RETAINED WEALTH AND FAMILY FIRM IPO Hung-bin Ding Loyola College in Maryland Kuntara Pukthuanthong-Le San Diego State University ABSTRACT Most IPO firms are new and difficult to value. Investors can become informed by obtaining information about the issuing companies. However, overcoming information asymmetry is costly. Signaling is an effective approach for an issuer to communicate with its aftermarket investors. We argue that the uniqueness of family firms have impact on how investors interpret the signals. In this research, we investigated the effect of IPO signals in family firm IPOs. Our sample includes 84 family IPO firms and 84 comparable non-family IPO firms. The family firms in our sample have been constantly named as top 250 largest corporations in Taiwan over the period of 1997-2004. The results of analysis suggest that family businesses are unique in the relationship between IPO signals and underpricing. Practices of signaling such as the appointment of non-family directors and partnering with prestigious underwriters significantly reduce underpricing. In addition, family owners’ intent to retain large percentage of share in the long run is an indication of original shareholders’ level of confidence in their own companies. Such confidence helps reduce after market investors’ uncertainty and thus underpricing. 1 INTRODUCTION Do equity investors view family firms as a unique target of investment? One of the central assumptions of family business research is that family-controlled or family-owned firms systematically demonstrate distinctive behavioral patterns. Such uniqueness is largely viewed as the results of business owners making efforts to balance the family interests and to maintain sustainable business operations in the same time. A growing number of empirical studies have identified many areas of such behavioral differences (e.g. Ram & Holliday, 1993; Tsui-Auch & Lee, 2003; Craig & Dibrell, 2006). Since family firms demonstrate distinctive behavioral patterns, shouldn’t they receive unique treatment from investors? Consultants have long been working with their family business clients to seek means to best preserve the value of stocks and assets of companies. The discussions of shareholder rights are closely associated with the extensive studies on family business succession (Davis & Harveston, 1998; Lee, Lim, & Lim, 2003; Chrisman, Chua, & Sharma, 1998; Sharma & Rao, 2000; Sharma & Irving, 2005). Along the line of succession research, changes in tax laws and other regulations also motivate researchers to look into the impact of these changes on incumbent owners’ ability to transfer wealth and the control of companies to the inheriting generations. Recently, the interests in the performance of family firms in the capital market are on the rise. More family firm owners have come to realize that going public is essential for long-term growth and to survive (Chemmanur, He, & Nandy, 2006; Pagano, Panetta, & Zingales, 1998). In the United States, despite higher ROA before going public, the equity prices of family firms tend to be lower than those of non-family firms (Astrachan & McConaughy, 2001). Similar results were found in a study on the long-term stock performance of family firms in Germany and Spain (Jaskiewicz, Gonzalez, Menendez, & 2 Schiereck, 2005). Same article also reports that family involvement has positive contribution to the equity price (Jaskiewicz et al., 2005). However, evidences from Standard & Poor’s 500 companies suggest that family firms perform better than non-family firms in the capital market (Anderson & Reeb, 2003; Villalonga & Amit, 2006). Despite the recent progresses, studies on long-term performance give us little information about how investors view family firms when they make investment decisions. In addition, strategic management researchers have suggested relationships between share price and a number of factors. For example, the percentage of shares controlled by individual investors has positive contribution to share price volatility (Hansen & Hill, 1991). A research on Japanese and American public companies asserts that lay-off announcements significantly bring down stock prices (Lee, 1997). Before the bust of Dot-Com, changing the name of a company to Dot-Com significantly boasts the price of a name changer’s stock (Lee, 2001; Cooper, Dimitrov, & Rau, 2001). The results of a study on 181 multinational corporations (MNCs) uncover that the performance indicators such as stock price reflect the confluence of multiple competitive advantage-building activities including the emphasis on market orientation, entrepreneurship, and innovativeness etc. (Hult & Ketchen Jr., 2001). Observations on the extent of underpricing in family business IPO allow us to focus on the investor effects on IPO by ruling out most of the contributing factors of long-term stock performance. In the United States, IPO underpricing refers to the difference between the offer price and the closing price on the IPO day. Since issuing shares are allocated mainly to the most influential or institutional investors, the offer price reflects the information possessed by the most informed investors. On the other hand, the closing price on the IPO day reflects private information from small or retail investors, who rarely receive an allocation of issuing shares. 3 This price difference is viewed a “money left on the table” since the original equity owners have sold their shares to institutional or individual investors at a pre-market price, which is lower than the first-day closing price. Overall, the first-day return phenomenon is explained by asymmetric information between issuers and other two major stakeholders of IPO, underwriters and investors. Issuers can close the gap of information asymmetry by working closely with underwriters or by signaling to the market. In this research, we focus on the impact of market signal on family firm IPO performances. Since we are interested in the interactions between issuers and investors, we tested our hypotheses in an auction IPO market to minimize underwriters’ effect in underpricing. This study extends current literature in two ways. First, it highlights the extrinsic uniqueness of family firms. Second, we reconceptualize the insider-outsider dichotomy in the corporate governance literature by highlighting the importance of non-family board members in IPO performance. This article is structured as follows. We will review the theories of IPO underpricing and present our hypothesis development in the next two sections. The third section offers a description of data collection and methodology. The results of our analysis are presented in the fourth section, followed by discussion and conclusion. IPO STAKEHOLDERS AND UNDERPRICING The issuing company, underwriter, and investors are the three major stakeholders in an equity offering deal. Underpricing occurs when investors after the issuance are willing to purchase the issuers’ stock at a price higher than the offer price. The issuers would be able to completely retain the wealth created from IPO if investors believe the offer price reflects the fair value of the stocks. However, multinational surveys on initial returns of IPO suggest that the 4 offer prices are usually set below the fair market price (Lounghran, Ritter, & Rydqvist, 1994; Ljungqvist, 2006: 9-10). Underwriter Effects in Bookbuilding and Auction IPO The IPO stocks are priced and introduced to the market following two broadly defined mechanisms. The first one is bookbuilding. This mechanism requires one or a coalition of investment bankers to underwrite the offering. In addition to preparing paper works for regulatory scrutiny, underwriters are responsible for allocating IPO shares to their favorite institutional investors. Interactions between underwriters and institutional investors reduce the risk of undersubscription for issuers (Sherman, 2005.) However, underwriters are also given great discretion to set an offer price. The second IPO mechanism is auction. In an auction IPO, the stocks are sold to bidders before being traded in the public market. An investment banker is usually hired by the issuer to manage the offering process and to guarantee sufficient interests in the IPO (Sherman, 2005). However, instead of allocating IPO shares to institutional investors, underwriters of auction IPOs are responsible for selling equities to winning bidders in pre-market auctions. The offer prices reflect the result of pre-market auctions. There are extensive discussions and debates about the effects of underwriters in IPO underpricing (see Ljungqvist, 2006 for a comprehensive review). The great discretion of underwriters in bookbuilding motivates many researchers to investigate why underwriters underprice their clients’ equities. One of the arguments is information asymmetry between issuing companies and underwriters (Rock, 1986; Beatty & Ritter, 1986). An issuing company may be too optimistic when presenting its operation data and financial outlook to its underwriter. Of course underwriter will verify the accuracy of information provided by the issuing firm. The more transparent the latter’s operation is, the more underwriter trusts the reports and assessments 5 from the issuer. When information asymmetry is not a major concern, the underwriters are likely to price the equity offering close to the expected market value. Nonetheless, underwriters will not be able to fully trust the assessment and self-evaluation provided by their IPO clients if the business operation and financial reporting of the latter are less transparent. The underwriter can elect to ignore the problem with the quality of data provided by the issuing companies and determine the offer prices accordingly. However, doing so will increase the underwriter’s risk to overprice an IPO. Lowering the offer price allows underwriters to avoid potential overpricing. Such information asymmetry motivates underwriters to price the equity below an optimal price to avoid undersubscription. In other words, underwriters discount the offer price to offset risk derived from business (Certo, Covin, Daily, & Dalton, 2001). An IPO underwriter is also an agent to the issuing company. Agency problems occur when an underwriter obtains economic gains by not maximizing its issuing company’s gains from IPO. The agency problem arises because underwriters are investment banks. Besides public offering deals, these banks usually offer different types of banking services. If selling a public offering equity at a low price to selected clients helps retaining these major clients for the investment bankers, underwriters may have strong incentive to introduce the IPO deal at a low offer price (Ritter and Welch, 2002; Loughran and Ritter, 2002). The balance of bargaining power between underwriters and issuing companies also affects underpricing. Underwriters are prone to press the issuing companies to underprice the equity to attract investors (Beatty & Ritter, 1986). Large underwriters usually price their IPO equities lower than their smaller competitors (Beatty & Welch, 1996). Moderately underpriced equities are found to generate more investors’ interests (Nanda & Yun, 1997). Because of large 6 underwriters’ marketing power to reach investors, issuing companies may be willing to accept a low offer price for more investor interests and more after-market trading (Ljungqvist, 2006). Underwriters receive underwriting fees from equity offering firms for the service provided in researching, valuing the deal and finding institutional investors to bid for the equity offering. An underwriter also receives a commission or remaining equity from the sales of the IPO equities. If the underwriters are forced to charge a low underwriting fee for their services, underwriters are likely to intentionally price the IPO deal low to attract more buyers to bid for the stocks. For example, Taiwan stock exchange adopted a hybrid approach of IPO sales. In the Taiwanese market, underwriters are used to auction off the IPO equities. Underwriters are also required by law to buy unsold equities from an IPO deal. In addition, the hyper competitive underwriting market allows issuing companies to bargain a low underwriting fee against underwriters. To recover from the cost of underwriting a deal, underwriters often use a low introduction price to attract bidders and to lower the liability in case there is large quantity of equity remaining unsold (Chen, Fok, & Wang, 2006). In the United States, stringent rules of disclosure expose the underwriters to great legal liabilities. A recent study estimates that about six percent of underwriters were sued for violating disclosure rules from 1988 to 1995 (Lowry & Shu, 2002). In addition to financial damage, lawsuits can have negative impact on an investment bankers’ reputation (Ljungqvist, 2006). Intentionally setting the IPO offer price below the fair price is an insurance measure for underwriters to avoid litigation (Tinic, 1988). Although some theorists believe that auction mechanism reduces the impact of underwriters and thus IPO underpricing (Sherman, 2005), Lounghran, Ritter, & Rydqvist’s (1994) cross country survey indicates that underpricing exists in both auction and bookbuilding 7 markets. To give a fair assessment of IPO equity, auction bidders need firm-specific information such as business operation, major clients, competition, and management, etc. Information production is not free. High information production would limit the number of potential bidders and cause IPO undersubscription. If the cost of information production is low, the number of potential bidders increases. Since the equity bidding is expected to be highly competitive, potential investors may decide to withdraw from the bidding thus increases the variance of auction participation (Sherman, 2005). The upshot of information production cost is that auction mechanism can create even higher underpricing than bookbuilding (Sherman, 2005). Investors and Underpricing Most IPO firms are new and difficult to value. Unlike trading existing stocks in the market, investors face a great uncertainty to determine the fair price of the stocks. Investors can become informed by obtaining information about the issuing companies. The information gathering efforts reduce the uncertainty of IPO valuation. However, overcoming information asymmetry is costly. Informed investors would not buy the IPO stock in the aftermarket if the difference between the fair price and offer price is not big enough to compensate the information gathering cost. Underpricing thus offers needed compensation to attract informed investors (Ritter, 1984; Beatty & Ritter, 1986). There is a positive correlation between the cost of information and the extent of underpricing (Beatty & Ritter, 1986). On the other hand, uninformed investors contribute to underpricing by buying the IPO stock at prices higher than informed investors. Uninformed investors who pay below fair price will not be able to buy any stock from the market. However, uninformed investors are likely to pay too much for IPO stocks (Rock, 1986). Underpricing will exist even if most of the investors are well-informed about the value of IPO stock. 8 Recent behavioral finance literature highlighted many contributing factors of market sentiment. For example, investors may develop overconfidence in their knowledge of investment target (Odean, 1998). In addition, self-attribution bias leads investors to believe that unfavorable outcome of investment is bad luck and attribute favorable outcome to their knowledge of market (Daniel, Hirshleifer, & Subrahmanyam, 1998). Although underpricing caused by market sentiment necessarily upset original shareholders of issuing companies, these shareholder are able to regain their loss from selling their retained shares in the high price aftermarket (Derrien, 2005). Despite the potential to make up the lost wealth in the aftermarket, the equity owners may opt not to sell their shares to the aftermarket investors. This is particular salient in family business IPOs when family owners intend to retain control of the firm long after IPO. In addition, overpriced stocks in the early stage of IPO are likely to underperform in the long run and thus increase the risk for shareholders (Ritter, 1991). Underwriters and investors both have strong influence to the extent of IPO underpricing. As underpricing transfers issuers’ wealth to pre-market institutional investors or auction winners, issuers are motivated to reduce the cost of information gathering for underwriters and investors. Issuers may neutralize the underwriter-driven underpricing by working closely with underwriters to reduce the information asymmetry. However, bridging the gap of information asymmetry between issuers and aftermarket investors is a great challenge. The number of aftermarket investors is usually far greater than that of underwriters. Working closely with all investors is simply not possible since the cost of communication will be very high. Additionally, it is not aftermarket investors’ best interest to overload themselves with excessive information. Therefore 9 sending positive signals to aftermarket become an important measure to close the information gap between issuers and investors (Beatty & Ritter, 1986; Filatochev & Bishop, 2002). INVESTORS AND FAMILY FIRM IPO Signaling is particularly important to family business IPO deals. There have been extensive studies on the behavioral difference between family and non-family firms (Brochaus, 1994; Litz, 1995; Zahra, Hayton & Salvato; 2004) and the implications of such uniqueness to firm performances (Alvesson & Lindkvist, 1993; Ainsworth & Cox, 2003; Anderson & Reeb, 2003; Villalonga & Amit, 2006.) The uniqueness of family firm behaviors is, by definition, a result of overlapping between emotion-based human family and exchange-based business organization (Litz, 1995; Chrisman, Chua, & Sharma, 1998). A recent study suggests that this overlapping enables the efficiency enhancing practices such as commitment to long term objectives and human capital development (Bertrand & Schoar, 2006). In addition, family ties provide a trust network when the business environment lacks strong legal structure (Oxfeld, 1993; Rose, 2000; Burkart, Panunzi, & Shleifer, 2003). However, family firms may be over- committed to family value (Bertrand & Schoar, 2006). Strong family ties may become the culprit of nepotism (Barnett, 1960). Research on family business governance has also pointed out an agency problem between family shareholders and non-family shareholders in family firms (Morck & Yeung 2003). Such agency problem arises when a family-controlled corporate board makes decisions in favor of family shareholders’ interests. Investors may be able to learn if such agency problem is a concern from the track record when considering buying a family business stock in the aftermarket. However, with few exceptions of celebrity companies, there is very little track record information about the 10 corporate governance quality of IPO stocks. As the appointment independent directors is viewed as a signal of good governance practice in IPO (Certo et al., 2001), increasing the influence of non-family directors on the board may reduces the uncertainty associated with investing family IPO. Therefore: Hypothesis 1 Giving non-family directors more seats on the corporate board reduces underpricing of a family firm IPO. For an IPO firm, the degree of IPO underpricing is likely to be associated with its level of pre-IPO insider ownership. The higher the pre-IPO percentage of insider ownership, the higher the cost imposed on insiders from the decline of firm value (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Entrepreneurs will suffer substantial economic losses if the firm’s future performance is poor. A higher percentage of insider ownership signals to the market that the firm is of high quality. As insiders are supposed to know the true value of company, their willingness to retain large amount of shares after IPO indicates their confidence in the future prospect of the firm (Leland & Pyle, 1977; Downes & Heinkel 1982; Clarkson, Dontoh, Richardson, Sefcik, 1991; How & Low, 1994). In short, insiders’ retained stock post ante is an indication of original shareholders’ level of confidence to their own companies. Such confidence helps reduces aftermarket investors’ uncertainty (Certo et al., 2001). An extension of Leland and Pyle’s (1977) model is that family insiders may intentionally send a signal of their firm’s quality by retaining a high level of pre-IPO ownership. Allen and Faulhaber (1989), Grinblatt and Hwang (1989) and Welch (1989) model a separating equilibrium 11 where high quality firms have high underpricing and pre-IPO insider ownership. They explain that good quality firms are willing to underprice their IPOs because they expect to raise more money after the IPO. In contrast, low-quality firms do not expect to access the capital markets for further rounds of financing; therefore, they are not willing to underprice but rather take the money from their IPO and “run”. An implication of this separating equilibrium is the positive relation between underpricing and post-IPO market valuation. Moreover, underpricing is positively related to the probability of issuing second equity offerings (SEOs) and the size of SEOs. Based on a survey of insiders’ retained stock 1 year post-IPO, Habib and Ljungqvist (2001) explain that the underpricing of IPO is high for IPO firm whose owners sell the fewer shares at the IPO or retain their ownership after the IPO and thus are more tolerant of underpricing. Taken together, we hypothesize that the expected large long-term insiders’ equity stakes decrease underpricing. Hypothesis 2 The expected long-term family ownership decreases underpricing. Underwriters assist issuers to satisfy legal requirements of IPO by closely monitoring issuers’ pre-IPO activities. The quality of their works in IPO preparation has significant impact on their reputation. The need to uphold reputation motivates underwriters to work diligently during the IPO process. However, some underwriters are more capable than others in identifying the fair price of IPO stocks by, for example, uncovering hidden assets or other variable factors in the issuer. These more capable investment bankers enjoy higher prestige than their peers in the underwriting industry. Partnering with these high prestige underwriters sends a positive signal 12 about the quality of the firm to the market (Beatty & Ritter, 1986). Since family firms are more likely to have hidden variables than non-family firms due to the closed link between family life and business operations, hiring a prestigious underwriter may have a stronger effect in reducing family firm IPO uncertainty than in non-family IPOs. Hypothesis 3 Using prestigious underwriters lower the underpricing of family and non-family firm IPOs, but this effect is greater in family firms. RESEARCH DESIGN AND VARIABLE DEFINITION Empirical Models and Key Variables We examine the association of underpricing with various family ownership and IPO variables using the following regression model (time subscript omitted): 1. Family IPOs Underpricing k = B 0 +B 1 (% of outside directors) + B 2 (% of family ownership at IPO) + B 3 (% of family ownership 3-yr post-IPO) + B 4 (potential successor dummy) + B 5 (underwriter’s ranking) + B 6 + ( IPO volume) + B 7 (high-tech dummy) + B 8 (log of proceed) + B 9 (firm age) + B 10 (bubble period dummy) + E (1) 2. Non-family IPOs 13 Underpricing k = A 0 + A 1 (underwriter’s ranking) + A 2 + ( IPO volume) + A 3 (high-tech dummy) + A 4 (log of proceed) + A 5 (firm age) + A 6 (bubble period dummy) + E (2) where Underpricingk is the extent of IPO underpricing for firm k, measured as the percentage return from the offer price to the closing price on the fifteenth calendar day after the IPO. Note that our definition of underpricing is consistent with existing international IPO studies that generally measure IPO initial returns over a period of several weeks (e.g., Loughran, Ritter, and Rydqvist., 1994; Ljungqvist, Jenkinson, and Wilhelm, 2003; Ritter, 2003). The reason for the use of longer return windows is twofold. The price movements in the Taiwanese market during the initial days of trading are restricted by exchange regulation, delaying the emergence of an equilibrium price.1 Hsu and Hung (2005) report a daily price limit of +/-7% is imposed on securities traded in Taiwan’s stock markets; therefore, a stock price could continue to hit the limit several days after the IPO date. Lin, Lee, and Liu (2003) measure initial return using the closing price on the 20th trading date. They argue that the first closing market price or the “non-hit” price in the post-IPO market does not hit either the upper or lower price limit. To compute IPO underpricing using the first closing price ignores any adjustments in the market value of the IPO shares after the “non-hit” price is observed. We estimate equation (1) on sample of 84 family IPOs and on sample of 84 non-family firms. Indepedent variables The first independent variable is the percentage of outside directors (% of outside directors), which is defined as number of directors who are not members of controlling family This argument also applies to France and Japan where “circuit breakers” are installed to limit post-IPO daily price fluctuations within a certain preset limit. 1 14 per total number of directors. Managerial entrenchment is less likely to occur with the presence of outside directors. In addition, the outsiders may bring expertise to complement the abilities of incumbent board members (Filatochev & Bishop, 2002). We thus expect IPOs with higher % of outside directors display lower underpricing. The second and third independent variables are the percentage of family ownership at the IPO and the expected percentage of long-term family ownership. The first variable is measured as the percentage of shares owned by original family business owner before the trading date. The second variable is such percentage measured for 36th month after the date of IPO or from the IPO date until the third year after the IPO. For the second variable, we apply the same methodology used by Purnanandam and Swaminathan (2004) regressing underpricing on forecasted book value to market value ratio where market value is known after the IPO. The third independent variable is underwriter prestige. We hypothesize that IPOs that have high family control should benefit more from working with more prestigious underwriters who can provide expertise and strategic guidance in helping them harvest the fruits of their labor through an IPO. Underwriter prestige (Underwriter prestige) is constructed based on the US$ proceeds of the IPOs each underwriter underwrote during our sample period. We followed the approach developed by Carter and Manaster (1990) to rate underwriter prestige. The Carter and Manaster measure is constructed from the placements of IPO underwriters in the prospectus, which lists all the investment banking firms that comprise the underwriting syndicate of an IPO issue with more prestigious underwriters listed higher. This measure, however, is limited to U.S. underwriters. Following the idea that more prestigious investment banks generally underwrite more IPOs, most of which tend to be larger offerings, we construct a discrete measure of underwriter ranking from 0 (least prestigious) to 9 (most prestigious) by classifying each lead 15 investment bank for our sample IPOs into one of 10 categories according to the total proceeds of the IPOs the investment bank underwrote during our 1987– 2004 sample period.2 Note that our measure is consistent with that used by Megginson and Weiss (1991) who gauge underwriter quality with the average market share of the underwriter. Control Variables We derive control variables from the extant IPO literature. These variables reflect the extent of information asymmetries in the IPO process and the degree of uncertainty over issue value. Specifically, we include six firm-level underpricing determinants, which we discuss below. The first control variable is the natural logarithm of issue proceeds (Log of proceeds), one of the most commonly used for underpricing determinants. Larger firms are generally considered less risky than smaller firms. Hence, the size of the issue (in U.S. dollars) is expected to be negatively correlated with underpricing (Beatty and Ritter, 1986). The second control variable is the existence of potential successor (Successor dummy). A family firm would be coded 1 when a successor from the family is either placed in the top management team or the corporate board, coded zero for otherwise. Having a potential successor from family implies that family wants to retain ownership for a long-term; therefore, they may want to price the IPO correctly and thus decrease underpricing. In addition, the presence of potential successor reduces the uncertainty derived from succession planning (Davis & Harveston, 1998; Lee, Lim, & Lim, 2003). 2 Specifically, we assign a discrete integer to each lead underwriter as follows: 9 if its total proceeds are no less than $20 billion; 8 if proceeds are between $10 and $20 billion; 7 if proceeds are between $5 and $10 billion; 6 if proceeds are between $2 and $5 billion; 5 if proceeds are between $1 and $2 billion; 4 if proceeds are between $0.5 and $1 billion; 3 if proceeds are between $0.2 and $0.5 billion; 2 if proceeds are between $0.1 and $0.2 billion; 1 if proceeds are below $0.1 billion; and 0 if the lead underwriter is not ranked among the top 500 by the SDC. 16 The third control variable is IPO volume (IPO volume). The extant IPO literature has long recognized that cycles exist in both the volume and the average initial returns of IPOs. 3 For example, Ibbotson and Jaffe (1975) and Lowry and Schwert (2002) find a strong pattern of negative associations between current IPO underpricing and prior IPO volume. To control for cyclical patterns in the IPO market, we construct an IPO volume variable for every IPO, which is defined as the total number of domestic IPOs issued over the 12-month period ending in the month in which the IPO was issued. The fourth control variable is high-tech dummy (High-tech dummy). To the extent that information asymmetry tends to be similar within industries, industry effects provide some control for cross-sectional variation in information asymmetry (Ljungqvist et al., 2003). As a result, we include high-tech dummy in our regressions. High-tech firms are identified following the classification methods in Loughran and Ritter (2004) and Cliff and Denis (2004) and expected to have higher underpricing than other IPOs.4 The fifth control variable is bubble period dummy (Bubble period dummy), which is equal to one if the IPO was issued in 1999 or 2000, and zero otherwise. Bubble period dummy controls for time-series variation in underpricing (Loughran and Ritter, 2004). Lastly, we control for firm age (Firm age). We calculate a company’s age as the difference in years between its founding date and its IPO date. We hand-fill gaps in SDC’s coverage of company founding dates, and manually check all firms that according to SDC were zero to three years old at the time of their IPO, because Loughran and Ritter (2004) note that Periods of high average initial returns and rising volume are commonly referred to as “hot issues” markets. Loughran and Ritter (2004) and Cliff and Denis (2004) categorize firms with the following SIC codes as high-tech firms: 2833, 2834, 2835, 2836, 3571, 3572, 3575, 3577, 3578, 3661, 3663, 3669, 3674, 3812, 3823, 3825, 3826, 2827, 3829, 3841, 3845, 4812, 4813, 4899, 7370, 7371, 7372, 7373, 7374, 7375, 7377, 7378, 7379. 3 4 17 SDC frequently reports the most recent incorporation date rather than the founding date.5 According to existing studies, we expect this variable to be negatively related to underpricing since younger firms at time of IPO are more risky and have high information asymmetry. SAMPLE AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Sample Selection Business Groups in Taiwan, published annually by China Credit Information Service, profiles the largest 250 Taiwan-based business groups in terms of total assets. This guide identifies family-owned firms and publishes the family trees of the controlling families in the corporate profiles. We identify 98 family firms whose profiles have constantly appeared on Business Groups in Taiwan from 1997 to 2004. Among these firms, we chose IPO firms issued between 1987 and 2004 that have been constantly named as top 250 largest corporations in Taiwan. We are able to obtain the IPO performance data of these 98 family firms from the Securities Data Corporation’s (SDC) Global New Issues database. The corporate governance data is obtained from Taiwan Economic Journal (TEJ). We then match these 98 IPO firms against DataStream by requiring them to have closing stock prices available in DataStream on the fifteenth and thirtieth calendar day after the IPO. Our close examination of the SDC database reveals several data problems. We find errors in IPO issue dates for the majority of our sample. For example, the SDC often mistakenly provides announcement or subscription dates as issue dates. Over 50 percent of IPOs in Taiwan have this problem. To overcome this data problem, we manually cross-reference each of our sample IPOs A detailed discussion of some of the errors in the SDC database can be found on Alexander Ljungqvist’s website at http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~aljungqvist.htm. 5 18 with Bloomberg to identify and correct the erroneous issue dates. Our final sample consists of 84 family IPOs and 84 non-family firms.6 Non-Family Matching Firms We also create a list of 84 non-family Taiwanese firms to test the second hypothesis. Following the process developed by Kim and Ritter (1999) and Purnanandum and Swaminathan (2004), we identify a matching non-family firm for each family firm in our sample that had comparable IPO date, size, and liquidity as IPOs in the most recent fiscal year. Total offer value captures size and cash and equivalent captures liquidity. The first-day IPO market capitalization is not used in matching because it would not be available to an investor or underwriter before the offering date. To choose a particular matching firm, we first explore the Taiwanese IPO data in SDC and stock prices in Datastream. We identify non-family firms sharing the same four-digit SIC code as its family firm counterpart and then shorten the list by excluding firms whose IPO dated three years before or after the IPO date of comparable family firm. Setting a limit to the date of IPO allows us to estimate the IPO performance of non-family firms under similar market conditions. From these firms, REITs, closed-end funds, ADRs, and firms with share prices less than five dollars are excluded. This screening criteria is normally used in the extant IPO literature. Then, we searched for firms whose total offer value is between 75% and 125% of the family IPO’s total offer value. If we have more than one firm left on the list of potential candidates, we choose the one whose cash and equivalents is closest to the family firm in the most recent fiscal year. If there is no qualified candidate, we relax the criteria to widen our search. Each family IPOs gets a unique matching firm that is closet in total offer value and cash & equivalent. 6 Among 84 family IPOs, one of them went public in 1987, 8 in 1991, 9 in 1992, 6 in 1993, 8 in 1994, 10 in 1995, 11 in 1996, 4 in 1997, 6 in 1998, 7 in 1999, 5 in 2000, 4 in 2001, 4 in 2002, and 1 IPO in 2004. 19 Descriptive Statistics Table 1 provides mean and median among all variables for family and non-family IPOs. We also provide p-value of t-statistics (Wilcoxon signed rank test) of mean (median) differences. The results illustrate that the average 15-day returns of family IPOs is 18.94%, which is lower than that of non-family IPOs, 22.35%. Along the same line, the average 30-day return of family IPOs is 25.79%, which is lower than that of non-family firms, 35.85%. The differences in mean and median are significant at 1% level. Family firms have mean (median) % of outside directors as of 40.28% (36.99%). The mean (median) % of family ownership at the IPO is 17.86% (17.43%) and the mean (median) % of family ownership 3 year post-IPO is 13.56% (11.54%). On average, 43% of family firms have potential successor but at the median level, none of them has. The information of family ownership, percentage of outside directors, and potential successor is available only for family firms. Underwriters of family firms are less prestigious and do fewer international deals than those of non-family firms. The mean (median) of underwriter prestige of family firms is 3.42 (3.00) whereas that of non-family firms is 4.29 (4.00). Underwriter reputation is a dummy variable equals to one if underwriters do both international and domestic deals and zero if underwriters do only domestic deals. We apply this measure in the robustness test section. On average, 16% of investment bankers associating with family IPOs do international and domestic deals; whereas, 21% of those partnering with non-family IPOs do both types of deals. In term of offer size, family firms have lower logged proceed than non-family. The mean (median) size of family firms is 16.67 (16.61), which is not significantly different from that of non-family firms, 16.73 for mean and 16.64 for median. Family firms went public when average (median) 40 (41) 20 IPO firms went public, which is about the same as 40 (40) mean (median) of other IPOs that went public at the same time when non-family firms did. In addition, on average 14% of family firms went public during dot-com bubble, which is significantly lower than 38.5% of non-family firms going public during this period. Along the same line, both mean (32%) and median (0%) of non-family firms in our sample are high-tech firms, which is significantly lower than mean (57%) and median (100%) of family firms. Further, family firms are older than non-family firms when they went public. Finally, family firms have significantly lower liquidity with the average of US$ 6.8 million and median of US$1.5 million in cash and equivalents than non-family firms that have the average of US$14.4 million and median of US$2.5 million. Taken together, most of non-family firms in our sample are more high-tech, younger, and more liquid than family firms. *** Insert Table 1 about here *** Table 2 provides Pearson correlation coefficients among variables for family and nonfamily IPOs. The numbers above diagonal are for family firms and those below diagonal are for non-family firms. The results of correlation coefficients do not show a sign of multicollinearity problem. % of outside directors, % of family ownership at IPO, % of family ownership 3 year after IPO, and potential successor dummy are not highly correlated. The second and third variables are not highly correlated because the latter, % of family ownership at 3 year post IPO is measured after the first trading day. IPO volume, underwriter ranking, underwriter reputation, and firm age are positively correlated with 15-day and 30-day returns of non-family firms but negative correlated for family firms. Logged proceed is positively (negatively) correlated with 15-day (30-day) returns of family firms while it is positively correlated with 15-day and 30-day returns of non-family firms. 21 *** Insert Table 2 about here *** Results of Analysis Table 3 illustrates regression results of underpricing on various IPO and family ownership variables. Having outsider on board significantly reduces underpricing for 15-day returns of family firms. The higher the percentage of outside directors, the lower 15-day underpricing supporting our first hypothesis.. In addition, the expected percentage of family ownership 3 year post-IPO is negatively related to 15-day underpricing. IPOs that have high expected family ownership 3 year post-IPO indicate original shareholder’s confidence in the firm. Such confidence lowers the amount of market uncertainty and thus underpricing. This is in contrast to the effect of family ownership at the IPO. The higher the percentage of family ownership at the IPO, the more insider entrenchment increasing information asymmetry and underpricing. This result supports our second hypothesis. Next, the existence of potential successor does not affect the magnitude of family IPO underpricing. Finally, partnering with high-ranked underwriters reduced the extent of underpricing in family IPOs. On the other hand, partnering with highly ranked underwriter significantly increased the underpricing of non-family firms. The difference of underwriter ranking coefficients between family vs. non-family firms is significant at 1 % with p-value of 0.009. This result supports the our last hypothesis in which we predict the underwriter prestige negatively affects underpricing of family firm IPOs. The negative relation between underwriter ranking and underpricing of family firms supports Carter and Manaster (1990)’s and Carter et al. (1998)’s finding positing that underpricing is negatively related to underwriter prestige because 22 prestigious underwriters are more likely to underwrite high quality issues with a lower level of uncertainty. Moreover, prestigious underwriters should provide certification to an issuer; thus lowering the probability of having a lawsuit and decreasing underpricing. On the other hand, the positive relation between underwriter ranking and underpricing of non-family firms is consistent with Cliff and Denis (2004)’s finding of a positive association between underpricing and analyst coverage by prestigious underwriters. For non-family firms, the variation of their underpricing can be explained by high-tech dummy, logged proceeds, firm age and bubble period dummy. Non-family IPOs that are hightech, have small offer size, young, and went public during bubble period are more underpriced than vice versa. These factors do not explain the variation of family firm underpricing and pvalue of the differences in the coefficients of these factors between family vs. non-family firms are significant. Overall, percentage of outside director, percentage of family ownership, and underwriter ranking explain the variation of family firms underpricing. For non-family firms, underwriter ranking has an adverse effect on their underpricing, which is also affected by IPO characteristics. Robustness checks In this section, we perform a battery of sensitivity analyses to check the robustness of our findings and the results are shown in Table 4. First, we apply 30-day underpricing as a dependent variable. The results remains consistent with those in Table 4 supporting our three hypotheses. Potential successor that does not explain the variation of family firms 15-day underpricing explain the variation of 30-day underpricing. Potential successor may want to retain long-term ownership and want to price the offer correctly thus reduces underpricing. Moreover, the presence of successor may reduce uncertainty derived from succession planning. Percentage of outside directors, percentage of family ownership 3-year after IPO, and underwriter ranking negatively affect 30-day underpricing. 23 Second, potential cross-sectional correlation where the error terms of equations (1) and (2) were correlated would lead to an underestimation of the standard errors and an overstatement of the significance of the coefficient estimates. We note that the extant IPO literature treats IPO underpricing levels (i.e., initial returns) across firms as independent observations. Nonetheless, to ensure that our results are not affected by this potential problem, we repeat the regression analysis of equation (1) and (2) using Newey-West heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation corrected standard errors. As shown in column fourth to sixth of Table 4, although the Newey-West standard error is higher (by construction) than the White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard error in Table 3, the results remain intact with those in Table 3. Third, we replace underwriter ranking by underwriter reputation using binary underwriter reputation dummy. We define a high-quality underwriter as one that underwrites both domestic and international IPOs while low-quality underwriters only underwrite domestic IPOs. We argue that underwriters with international exposure have more experience and a better reputation than underwriters who are only domestically active. We find that our results are consistent with those in Table 3. % of outside director, % of family ownership 3-year after IPO, and underwriter ranking have negative coefficients; whereas, percentage of family ownership at the IPO has positive coefficient. The only coefficient in this regression that is different from that in Table 3 is high-tech dummy, which is positively significant for family IPOs. Fourth, we find another set of non-family comparable firms matched by industry, market capitalization, and profit margin. Market capitalization captures size; while, profit margin or profit divided by sales captures profitability. This matching method is consistent with Kim and Ritter (1999) and Purnanandum and Swaminathan (2004), who matched IPO firms by size and profitability. The essence of our findings remains the same with those in Table 3. 24 Finally, to ensure that our results are robust across different time periods, we perform a robustness test in which we divide our IPO sample into two halves, i.e. January 1987 to December 1995 and January 1996 to December 2004, and test whether we have similar findings in each sub-period. Although the magnitude and significance of coefficients in the 1996-2004 regression are lower than those in the 1987-1995 regression, our findings are little affected as our sub-period results are quantitatively and qualitatively consistent with the results for the full sample. How are the Interaction Effects different between Family IPOs vs. Non-family IPOs? In this section, we explore the difference in the interactions effects between family IPOs vs. non-family IPOs. In particular, we focus on the interaction effects of the existence of potential successor, % of family ownership at the IPO, % of family ownership 3 year post IPO, underwriter ranking, age, and high-tech dummy with other variables. We first develop theoretical predictions on how these factors affect the other factors-underpricing relation differently between family and non-family IPOs. To investigate whether the effect of various variables on underpricing varies with each other, we estimate the following regression models: 1. Family IPOs Underpricing k = B 0 +B 1 (% of outside directors) + B 2 (% of outside directors)*Interaction term + B 3 (% of family ownership at IPO) + B 4 (% of family ownership at IPO)*Interaction term + B 5 (% of family ownership 3-yr post-IPO) + B 6 (% of family ownership 3-yr post-IPO)*Interaction term + B 7 (potential 25 successor dummy) +B 8 (potential successor dummy)*Interaction term + B 9 (underwriter’s ranking) + B 10 (underwriter’s ranking)*Interaction term +B 11 (high-tech dummy) + B 12 (high-tech dummy)*Interaction term + B 13 ( IPO volume) + B 14 (log of proceed) + B 15 (firm age) + B 16 (bubble period dummy) + E (3) where interaction term is % of family ownership at IPO, % of family ownership 3-yr postIPO, potential successor dummy, underwriter’s ranking, high-tech dummy, or age. 2. Non-family IPOs Underpricing k = A 0 + A 1 (underwriter’s ranking) + A 2 (underwriter’s ranking) *Interaction term + A 3 (high-tech dummy) + A 4 (high-tech dummy) *Interaction term + A 5 ( IPO volume) + A 6 (log of proceed) + A 7 (firm age) + A 8 (bubble period dummy) + E (4) where interaction term is underwriter’s ranking, high-tech dummy, or age. The regression results for equations (3) and (4) are summarized in Table 5. Several findings emerge. First, although the existence of a potential successor alone is not adequate to affect underpricing, its interaction with % of outside directors, % of family ownership 3-year post-IPO, and underwriter ranking empower the negative impacts of these three factors on underpricing. In Model 1, Table 5, the coefficient of % of outside directors changes from -0.118 in Table 3 to -0.489 in Table 5. The coefficient of % of family ownership 3-yr post-IPO changes from -1.473 in Table 3 to -1.991 in Table 5. The coefficients of underwriter ranking alone and of its interaction with potential successor dummy are -2.275 and -2.717, which are significant at 5% and 1%, respectively. This implies that IPOs that have high % of outside directors, % of family ownership 3 year post-IPO, or 26 are associated with prestigious underwriter and have a presence of potential successor are less underpriced than IPOs that have these three factors but do not have a presence of potential successor. A decrease in information asymmetry and uncertain may be a result of a potential successor presence, which reduces succession planning. Second, in contrast to the interaction effects of potential successor, % of family ownership at the IPO does not have any interaction effect. Although IPOs that have high family ownership at the IPOs are more underpriced, having high family ownership at the IPO does not significantly affect a decrease in underpricing from having high % of outside directors, % of family ownership 3-year post-IPO, and high ranked underwriters. The coefficients of % of outside directors, % of family ownership 3-year after IPO, and underwriter ranking remain significantly negative but their interactions with % of family ownership at the IPO are insignificant. This implies a good signal from a decrease in information asymmetry from having high % of outside directors and family ownership 3-year post-IPO overpowers a bad signal of management entrenchment from having high % family ownership at the IPO. Third, similar to the effect of % of family ownership at the IPO, % of family ownership 3-year post-IPO does not interact with % of outside directors and % of family ownership at the IPO significantly enough to have any effect on underpricing. However, IPOs that have high % family ownership 3-year post-IPO and that are partnering with prestigious investment banks have significantly lower underpricing than such IPOs associated with less prestigious investment bankers. The coefficients of % family ownership 3-year post-IPO*underwriter ranking are -4.139 and -1.755 in Model (3) and (4), respectively and they are significant at 1%. Prestigious underwriter really strengthens a decrease in underpricing from having high % of family ownership 3-year post-IPO. This indicates the important role of high ranked underwriters in helping family firms reduce underpricing. 27 Fourth, being high-tech reduces a decrease in underpricing from having high % of outside directors, % of family ownership 3-yr post-IPO, and high ranked underwriter. In Model 6, Table 4, family column, the coefficient of these interaction terms are 0.225, 0.811, and 1.276 and they are significant at 5%, 5%, and 10%, respectively. That means high-tech IPOs have the coefficients of % of outside directors, % of family ownership, and underwriter ranking equal to -2.286 (from 2.511+0.225), -4.805 (from -5.616+0.811), and -0.663 (from-1.939+1.276). These coefficients remain negative but the magnitude is less than that of non-tech IPOs. Therefore, family IPOs that have high % of outside directors and expected family ownership 3 year post IPO, and are partnering with prestigious underwriters do not benefit much from reduced underpricing if they are high-tech. On the other hand, high-tech IPOs that have high IPO ownership at the IPO are more underpriced than high-tech IPOs that have low ownership but the difference is not significant. In contrast to family firms that prestigious underwriters help reduce the magnitude of underpricing, the prestige of underpricing increases underpricing of non-family firms. The underwriter’s role for nonfamily firms is consistent with Cliff and Denis (2004), who find that a positive association between underpricing and analyst coverage by prestigious underwriters and Beatty and Welch (1996), who observe the relationship between underwriter prestige and underpricing switching from negative to positive during the 1990s. Beatty and Welch (1996) and Cliff and Denis (2004) explain prestigious underwriters take higher quality firms public, thus the presence of prestigious underwriters is positively related to IPO underpricing. In contrast, the underwriter’s role for family firms can be explained by Carter and Manaster (1990) and Carter et al. (1998) positing that underpricing is negatively related to underwriter prestige because prestigious underwriters are more likely to underwrite high quality issues with a lower level of uncertainty. Moreover, prestigious underwriters should provide certification to an issuer; thus lowering the probability of having a lawsuit and decreasing underpricing. Being high-tech weakens the negative impact of underwriter’s prestige on 28 underpricing of family firms whereas it strengthens the positive impact of underwriter’s prestige on underpricing of non-family firms. Lastly, there is no interaction effect of age and other variables on underpricing. The signs and significance of other coefficients remain intact with those in Table 3. Taken together, the presence of potential successor helps family firms that have high % of outside directors and % of family ownership 3-year post IPO reduce the magnitude of underpricing. In contrast, being high-tech counteracts family firms’ benefits of reduced underpricing from having high % of outside directors and % of family ownership 3-year post IPO, and partnering with high ranked underwriter. Being high-tech hurts non-family firms as it increases positive impact of high ranked investment bankers on underpricing. DISCUSSION The central message of our research is that adoption of monitoring mechanisms and family owner commitment signal investors about the quality of an IPO firm thus decrease the underpricing family firm IPO. This finding is in agreement with recent studies on the impact of corporate governance practices on family business performances (Schulze, Lubatkin, Dino, & Buchholtz, 2001; Andersen & Reeb, 2004; Andersen, Mansi, & Reeb, 2004). In addition, we identify two notable uniqueness of family firms. First, outside directors who are not owners or employees of a firm play a major role in the reduction of IPO underpricing. When we specifically test the impact of non-family director appointment on family firm IPO performance, the results suggest that the appointment of non-family directors, not necessarily non-employee, significantly reduce underpricing in family IPOs. This result implies that family firms may avoid engaging in time consuming and sometimes expensive search process to find and hire director candidates who are not currently on the payroll of the company. The second uniqueness is that 29 teaming up with prestigious underwriters significantly reduces underpricing. Surprisingly, this effect is opposite in non-family firm IPOs. This result suggests that the beneficiaries of underwriter prestige are unique to the family firms. Non-family firms partnering with prestigious underwriter for lower IPO underpricing may be sacrificing bargaining power against their underwriters for little gains. Although the impact of external environment has been well studied by strategic management and family business researchers in the past, family business literature has been more inclined to focus on intrinsic uniqueness such as how a family firm react to external challenges. However it is not unusual that the label of family-owned business invokes distinctive perceptions for external stakeholders. Based on a survey of family and non-family managers in family firms, Poza, Alfred, & Maheshwari (1997) report that these two groups demonstrate different perceptions about the managerial practices, cultures, and succession processes. The results of our analysis show that investors react to IPO signals differently when evaluating family firm IPO deals. It would be helpful for future researchers to identify more sources of such extrinsic uniqueness and the impact of these extrinsic factors on the strategy formulation and implementation of family firms. The results of such research would highlight when and how family and non-family firms adopt different strategies to address competitive challenges. The findings of these studies would also help family firm managers develop effective strategies. Our research also contributes to an on-going debate of IPO underpricing research. Several earlier studies find that underwriter reputation tends to reduce underpricing (Carter and Manaster, 1990; Carter, Dark and Singh, 1998). In contrast, studies based on more recent years find a significant positive association between underwriter reputation and IPO underpricing (Cliff and Denis, 2004; Loughran and Ritter, 2004). Current explanations for such shift put 30 strong emphasis on the role of underwriters. For example, Cliff and Denis (2004) argue that underpricing is used by issuers to compensate prestigious investment banks for expected postIPO research coverage from highly ranked analysts. In addition, Loughran and Ritter (2004) propose a spinning explanation of underpricing which suggest issuers’ intent to allocate hot IPOs to “friends and family” and other insiders in recent years creates strong incentives for issuers to seek underwriters with a reputation for severe underpricing. Our analysis presents an investorside explanation. Researchers are likely to observe a negative correlation between underwriter prestige and underpricing if there is a surge of family firm IPO during the time span of observation. On the other hand, the observed relationship between underwriter prestige and underpricing may not be much less profound when few family firms go IPO during the period of observation. Historical research reports that legal environments have profound impact on the ownership structure of family firms in France, Spain, and U.K. (Colli, Fernandez Perez, & Rose, 2003). Changes in wealth transfer regulation often motivate incumbent family business owners to take necessarily measures, including offering stocks to the public, to retain desirable level of family wealth. Further investigation is needed to link the shift of prestige-underpricing relationship to the prevalence of family firms in an IPO market. The practical implication of our research is that the conventional wisdom of signaling still holds. Practices to improve quality of corporate governance and owner commitment help investors to better evaluate the quality of the IPO deal. Similarly, family business owners and institutional shareholders such as venture capitalists can minimize underpricing by adopting the corporate governance practices we suggested in this paper, non-family directors, prestigious underwriter, and long-term share holding. 31 CONCLUSION IPO has become an important measure to sustain long-term growth of family firms. Signaling help prospective investors of family firm IPOs to better evaluate the value of the firm. The findings from this study indicate that the appointment of non-family outside directors, use of prestigious underwriters, and expected long-term share holding are viewed by the investors as positive signals thus reduce the extent of underpricing. Our study also suggests that investors’ perception toward family firms and non-family firms are different. Further research on the sources of effects of family firm extrinsic uniqueness would enhance our understandings in family firm strategy and the impact of underwriter prestige on IPO underpricing. REFERENCES Anderson, R., Mansi, S., & Reeb. 2004. Board Characteristics, Accounting Report Integrity, and the Cost of Debt. Journal of Accounting and Economics. Anderson, R. 2004. Board Composition: Balancing Family Influence in S&P 500 Firms. Administrative Science Quarterly. Ainsworth, S., & Cox, J.W. 2003. Families divided: culture and control in small family business. Organization Studies, 24: 1463-1485. Allen, F., & Faulhaber, G. 1989. Signaling by underpricing in the IPO market, Journal of Financial Economics, 23: 303–323. Alvesson, M., & Lindkvist, L. 1993. Transaction costs, clans and corporate culture. Journal of Management Studies, 30: 427-452. Anderson, R., & Reeb, D. 2003. Founding family ownership and firm performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. Journal of Finance, 58: 1301-1328. 32 Astrachan, J.H., & McConaughy, D.L. 2001. Venture capitalists and close held IPOs: Lessons for family-controlled firms. Family Business Review, 14: 295-312. Barnett, M.L. 1960. Kinship as a factor affecting Cantonese economic adaptation in the United States. Human Organization, 19, 45: Beatty, R., & Ritter, J. 1986. Investment banking, reputation, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 213-232. Beatty, R., Welch, I., 1996. Issuer expenses and legal liability in initial public offerings. Journal of Law and Economics, 39: 545-602. Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. 2006. The role of family in family firms. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20: 73-96. Brockhaus Sr., R.H. 1994. Entrepreneurship and family business research: comparison, critique, and lessons. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 19: 25-38. Burkart, M., Panunzi, F., & Shleifer, A. 2003. Family firms. Journal of Finance, 58: 2167-2202. Carter, R., & Manaster, S. 1990. Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. Journal of Finance, 45: 1045-1067. Carter, R., Dark, F., & Singh, A. 1998. Underwriter reputation, initial returns and long run performance of IPO stocks. Journal of Finance, 53: 285-311. Certo, S.T., Covin, J.G., Daily, C.M., & Dalton, D.R. 2001. Wealth and the effects of founder management among IPO-stage new ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 641658. Chemmanur, T., He, S., & Nandy, D. 2006. The going public decision and the product market: Empirical evidence. Working paper, Boston College Carroll School of Management, Chestnut Hill, MA. 33 Chen, H.C., Fok, R.C.W., & Wang, Y.J. 2006. Why do underwriters charge low underwriting fees for initial public offerings in Taiwan? Journal of Business & Accounting, 33: 9791005. Cliff, M., & Denis, D. 2004. Do initial public offering firms purchase analyst coverage with underpricing? Journal of Finance, 59: 2871-2901. Chrisman, J.J., Chua, J.H., & Sharma, P. 1998. Important attributes of successors in family businesses: an exploratory study. Family Business Review, 11: 19-34. Clarkson, P. M., Dontoh, A., Richardson, G., & Sefcik S.E. 1991. Retained ownership and the valuation of IPOs: Canadian evidence. Contemporary Accounting Research, 8: 115–131. Colli, A., Fernandez Perez, P. & Rose, M. B. 2003. National determinants of family enterprise development? Family enterprises in Britain, Spain, and Italy in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries. Enterprise & Society 4(1): 28. Craig, D., & Dibrell, C. 2006. The natural environment, innovation, and firm performance: a comparative study. Family Business Review, 19: 275-288. Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., & Subrahmanyam, A. 1998. Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. Journal of Finance, 53: 1839-1885. Davis, P.S., & Harveston, P.D. 1998. The influence of family on the family business succession process: a multi-generational perspective. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 22(3): 31-53. Derrien, F. 2005. IPO pricing in “hot” market conditions: who leaves money on the table? Journal of Finance, 60: 487-521. 34 Downes, D. H., and Heinkel, R. 1982. Signaling and the valuation of unseasoned new issues. Journal of Finance, 37: 1–10. Filatotchev, I., & Bishop, K. 2002. Board composition, share ownership, and ‘underpricing’ of U.K. IPO firms. Strategic Management Journal, 23: 941-955. Grinblatt, M., & Hwang, C.Y. 1989. Signaling and the pricing of unseasoned new issues, Journal of Finance, 44: 393–420. Habib, M.A., & Ljungqvist, A. P. 2001. Underpricing and entrepreneurial wealth loss in IPOs: theory and evidence. Review of Financial Studies, 14: 433-458. Hansen, G.S., & Hill, C.W.L. 1991. Are institutional investors myopic? A time-series study of four technology-driven industries. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 1-16. How, J., & Low, J.G. 1993. Fractional ownership and underpricing: signals of firm value. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 1: 47–65. Hsu, Y., & Hung, C. 2005. Why have IPO auctions lest market share to fixed-price offers? Evidence from Taiwan. Working paper, National Chengchi University Taipei, Taiwan. Ibbotson, R., & Jaffe, J. 1975. “Hot Issue” Markets. Journal of Finance, 30: 1027-1042. Jaskiewicz, P., Gonzalez, V.M., Menendez, S., & Schiereck, D. 2005. Long-run IPO performance analysis of German and Spanish family-owned business. Family Business Review, 18: 179-202. Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W.H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360. Kim, M., & Ritter, J. 1999. Valuing IPOs. Journal of Financial Economics, 53: 409-437. Lee, P.M. 1997. A comparative analysis of layoff announcements and stock price reactions in the United States and Japan. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 879-894. 35 Lee, P.M. 2001. What’s in a name.com?: The effects of ‘.com’ name changes on stock prices and trading activity. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 793-804. Lee, K.S., Lim, G.H., & Lim, W.S. 2003. Family business succession: appropriation risk and choice of successor. Academy of Management Review, 28: 657-666. Leland, H., & Pyle, D.H. 1977. Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32: 371–387. Lin, J., Lee, Y., & Liu, Y. 2003. Why have auctions been losing market shares to bookbuilding in IPO markets? Working paper, Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, LA. Litz, R.A. 1995. The family business: toward definitional clarity. Family Business Review, 8: 71-81. Ljungqvist, A., Jenkinson, T., & Wilhelm, W. 2003. Global integration in primary equity markets: The role of U.S. banks and U.S. investors. Review of Financial Studies, 16: 6399. Ljungqvist, A. 2006. IPO Underpricing: A Survey. In E. Eckbo (Ed.), Handbook in corporate finance: empirical corporate finance. Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. 2002. Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table in IPOs? Review of Financial Studies, 15: 414-443. Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. 2004. Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Financial Management, 33: 5-37. Loughran, T., Ritter, J., & Rydqvist, K. 1994. Initial public offerings: International insights. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2: 165-199. Lowry, M., & Schwert, W. 2002. IPO market cycles: Bubbles or sequential learning? Journal of Finance, 57: 1171-1200. 36 Lowry, M., & Shu, S., 2002. Litigation risk and IPO underpricing. Journal of Financial Economics, 65: 309- 336. Megginson, W., & Weiss, K. 1991. Venture capitalist certification in initial public offerings. Journal of Finance, 46: 879-903. Morck, R., & Yeung, B. 2003. Agency problems in large family business groups. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 27: 367-382 Nanda, V., & Yun, Y. 1997. Reputation and financial intermediation: An empirical investigation of the impact of IPO mispricing on underwriter market value. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 6: 39-63. Odean, T. 1998. Are investors reluctant to realize their losses? Journal of Finance, 53: 17751798. Oxfeld, E. 1993. Blood, sweat, and mahjong: Family and enterprise in an overseas Chinese community. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Purnanandam, A., & Swaminathan, B. 2004. Are IPOs really underpriced? Review of Financial Studies, 17, 811-848. Pagano, M., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. 1998. Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance, 53:27-64. Poza, E. J., Alfred, T., & Maheshwari, A. 1997. Stakeholder Perceptions of Culture and Management Practices in Family and Family Firms - A Preliminary Report . Family Business Review, 10, 135–155. Ram, M., & Holiday, R. 1993. Relative merits: family culture and kinship in small firms. Sociology, 27: 629-648. Ritter, J. 1984. The “Hot Issue” Market of 1980. Journal of Business, 57: 215-240. 37 Ritter, J. 1991. The long-run performance of initial public offerings. Journal of Finance, 46: 327/ Ritter, J. 2003. Differences between European and American IPO markets. European Financial Management, 9: 421-434. Ritter, J., & Welch, I. 2002. A review of IPO activity, pricing, and allocations. Journal of Finance, 57, 1795:1828. Rock, K. 1986. Why new issues are underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 187-212. Rose, M. B. 2000. Firms, Networks, and Business Values: The British and American Cotton Industries since 1750. Cambridge, U.K. Sharmar, P., & Irving, P.G. 2005. Four bases of family business successor commitment: antecedents and consequences. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 29: 13-33. Sharma, P., & Rao, A. S. 2000. Successor attributes in Indian and Canadian family firms: a comparative study. Family Business Review, 13: 313-330. Sherman, A., 2005. Global trends in IPO methods: book-building vs. auctions. Journal of Financial Economics, 78: 615-649. Tiniç, S., 1988. Anatomy of initial public offerings of common stock. Journal of Finance, 43: 789-822. Tsui-Auch, LS., & Lee, Y. 2003. The state matters: management models of Singaporean Chinese and Korean business groups. Organization Studies, 24: 507-534. Villalonga, B., & Amit, R. 2006. How do family ownership, control, and management affect firm value? Journal of Financial Economics, 80: 385-417. Welch, I. 1989. Seasoned offerings, imitation costs and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Finance, 44: 421–449. 38 Zahra, S.A., Hayton, J.C., & Salvato, C. 2004. Entrepreneurship in family vs. non-family firms: a resource-based analysis of the effect of organizational culture. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 28: 363-381. 39 Appendix: Variable before the IPO Definitions Panel A: Independent Variables Variables Source TEJ % of outside directors % of family ownership at IPO % of family ownership 3-year postIPO Underwriter ranking Underwriter reputation TEJ Percentage of total shares owned by members of a family before the first trading day TEJ Percentage of total shares owned by members of a family 36 months after the first trading day SDC SDC Loughran and Ritter (2004)’s adjusted Carter-Manaster underwriter reputation ranking A dummy variable equal to one if the lead underwriter underwrites both domestic and international IPOs and zero if it underwrites only domestic IPOs Panel B: IPO Variables Variables Source Underpricing (15 days) SDC TEJ Potential successor dummy IPO volume SDC High- tech dummy Log of proceeds Firm age Bubble period dummy Cash and equivalents Definition Percentage of number of non-family outside directions by total number of directors SDC SDC SDC and prospectus SDC and prospectus Definition 100[(closing price 15 days after the IPO date - offer price)/offer price] Coded 1 if at least one family member from the younger generation or a founder’s sibling is placed in the corporate board or is a member of top management team. The total number of domestic IPOs issued over the 12-month period ending in the month in which the IPO was issued A dummy variable equal to one if the IPO is high-tech and zero if it is non high-tech. Hightech firms are identified following the classification methods in Loughran and Ritter (2004) and Cliff and Denis (2004). The money raised, after fees and expenses or shares offered in IPO multiplied by offer price after fees and expenses, ($ millions) Number of years the firm was founded before the IPO A dummy variable equal to one if the IPO went public in 1999 or 2000 and zero for otherwise. The amount of cash and equivalents in the most recent fiscal year before firm going public 40 Table 1: Descriptive Statistics of IPO Underpricing There are 84 family and 84 non-family Taiwanese IPOs from January 1, 1987 through December 31, 2004. The matching firm is a non-family firm that was in the same industry, went public within three years of the family IPO and had comparable total offer value and cash & equivalents in its most recent fiscal year. All variables are described in the Appendix. White’s heteroskedasticity-adjusted t-statistic provides a test for the difference in means and the Wilcoxon Signed Rank test provides a test for the difference in medians. . Family-controlled IPOs Variables 30-day returns (%) 15-day returns (%) % of outside directors % of family ownership at IPO % of family ownership 3-year post-IPO Potential successor dummy (%) Underwriter ranking Underwriter reputation Log of proceeds IPO volume Bubble period dummy (%) High-tech dummy (%) Firm age (years) Cash and equivalent (thousand US$) Number of IPOs Non-family controlled IPOs Mean Median Mean Median 25.79 18.94 40.28 17.86 18.61 8.15 36.99 17.43 35.85 22.35 NA NA 22.48 13.56 NA NA 13.56 11.54 NA NA 42.86 4.29 16.11 16.67 40.39 14.29 0.32 28.29 6,824.68 84 0.00 4.00 0.00 16.61 41.00 0.00 0.00 27.00 1,485.60 NA 3.42 21.11 16.73 40.38 38.46 0.57 17.96 14,447.91 84 NA 3.00 0.00 16.64 40.00 0.00 1.00 17.50 2,480.50 Difference T-stat (P-value) WilcoxonTest (P-value) 0.007 0.003 0.005 0.002 0.003 0.009 0.212 0.351 0.076 0.019 0.095 0.158 0.002 0.117 0.439 0.217 0.115 0.001 0.078 0.246 41 Table 2: Correlation Coefficients of Family and Non-Family Controlled IPOs There are 84 family and 84 non-family IPOs from January 1, 1987 through December 31, 2004. The non-family IPOs are matching firms that was in the same industry, went public within three years of the family’s IPO date, had comparable log of proceeds and cash and equivalent in its most recent fiscal year. Descriptions of all variables are in the Appendix. Pearson correlation coefficients for family (non-family) IPOs are reported above (below) the diagonal. P-value for t-test significance of each correlation coefficient is reported under each correlation coefficient. Variables 30-day returns (%) 30-day returns (%) 15-day returns (%) % of outside directors % of family ownership at IPO % of family ownership 3-year post IPO Potential successor dummy (%) Underwriter ranking Underwriter reputation IPO Volume High-tech dummy (%) Log of proceeds Firm age (years) Bubble period dummy (%) 15-day returns (%) % of outside directors 0.926 0.000 0.058 0.598 0.020 0.857 0.963 0.000 % of family ownership at IPO -0.010 0.930 -0.088 0.428 -0.081 0.464 % of family ownership 3-year post IPO -0.113 0.306 -0.154 0.163 -0.102 0.355 0.283 0.000 Potential successor dummy (%) Underwriter ranking Underwriter reputation IPO Volume Hightech dummy (%) Log of proceeds Firm age (years) Bubble period dummy (%) -0.115 0.298 -0.185 0.092 0.050 0.651 0.117 0.289 0.071 -0.011 0.920 -0.032 0.771 0.074 0.505 -0.110 0.318 -0.076 -0.026 0.877 -0.024 0.889 -0.176 0.298 0.132 0.437 0.184 -0.084 0.448 -0.182 0.097 -0.016 0.888 0.182 0.098 0.115 0.052 0.641 0.148 0.180 -0.170 0.122 -0.053 0.635 -0.066 -0.053 0.632 0.033 0.765 0.054 0.625 0.071 0.522 0.150 -0.052 0.637 -0.066 0.553 0.250 0.022 -0.031 0.777 -0.023 0.094 0.397 0.114 0.301 -0.166 0.131 -0.067 0.544 -0.040 0.519 0.495 0.275 0.299 0.549 0.175 0.835 0.721 0.026 0.817 -0.079 0.644 0.212 0.207 0.137 0.215 0.055 0.619 -0.173 0.115 0.125 0.257 0.062 0.578 -0.119 0.281 0.099 0.369 0.147 0.181 -0.147 0.181 -0.113 0.307 0.219 -0.123 0.184 -0.283 -0.040 0.434 0.662 -0.021 0.847 0.511 -0.063 0.566 -0.040 0.721 0.307 -0.041 0.708 -0.372 0.001 0.170 0.121 0.887 -0.203 0.064 0.133 0.228 0.029 0.790 -0.186 0.091 0.504 0.010 0.447 0.025 0.296 0.342 0.332 0.284 0.057 0.786 0.207 0.321 0.545 0.005 0.365 0.073 -0.442 0.027 0.212 0.066 0.755 0.254 0.221 0.594 0.002 0.296 0.151 -0.415 0.039 0.227 -0.092 0.661 0.202 0.332 0.262 0.206 0.170 0.417 -0.344 0.092 -0.013 0.939 0.085 0.618 0.239 0.155 -0.233 0.164 0.228 0.176 0.067 0.750 0.363 0.074 -0.264 0.203 -0.384 0.058 0.426 0.034 -0.290 0.160 -0.068 0.747 -0.001 0.995 -0.513 0.009 -0.157 0.453 42 Table 3 Determinants of IPO Underpricing This table presents regressions of 15-day underpricing of 84 family and non-family IPOs that was in the same industry, went public from January 1, 1987 to December 31, 2004. The non-family IPOs are matching firms that went public within three years of the family’s IPO date, had comparable log of proceeds and cash and equivalent in its most recent fiscal year. Descriptions of all variables are in the Appendix. White’s heteroscedasticity-adjusted t-statistic is shown under each coefficient. P (Diff) is the p-value from a t-test for the difference between corresponding coefficients of family and nonfamily firms. *** Indicates statistical significance at the 1% level. ** Indicates statistical significance at the 5% level. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10% level. Explanatory Variable Constant % of outside directors % of family ownership at the IPO % of family ownership from IPO date to 3rd year after the IPO Potential successor dummy Underwriter ranking IPO volume High-tech dummy Log of proceeds Firm age Bubble period dummy Adjusted R-squared 15-day Underpricing Family Non-family P(Diff) 32.487 0.389 -1.578*** -2.804 3.595*** 2.985 -3.252** -2.007 -1.188 -1.164 -2.792** -2.394 -87.547** -2.490 0.017 4.890** 2.167 0.009 -0.393 -0.910 2.272 0.549 1.116 1.420 1.209 1.346 2.340 0.478 15.82% -2.249 -0.312 3.311*** 3.391 -8.412** -2.224 -2.606** -2.411 4.511** 2.308 34.86% 0.315 0.003 0.026 0.001 0.017 43 Table 4 Robustness Tests of Various Variables on IPO Underpricing This table presents regressions of 15-day underpricing of 84 family and non-family IPOs that went public from January 1, 1987 to December 31, 2004. The non-family IPOs are matching firms that was in the same industry, went public within three years of the family’s IPO date, had comparable log of proceeds and cash and equivalent in its most recent fiscal year. Descriptions of all variables are in the Appendix. White’s heteroskedasticity-adjusted t-statistic is shown under each coefficient. P (Diff) is the p-value from a t-test for the difference between corresponding coefficients of family and non-family firms. *** Indicates statistical significance at the 1% level. ** Indicates statistical significance at the 5% level. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10%. Independent Variables Constant % of outside directors % of family ownership at the IPO % of family ownership from IPO date to 3rd year after the IPO Potential successor dummy 30-day underpricing as a dependent variable Newey West standard errors Underwriter reputation dummy as underwriter ranking Family Nonfamily P (Diff) Family Nonfamily P (Diff) Family Nonfamily P (Diff) 19.0874 -75.041** 0.021 32.487 -87.547** 0.019 24.585 -78.252** 0.023 1.273 -2.355 1.471 -2.340 1.264 -2.190 Non-family IPOs matched by Industry, market capitalization, and profit margin NonP Family (Diff) family 34.631 0.015 83.474*** 0.551 -2.844 1.004*** -3.728 Include only 1987-1995 Family Nonfamily P (Diff) F 21.849 -70.946** 0.028 3 1.330 -2.063 -1.118*** -1.578** -1.248*** -2.835 -2.725 -3.135 2.873** 3.595*** 6.009** 2.427** 6.663** 2.586 2.795 2.683 2.404 2.566 -3.473*** -2.879 -3.252* -1.914 -3.115*** -3.078 -2.685** -2.082 -3.031*** -3.359 0 -0.946** -1. -2.381 -2 3. 2 -2. -2 -2.909* -1.188 -0.308 -1.457 -1.949 -1.342 -1.572 -1.195 2.194*** -3.689 8.001*** -0.394 0.315 -0.671 0.307 0.364 1.168*** Underwriter ranking -3.155*** 2.318*** -3.111 2.768 IPO volume -2.572 0.576 -1.665 0.083 High-tech dummy 2.605 1.994** 0.735 2.416 Log of proceeds 1.644 -6.631** 0.667 -2.065 0.008 0.337 0.003 0.030 -2.792** 4.890** -2.063 2.670 -0.393 2.249 -0.790 0.264 2.272 3.311*** 0.619 4.061 1.116 -8.412* 1.128 -1.779 0.010 0.285 0.003 0.03 -3.858*** 1.984** -3.833 2.512 -0.648 0.871 -1.643 0.074 2.207* 1.468*** 1.904 3.012 1.668 -5.545* 0.534 -1.931 0.009 0.399 0.003 0.028 <0.0 01 3.266 0.526 3.851 0.981 -7.998 0.877 -1.671 0.349 0.003 0.034 -2.328 -0 -1.363 -1 -4.314*** 2.215 -3.382 1.402 -2.301 0.614 -1.454 0.056 1.764 1.642** 0.770 2.742 1.529 -4.729 0.609 -1.601 44 0.011 -3 -1 0.429 -0 -0 0.003 2 0.03 -1 1 -1 Firm age Bubble period dummy Adjusted Rsquared -2.399** -2.207* -2.243 -1.962 5.082 2.855*** 0.304 16.49% 0.001 1.209 -2.606** 1.026 -2.718 2.340 4.510** 3.476 0.439 38.12% 15.82% 0.017 0.001 -2.822* -2.873** -1.745 -2.138 3.911 2.990*** 2.562 0.365 34.50% 16.00% 0.02 0.001 1.478 -1.339** 1.332 -2.236 4.907 4.002*** 3.715 0.519 34.81% 19.98% 0.021 0.001 -3.177 -2.499** -1.729 -2.045 1.368 2.243*** 2.960 0.452 3.074 2 30.25% 19.99% 43.16% 15 0.024 45 0.001 1 1 0.019 2. Table 5 Interaction Effect of Various Variables on IPO Underpricing This table presents regressions of 15-day underpricing of 84 family and non-family IPOs that was in the same industry, went public from January 1, 1987 to December 31, 2004. The non-family IPOs are matching firms that went public within three years of the family’s IPO date, had comparable log of proceeds and cash and equivalent in its most recent fiscal year. Descriptions of all variables are in the Appendix. White’s heteroskedasticity-adjusted t-statistic is shown under each coefficient. P (Diff) is the p-value from a t-test for the difference between corresponding coefficients of family and non-family firms. *** Indicates statistical significance at the 1% level. ** Indicates statistical significance at the 5% level. * Indicates statistical significance at the 10%. Interaction terms Potential successor At IPO ownership Model specification (1) (2) Family ownership 3 yr post IPO (3) Independent variables Family Family Family Family Constant 64.027** -36.895** 4.698 -39.791* -34.156 2.151 2.067 -1.038 -2.598** 1.106 -2.381** -3.401*** 1.407 -2.116 -3.520 -1.864 2.511*** -2.836 -0.489*** 0.223 -0.063 -2.765 1.106 5.474*** 3.028 % of outside directors % of outside directors*interaction term % of family ownership at the IPO High-tech dummy (5) Nonfamily Age (5) Nonfamily P(Diff) Family 0.005 68.258 -84.086 1.519 -1.349 Underwriter ranking P(Diff) Family 0.006 83.470* -2.537 1.769 0.903*** -2.926 0.225** -0.026 0.336 -0.732 2.417 -0.624 1.262 2.574** 4.987** 4.339** 6.442*** 3.257*** 2.200 2.279 2.684 3.559 3.261 -3.014** % of family ownership at the IPO *interaction term 2.462 -0.266 0.454 0.181 -0.013 1.294 -0.309 0.212 -0.114 % of family ownership from IPO to 3 yr post IPO 1.816 -3.478** -2.005 -2.555*** 0.333 0.531 -2.726 -2.420 1.678 5.616*** -2.901 -3.070 % of family ownership from IPO to 3 yr post IPO * interaction term -1.991** 0.055 0.811** 0.192 -2.135 0.076 2.305 0.506 1.630 1.755*** -3.051 Potential successor dummy 2.134 -11.729 -0.014 -2.706 -1.568* -2.027 0.336 -1.352 -1.399 -1.186 -1.776 -0.144 Potential successor dummy * 0.339 -0.717 -0.811 -0.257 -1.065 interaction term 0.611 -0.898 -1.193 -1.183 -0.710 (4) Nonfamily 50.156** -2.598 P(Diff) 0.043 46 Underwriter ranking Underwriter ranking * interaction term High-tech dummy High-tech dummy * interaction term IPO volume -2.275** -3.138*** -2.526** -1.939** 1.106* -2.096 -3.039 -2.473 -2.152 1.910 -2.717*** -1.010 -0.115 1.276* 0.642** -3.235 -0.066 -0.662 1.928 2.563 9.888*** 5.345*** 0.792 2.968** 1.199** 3.623 3.280 0.847 2.180 2.230 -1.055 0.073 -0.402 2.536 -2.682** 7.042*** -2.406 3.928 -0.082 0.885 -0.640 1.276 15.559*** 1.766*** 3.110 -4.139*** 0.094 -3.888 1.588 5.665* 2.167 1.199** 1.381 1.615 1.827 1.652 2.230 Log of proceeds 3.597 -2.506** -3.896* -3.585 -6.495** 1.607 -2.594 -1.937 -0.860 -2.378 Firm age -3.048** -2.079* 0.544 -2.661 -3.937 -2.116 -1.802 0.391 -1.428 -1.599 1.229 5.454 5.729 5.563 0.163 0.360 1.315 1.324 1.302 0.177 13.42% 12.23% 12.92% 21.84% 32.54% Bubble period dummy Adjusted R-squared <0.001 0.025 0.003 0.061 0.042 0.207 0.159 <0.001 20.610** -2.150 3.106** 2.617 0.238 7.896*** 0.962*** 2.292 2.866 3.288 -0.569 0.081 -0.928 0.094 -0.213 0.119 -1.380 0.563 4.842** 0.125 0.047 2.419 0.199 1.153 0.230 0.011 -1.941** -5.495** 2.346 0.167 1.517 -4.945** 1.101 -2.587 0.821 -4.823* 0.532 -1.976 11.609 -18.716 0.387 -0.936 26.40% 43.09% 0.002 0.002 0.082 0.093 -2.515 -2.378 -0.270 -2.937** -0.702 -2.599 1.971 3.163** 0.244 2.177 13.01% 32.54% 0.012 0.164 0.059 0.008 0.052 0.046 47 48