becomes responsible for redistributing resources to an ever larger group if he is to maintain his status. However, this leads to a need to increase the productive levels of his home group, and can restrict his ability to meet his redistributive responsibilities to them as he is forced to channel redistribution into a wider area to maintain control. This can lead to defections from the ranks of supporters, and is one reason the big man system is inherently unstable.14 At base this instability grows out of the nature of legitimacy in the traditional system. The big man embodies what Weber called charismatic authority. The big man’s legitimacy, status and power are based on personal qualities; when he dies or is removed from the scene his faction rarely survives him. Even if a big man is successful in extending the area of his prestige and control well beyond his natal group, and manages to overcome the obstacles to maintaining that control in the face of the increasing demand for goods and wealth, there is little chance that power will survive his death. There are always many big men in the same area waiting to step into the breach and to hive off followers when a vacuum in authority develops. Big man status is not often passed from father to son. There is little likelihood his child will embody the same rare combination of skills necessary to assume his position, and even if the child did have such skills potentially, their possession only guarantees one has the possibility of becoming a big man in future. Members of the big man’s “faction” do not have a social obligation to carry over their debts and allegiances to another generation, and will quickly desert to another individual who is able to meet their immediate needs and expectations. Thus the topography of power and charismatic authority where the institution of the big man holds sway changes frequently and oscillates wildly over time. Even while the big man is active he is always at risk of losing the trust or allegiance of his followers, and he is under constant pressure to both redistribute resources to them and impress them with his abilities in a number of arenas. The big man’s organization – his team - is in constant flux and at constant risk. In similar fashion, his relations with other big men are impermanent and subject to change, often sudden and dramatic as allies abandon him for 14 See, e.g., Brunton, R. 1989. The Cultural Instability of Egalitarian Societies in Man (N.S.) 24, 673-81. 10 another big man to mount a challenge to his authority. The nature of the rules of the game, and the incentives for the actors engaged in the game effectively prevent the permanent establishment of more extensive political groups and structures. The political lesson of the insituttion of the big man is that there is no permanence to political organizations; the organizations change as circumstances dictate. The institution of the big man can never lead to the kind of large scale political structures found in Polynesia. Finally, the institution of the big man is a socially exclusive form in the most rudimentary sense. The institution, and the organizations formed to “play the game”, are, as the name implies, the purview of men alone.15 Women need not apply. In the traditional big man complex women have two roles. The first is as a social and, importantly, economic alliance between households or kinship groups through the marriage link. The important aspect is the link, not the woman, and the status and access to resources the link affords. The male pays handsomely to establish it, and the more powerful the family into which he marries the higher the brideprice to be paid, confirmation that it is the link and not the woman being purchased. For the aspiring big man this is an instrumental decision of some importance and is made in the context of his assessment of its utility for his future career. The second role of the woman is as a source of labor, both in the “ordinary” household and in the household of the emergent big man. In these societies women take primary responsibility for most of the labor-intensive activities. Women tend the children, procure water, firewood and other necessities several times a day, often requiring a substantial journey and considerable weight on the return trip (perhaps including the additional weight of an infant who is taken along). Women also bring all the foodstuffs from the gardens and prepare meals and keep house. This is the lot of a woman in an ordinary household. In the household of an aspiring big man the burdens are even greater as the woman is under pressure to increase her production of foodstuffs so the big man has more resources for his ceremonial purposes, important transactions, or for more pigs which are then translated into greater wealth. Often a hierarchy emerges in which one wife is dominant and is responsible for overall organization of the household, with other wives subordinate to her. In sum, in these societies the relations between the sexes are exceptionally inequitable. This is most starkly illustrated in the sexual division of labor. At base women are the producers, the source of labor, while men are the transactors, the ones who play the game of power, wealth and status. To play that game the men require resources; it is women who produce them. Though women invest much more labor in the production of goods and wealth, the fact that men are the transactors means that men monopolize the decisionmaking process in virtually all arenas - political, social, and economic. Women produce the wealth; men mobilize the wealth and tend to monopolize the benefits. See Garap, Sarah Women Caught in a “Big Man” Culture: Challenges for Future Democracy and Governance, State, Society and Governance in Melanesia Project, SSGM Conference Papers, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Australian National University. 2004. 15 11 d. The Chiefly Complex: Ascriptive Systems This discussion of big men has been extended, partly because some form of the big man complex is widespread throughout PNG, and particularly on the mainland. However, the charismatic authority of the big man and his achieved political position is not the only model present in PNG. Melanesia is also home to broadly ascriptive systems based on inherited position in which certain lineages continue, as long as they produce offspring, to provide individuals who inherit leadership positions. This is a common model in Vanuatu and the Solomon Islands, and, though less frequent, in several of the major offshore islands of PNG, as well as, at least incipiently, in a number of the shore areas of the main island. On the offshore islands the institution is notably widespread on the island of Bougainville and in the Trobriands of Milne Bay Province. The “chiefly” system in Bougainville16 (mainly in the south and north of the island, as well as on the nearby island of Buka), the Trobriands and other areas of the country leads to a style of social and political life distinct from that characterizing areas in which the big man complex is entrenched. In these areas political power is based on what Weber called traditional authority; authority flows from linkages to ancestors established through real or claimed lines of descent. This has several consequences that distinguish the political and social system from those in which the big man flourishes. First, political stability is greater because position is inherited and does not have to be achieved with each generation; there are clear rules establishing who assumes authority with the passing of someone with traditional authority. The death of a leader does not produce the chaos of a political vacuum provoking a scramble among contenders for political leadership. This imparts a political predictability to society absent in the areas in which the big man dominates. Second, the chiefly system promotes greater stability in relations among groups, since neither the locus nor the extent of political power shifts dramatically with the loss of a key political figure or with the passing of power from one generation to another. Third, the chiefly system provides at least a latent mechanism for establishing more encompassing and stable political structures extending over larger geographic areas. The main institutions of the chiefly system are therefore more stable and persistent and the organizations formed lead to a more stable political system than those of the big man complex in which the turmoil of constantly shifting personal alliances and allegiances expend much of the political capital of a society. But though these systems were more stable, in PNG the chiefly systems almost never led to more encompassing jurisdictions as occurred in some areas of the Solomons, Vanuatu, Fiji and throughout Polynesia. 16 There is considerable discussion of the extent to which the systems in southern and northern Bougainville and Buka were actually systems in which there was strict inheritance of political position – i.e., the extent to which they were ascribed systems. Today there is a general notion in the province that the traditional systems were “chiefly” systems, and there is little doubt that traditionally certain lineages tended to inherit certain positions, even though this was certainly not as ascriptive as many Polynesian systems nor did it, at least traditionally, lead to the “pyramiding” of political systems to a political apex as occurred in Polynesia. 12 Interestingly, it was with the difficulties, particularly in Bougainville, during the postIndependence period that the traditional chiefly structure was called on to serve as a framework for wider political processes in the province.17 Thus, following the withdrawal of the PNG Defence Force in 1990 a series of councils of chiefs was established based on “traditional” structures. This included a three level system of Clan Councils of Chiefs (CCCs), Village Councils of Chiefs (VCCs) and Area Councils of Chiefs (ACCs), though, in fact, such “councils” had not generally existed traditionally. The subsequent history of Bougainville has seen a number of shifts in this system, but even today there is a general feeling in the province that traditional leaders and traditional leadership structures have an important role to play in the Autonomous Province. The chiefly system is also distinct from the big man complex in the role of women. In most chiefly societies women play an important role, and in some, notably those that are matrilineal, women have control of the most important social and economic resources, including land. In PNG there is substantial overlap of matrilineality and chiefly systems. e. Matrilineality in PNG In some parts of Bougainville, as well as in New Britain (particularly among the Tolai of the Gazelle Peninsula) and some parts of Manus and the Trobriands, societies were organized along matrilineal lines. Though the details vary according to locality, this means that in many of these societies women wielded considerable power, politically, economically and socially, in contrast to their position in traditional societies in most of the rest of the country. Overall, the situation of women in the traditional societies of Papua New Guinea, and particularly in the areas characterized by the big man complex, is as inequitable as that in any country of the world18. However, among the matrilineal societies noted above women are in a generally stronger position, and there is less resistance to women participating in decisionmaking processes and sharing authority in general, with clear consequences for inclusion and governance in the modern state. In these matrilineal societies women are more than mere producers or instrumental links to powerful families to be exploited through marriage. In much of Bougainville, and in the Trobriands, the main elements of economic wealth pass through the female line. Land, the sine qua non of economic power, passes from mother to daughter, not from father to son. The male child in a household has his primary allegiance, and owes much of his socialization to his mother’s brother rather than his father, since it is through his mother’s line that he will inherit any wealth or land for his use on his passage to adulthood or marriage. Instrumentally and in terms of social status and economic power, 17 See, e.g., Anthony Regan, Traditional Leaders and Conflict Resolution in Bougainville: Reforming the Present by Re-writing the Past? in S. Dinnen and A. Ley (eds), Reflections on Violence in Melanesia, Hawkins Press and Asia Pacific Press, Leichhardt:290-304. See, e.g., Margaret Mead, “Sex and Temperament in Three Primitive Societies” in which she discusses masculine and feminine roles among the Mundugumor, Tchambuli and Arapesh societies of PNG. 18 13 his father is much less important, since the economic goods, and land, to which his father has access will pass not to his father’s children, but to his father’s sister’s children. This basic fact of matrilineal life – the control of land through the female line – necessarily gives women a much larger role in the everyday decisions made in the household and village. The institutions of a matrilineal society inevitably include rules of the game that include women as key, sometimes the key actors. This means the organizations, the teams constituted to pursue objectives in ways defined by the rules of the game, include women in focal positions, often in leadership positions. It is frequently the case in such societies that women allow the men to make day to day decisions, but when more important, contentious or long term issues are to be addressed women tend to step forward and take an more active role. The integral roles women play in such societies has important consequences for their involvement and participation in the institutions and organizations that arise with imported systems such as those introduced during the colonial period and entrenched with independence. f. Societies with Extensive Trading Relations I have noted the tendency of most traditional New Guinea societies to be somewhat compartmentalized with respect to economic activity. In most instances, and this includes the chiefly societies of Bougainville, economic exchange occurs primarily with those small scale societies immediately adjacent to the society in question. However, there were exceptions to this among traditional New Guinea societies. Some parts of the country were unusual in the extent of their external trading relations, both substantial and ceremonial, and those societies were more externally oriented and predisposed to engaging with outside groups than were the more compartmentalized groups in the rest of the island. The Motu-Koitabu people of the modern-day Central Province shared some aspects of a chiefly society in that the paramount position in the iduhu, the main lineage or clan group, was inherited through primogeniture, but they had little authority outside their immediate group and there was little overarching political structure.19 However, these people had traditions of long distance trade that gave their societies a distinctive outwardlooking aspect. Partly this is because they lived in one of the least favorable environments for year-round horticulture, so they developed a long-distance sea trading network, known as the Hiri expeditions, linking them to what is now the Gulf province in order to supplement their food resources. Sailing in fleets of lakatoi, multi-hulled outrigger canoes carrying as many as 500 people, they traveled annually to several Gulf villages where they traded thousands of clay pots for sago, foodstuffs and other necessities. On arrival they spent a month or more during which ceremonial feasts were held, marriages consummated between the two peoples, and long term relationships cemented. The Hiri expeditions lasted months and resulted in the exchange of considerable amounts of manufactured and agricultural trade goods. These expeditions were massive undertakings, and they served to unite the Motu Koitabu, into a single people with an 19 See Goddard, Michael, Rethinking Western Motu Descent Groups, in Oceania, June, 2001. 14 identity extending well beyond individual villages or groups of villages. Partly as a result, the Motu-Koitabu had little history of inter-tribal warfare, and some authors feel they were poised, at the time of independence, to develop a more encompassing political structure that would have included a number of local groups, at least partly as a result of the interdependence engendered as a result of the annual Hiri expeditions. Another group that engaged in long-distance exchange was the Trobriand Islanders in modern Milne Bay Province, a group we have already discussed several times. In their case the trade was less a necessity of livelihood and more a matter of the ceremonial establishment of prestige and social status. A hereditary chieftainship society, they were a part of the anthropologically famous Kula Ring in which two kinds of valuables were exchanged over a networks stretching through as many as eighteen or twenty islands and a thousand kilometers. In one direction, clockwise, a shell disk necklace called “soulava” was sent from island to island, and was exchanged for an shell armband called “mwale” that moved in a counter-clockwise direction. Many of the more important armbands and necklaces were named, and they proceeded in an endless cycle around the Ring, returning to their starting point once every generation or so. The number of Kula partners an individual had was a measure of social status. Interestingly, it was the relationships rather than the possession of the valuable per se that was important. No one actually held onto a particular necklace or armband for a long period of time, but instead used it to induce a sense of obligation on the part of selected partners to whom the valuable was sent. The Kula Ring was an integrative mechanism that established social relations among a large number of societies ranging across an extensive area. This system served as a peaceful means of integrating a large area to the east and southeast of modern PNG into a regional trading network. g. Similarities and Differences among Traditional PNG Societies This brief overview of different regions of modern day PNG shows there are both differences and similarities within and across regions. Among the similarities are, first, that members of traditional society are not equal. Papua New Guinea has been for thousands of years, and remains today dominated by social and political systems defined in kinship-based exclusive terms in which every member of society is seen as different and, in many cases, with different rights and privileges. These sets of rights and privileges, whether in a big man complex or a chiefly system, are defined in a variety of ways, by sex, age, social position, presumed links of lineage to ancestors both real and totemic, by birth order, by marriage links, by control of land and a range of other factors. The rights and responsibilities of women, in particular, vary across societies, and in general their position in traditional society is lower than men, and often considerably so. Rights within the group differed fundamentally from rights between groups. Second, the basic unit in the traditional system has always been local and relatively insular. Even in the chiefly areas there was little inclination or tendency to bring together local groups into larger political structures, unlike the situation in Polynesia. In the 15 Highlands and other areas in which the big man complex was dominant political groupings beyond the local lineage were frequent but fleeting, and rarely survived the demise of the big man who had provoked them. Though the Trobrianders and the MotuKoitabu engaged in long distance trading and exchange networks, in neither case did this lead to equivalently encompassing political structures, though in the case of the Trobrianders some chiefs did hold political sway over a dozen or more villages. Still, in the majority of instances in traditional PNG relations between local groups were tense, often competitive and as often violent. Some inter-group conflicts were highly ritualized, with strict and well institutionalized protocols for behavior between groups.20 However, others were not and included personal fights, raids, fortuitous attacks on individuals and ambushes. Some of these latter were themselves seen as justification for engaging in full scale tribal war. Ultimately, however, there were usually well established mechanisms for re-establishing some form of stability, generally involving ceremonial exchange, payment of compensation and feasting, though in fact intermittent conflict and attacks between groups tended to be an enduring feature of inter-group relations. Though relations between groups were often competitive and even violent and highly ritualized, relations within groups were based much more on consensus, cooperation, support and public discussion and negotiation. Strathern21 notes the importance in intra-group conflict resolution of public discussion in which the disputants are brought together in front of the entire community to argue their cases. She also notes the importance in traditional society of providing everyone in the group with an opportunity to express an opinion. This is the essence of consensus building, and at the end of the process the elders or other leaders of the group will make a judgment that has, in effect, already been negotiated by the collective. Charles Yala notes that “The actual process of traditional conflict resolution resembled modern court hearings, with the entire community acting as jurors and the presiding judge being the village or community elder. Where necessary, witnesses were called upon to assist community elders in making their final decision, which was backed by community consensus.”22 Because of the tendency to insularity of local social groups widespread interaction among these various societies was, with a few exceptions, infrequent. For the millennia preceding colonialism the continental main island was effectively completely separate from the large offshore islands. The commerce between New Britain and the Highlands was virtually nil, and to the extent that it occurred it was through scores, probably hundreds of intermediaries. 20 This includes tribal war, which had well understood codes of behavior, including acceptable and unacceptable justifications for initiating warfare, ritualized battles and highly organized ritual activities to negotiate compensation and exchange following conclusion of the war (which, at least traditionally, generally resulted in few actual casualties). See, e.g., Brown, Paula, Conflict in the New Guinea Highlands in Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 26 No. 3, Sept. 1982 (pp. 525 – 546). 21 Strathern, M. (1974). “Managing Information: The Problems of a Dispute-Settler (Mt. Hagen)”. In Contention and Dispute. A.L. Epstein, ed., Canberra, ANU Press. 22 See James Weiner, Abby McLeod and Charles Yala, Aspects of Conflict in the Contemporary New Guinea Highlands in Discussion Paper 2002/4, the State Society and Governance in Melanesia Project, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, the Australian National University. 16 A kina shell (the precursor, at least in name, of the modern currency) could make its way to the Highlands, where it was considered, given its rarity, an item of wealth. But those who possessed the kina shell in the Highlands had no real idea that it was from a marine animal, that it was from an environment in which one could look at a body of water and not see the opposite shore, in short, that it had anything to do with an ocean since they had absolutely no concept of what an ocean might be. While there were general similarities among most of these societies, the differences were in many respects as significant. Social and cultural forms, though sharing general respects such as an emphasis on clans and lineages, differed substantially in detail, with some areas characterized by achieved position while others were based on ascribed/inherited position with chiefly lineages passing power from generation to generation, some matrilineal/matrilocal, others matrilineal/bilocal, others patrilineal and so on. The basic elements of livelihood varied at least as much, with subsistence activities ranging from sweet potato cultivation in the Highlands to a dependence on marine resources on the shores, to sago and taro production in the vast lowlands in modern-day Gulf, Western and Sepik provinces. There were cultures based on riverine commerce, oceangoing peoples along the shore with extensive trading networks to others along the shore and to other islands, and rainforest horticulturalists and hunters and gatherers in the interior. Among the most important differences for our purposes, of course, are in the sources and nature of authority and in the control of economic resources, land and other goods. The charismatic authority of the big man was flexible and ever-mutating, militating against long-term establishment of stable higher level political structures, and this was the dominant system in the island. The ascriptive chiefly system was more stable and held more promise of enduring higher level structures, but was restricted to a smaller area. Women’s roles were also important differences, and to some extent these overlapped with the big man/chiefly distinction with women tending to have more power and greater levels of participation in the chiefly societies while suffering extreme social inequities in the big man societies. These differences in traditional societies have led to significant distinctions in the ways in which those societies have interacted with those political, economic and social systems introduced during the colonial period that became the formal/legal basis of the “state” following independence. In most cases traditional societies reacted strongly against the imposition of a state that claimed legitimacy and domination based on legal-rational authority. However, the nature of that reaction varied depending on whether the preexisting traditional society was one based on charismatic or traditional authority. Further, an almost complete failure on the part of the colonial powers to understand the basis of authority and legitimacy in traditional societies (or, at the least, to understand how those bases would likely interact with the imported system) meant that moves to address the problems that emerged in the formation of the state consistently entailed attempts to strengthen the formal state institutions while failing to attend to the way in which those institutions articulated with the traditional mechanisms of decisionmaking, authority and legitimacy. I now turn to consider these more recent developments. 17 D. Modern Political Developments a. Early Colonial History There is not sufficient time in this note to provide even an overview of the history of colonialism in Papua New Guinea. However, for our purposes a brief outline will suffice. The point is to recognize the essential serendipity of the process that led to the emergence of the “state” of Papua New Guinea. The original European explorations were by the Portuguese and Spanish in the early 16th century. The first colonial claims were of the western half of the island by the Dutch in 1828 and of the eastern half by the English and Germans in the later years of the century, with the English taking the southeastern portion of the eastern half of the island and the Germans the northeastern portion. Australia assumed full responsibility for the Territory of Papua in 1906 under the Papua Act, and from the outbreak of World War I the German New Guinea Territory (Deutsch Neu Guinea) was effectively administered by Australia as well and following World War I Australia was given a mandate by the League of Nations (in 1921) to administer the territory. After World War II the two territories were placed under Australian jurisdiction as United Nations Trust Territories and were amalgamated for administrative purposes though the legal distinction between the two was maintained. The western half of the island was annexed by Indonesia under a controversial process known as the Act of Free Choice in 1969. It was, therefore, through a process driven as much by historical accident as by any sense of social or cultural integrity that the great variety of societies occupying the area from New Ireland in the north to Bougainville and the Trobriands and through Papua, the Highlands and the north coast came to constitute a single entity. It was an entity unknown to anyone but the colonial powers. It soon became clear that the pre-existing social and political systems were not automatically abrogated and transformed by the mere introduction of the forms of a western political and economic system. Indeed, the tendency to assume that the forms of western political, juridical and other systems automatically means acceptance of the rules of the game of such systems has been a limiting factor in developing workable strategies for development in the country. b. The Regional Reaction to Independence and Inclusion These realities were given stark confirmation during the late 1960s and 1970s when the country was being “prepared” for Independence. From the moment, indeed, even before the state of PNG was formed, there were strong forces resisting inclusion and fighting to either prevent incorporation or, once it occurred, to at least modify, if not reverse it. At the time of independence there was little sense on the part of the various regions that they should constitute a single nation, and there was considerable confusion about what areas of the former territories of Papua and New Guinea, including notably some islands such as Bougainville as well as the Papuan coast, would be included in the new nation. 18 When it became clear the Australians intended to create a single country out of the entire expanse of Papua, New Guinea, the Highlands and the Islands, pre-existing separatist movements became more widespread and stronger and new ones developed. The more organized of these movements, unsurprisingly, emerged in those areas that had some combination of traditional, as opposed to charismatic, authority structures, a certain degree of ethnic/tribal homogeneity, and/or traditions of long-range trade or exchange that provided perspective on other societies and cultures. Essentially this meant the strongest and most organized reactions to the imposition of a state defined by outsiders were from the islands and Papuan coast. i. The Mataungan Movement of New Britain In New Britain the Mataungan Movement emerged in the late 1960s, at least partly in reaction to the plans of the Colonial Administration to replace an all Tolai Local Government Council with a council including other ethnic groups23. However, the Mataungan Movement quickly mutated into a political movement that in some respects operated as an alternative government to the colonial administration, and some in the movement expressed a preference for at least autonomy if not independence for New Britain and/or the islands region. It is no accident that the Tolai were a large and homogeneous ethnic group who recognized themselves as such, largely because of their matrilineal structure. Even though, as many ethnographers have noted, the Tolai were organized in small, local units that were frequently in conflict, the matrilineal nature of Tolai society had a strongly integrative effect. All of Tolai society, across the Gazelle Peninsula and even into its points of origin in New Ireland, was divided into two exogamous units represented by two female lines, and these divisions regulated marriage for all Tolai24. An extensive network of marriage relations therefore mitigated the competition between the smaller residential units and gave an element of commonality to all Tolai. This unity found its expression in the Mataungan Movement and the concerted reaction against the plans of the colonial administration. ii. The North Solomons Republic Movement An even stronger reaction occurred in Bougainville. There the strength of the separatist movement was such that a group led by Leo Hannet and Father John Momis actually declared the independence of the “North Solomons Republic” three weeks before the country of PNG became independent, and in doing so forced the emerging central government to create the provincial government system to devolve sufficient power to mollify the Bougainvilleans, with ultimately troubling consequences for the development 23 The Tolai are the dominant, both in numbers and politically, ethnic group in East New Britain Province. They are descendants of a migratory group that arrived in the Gazelle Peninsula area from New Ireland sometime in the mid-eighteenth century and extended their control over land previously controlled by the Pomio, Baining and several smaller pre-existing ethnic groups. 24 See, e.g. A.L. Epstein, Tambu: The Shell Money of the Tolai at www.appropriateeconomics.org/asia/png/Tabu_-_Shell_Money_of_the_Tolai_-_Epstein 19 of the country. The continued separatist sentiments in the province have recently led (through a tortuous 25 year process) to its designation as an autonomous province with an Autonomous Bougainville Government. In the case of Bougainville there was a pre-existing system of traditional authority that lent stability to the local political systems, and though there were few overarching political structures uniting the local systems there was a long history of peaceful interaction among those systems. These groups felt little affinity with the populations of the mainland and saw little utility to the integration of the island with the rest of what was portended as Papua New Guinea, and they were sufficiently organized to make those feelings widely known. iii. The Papua Besena Movement Less well known is the Papua Besena movement led by Josephine Abaijah and centered in what is now Central Province among the Papuans of the south coast of the country. This was a social group that had long experience of dealing with external groups as a result of the Hiri exchanges. Papua Besena demanded a referendum be held to determine whether Papua would join the proposed country, and when the referendum was denied, actually declared unilateral independence six months before national independence in 1975, well ahead of the declaration of the North Solomons Republic on Bougainville. Again, this is an area in which there is considerable cultural homogeneity, and which, additionally, had a long history of extensive trade and interaction with outside cultures. This is also the area in which the headquarters of the colonial administration had long been established, and this leant the local groups a level of knowledge and sophistication not generally shared in the rest of the country. As with Bougainville, the Papuans saw little attraction in being joining an emerging political entity that would include the Highlands, the North Coast and the Islands regions. iv. Lack of Coordinated Reaction in Big Man Societies The reactions to the impending amalgamation of these disparate regions into a single state are as remarkable for where they did not occur as where they did. The single largest area in which there was no organized movement against integration into the emerging state was the Highlands and associated areas stretching from the Highlands to the coast along the Sepik in the north and the Fly and Purari in the south. These are precisely the areas in which the big man complex was strongest, long distance interaction among societies lowest and insularity greatest. These are also areas that were, in some senses, well out of the mainstream (to the extent such could be said to exist) of communications and transportation, and it is well accepted that many in these more remote areas were simply not aware of the impending formation of the state or, if they were, did not understand the political implications of such. It was not until well after Independence, in the 1980s, that some nascent separatist tendencies began to emerge in the Highlands largely at the instigation of Iambakey Okuk, a popular Highlands leader who urged his fellow Highlanders to resist domination by the peoples of the 20 “nambis” (shore or coast). Even this, though, was not unambiguously separatist in intent and faded rapidly with Okuk’s death. v. the Institutional Reaction to Separatism: The Unitary State becomes Federalist These movements were essentially regionally based, and they illustrated that if Papua New Guinea was to come together as a country it would do so only as distinct regions in an overall framework that would be federal in structure. This was counter to the original thinking which was that PNG should be a unitary state, and this was assumed until almost literally the last minute before Independence when it was clear that Bougainville would not join the emerging country – willingly, at any rate – without a good deal of autonomy. The presence in Bougainville of a major copper mine that represented a substantial proportion of the proposed state’s potential revenues meant that concessions had to be made. Similar movements in the other Islands and Papua only reinforced this imperative. Thus was the provincial government system born. However, this occurred so late in the process that there was no chance for in-depth planning, and the easiest way to meet the needs of Bougainville and to create what amounted to a federal system, rather than a unitary one, was to simply convert the pre-existing administrative units that had constituted districts under Australian administration. So it was that there was a nearly exact transformation of the 19 districts of the Territories of Papua and New Guinea into the nineteen provinces of the newly independent state. These divisions took little account of social and political realities in the several regions of the country, and resulted in a dramatic swing from what had been intended as a unitary state to a federal system in which a total population of less than 3 million was divided into 19 (20 counting the National Capital District) provinces, or an average of less than 150,000 per jurisdiction. Each province established a system of electorates, government and administration separate from an already complex national system. This was a prescription for, at best, inefficiency and, at worst, disaster. E. The Emergence of the Current System a. The Westminster System and Traditional Institutional Rules Papua New Guinea became an independent state from Australia in 1975, at which time it adopted a Constitution enshrining a formal governmental system modeled on a Westminster Parliamentary system. This system was bequeathed by the colonial power which had, itself, adopted it as a variant of the system of its former colonial power, Great Britain. In fact, the system enshrined in the Constitution of Papua New Guinea was a mix of the unitary state of Great Britain, the federal system of Australia and the preexisting colonial structure through which Australia had administered the Territories of Papua and New Guinea for most of the twentieth century. The result was a governmental system that combined forms of several different systems, with enduring consequences for the development of the state and the sense of nation. 21 i. The Structure of Government: A Majoritarian and Consensus Cocktail In his work on modern democratic systems Lijphart25 classes the Westminster Parliamentary system (quintessentially represented in Great Britain) as a “majoritarian” democratic system, characterised by a plurality electoral system, unitary government, parliamentary sovereignty, one-party and bare majority cabinets, cabinet dominance and asymmetrical bicameralism. Lijphart contrasts this to a consensus form of government which includes, inter alia, grand coalitions, separation of powers, balanced bicameralism, proportional representation and federalism.26 Interestingly, Lijphart concludes that the majoritarian form of democracy is most appropriate to societies that are substantially homogeneous while the consensus model is appropriate to more heterogeneous or plural societies27. What was bequeathed to Papua New Guinea at independence was clearly a curious mixture of majoritarian and consensus democratic structures. While the PNG system shared the majoritarian features of a plurality electoral system,28 cabinet dominance and parliamentary sovereignty, it also had consensus features including, most significantly, a federal structure. In addition, the PNG system is unicameral, and this mutes the potential balancing of power at the national level. This is aggravated by the absence of a strong executive, as the Prime Minister serves, essentially, only at the sufferance of Parliament. There is therefore little separation of powers, which Lijphart identifies as an attribute of a consensus system. As we will see below, it is unfortunate that the specific majoritarian and consensus features selected for inclusion in the PNG governmental system seem to have worked against the inherent strengths of PNG traditional societies while at the same time amplifying some of the most dysfunctional (from the perspective of effective higher level government institutions) aspects of traditional societies. This has resulted in a system that neither performs as intended (by those introducing the Westminster System) nor overcomes some of the traditional obstacles to integrating a great variety of pre-existing social and cultural systems into a single nation-state. 25 See Lijphart, Arend, Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty One Countries, New Haven. Yale University Press, 1984 and Lijphart, 26 This division of contemporary democracies into “majoritarian” and “consensus” models mirrors earlier similar distinctions, notably that of Robert Dahl’s distinction between “populist democracy” (majoritarian) and Madisonian democracy (consensus). 27 In Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty One Countries Lijphart says that for heterogeneous or plural societies “majoritarian rule is not only undemocratic but also dangerous, because minorities that are continually denied access to power will feel excluded and discriminated against and will lose their allegiance to the regime.” (pp. 22-23). 28 A plurality electoral system is one in which the candidate can win an election without receiving a majority of the votes, and generally (as in PNG) consists of single member electoral districts. All that is necessary for election is to receive more votes than any other candidate, even if that number of votes is a substantial minority of total votes cast. 22 ii. Electorates, the Electoral System and Big Man Politics The basic political structure of the country is based a division of the provinces into a total of 109 electorates, from each of which a Member is elected to the unicameral National Parliament. In a country of (today) about five and a half million people, this represents roughly one parliamentarian for every 50,000 people. Of the 109 MPs, 90 are elected from “open electorates” and 19 from “regional electorates”. Open electorates are mutually exclusive districts within each province, while each province also has one regional electorate coterminous with provincial boundaries. Both open and regional MPs have identical powers at the national level. MPs are intended to represent the interests of their electorates at the national level. Political allegiances are formally based on membership in a party, each of which has a formal platform or policy stance. Parties work to form coalitions in contests for control of government. The Constitution establishes a Parliamentary, and by extension governmental, term as five years, after which new elections are held. Members of parliament have historically been elected through a plurality electoral system based on a first-past-the-post method in which there is a single round of voting with the individual receiving the most votes declared elected; there is no requirement that any candidate receive a majority of the vote. This system was introduced for a number of reasons, not the least of which is that the electorate in PNG is extremely inaccessible, and several rounds of voting would therefore be logistically daunting29. The use of the first past the post electoral system has only reinforced the traditional fragmentary nature of PNG social and political life. In many cases 40 or more people have run for a single office, so members of Parliament can be elected with less than 10 percent of the vote. In the 1997 elections more than 1,000 candidates contested the 109 seats, and more than half the parliamentarians were elected with less than 20 percent of the vote; this trend was aggravated with over half the candidates winning with less than 16% of the vote in 2002. The system encourages candidates to focus on mobilizing support among their traditional constituency of supporters, and particularly among the candidate’s core social and cultural group. The candidate who can secure the full support of a small portion of the electorate stands an excellent chance of being elected. This is a direct extension of the institution and organizations of the big man complex to the national level. In most respects it is clear that what has happened is a transferal of the traditional big man system of gaining followers into the modern political system. This is a strategy that is well understood by both leaders and followers, and as long as the traditional redistributive system works effectively the system will continue to be popular. Campaigning is based on those traditional redistributive relationships, with the leader providing resources to traditional supporters. The candidate spends most of his time and effort in the discrete area in which he has kinship links and where his faction is strongest. He provides goods during the course of the campaign, hosts feasts and distributions of wealth, including pigs, food and other resources to cement the support of his core 29 Recently a new, more proportional electoral system based on a limited preferential system was enacted, and this system will be used widely for the first time in the 2007 elections. The possible implications of this introduction are several, which will be further discussed below 23 constituency. In the modern system he will also provide cash, beer, vehicles, computers and other benefits to his followers. In return the supporters provide votes at the election. Therefore, once the candidate is elected, allegiance is not to the entire electorate, but to the leader’s immediate supporters. It is understood that the primary responsibility of the leader is to redistribute resources to those who supported him/her, not to the electorate as a whole. This system is recognized and accepted by all—including those who are left out because their candidate was unsuccessful—and reinforces the fragmentary tendencies of Papua New Guinea society. Though the elections are ostensibly held under rules of the game defined by the Westminster System, in fact the organizations created to contest them are substantially analogous to those used by the big man to achieve his political power in the traditional system. In fact, the adoption of a plurality electoral system was ideally suited to preserving the traditional political and social divisions between local level groups in Papua New Guinea, and did nothing to encourage the extension of consensus-building traditions beyond the local group. Once organizations defined by the rules of the big man complex became the dominant political teams, the rest of the political process was inevitably conditioned to operate by the rules of the traditional system. This became clear in the structure and operation of political parties, the formation of government and, ultimately, the fragility of governments once formed. iii. Parties, Government and the Fragility of Power The structure and working of political parties illustrates a rhetorical reality that pays lip service to the Westminster system and a behavioral reality that illustrates the actual institutional rules of the game. If we look closely at how parties are formed and how they behave once formed the actual institutional basis of PNG politics will become clear. In this section I will look at the tendency of parties in the PNG context to proliferate rather than consolidate the insecurity of MPs once elected, the process of formation of government and the essential fragility of government once formed. These factors together conduce towards a political system based on short term, personalistic goals and working strongly against consensus and the establishment, and implementation, of long term governance and development strategies. Each party in PNG has a single leader and develops a party platform and party policies that provide blueprints for social and economic programs. But these statements do not provide the real rationale for action and despite the existence of party platforms and formal party policies, membership in a political party is actually based on patronage and personal allegiance rather than ideology. The parties themselves are not institutionalized – parties are only vehicles for the expression of the power of individuals who have established themselves as charismatic leaders in the new national arena through the first past the post system. The dominance of the traditional system is evident in the pattern of party proliferation that has characterized PNG since independence. Most theorists have posited that the use of a plurality voting system should, over time, lead to a narrowing in the number of political parties. Duverger30, Lipset31 and others, 30 See M. Duverger, Political Parties: The Organization and Activity in the Modern States 24 predict that over time a plurality voting system, such as the first past the post system in PNG, will lead to a few dominant parties as it becomes clear to the electorate (though this may take several electoral cycles) that their vote is wasted on smaller parties and only has impact if they support one of the larger parties which shares in general substance the voter’s ideological stance. Lijphart, as well, expects a majoritarian system to be associated with a plurality system of elections and a small number of political parties. So if the system was actually working according to the institutional rules of the game of the Westminster system one would have expected that, over time, the number of political parties would have been reduced to only a few, perhaps even to two, a pattern characteristic of majoritarian systems However, in PNG the opposite has occurred, and it appears the consolidating tendencies of a plurality system of voting have been trumped by the extreme diversity of social groups and the strength of the pre-existing institutional rules for political behavior. For example, in the 1977 election only six political parties were represented in Parliament. By 1987 this had risen to ten, by 1997 to 13 and the 2002 election, the most recent, returned MPs representing 22 different political parties (and a total of 43 actually contested the elections)32. This is exactly opposite to what would be expected if party ideology actually structured the rules of the game. At the same time the number of independents has consistently been high, with 20% of the 1987 Parliament, 36% of the 1992 Parliament, 33% of the 1997 Parliament and 17% of the 2002 Parliament consisting of independents. What has occurred is, rather than the entrenchment of the rules of the game of the Westminster Party System, the persistence of the traditional system in which allegiance to a leader is fluid and instrumental, and the inherent competition of the system leads to fragmentation and fracturing of factions which form, dissolve, and re-form as the interests of the big men who constitute the faction dictate. This is encouraged by the large number of electorates which effectively reduces the number of votes required for election, particularly in a plurality electoral system. The result is that the institutions that are relevant are not the Westminster parties, but the traditional big man factions based on personal charisma and power This instability and proliferation of political parties is both encouraged by and encourages the remarkable insecurity of MPs once elected. While western political systems tend to return a very high percentage of elected representatives each electoral cycle (well over 90% in American congressional elections, for example), in PNG tenure of office is very low. In the 1977 election 62% of all MPs were not returned. This has remained fairly consistent over the years at well over 50%, and actually reached a high water mark of (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1966-first published 1954). See S.M. Lipset and S. Rokkan, ‘Cleavage Structures, Party Systems, and Voter Alignments: An Introduction’, in S.M. Lipset and S. Rokkan (eds.), Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross National Perspectives (New York: Free Press, 1967), 31 See Okole, Henry, The ‘Fluid’ Party System of Papua New Guinea in Commonwealth & Comparative Politics, Vol.43, No.3, November 2005, pp.362–81 for a discussion of the growth of political parties and the essential instability of political office at the national level in PNG. 32 25 75% not returned in the 2002 election.33 This is partly because both the margins of victory and the total number of votes cast in each electorate are so small that a shift of only a few hundred votes in the next election can make the difference between victory and defeat. Since the MP knows he (or, very infrequently, she) is extremely vulnerable in the next election, he is encouraged to operate according to the rules of the game of the traditional system since they recognize that they have only one five year period during which to cement their status as big men. They are therefore much less concerned about party ideology or platforms, and more concerned about how they can gain access to resources and funds for redistribution in order to establish their status. Even within this fluidity, parties tend to be regionally based, and the leader of the party is the biggest of the big men from the region. In this case the members of the faction are other MPs and the leader of the faction is that MP perceived as most powerful among his followers, primus inter pares34. The party itself is considerably less important than the individuals who constitute it. This was dramatically illustrated in a 1987 survey of electoral behavior in which only 4.8% of the respondents cited party affiliation as a factor in their decision to vote for a specific candidate35. It is individual status that is determinative. The importance of personalistic factors is given further confirmation in the process of formation of government after the parliamentary elections. No party has ever gained an absolute majority of the seats in Parliament in a national election36. Over the years the multiplication of parties has meant the prospect of achieving a majority in Parliament has diminished. This means that all governments have been, of necessity, coalitions. The jockeying to establish a coalition with sufficient numbers to form government in the weeks following a general election is intense and patently instrumental. Large sums of cash are passed to potential allies by those trying to form government, providing those politicians with additional resources for redistribution to their followers. Those who are the leaders of parties – effectively the biggest of several big men who constitute their faction - command the greatest price since they can, at least potentially, deliver several votes. They then, in turn, redistribute some of the largesse they have received to the other members of the party. Members who have accepted such prestations and who have agreed to participate in the coalition are sequestered in removed locales where they are literally guarded by followers of the lead members of the coalition in order to prevent the competition from approaching and luring them away with more substantial offers, a recognition of the essential instrumentality of the process. 33 Ibid. 34 For a discussion of the factional nature of PNG political parties see Kurer, Oskar, Voting Behavior and Governance: the Case of Papua New Guinea, Institut für Wirtschaftswissenschaft, Universität ErlangenNürnberg, IWE Working Paper Nr. 04 2006 35 See Y. Saffu, ‘Survey Evidence on Electoral Behaviour in Papua New Guinea’, in M. Oliver (ed.), Eleksin: The 1987 National Election in Papua New Guinea (Port Moresby: University of Papua New Guinea Press, 1989) 36 In the 1982 Pangu Pati actually gained 50 of 109 seats, and this is the most any single party has ever gained. However, since that time factionalism has deepened, and in the 2002 election no party got more than 20 MPs. 26 The key inducement to participation in a coalition is a position in government that ensures the candidate two things critical to a big man: public recognition of status and access to substantial resources in goods, services and cash. The plums in this game are offers of important ministries, particularly natural resource ministries with the potential to provide significant rents to the minister concerned. Nonetheless, possession of any ministry will provide the incumbent with access to some resources, and with a title that confers public status. The utility of ministerial position as a mechanism of redistribution to induce support for a coalition is the reason behind the growth in the number of ministries as their potential for garnering political support has become clearer. At Independence in 1975 there were twelve government departments, each headed by a member of parliament as minister. By the mid-1980s that number had expanded to over twenty, and as of the beginning of 2006 the total number of ministries had grown to 29. The growing number of available ministries has greatly increased the inducements available to attract potential coalition members. Additionally, in the late 1980s the office of vice-minister was created and has been added to several ministries; today a number of ministries also have an office of vice-minister. This means that nearly every member of government can be guaranteed a position which provides social standing and access to significant resources and funds. The offices of minister and vice minister are examples of structures in the imported system that have been adapted to meet the needs of the traditional system. Despite the fact that PNG has several traditional institutional models, including the big man, chiefly systems and chiefly systems in the context of matrilineality, the dominant model at the national level has been that of the big man. Even once a government is formed, the basic flux of the big man system continues to affect the political process. The essential quality of relationships among big men is that they are unstable and when the opportunity presents itself for one big man to gain an advantage over another it is inevitably taken. The faction is stable only to the extent that all the members feel their allegiance to the leader provides them with optimal access to resources for redistribution to their own followers. When they make the judgment there is an option that provides them with access to more resources their allegiance shifts. This is a partial explanation of why, in the first twenty five years of Independence, not a single government was actually able to serve out a full five year term37. The PNG Constitution originally provided for a “constructive” vote of no-confidence – i.e., where a new prime minister is proposed – anytime after six months of a government’s term and before the last year of the term. A Constitutional amendment in 1991 extended the “grace period” at the start of a government to eighteen months, but still left two and a half years in the middle of a government’s term when a vote could be held. The effect is that the Prime Minister, government in general, has been held hostage to the ebb and flow of factionalism in Parliament, with the result that every government from Independence until the present government was turned out on a vote of no confidence. Votes of no 37 The current Somare Government will, in fact, be the first since Independence to actually serve out a five year term., though even this has only been possible after a tortuous process in which the Prime Minister attempted to adjourn Parliament for six months to avoid any no confidence vote. When this move was rejected by the Supreme Court Parliament was reconvened and the Prime Minister managed to avoid termination of his government by deft negotiation to include additional parties in Government. 27 confidence are successful because allegiance is purely instrumental; teams are based not on ideology, but on instrumental return, not on the rules of the Westminster system, but on those of the big man complex. The argument is even more convincing when we consider the Constitution also provides for Parliament to dissolve itself and to call new elections, and this could be done, as is often the case in western parliamentary systems, when a vote of no confidence against government is successful. But this option has never been exercised, primarily because the pattern in elections in PNG has been that over 50%, and sometimes nearly three quarters, of sitting MPs have been turned out at each election. Effectively, most parliamentarians feel they have only one term in which to take full advantage of the resources to which they have access as parliamentarians, and they are loathe to take the risk of shortening their time in office by calling for new elections. The translation of traditional institutional understandings, and traditional organizations, to the imported governmental structure leads to little concern for the development of the nation as a whole and much concern for the advancement of narrow constituencies, largely defined as kinship based groups who form the core support of the MP. In this context the fiscal assets of the state are used to build the strength of parliamentarians— and to weaken rivals and competing social groups, a pattern with which we are familiar from the traditional big man complex. National planning is weak and poorly implemented, with implementation decisions driven by patronage and personal contacts rather than by concerns for sustainable development. Political influence extends to the bureaucracy, with ministers still, despite recent improvements, able to exercise considerable sway over career civil servants. Politicians can exercise discretionary control over large amounts of the state’s resources through the annual budget, and in recent years this discretion has increased, with little transparency or accountability in the use of budget funds. If members of Parliament were accountable to all of their constituents, their funding of projects that make them more electable would simply mean that the political process was working. In the absence of political accountability, this use of public funds is self-serving and inappropriate. In hindsight it appears considerable more thought might have been given to the nature of the political/governmental system bequeathed to PNG, particularly given the traditional social and cultural structure of the constituent societies of the emergent nation. Though it is difficult to be prescriptive, it seems clear that such a system would include more of what Lijphart has called a “consensus” system and Dahl has called “Madisonian democracy”. There are a variety of components to such a system, and within each component there are a variety of possible approaches, but in essence it would consist of several key aspects. First, the system would be one based on proportional representation rather than a plurality electoral system. As we will see, to some extent this issue has been addressed recently with changes in the electoral system. Second, the system would be one that encouraged federalism rather than the substantial centralization of power in one (usually national) level. However, that federalism could usefully have been at a more encompassing level, and the existence of 20 provinces and 109 electorates has had a negative effect as we will see. Third, it would be a bicameral rather than a unicameral system, which would result in a more effective division of powers and encourage the tendency to work by consensus. Fourth, there would be a greater separation of powers 28 among the key branches of government, with the executive, in particular, held less to hostage by the legislature. What seems clear is that the nature of the majoritarian/consensus mix unfortunately selected the very aspects of each of those approaches that had the unfortunate effect of encouraging the most divisive and competitive aspects of the traditional system, notably the faction-based organizations inherent in big man politics, and discouraging the most integrative aspects, notably the consensus and negotiation-based nature of local political and social structures. Any governmental system bequeathed to a developing nation is necessarily a work in progress that must be gradually adapted to meet local needs and realities. But it is clearly useful to begin from a position that, at least in general outline, is consistent with the inclusive and incorporative tendencies of traditional societies rather than the opposite. That this was not the case in PNG is clear in the failure of the system to move towards one based, at the national level, on consensus and national strategic directions. The weaknesses of the system bequeathed to the country at Independence were recognized almost from the moment of – indeed, in some instances even before – formal Independence. Much of the political history of the country since then has consisted of attempts to overcome these weaknesses by introducing changes to the system (though in some cases the desire to overcome those weaknesses was more rhetorical than real). These results of these attempts have been mixed, generally improving the situation to the extent they resulted in a move towards a more consensus-based system and aggravating the situation when they resulted in more majoritarian approach. I now turn to consider those changes, and to assess the effects those changes have had on the ability of the system to delivery effective governance and development outcomes. F. Changes in the System a. Introduction There has been a tension between the assumed rules of behavior informing the Westminster Parliamentary system and the reality of the traditional institutional rules that have ordered political activity in PNG since independence. Outside actors, notably the Australians but also international organizations such as the ADB and World Bank, have strongly urged reform of the political and economic system to make it more accountable and transparent, though generally these have been reforms at the edges. Partly as a result of these pressures, and partly as a result of recognition by Papua New Guineans themselves that the system has been dysfunctional, a number of changes have been made in the political system since independence, ostensibly to improve governance and development outcomes. In fact, however, most of these changes have failed to achieve their alleged objectives, partly because many of those making the changes actually had other intentions and have managed to subvert the alleged intent, and partly because of a general misunderstanding of the importance of adjusting the national and subnational systems to take greater advantage of the inherent strengths of the traditional systems of the country. There are four changes in particular that are of importance here: the Public Service (Management) Act of 1986, the Organic Law of 1995, the Integrity of Political Parties 29 Act of 1999 and the move from first-past-the-post to a limited preferential voting system. One of these, the Public Service Act, was a clear retrograde step (and has, at least partially, been corrected), but the other three have promise. In each case, however, there is evidence that the apparent adaptation of the system has actually been subverted by reversion to the more traditional rules of the game under the influence of organizations devoted to the achievement of goals defined by traditional understandings. b. The Public Service (Management) Act The Public Service (Management) Act, 1986, was a step backward in establishing an effective civil service and improving governance. This Act severely curtailed the constitutional powers of the Public Service Commission (PSC), which had been a relatively independent body responsible for overseeing public service salaries, employment, promotion and acting as the arbiter of disputes. In essence this was an admission that it was uncomfortable for big men to operate with others over whom they had no control, so they had to “personalize” the system. In the place of the PSC the Act established the Department of Personnel Management to carry out these functions, with the result that elected officials, parliamentarians, gained considerable control over the public service which became increasingly politicized as ministers were able to hire and fire department heads and other officials with relative impunity. In recent years there have been moves to restore the Public Service Commission as a body with authority over these issues, and legislation passed in 2003 reinstated much of its original power. It is still unclear the extent to which this will restore public service independence and integrity. c. The Organic Law on Provincial Government and Local Level Government The most ambitious of the reform efforts is the Organic Law on Provincial Governments and Local Level Governments, enacted in 1995. This legislation was a clear admission of the failure of the provincial government system to function effectively with respect to issues of service delivery and governance. The rhetoric that accompanied the legislation made it clear the intent was to shift power to the local level to reverse what was seen as a stagnation, or even gradual decline, in the quality of governance, as reflected in the failure to record improvements in basic social and economic indicators over the previous ten to fifteen years. The talk was of the need to reduce the level of political interference in the delivery of basic services, particularly education and health, and to improve the provision and maintenance of critical infrastructure. There was much discussion about improving capacity at the subnational levels to improve development outcomes for the people of the country. While there is little doubt some politicians were genuinely motivated by these concerns, it is equally certain more were motivated by concerns revolving around dealing with political rivals, guaranteeing access to resources for redistributive purposes and 30 expanding their own base of power as a big man38. A closer examination of what actually occurred under the Organic Law and of the outcomes of its implementation will be instructive. In addition to decentralizing functions to the district and local levels, the Organic Law altered the structure of provincial government. In a word, the OLPGLLG eliminated provincial politicians. Prior to passage of the Organic Law there was both a provincial political cadre and a national cadre, and provincial government consisted of politicians elected directly to a Provincial Assembly in addition to the national politicians elected to the National Parliament. This system was changed so there are no directly elected provincial members. Instead, provincial assemblies now consist of all local government council presidents in the province plus the national MPs from each province. The regional MP from each province is automatically Governor of the province, unless he holds a national ministry in which case another MP is elected Governor. National MPs now control the provincial legislatures and are also in positions of power at the local level through their chairmanship of the Joint District Planning and Budget Priorities Committee which exercise control over the District Support Grant (DSG, discussed further below). There are several ways to interpret these changes. From the perspective of outsiders this looks to be a somewhat rational reduction in what was an overly politicized system, eliminating arguably the least efficient political level. There can be little doubt the elimination of the politicians at the provincial level is, given the history of performance of most provincial governments, not a bad idea. However, in the context of the traditional institutions, or rules of the game, what occurred was not so much the elimination of politics at the local level as the usurpation by the national level big men of the turf and resources of their provincial level rivals. At the same time this represented a roll back of provincial autonomy, which would have important consequences down the road, particularly in Bougainville where provincial government had represented the key concession necessary to convince the province to join the country in the first place. If the change is given the first interpretation the legal-rational “rules of the game” would lead us to expect improved transparency and accountability in the delivery of resources, services and goods from the national to the local level, and this was what many expected at the time. If, on the other hand, we accept the second interpretation we would expect the now triumphant big men to utilize their newfound control over additional resources to enable them to redistribute even more resources to their core followers, just as the nowdeposed provincial politicians had distributed resources to their followers. One piece of May noted in 1999 that “The avowed purpose of the ‘reform’ of decentralization was to shift power towards local-level government. It must be seriously questioned whether local-level government will have the capacity to carry this load….In the absence of a strong local-level government structure, the new system is likely to increase substantially the political role of national MPs. Arguably, this was the real objective of the reforms.” See May, R.J., 1999. Decentralization in Papua New Guinea: F Two Steps Forward, One Step Back’, in Mark Turner (ed.), Central-Local Relations in Asia-Pacific. Convergence or Divergence? Houndmills: Macmillan Press, pp.123-148. 38 31 evidence that will help us to decide among these interpretations is how the provisions of the Organic Law with respect to fiscal transfers have been implemented, and what has actually happened to those transfers in practice. At the heart of the Organic Law is a system of fiscal transfers designed to provide resources to subnational levels to enable them to carry out the decentralized functions. This was to have resulted in an increase of about 50% in the fiscal resources delivered to subnational levels. These transfers39 provide the key support for the decentralization of many basic functions of the state, including important aspects of health, education and basic infrastructure, and they provide a potential area of significant flexibility and choice at lower levels. Unfortunately, the transfers have never been consistently provided, despite the legal mandate to do so. Even worse, the way in which the transfers have been provided and manipulated has reinforced the fragmentary and exclusive aspects of the traditional system rather than encouraging inclusion and strengthening the sense of nation. First, most of the grants have been only intermittently and/or incompletely provided, thereby preventing any effective, long term planning at subnational levels predicated on availability of the funds. Second, the transfers most consistently provided are the Provincial and District Support Grants, intended for rural action and urban rehabilitation programs. The District Support Grant (DSG) is divided, with one-half provided directly to the MP for the electorate, and the other half provided to the Joint District Planning and Budget Priorities Committee (JDPBPC) which the MP chairs and over which he has substantial control. The other grants, those intended to go directly to subnational levels for the functions of education, health and infrastructure have not been regularly delivered. The only grants regularly delivered are under the control of the MP, and this pattern is more consistent with the rules of the game of the traditional system than of the introduced system. The important resources to deliver are those under the control of the big man; any other resources are either, at worst, a direct challenge to the position of the big man or, at best, of little interest since he cannot take credit for their delivery. The result is that a potential avenue for encouraging inclusion at the local level and, by extension, building legitimacy of the state has in fact been co-opted by the MP and is used in service of building his status among his followers, with the predictable effect that his followers benefit inordinately and to the exclusion of others in the electorate. This dysfunctional approach was exacerbated with the 1999 Budget Amendment 7 to the Organic Law which increased the DSG considerably and introduced a Provincial Support 39 The OLPGLLG mandated six kinds of grant from national to subnational levels: a provincial and locallevel administration grant, a local-level government and village services grant, a provincial infrastructure development grant, a provincial and local-level staffing grant, a town and urban services grant and a derivation grant (indexed to the value of commodities produced and exported from the province). These were supplemented in 1999 with a provincial and district support grant to be provided to newly created Joint Provincial and District Planning and Budgetary Priorities Committees, referred to in the text below. In the 2004 budget government amended the arrangements for funding provincial and local level governments by replacing existing grants with an unconditional block grant and three function grants, one each for basic education, rural health and transport infrastructure maintenance. 32 Grant40 that goes to the provincial equivalent of the JDPBPC and is under the control of the MP elected on a province-wide basis. At the same time the other sub-national grants – those not under the influence of the national MPs - were reduced. These changes strengthened the influence of MPs, and further stunted development of state legitimacy overall. However, having said this it is important to acknowledge there are instances in several provinces (notably East New Britain and in sections of some others) in which the MP has taken a “hands-off” approach to the Provincial and District Support Grants. In these instances the MP has turned those grants over directly to the Joint Provincial or District Planning and Budget Priorities Committee to utilize in ways they determine without the overt direction of the MP himself (though the details of decisionmaking vary somewhat). It is important to determine how such control (or, where delegated, lack of control) affects outcomes at the local level, a point addressed below. d. The Organic Law on the Integrity of Political Parties A third change is the passage of the Organic Law on the Integrity of Political Parties Act of 1999. The Act was passed in partly in response to the political instability caused by the tendency of MPs to change parties after the elections in order to solidify their personal standing as members of government and, ideally, as ministers of major portfolios which would allow them to fulfill their traditional role as redistributors of patronage. The Act established rules to regulate the formation, composition and funding of parties and also imposed restrictions on defections from political parties which, inter alia, were intended to have the effect of limiting the likelihood of votes of no confidence since members of specific parties could not shift allegiance simply to support a vote of no confidence. The law was amended in 2003 but retains its essential features, although it is unclear whether it will achieve its intended purpose. For example, the elections of 2002, the first under the new Act, saw a dramatic increase in the number of political parties to over 40. A second issue was the continued strength of independent candidates, and 17 independents were elected in 2002. Independents are essentially free to shift allegiance as they choose and therefore introduce an element of uncertainty, and that uncertainty increases as the number of independents increases. Nonetheless there are some hopeful signs as, for example, the fact that the number of parliamentary parties decreased from 21 to 15 in the aftermath of the 2004 elections at least partly as a result of the more strict application of rules for party registration. 40 In 1996, associated with the creation of Joint Provincial and District Planning and Budgetary Priorities Committees, a provincial and district support grant was added to the funding package. In 1998 the OLPGLLG was again amended; the minimum level of the provincial/district support grant was set at K500,000 per electorate, half of which was to be paid to the JP/DPBPC to fund rural action and urban rehabilitation programs, and half to the MP in the electorate, to be allocated at his/her discretion within district support grant guidelines (in some cases, MPs leave the allocation of the entire district support grant to the JDPBPC). 33 e. The Limited Preferential Electoral System A fourth change is the move from the first-past-the-post electoral system to the limited preferential system, essentially a move from a plurality-based to a majority-based electoral system and at least a partial step towards extending the appeal of candidates to a larger constituency41. The new system will ask all voters to vote for three candidates, a first, second and third preference. If a candidate receives an absolute majority of first preferences the candidate is elected (highly unlikely in PNG), but if there is no absolute majority then the candidate with the lowest total votes is eliminated and his/her second and third preferences are distributed as marked to the remaining candidates. Ideally this process continues until one candidate is allotted more than 50% of the votes. There are several overt objectives here. First, the new system is intended to encourage candidates to think of their electorates in more encompassing terms, to encourage efforts to gain support from a much wider constituency than under the first past the post system since they are now competing not for a single vote, but for second and third preferences as well. Second, the system may encourage the establishment of “preference alliances” between politicians in the belief that it is to their advantage to be able to deliver second preferences to another candidate with whom they are in fundamental policy agreement in return for reciprocity on the part of that candidate in directing second preferences to them. This, it is hoped, will lead to less “confrontational” campaigning and greater tendencies towards alliance building. Third, the possibility of using second and third preferences will eliminate the “all or nothing” nature of support for a candidate, and this will reduce “paybacks” after elections, reduce the stress on voters in areas where one candidate has strong support and reduce violence overall resulting from perceptions of betrayal or the breaking of promises. Finally, the option of second and third choices is thought to be an opportunity for women to express greater independence since under the prior system they were under tremendous pressure to vote as their husbands voted in order to support the local big man. Under this system they will have a greater say because they will be able to express their preference for candidates other than those supported by the men of the village. To this point the limited preferential system has been used in ten by-elections, and the results are uncertain42. In many instances candidates themselves had limited understanding of the functioning of the new system, and campaigned in ways indistinguishable from the old system. At the same time voters also had trouble understanding the system, though they generally were able to make their three preferences. Standish notes that overall the elections appeared to be less violently contested, with candidates agreeing, even encouraging, rivals to campaign in their core 41 The preferential system implemented in PNG is applied in single-member constituencies only, so it is not genuinely proportional in the sense that the first votes of those whose candidate is eliminated in the first round of counting do not count towards any representation, and only one representative is elected overall. Nonetheless, it aspires to be at least a majority voting system in that the intent is that one candidate will gain a majority of votes and be seen to represent a majority of the constituency. 42 See Bill Standish, Limited Preferential Voting in Papua New Guinea: Some Early Lessons, in Pacific Economic Bulletin, also available at peb.anu.edu.au/pdf/PEB21-1Standish-policy in which lessons from the first six by-elections are drawn. 34 areas of support in return for being allowed to do the same. There was some indication that voters who felt obliged to vote for the local “big man” then assigned their second and third preferences to other candidates who were fairly well known and who were believed to have the good of the larger electorate at heart. The results with respect to women were unclear, with many indicating they liked the idea of having “free” second and third votes, but many also indicating they voted all preferences according to the way they were instructed by the men of the village. Overall there were still many problems associated with accurate electoral rolls, the filling out of ballot papers, particularly second and third preferences, by polliing officials and related problems, but on balance the system seems to hold promise of reducing electoral violence and extending the size of the electorate to which the successful candidate feels a responsibility. Nonetheless, there is reason for cautious optimism that the introduction of the system will encourage the development of larger communities of interest than have hitherto existed under the traditional social and political systems; that the system will, in some sense, encourage consensus politics at the local level. G. Identity and Nationhood This discussion of the traditional systems of New Guinea and their interaction with the introduced Westminster Parliamentary System provides the context of the current situation with respect to the state and nation in modern PNG. Though there have been some integrative advances, the simple fact is that today PNG remains predominately an aggregation of small, fragmented social groupings with little idea of common identity or interest. There is no genuine sense in which the people see themselves as Papua New Guineans. Rather, people see themselves as members of a localized, usually clan-based group, sharing a common language, common ancestry, attachment to a specific area of land and a mythic corpus explaining their origins and place in the world. In some areas, notably the Islands and along the Papua Coast (and, at least nascently, in sections of the Highlands) there is a perception of regional interest, though this is often conceptualized in contrast to national interest or identity. There has been no galvanizing experience (as a protracted, often violent, independence movement characterizing many former colonies) to promote a shared sense of identity and national purpose. Legitimacy is conferred to local leaders, be they big men in the Highlands or chiefly lineages in Bougainville. Legitimacy is still based on either charismatic authority or traditional authority, and the legal-rational authority of the states comes a bad third among the bulk of the population. What it is to be Papua New Guinean is still being determined. This is both a weakness and an opportunity. Three lessons emerge from this analysis that can point the way to overcoming the weakness and seizing the opportunity. First, in order to build an effective state and, by extension, a sense of nation the minimum requirement is for central government to demonstrate unequivocally the state is able to actually provide benefits to its citizens. If this minimum standard is not met, the frank truth is that there is little motivation for the various components of the country to remain together. The inherent centrifugal tendencies have already been manifested clearly in the 35 move to autonomy on the part of Bougainville province and the long-standing sense among the other island provinces, as well as lingering feelings in Papua, that they might actually be better off as autonomous, or even independent, entities than as members of the PNG state. These tendencies are never far beneath the surface, and if the various areas do not see clear benefits to remaining a part of the state they are likely to emerge once again. Government must recognize this imperative and act on it, in ways I discuss further below. The time has come for a decision on the part of the national political powers whether they are committed to pursuing traditional, inclusive redistributive practices or whether the survival of the state as a viable entity is more important. Second, in demonstrating that membership in the state is of benefit to the constituent elements the national government must recognize that the institutional structures and rules of the game of the Westminster System (or, more accurately, of the mix of majoritarian and consensus systems of which the PNG political economy consists) are not those that will order the political economy of the country. Interaction with different regions, even different provinces and districts, will require different approaches to governance, decentralization and service delivery that encourage inclusion and participation, but structure the participation in ways appropriate under a variety of different traditional systems. This flexibility will be necessary if the various parts of the country are to effectively promote development outcomes in their respective areas, thereby demonstrating the benefits of remaining within the state as a whole. Some ways in which this might be done are discussed in the following section. Third, the goal of activity by government as well as by development partners such as Australia, the World Bank, ADB and others should at all times be oriented towards encouraging the inherent integrative and consensus building tendencies of PNG societies and discouraging tendencies towards conflict and fragmentation. Realistically it is unlikely major changes will be made to the system of government over the short to medium term, so this means other gradualist approaches need to be taken. At the national level strengthening accountability, transparency and reliability in the delivery of resources and services is important. At the local level this means any development activities should include explicit incentives for local groups to cooperate with one another in defining development objectives, particularly where those local groups have not had histories of cooperation. The intent should be to promote coalitions of local level groups where such coalitions have not previously existed, in order to develop “communities of interest” that will put pressure on the formal (and other) structures to meet wider local level needs than have been operative in the past. 36 Part II: Ways Forward A. Introduction At the beginning of this paper I asked what adjustments could be made in both sets of institutions – the traditional and the introduced – so the organizations, the teams, responding to the rules of the game, the institutions, are oriented towards objectives that will work to the benefit of the country as a whole, that will lead to good governance and positive development outcomes. The analysis has pointed to two areas in which adjustments can be made, and provides some hints concerning the kinds of strategies that might be effective in improving governance and development outcomes. The strategies need to be applied from two directions. One approach focuses on the lower levels – it is bottom up – and one focuses on the higher levels – top down. The first area in which evolution is possible is with respect to the challenge of local level inclusion in which traditional mechanisms of consensus and social control are put to the service of equitable local level participation in the process of nation building. The second is the challenge of effective national level articulation with those emergent, inclusive local level structures and processes that take advantage of the strengths of traditional PNG societies – such as consensus building and negotiating skills – while overcoming some of the disadvantages – such as exclusionary tendencies and a failure of cooperation across local groups. It is important to recognize that there are strengths in the traditional systems of the country that can be built on to improve overall governance and development outcomes. However, the simple fact is that the current structure of government militates against these strengths. The trick will be to pursue strategies that build on traditional strengths in the short to medium term, both at the local level by encouraging inclusive processes and at the national level by developing strategies that articulate with those inclusive processes. B. From Conflict to Consensus at the Local Level: From the Bottom Up At the local level the main challenge is to move beyond the exclusive and fragmented local level structures symptomatic of the grass roots levels of PNG society and that provide the impetus to view the state as a resource to be plundered and competed over for distribution through patronage networks. This is the demand side of the equation. It is the demand from this level that has conditioned the ways in which national level officials have personalized the institutions of the Westminster System in order to use them for the achievement of objectives defined by the traditional systems. The persistent tendency of national level politicians to pervert the intent of the introduced system is a result of the expectations to which they respond from the local level. If this behavior is to change it will only be through a change in demands from the local level. This entails the promotion of mechanisms and processes by which legitimacy is gradually transferred from primarily local to broadly trans-local and, eventually, regional and even national groups. Despite a general pessimism at the quality of development in PNG, there are promising signs this has been occurring for some time. These examples need, 37 first, to be recognised and, second, used as templates for similar processes in other areas of the country. These processes have been occurring for decades, but have frequently been ignored, marginalized, even seen as threats. In many areas of the country, both urban and rural, groups have been established that are deepening links across local groups that, in turn, lead to an extension of legitimacy beyond the clan or village to larger social aggregations. These are disparate groupings and have emerged in a variety of contexts, including urban squatter settlements, in institutions of higher learning, at the instigation of churches, in some rural areas in which formerly competing groups are being brought together in pursuit of common interests, in mining areas, and even among raskol gangs. These groups are indicative of the slow emergence of a more inclusive sense of identity. These processes respond to and are reflections of traditional Papua New Guinean understandings, and have the potential to evolve into sustainable institutions and organizations to promote equitable development across the country. Despite the fact that PNG societies have traditionally been exclusive and competitive, those exclusive groups embody, within the group itself, some decisionmaking processes that can serve as a basis for more inclusive processes. Many local groups take generally similar approaches to methods of conflict resolution, decisionmaking and consensus building, social support, systems of land use and tenure, means of achieving and retaining status, approaches to critical life events and so on. These essential similarities have been the platform on which many local initiatives have built links across more inclusive and extensive groups, pointing the way to a truly endemic sense of what it means to be a Papua New Guinean. Though there is not space to examine all such examples here, a few will be illustrative. a. Some Integrative Local Level Processes These groups have emerged in a variety of contexts and in response to a variety of stimuli. In the Highlands of Oro Province the Managalas Plateau is home to more than 10,000 people organized into more than 100 sub-clan groups living in small village and hamlet communities and primarily dependent on subsistence agriculture. Over the course of the past fifteen years the Plateau has been the site of a process that has taken an approach including provision of information about the potential of the area for income generating activities, awareness building of the implications of potential development activities, consensus building among groups who had previously not cooperated with one another and the implementation of various small scale enterprises, including coffee cultivation, okari nut cultivation and other eco-enterprise activities.43 . The entire Plateau has been divided into ten culture zones, each of which includes a number of villages and hamlets and brings together six to fifteen different sub-clan groups. Each zone works to develop a long term sustainable development strategy, working closely with local level governments and political representatives. This is a long term process involving repeated meetings among local groups, extensive negotiation of ideas and goals and the full participation of all local stakeholders in a 43 See Managalas Plateau Conservation Area Project, at http://www.pwmpng.org.pg/program.html 38 process to understand potential development activities and agree on those that make most sense in the local context. Once groups agree on development strategies the process introduces business structures and practices to enable participants to extend economic activities and take advantage of opportunities. Standard business organizational structures and management practices are adapted to more accurately reflect core Managalas cultural values and to provide greater autonomy for local clan/cultural groups at the same time they encourage collaboration among local groups in meeting the needs of potential outside buyers and marketers. The intent is to extend new income generating opportunities and to provide the tools necessary to empower stakeholders to take a controlling role in the direction of their development, so that program goals become community and clan goals in the future. Several of the zones have established incorporated business entities, and on an annual basis the villages in each zone come together to discuss progress in the past year, plans for the future and to adjust their development strategy. Following the separate zone meetings a combined forum is held on an annual basis at which all the zones come together to discuss how they can work more effectively together, what opportunities exist and how to take advantage of them and other issues of mutual interest and importance. At each stage of the zone and combined zone meetings the Local Level Governments, District level bodies (such as the JDPBPC) and other formal institutions at the local and district level are full participants in the process and this leads to integration of local development strategies into formal government planning and implementation processes. Another example of the development of more inclusive groups at the local level involves the transparent and accountable use of the District Support Grant that goes to the Joint District Planning and Budget Priorities Committee in East New Britain Province. As we have seen, District Support Grants can be an important element of local level governance as they are annual grants provided to the District (and, with respect to Provincial Support Grants, the province) level as a part of the fiscal transfers mandated under the Organic Law of 1995 intended to be used for local level development, particularly infrastructure. As we have also seen, there have been consistent problems over the past ten years and more because the MPs have had effective control of the funds and the great majority of them have failed to adequately acquit their use (a number MPs have been called before the Leadership Tribunal and/or Ombudsman, and several have been forced to resign as a result of malfeasance). The majority of MPs have treated the DSGs as a “slush fund” to be used to the benefit of their followers with little regard for the overall development of their constituencies. But there are exceptions. In Gazelle District the MP has made the decision to turn all DSG, and some additional, funds over to the JDPBPC to be used in ways determined by the district administration, and to be clearly and transparently acquitted. The District Administrator recognized that the competing interests of over 130 wards in the district meant that there would be too little for each ward and that having each ward prepare submissions for use of the funds would be both inefficient and wastefully competitive. He and his deputy, with the full support of the MP for the district, therefore developed a system intended to promote the development of consensus across formerly exclusive 39 groups. They insisted that wards amalgamate before they prepared submissions for funding. This has resulted in the 130 wards amalgamating into 14 “zones” with an average of 9 to 10 wards in each zone. This encourages wards with common needs and priorities to come together and jointly prepare proposals for funding. This is done with the assistance of technical expertise from the District Administration. Once proposals are prepared, the zone representatives sit with district officials and it is made clear the exact envelope of funds available over the next three to five years, and within this envelope a specific plan for implementation is devised. This results in more realistic and integrated plans for local development, and provides a clear and predictable timetable for implementation. Full involvement of local people is encouraged, in preparation, implementation and operation and maintenance. This is a potential model for rural development in other areas of PNG. These are only some illustrative examples of the kinds of integrative activities already occurring at the local level throughout the country. In different parts of the country other mechanisms are used to achieve substantially the same objective. In some parts of the country institutions and organizations are being developed around mining and other resource extraction activities, in some areas MPs are developing innovative approaches to providing sustainable development programs, in some areas there are interesting private/public sector partnerships emerging, as in Western Province where the PNG Sustainable Development Program, Ltd., is making use of mining revenues from the Ok Tedi mine for a variety of development activities, some of them, as in the Microfinance Project, in partnership with the private sector. The point is that in different parts of the country there are different traditional structures oriented towards consensus building and negotiation, there are different kinds and levels of resources available, and there are different needs. No one size will fit all, but all are capable of extending the range of cooperation beyond the purely local group and all can make more effective use of the resources available, even where those resources are limited. b. Some Lessons of Local Level Development Activities and Potential Areas of Inquiry These approaches are not isolated examples. The GoodNews Workshop, conducted in November, 2005 in Madang and sponsored by the State, Society and Governance in Melanesia Project44 of the ANU in collaboration with the Divine Word University, examined a range of approaches that show promise for improving development outcomes and governance at the local level. The Workshop came to many of the same conclusions as this paper with respect to the kinds of approaches likely to be effective and sustainable in the PNG context. Some important conclusions of the workshop were that: “Statist” approaches to development assistance are of course vital – we cannot give up on strengthening the state – but there are considerable traps 44 The State, Society and Governance Project of the School of Asia and Pacific Studies of the Australian National University has done more consistent and seminal work in the area of governance in the Pacific, and in PNG in particular, than any other organization since its establishment in 1996. Their website can be visited at http://rspas.anu.edu.au/melanesia/ 40 for players unprepared or lacking an understanding of the interplay between Melanesian societies and the introduced state apparatus (or indeed of the nature/model of the weak state that was left at independence). The existence of vibrant and robust societies getting on without the state, finding local solutions, coping with considerable adversity with or without some partially effective state assistance becomes increasingly obvious as the social ‘lens’ is applied to PNG. Social capital is developing rapidly and with it, civil society. Local level organizations – spontaneous and assisted – are emerging at a rapid rate. “Transactions” of a modern economic and political nature (i.e., beyond ‘tribal’ but also within it) are expanding exponentially. Entrepreneurship and the thrust for economic gain is one of the major drivers of this development, but it is by no means the sole force for change. The further development of social capital would be enhanced greatly if communications and information flows could be dramatically improved. A constant theme was that of making more widely available knowledge of the successful ventures and initiatives and their rationale and modus operandi. How to help other communities emulate these initiatives – in social order, provision of services, connectedness to the state, and in generating general well being? How to expose a broader range of communities to these role models and champions of development and reform? Research into, for example, the conditions and triggers for such community initiatives, into the spatial distribution of such initiatives (e.g., are they more concentrated in remote areas, for example, Burum Valley, or around existing economic hubs, for example the oil palm schemes?) would throw further light on these dynamics of development.45 This kind of work shows that there are a variety of initiatives occurring at the local level in PNG that show promise for improving governance and development outcomes. However, more work needs to be done to understand the kinds of local level groups that have emerged and proven successful in bringing together local constituencies to cooperate in planning, implementing and operating local initiatives, and the extent to which the existence of such groups is correlated with shifts in ascription of legitimacy. Building on the analysis in this paper, the outcomes of meetings such as the GoodNews Workshop and others, some obvious routes of inquiry at the local level should include: 45 See SSGM Report on the Conference GoodNews Workshop: Examining successful models of community development, entrepreneurship and governance by David Hegarty, Australian National University. The conference was organized by the State Society and Governance in Melanesia Project, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Australian National University in collaboration with Divine Word University and held in Madang, Papua New Guinea on 24 – 26 November, 2004 with funding support from the Australian Government through AusAID. 41 1. What is the range of trans-local groups operating at the local and district levels in PNG? This will include church groups, mining groups, groups established for specific purposes in rural areas, urban squatter groups of various sorts, migrant worker groups and others. 2. How are such groups structured and how do they function? This will include the areas from which the groups draw membership, the makeup of membership (male, female, livelihood groups, special interest groups, external members, etc.), how leadership is structured and determined, how decisions are made within the group, areas of interest of groups, resources available to the groups, how they seek to influence activities and processes affecting the local level, and so on. 3. What is the quality and nature of the relationship between trans-local groups and other organizations and institutions in general, as well as specifically local level and district level governments and government agencies? What are the levels of and sources of support provided to trans-local groups, and the extent of input of such groups into planning and decisionmaking at local and district levels? 4. What kinds of legitimacy do such groups have among the villages and/or communities in which they operate? This would initially take the form of focus groups in which an institutional mapping is done of the groups and organizations seen as important to local people, the links among groups, along which dimensions they see those groups as important, and their attitudes towards the effectiveness of those groups. 5. Identify those areas in which trans-local groups have been particularly successful, have a high degree of legitimacy and have operated for a reasonably long time. 6. How are the existence of such groups, perceptions of them among the local population, and perceived success of activities in which they are involved correlated with levels of resources delivered to the local level and with the ways in which formal institutions, such as LLGs and JDPBPCs, operate at the local level? The initial results of these analyses will be a picture of the extent to which different kinds of integrative local groups are active in PNG, the nature of their activities, the ways in which they are supported through the transfer of resources, and the extent to which they are being mainstreamed as full partners in the development process. The work will identify those situations in which local level groups are able to most effectively cooperate to achieve common goals and how they can be most effectively supported in the achievement of those goals. The level of success and effectiveness will be further correlated with the structure and nature of fiscal transfers occurring to the provincial, district and local levels, and in particular with the extent to which those transfers provide flexible resources that can be adapted to the specific needs of each local situation. This information will reveal a number of contexts in which the process of establishment of trans-local groups and their effective articulation with state (and other) institutions has proceeded successfully, thereby providing both an entry point for further support and models for implementation of similar processes in other areas of the country. This would be done in an integrated manner, in which, e.g., CDD operations engage trans-local groups, but only if there are guarantees on the part of government that fiscal transfers are 42 consistently provided under the conditions the research establishes as optimal for success in local level development. However, these approaches cannot be viable on their own. They require support – consistent and predictable support – from higher levels. If the state is to become a truly viable entity it needs to become actively involved in supporting and promoting these kinds of integrative activities at the local level. C. The State as Nurturer of National Identity: from the Top Down The second challenge, therefore, is to structure the state and state interventions so they are supportive of the already occurring processes that could eventually lead to the development of a national identity. This is critical if the state is to achieve widespread legitimacy among the people who are intended to be its constituents. If we recognize the local level needs to become more inclusive, then the role of the national level is to support those traditional tendencies towards inclusion. This is not to deny the importance or working to improve the performance and capacity of the state from the top down – improved oversight institutions, better public expenditure management, improved planning, budgeting and implementation capacity is critical – but care should be taken to ensure that those attempts are not directed more towards propping up a decaying and inappropriate state structure than to adapting the structures of the state to articulate effectively with the emerging social and cultural understandings shared among Papua New Guineans qua Papua New Guineans. In this section I will first address some of these issues of strengthening national level accountability and transparency, after which I will move into a discussion of ways in which the national level needs to acknowledge and account for differences at the subnational level if it is to become more effective in meeting the governance and development needs of the country. a. Oversight Institutions There has been a good deal of concern with strengthening the oversight institutions with responsibility for ensuring the accountability and transparency in operation of the country’s public institutions. The country has a range of oversight institutions, including an Ombudsman Commission, the Auditor General’s Office, the Office of the Attorney General, the Solicitor General, Pubic Prosecutor and Parliament itself (through such bodies as the Parliamentary Public Accounts Committee). As a recent mission to PNG by Richard Messick has confirmed, there is clearly room to strengthen these institutions and to provide them with additional human and financial resources so they can operate as effective checks on malfeasance, mismanagement, corruption and waste in the public sector institutions. For example, the mission found that the capacity of the Auditor General’s Office “to audit provincial and local governments, through which close to 70% of the national budget flows, is virtually non-existent”46. The mission also reported that a 2005 management review of the Ombudsman Commission “praised the commission for 46 See Messick, Rick, Back to Office Report PNG Oversight Institutions, Pre-Identification Mission, March 8 – 16, 2007. 43 its vigorous enforcement of the Leadership Code, [but] nonetheless found that the commission fulfilled only two of the 112 primary duties assigned to it by law”47. Activities to increase awareness of the importance of oversight institutions, combined with the strengthening of those institutions themselves, will be important in the short to medium term. However, having said this the core problems in the country have more to do with incentives for behavior and with the expectations of national politicians by citizens than with enforcement activities per se. Enforcement is useful, but has its primary utility in a situation in which the general institutional rules of behavior are accepted by most actors. At this point in PNG it is not the case that the Westminster rules are accepted. If we can progress to a point where a workable adaptation of Westminster and traditional rules are the accepted rules of the game, then enforcement activities will be both more accepted and more applicable. Right now this is not the case; there is a need to transform the notion of the state from a distant and largely irrelevant arena in which big men pursue their individual aims and objectives to one that is in close and consistent contact with lower levels in a predictable and supportive manner. Once those more inclusive rules are generally accepted as the template for action, enforcement will be both more manageable and more effective. There are several steps the state and central government can take to promote the acceptance of those rules. b. The Importance of Consistency and Reliability of State Support One key to this supportive role of the state is to promote the perception (based on reality) that the state is a dependable source of supply of needed resources. This perception will not develop if the support of the state is not consistent and predictable. Support for basic services, such as health, education and basic infrastructure, has never been consistent, and has therefore never been something on which people could depend. Where infrastructure has been provided, e.g., there is almost always insufficient attention paid to operation and maintenance, with the result that the benefits are short term and intermittent. Clearly there is a place here for capacity building, both with respect to provision of improvements and maintenance of those improvements once provided. This is a long term process that is necessary, but not sufficient to promote sustainable development. In addition, or in concert, the state needs to adopt a more nurturing and supportive role, to fully engage all subnational levels (down to and including trans-local groups) on an equal footing to promote the development of a distinctly Papua New Guinean idea of nation. The state should recognize it needs to learn from those lower levels what kinds of organization work to promote the expansion of identity beyond the purely local group, and it needs to support those groups and pull them into active participation in development, both of the country and of the nature of the state. The kind of group and the ways in which such groups interact with the state will differ depending on the region and the pre-existing sociocultural structures, but in all cases there are local level allies who need to be enlisted in the effort. If this becomes the goal of state activity, then the state itself will gradually evolve to reflect the endemic Papua New Guinean approach to 47 Ibid. 44 building consensus and acting for the common good which has allowed these groups to emerge in the first place. The emergent sense of nation will then be one that reflects, but transcends, traditional Papua New Guinean social and cultural understandings, and not one predicated on imported structures and understandings. Rigid prescriptions about how higher level institutions interact with lower level institutions and groups risk stunting the development of creative mechanisms of inclusion at lower levels. Though this is clearly a long term process, there are some avenues already available that can go a long way towards institutionalizing this kind of approach. One readily accessible avenue for this kind of open-ended engagement is through the fiscal transfers mandated under the 1995 Organic Law. As we have seen, these transfers provide the key support for the decentralization of many basic functions of the state, including important aspects of health, education and basic infrastructure. They provide a potential area of significant flexibility and choice at lower levels. If the fiscal transfers, which include considerable sums for the local levels, can be effectively implemented, they would provide an avenue at the local level for engaging those groups, structures and institutions that are trans-local, that have extended inclusion beyond the clan and village to include other groups in the local arena. The nexus of local, inclusive groups and the lowest levels of formal government, particularly local level governments and the district level, is critical in promoting a healthy relationship between emergent trans-local groups and the state. If the fiscal transfers can be effected in a consistent, dependable manner, and if the application of those resources can be removed from the control of those who would utilize them for traditional, exclusive purposes, local level planning and budgeting holds the promise of supporting and nurturing the emergence of a truly productive and legitimate process of development. This requires recognition that a variety of local level institutions and groupings have roles to play in expressing the demands and of, and providing basic needs and services to people at the local level. These groups need to be fully engaged in planning, budgeting and implementation activities. This will both support local level development in an inclusive and sustainable manner and gradually influence higher levels of the state to adapt its institutions and processes to the needs and demands of Papua New Guineans rather than operate in the straightjacket of imported understandings and structures. c. Different Strokes for Different Folks: Equity in Resource Transfers The fiscal transfers are only one part of the puzzle. Overall the national government needs to become a more dependable source of support for the lower levels of government and, eventually, for the citizens of the country. In addition to the transfers, this requires more effective planning, budgeting and implementation of such basics as service delivery and infrastructure provision. In order to do this there is a need to recognize the differing situations and needs of different areas of the country. Different provinces have different social and cultural structures, different challenges with respect to access, and different 45 capacities and potentials with respect to both human and physical resources. Interventions need to recognize these differences and be tailored to the distinct needs and situations in different parts of the country. Some important work in distinguishing among the capacities and needs of different parts of the country has been done by the National Economic and Fiscal Commission. The NEFC was established by statute consequent on the Organic Law of 1995 to advise on national macro and micro economic issues and monitor overall development, including provincial and local levels. The NEFC was to monitor the implementation of, inter alia, the fiscal transfers mandated under the Organic Law and to ensure that such transfers were made in an equitable manner. In recent years the NEFC has done groundbreaking work in analyzing the effectiveness and equity of not only the fiscal transfers but resources in general available to different provinces across the country48. It has determined that when the overall resource envelope available to provinces is considered certain provinces are far better off than others. Specifically, some provinces benefit inordinately as a result of resource extraction activities resulting in large sums being returned to them as royalties or derivation grants (based on a percentage of total exports from a province), while those provinces with no resource extraction activities tend to receive far less and much less than is necessary for basic maintenance and operation of infrastructure, service delivery and other functions assigned them under the Organic Law. NEFC has determined that the total transfers for 2005 to the provinces and lower levels amounted to a total of K385 million. Of this, only K100m, or 26%, consists of Organic Law grants. K160m, or 40%, consists of GST transfers, 19% (or K75m) of royalties, and 15% (or K50m) of locally raised revenues. This work by NEFC has demonstrated that the combination of grants, royalties (for mining provinces), GST, and local revenues available to provinces is extremely inequitable. Those that receive large royalties (e.g., New Ireland, Western, Enga, Southern Highlands) all are able to meet 100% or more of their costs49 while this is true of no other province. At least eight provinces are unable to meet even 50% of their costs under the current system. The current system of Organic Law transfers (based largely on population) does not take account of the difference among provinces with respect, e.g., to the accessibility of population, which can add a great deal of expense to the provision of services and infrastructure. In addition, fully 60% of the funding for goods, services and development in the provinces is in the form of GST and royalties, and these are distributed to the provinces from which they originate. This means GST funds go primarily to only six provinces50 48 See Review of Provincial Function Grants in 2005, by the National Economic and Fiscal Commission, September, 2006. 49 The NEFC bases its estimates of provincial expenses on what it would cost to provide basic services as well as maintenance for basic infrastructure. This does not include possible development expenditure, so is very much a baseline fiscal requirement. 50 Total GST redistribution amounts to K160 million per year, of which K71m goes to NCD, K27m to Morobe, K9m to Western Highlands, K9m to East New Britain, K8m to Madang, K6m to Eastern 46 while royalties go overwhelmingly to four provinces51The NEFC has made a number of recommendations for improving the equity of total resources available to provinces, revolving around reallocation of, GST based on the actual costs per capita of delivering services to various provinces (which vary hugely – service delivery costs per capita range from K47 in Southern Highlands to K124 in Sandaun, largely because of remoteness of population, large land area, etc.), shifting more spending to the district level, particularly in health and agriculture, and shifting more spending into goods and services and out of development per se.52 Understanding the structure and impacts of resource and fiscal transfers is an important part of improving governance in the country, and the work of the NEFC provides several points of entry for such work. d. Assessing Provincial Differences This further illustrates that the situation in PNG varies dramatically from province to province, and even within provinces from district to district. These differences need to be better understood. One useful exercise will be to do an assessment of the situation on a province by province basis along a number of dimensions in order to understand the particular challenges being faced by each province so strategies for development can be formulated that take account of the distinctions among provinces. Though it is early to specify what the important variables are across provinces, the work to this point indicates there are several that could be useful. These include: (1) resources, particularly financial, available, (2) institutional capacity for development planning and implementation, (3) sociocultural heterogeneity/homogeneity, (4) accessibility of population, (5) levels of corruption, (6) degree of participation of various groups and institutions in planning and implementation of development strategies and (7) a variable that is , in a sense, not a variable at all from the provincial level but that affects all provinces, the effectiveness/efficiency of the national government in planning, budgeting and delivering resources. The first variable is resource availability. As we have seen, several provinces have sufficient or even more than sufficient, resources available to them, particularly those with major resource extraction activities such as Western, Enga, New Ireland and Southern Highlands. There are also many provinces, the majority, with too few resources to meet their basic needs of maintenance, service delivery and other recurrent activities. NEFC has done some solid work to identify the relative positions of provinces along this dimension. A second variable revolves around provincial, district and LLG capacity for planning and implementation of development activities. At the provincial level this includes the ability Highlands and only K27m to all other provinces. See Proposals for Reform of Intergovernmental Funding in PNG, Presentation by NEFC to Special Governors Conference Mt Hagen October 18-20, 2005 51 Total royalty redistributions in 2005 amounted to nearly K75, of which K27m went to Western Province, K17m each to Enga and Southern Highlands, and K 10m to New Ireland. 52 See Review of Intergovernmental Financing, Presentation to Special Governors Conference, Mt Hagen October 18-20, 2005, Proposals for reform of intergovernmental funding in PNG. National Economic and Fiscal Commission. 47 to do medium to long term planning for development of the province, a capacity present in only a small minority of provinces. The majority have little such capacity. However, it is not the case that provincial capacity is in any way related to the level of resources available to the province. Western, Enga and several other provinces with considerable resources available (through the additional funds accruing from mining activities) nonetheless have weak and ineffective provincial administrations, while some provinces (for example, East New Britain) with few resources available nonetheless have solid provincial capacity. The situation at district and local levels is even more variable, not only among provinces but within individual provinces. The third variable is sociocultural homogeneity/heterogeneity within the province. Sociocultural fragmentation is a hallmark of Papua New Guinea, and many provinces have extreme levels of such fragmentation. The provinces of Morobe, Madang, the Sepiks and several of the, particularly, eastern Highlands provinces have extreme sociocultural diversity, each with up to 50 or more different language groups. At the same time, some provinces, such as East New Britain, have as few as half a dozen or less language groups. Sociocultural homogeneity/heterogeneity is an important variable with respect to strategies for development in a province. Another distinction among provinces is the degree to which the population has access to services and to the outside markets and communities. Basic improvements, such as roads and other infrastructure, have proceeded unevenly across the country, partly because of difficulty of terrain, partly for political and related reasons. The effect that the cost of delivering services for some provinces, per capita, is much higher than that for other provinces. The NEFC has done some excellent work in this area, and has shown that the per capita cost of delivering services to some provinces is one third the cost in other provinces. The fiscal transfers do not take account of these distinctions. A fifth variable is corruption, particularly at the provincial level. There is a wide variance in the extent to which resources transferred to the provincial, and lower, level are properly acquitted and are utilized in an accountable and transparent fashion. Clearly, even if adequate resources are delivered to the provincial level, corruption can mean those resources do not have the impact we would expect and as clearly, in those provinces with already inadequate resources, corruption only aggravates the situation. A sixth variable is the extent of citizen participation in decisionmaking processes with respect to planning, implementation and maintenance. As we have seen, in some provinces and districts local groups participate fully in the planning development strategies, as in East New Britain where the DSG is utilized transparently and accountably. The extent to which citizens, and various institutions, participate inclusively (including with respect to gender) can make a major difference in the sense of local ownership and, by extension, the sustainability of local development activities. The final variable is one that is actually more or less generic to all provinces - the degree to which national government has both the capacity and will to deliverer resources to the provincial, district and local levels. This includes the ability of national government to 48 do an effective job of formulating the national budget, ability to actually deliver the resources called fro under that budget, and capacity to monitor and be accountable for delivery of those resources. These variables can be useful to do an initial assessment of provinces that would provide us with significant entry points for doing work in different areas. More work would be necessary to determine the specifics of the challenges facing different provinces, but these diagnostics can be an interesting point of departure. D. Where the Top Meets the Bottom: The District as Entry Point for Improving Governance and Development Outcomes The point at which the imported institutions of the Westminster Parliamentary System and the traditional systems of Papua New Guinea come together for the majority of the people of the country is at the district and local levels. Though the country can be approached at the regional or provincial levels, most of the actual work of development will occur at an even lower level, the district. In addition to the work suggested above, it would be useful to do a more fine-grained assessment of the actual situation at the district level across a number of districts in different provinces of the country. The intent of this work would be twofold. First, there is the question of what resources are actually available to the district level to meet service delivery, infrastructure and other development needs. Second, there is the question of how those resources are actually used, who makes decisions concerning their use and how effectively they are applied. This suggests a set of questions, including: What resources are actually delivered and available to the district and lower levels (including fiscal transfers/grants, GST, royalties, internal revenue, etc.); How are those resources applied – what use is made of them? To what extent are they used for the purposes intended? Who determines how those resources are applied? This will include different actors, institutions and groups depending on the nature of the resources (e.g., DSG is controlled by the JDPBPC, the unconditional block grant and three function grants are controlled by various local level government and district bodies, royalties flow to certain groups, etc.). What is the level of participation of various groups in the decisions concerning the use of different kinds of resources delivered to the district and local levels? Is the use of the DSG or the block grant determined in a participatory manner, and if so who participates? To what extent is there overall coordination in the use of resources delivered to the local level? Do agencies, institutions and groups who have decisionmaking power over the use of certain kinds of resources coordinate their activities and priorities with other groups who have decisionmaking power over the use of different resource streams? What is the effectiveness of outcomes at the local level? Can an assessment be made of the efficiency with which available resources are used? Are resources 49 applied in a strategic manner – i.e., is there a medium and/or long term plan for the use of resources to gradually improve conditions at the local level? Part of the work would be to attempt to assess the incentive structure for decisions made at the local level with respect to the use of resources. Once the decisionmakers for the use of resources are identified they should be interviewed to determine their rationales for the ways in which they apply the resources or “encourage” them to be applied. If we can understand the incentives for both efficient and inefficient behavior, we can begin to identify the levers through which such behavior can be changed or improved with respect to development outcomes. a. National Parliamentarians as Stakeholders One of the key groups of stakeholders/decisionmakers who should be engaged is the national parliamentarians, who play a major role in deciding and influencing how resources are used at the local level. If we can understand the incentives for those MPs who approach, e.g., the use of the DSG in a transparent, accountable and participatory manner we may be able to leverage this knowledge to encourage others to do likewise. It is clear that the main motivation for any politician in the distribution of benefits is to gain political support. It is interesting that PNG will, in the next election, shift from a first past the post to a limited preferential voting system for Parliament. It is hoped that this system will result in politicians responding to demands from a greater proportion of the total electorate, as electability will now depend not only on the ability to garner complete support of a small, usually kinship defined group, but on the ability to gain a second and third preference vote from a much wider range of voters. This provides an opportunity to apply the findings from this study in a way that could possibly provide a major “pay-off” to national politicians. If, for example, a correlation is established between those MPs who approach the use of the DSG and other resources at the local level in a transparent and participatory manner and the level of political support under a limited preferential system, this would have a powerful demonstration effect for other politicians to alter their behavior. If approached wisely, this could serve as an incentive for politicians to engage with more people in the electorate and to encourage greater participation of more groups in return for which he/she would receive political support sufficient to ensure election. b. CDD in the Context of Trans-Local Groups The potentially productive relationship between national level and more inclusive local level groups has implications for the way in which CDD operations are implemented in the country. One of the mistakes of CDD approaches in PNG has been the tendency to support purely local level groups (often on a village by village basis), rather than concentrating on supporting groups that represent wider coalitions of villages and communities. CDD that supports village based groups alone may provide needed basic services on a short term basis, but such approaches only reinforce the perception that 50 local groups are competitive, that the process of development is a zero sum game, and in the long run this can be more destructive than productive. Therefore, any CDD operation in PNG should promote the active building of consensus across groups concerning development priorities, and the aim of such operations should explicitly be the extension of legitimacy to larger groups than have traditionally existed. Institutionalizing links between these trans-local groups and local, district and provincial level government should also be a requisite component of any CDD operation. This means a strong emphasis on an often lengthy process of conflict resolution, consensus building and the development of common goals and recognition of a community of interest. 51 PART III: CONCLUSION This analysis of the political economy of Papua New Guinea, and of the processes and structures that have emerged in the context of that political economy, illustrates the complexity of issues of governance, development and sustainability of development activities in a situation in which pre-existing traditional structures are overlain with an introduced political system. The analysis has shown that there are several cross-cutting areas that need to be understood and addressed to achieve the goal of improving governance and improving the effectiveness and efficiency with which development is delivered to the people of the country. Ultimately, the way in which these issues are addressed will determine the success of Papua New Guinea in becoming a nation, a constituency in which all, or at the least most, members feel an allegiance to the state because the state has proven to be a dependable deliverer or the resources and expertise required to improve the lives of its citizens. The country of Papua New Guinea was, in many respects, accidental. The geographic expanse, the variety of social and cultural systems included in the new nation, and the nature of the governmental system introduced were all serendipitous. Little real thought was given to the ways in which the introduced system would articulate with the plethora of pre-existent systems already present. This has led to a variety of problems and obstacles with which the country has had to grapple for over thirty years. It is unfortunate that the way in which the introduced institutions were structured had the effect of simultaneously encouraging the divisive and competitive aspects of traditional societies while muting the traditional tendencies towards consensus building and negotiation. Nonetheless, this is the reality of the situation and the only path is to move on from here and attempt to make the best of a difficult situation. There is no guarantee that the country, much less the nation, of Papua New Guinea will, in the long term, be viable. If that is to be the case there will have to be some fundamental rethinking of how the national level works, how the national level interacts with the local level, and how the more integrative and inclusive aspects of the local level can be encouraged and fostered and how they, in turn, can force an adaptation of national level strategies and processes. The process of nation building is one that must build on endemic aspects of Papua New Guinean social and cultural processes while at the same time moving beyond those processes in terms of inclusiveness and the recognition of communities of interest. In general we have seen that this process of nation building will revolve around two approaches, one from the top down and one from the bottom up. The most critical of these is certainly the bottom up, the restructuring of the nature of the groups at the local level that make demands of higher levels, and the establishment of more encompassing communities of interest that promote wider local level concerns than is now common in the country. Development of such communities of interest is a precondition for the restructuring of higher levels to respond to these new local level demands. If the local level continues to operate in the way it has traditionally, representing narrow clan-based 52 interests, no amount of reform, capacity building or improved oversight at the national level will result in improved development outcomes. Therefore, the first step is to understand those processes already occurring at the local level in various parts of the country that are leading to more inclusive groups who are cooperating across traditional boundaries. There are many example of such groups, and analytic work to assess the range of such groups, how they are structured and function, how they draw membership, how decisions are made, the quality and nature of their relationship with each other and with formal institutions, their levels of legitimacy among their constituencies and the extent to which, and how, they have been successful is a necessary first step. This analysis will provide us with success stories, examples of how such groups can be effectively structured in different traditional sociocultural systems, and entry points for supporting and expanding such activities. This analytic work from the bottom up needs to be complemented by work from the top down. Here there are a number of different areas that require further work. First, we need to understand the kind of resources actually available from, as well as actually being delivered by the national level to lower levels. This work includes all forms of resource transfer, including national budget transfers for critical service delivery functions (health, education, infrastructure, etc.) as well as transfers such as the fiscal grants under the Organic Law, royalties to mining provinces, GST transfers and local level own resources. This needs to be done in the context of work such as that done by the NEFC that assesses the actual needs of provinces and lower levels given the reality that provinces and lower levels differ substantially across a number of variables. Serious consideration needs to be given to what can be done to improve equity in the delivery of resources to provinces and lower levels. This work will also require an assessment of the actual situation in different provinces and areas of the country across a number of variables. These will include resources available to each province, institutional capacity of provinces and lower levels, sociocultural diversity, issues of accessibility of populations in different provinces, levels of corruption and the degree of participation of various groups in decisionmaking and implementation. Understanding how these variables differ across provinces, as well as within them, is the first step in devising strategic approaches to improving governance and the delivery of services and development across the country. It needs to be recognized that the variety of situations across the country will call for distinct approaches by region, province and even, in some cases, district. Another important aspect of improving performance from the top down has to do with oversight institutions. The most important point here is to recognize that improvements in effectiveness of oversight institutions depend more on a change in the rules of the game that must emerge from the local level than in capacity building or the provision of additional resources. The latter is certainly necessary, but it is insufficient if improved governance is the objective. 53 Finally, the key point of intersection of formal, national level institutions and more traditional, local level institutions is at the district level, and it is here that considerable work needs to be done to understand how those two levels intersect currently, and how that intersection can be improved. This calls for some serious work at the district level that will answer such questions as what resources are actually delivered to the district levels, how the resources are applied (and whether they are applied in ways intended), who makes decisions concerning the use of resources, the extent to which there is full participation of stakeholders in such decisions and whether such groups have been able to establish larger, more inclusive communities of interest in pursuing development objectives. The process of nation building in Papua New Guinea will not be an easy one. It will require commitment of a variety of actors and stakeholders at all levels, from the national to the grass roots. However, there are fundamental strengths of traditional Papua New Guinea societies that can be enlisted in the effort. If all the key stakeholders – government, civil society, development partners – focus on activities that encourage those strengths while working to minimize the influence of inherently divisive strategies and activities there is hope that the country of Papua New Guinea, currently minimally defined as a physical but not a social reality, may one day be a nation as well. 54