CREDIT CARDS AND BANKRUPTCY TODD J. ZYWICKI Professor of Law, George Mason University School of Law Research Fellow, James Buchanan Center for Political Economy Abstract: From 1980 to 2005 consumer bankruptcy filings increased five-fold. Conventional wisdom holds that a primary cause of rising bankruptcy filing rates was increased household financial distress caused by increased indebtedness caused in turn by increased credit card borrowing. In 2005, Congress enacted the bipartisan Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act (BAPCPA). The legislation was enacted in response to twenty-five years of rising bankruptcy filings and a perception of widespread fraud and abuse that threatened the fairness and integrity of the system. BAPCPA marked the most profound and far-reaching overhaul of America’s bankruptcy system in over a generation. In the two years since BAPCPA’s enactment, bankruptcy filings have plunged. From over 2 million filings in 2005, filings plummeted to less than 600,000 in 2006 and 800,000 in 2007. Critics of the legislation argue that the drop in filings will be temporary, as the legislation does not address what they believe to be the underlying cause of the rise in bankruptcy filings in the 1980s and 1990s—excessive consumer debt caused by profligate lending by credit card issuers especially to risky borrowers. This article reviews three hypotheses about the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy: the substitution model, the “distress” or “overindebtedness model,” and the “strategic model” and concludes that the conventional wisdom is flawed. A review of empirical evidence and available data indicates that in fact the growth in credit card lending has not led to an increase in the consumer debt service ratio or financial distress more generally, suggesting that the rise in credit card borrowing has been primarily a substitution from other traditional types of consumer credit, such as retail store credit, personal finance companies, friends and family, pawnbrokers, and other types of consumer credit. The article then briefly examines the substitution hypothesis in more depth, describing how a substitution to credit card debt can bring about a rise in consumer bankruptcy filings even holding overall consumer debt obligations constant. Finally, the article examines the rationale and effects of the credit card provisions of BAPCPA for the substitution and distress models. To date, the response of consumers to BAPCPA has been consistent with the substitution model, suggesting that with respect to addressing particular problems regarding the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy BAPCPA has been accomplishing its stated purposes. 1 Credit Cards and Bankruptcy By Todd J. Zywicki* From 1980 to 2005 consumer bankruptcy filings increased five-fold. Conventional wisdom holds that a primary cause of rising bankruptcy filing rates was increased household financial distress caused by increased indebtedness caused in turn by increased credit card borrowing. In 2005, Congress enacted the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act (BAPCPA) by overwhelming bipartisan majorities in both houses of Congress.1 The legislation was enacted in response to twenty-five years of rising bankruptcy filings and a perception of widespread fraud and abuse that threatened the fairness and integrity of the system. BAPCPA marked the most profound and far-reaching overhaul of America’s bankruptcy system in over a generation. In the two years since BAPCPA’s enactment, bankruptcy filings have plunged. From over 2 million filings in 2005, filings plummeted to less than 600,000 in 2006 and 800,000 in 2007. Despite the overwhelming bipartisan support for the legislation in Congress and its apparent success in accomplishing its intended goals, BAPCPA has been criticized by many bankruptcy scholars and professionals. They argue that the rising trend in bankruptcy filings in the 1980s and 1990s was a manifestation of widespread consumer distress caused by excessive household debt obligations.2 Although multipronged, a core * Professor of Law, George Mason University School of Law; Research Fellow, James Buchanan Center for the Study of Political Economy. I would like to thank Josh Wright for extremely helpful comments on earlier drafts of this article as well as workshop participants at Duke, George Mason University, Georgetown, and Vanderbilt law schools. I would like to thank the Law & Economics Center at George Mason University School of Law for financial support for this project. 1 The vote in the United States Senate was 74 in favor and 25 opposed, with 1 abstention. The vote in the House was 302 in favor and 126 opposed with 7 abstentions. 2 See Michelle J. White, Bankruptcy Reform and Credit Cards, 21 J. ECON. PERSPECTIVES 175 (2007) ; TERESA A. SULLIVAN ET AL., THE FRAGILE MIDDLE CLASS: AMERICANS IN DEBT (2000); Elizabeth Warren, 2 element of the argument is that this economic distress was triggered by more widespread access to credit cards by higher-risk borrowers over the past three decades. Typically it is argued that credit cards combine high rates of interest with an “insidious” form of gradual and subconscious debt accumulation through many routine purchases that draw consumers into debt unconsciously3 or that credit card issuers prey on consumers’ cognitive biases and errors to trick them into excessive debt.4 Both credit card use and bankruptcies have increased dramatically over the past several decades, and this rise in credit card use and bankruptcy appear to be correlated— at least prior to BAPCPA.5 The raw numbers appear staggering at first glance. Consumers charge over 1 trillion dollars per year on their credit cards and revolve over $600 billion in credit card debt from month to month.6 Seventy-five percent of American households have some sort of credit card, compared to seven percent in the 1960s.7 Credit cards have transformed the way we live, shop, and travel. The ubiquity and importance of credit cards to the modern economy is summed up in the observation of economist Lewis Mandell that credit cards “have become an essential element of daily The Bankruptcy Crisis, 73 IND. L.J. 1079, 1082 (1998); RONALD J. MANN, CHARGING AHEAD: THE GROWTH AND REGULATION OF PAYMENT CARD MARKETS 35-72 (2006). 3 See SULLIVAN ET AL., supra note 2, at 108-40; Juliet B. Schor, Who’s Going Bankrupt and Why?, 79 TEX. L. REV. 1235, 1238 (2001). 4 See Lawrence M. Ausubel, The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market, 81 AM. ECON. REV. 50, 71 (1991); Oren Bar-Gill, Seduction by Plastic, 98 NW. U. L. REV. 1373 (2004). 5 See discussion infra at notes 110-111 and accompanying text. High levels of credit card use have continued post-BAPCPA even as the number of bankruptcy filings has fallen by half. 6 See BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM, REPORT TO THE CONGRESS ON PRACTICES OF THE CONSUMER CREDIT INDUSTRY IN SOLICITING AND EXTENDING CREDIT AND THEIR EFFECTS ON CONSUMER DEBT AND INSOLVENCY 7 (June 2006) (herinafter FED REPORT). 7 See FED REPORT, supra note, at 6. Seventy-one percent of families today have a bank-type card. “Banktype” card is used in this article to refer to general purpose payment cards such as Visa, Mastercard, American Express, or Discover. 3 life. With a credit card, you can buy yourself a new car. Without it, you cannot even rent one.”8 But with credit cards has come a chorus of critics who argue that this growth in credit card ownership has come with an excessive social cost—too many consumers overburdened by debt and an annual bankruptcy filing rate that quintupled between 1980 and 2005. Much of the blame for this skyrocketing bankruptcy filing rate is laid at the door of credit card issuers who, it is said, have extended credit in a profligate manner to unworthy borrowers and have lured borrowers into financial misery with easy credit, high interest rates, and an array of hidden fees. This article reviews the various theories that have been offered to explain the correlation between credit cards and bankruptcy. Conventional wisdom holds that the causal link is obvious: that the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy is obvious—that the rise in credit card use has produced a generation of overburdened consumers driven into bankruptcy by profligate and abusive lending by credit card issuers. This article tests the conventional wisdom and finds it wanting. In particular, data indicate that credit cards have not in fact led to an increase in household economic distress for a simple and, upon reflection, obvious reason: The growth in credit card borrowing has been a substitution from other traditional types of consumer credit, such as pawnshops, personal finance companies, retail store credit, department store credit cards and gasoline cards, layaway plans, and other similar products. Moreover, this substitution has been driven by rational consumer demand. Credit cards offer lower interest rates, better terms, ancillary benefits, and move flexibility than any other type of consumer credit. Although this substitution has also had the unintended consequence of 8 LEWIS MANDELL, THE CREDIT CARD INDUSTRY: A HISTORY at p. xi (1990). 4 increasing bankruptcy filings, it has on the whole been a great boon to consumers and the economy and it would be unwise to try to reverse it. Although total household has increased, steady economic growth, record household wealth accumulation, declining interest rates, and the substitution of high-interest consumer debt with lower-interest debt has dramatically increased household living standards while leaving their debt service burden largely unchanged for over twenty-five years. This article examines competing hypotheses regarding the possible link between credit cards and bankruptcy. After a brief background on the history of consumer credit in America and the rise of credit cards within this story, the article turns toward a detailed exploration of the competing hypotheses. After establishing the primacy of the substitution effect with respect to credit card credit, the article explores possible causal explanations for how a simple change in the composition of household credit holdings could lead to increased bankruptcies without an increase in the household debt burden. Finally, the article turns to the effect of BAPCPA on credit card debt to date and the implications for the future. I. “Charge It”: A Brief History of Credit Cards in America Although credit cards are a relatively new financial innovation, the use of credit is as old as human society and even predates money itself.9 And as old as credit is the reality that some borrowers will be unable to repay all that they borrow and that many others will engage in hand-wringing about others’ excessive borrowing.10 Lendol Calder refers to this as the “myth of lost financial virtue”—the belief that “earlier generations” 9 SIDNEY HOMER & RICHARD SYLLA, A HISTORY OF INTEREST RATES 3 (3d ed. 1991); Marion Benfield, Money, Mortgages, and Migraine–The Usury Headache, 19 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 819, 822 (1968) 10 See infra notes 29-36 and accompanying text. 5 were thriftier than the “current generation,” a refrain repeated steadily by almost every generation since at least mid-nineteenth century America.11 In fact, credit cards have spawned simply the latest expression of concern about consumer overindebtedness and reckless lending that has recurred repeatedly in American history. A. Consumer Credit in Early America In pre-Civil War America, most Americans were farmers, living outside major population centers. Gold and silver coins were scarce. Personal credit, however, was not, and farmers relied on credit to smooth investment and consumption across the crop harvesting season. Credit was as important as the Conestoga Wagon in conquering the west.12 In the decades following the Civil War, a tide of immigrants swept into America, building the great cities. Most urban dwellers were unskilled blue-collar workers with unpredictable employment and income, thus the consumer credit industry emerged to cope with seasonal fluctuations in employment. The emerging American middle class became homeowners and home furnishers through mortgages and consumer installment credit. Overall, late nineteenth-century households sought financial assistance from five major credit sources: pawnbrokers, illegal small-loan lenders, retailers, friends and family, and mortgage lenders.13 In post-Civil War New York City, for instance, twothirds of the city’s total consumer lending came from small-loan agencies, including loan 11 LENDOL CALDER, FINANCING THE AMERICAN DREAM: A CULTURAL HISTORY OF CONSUMER CREDIT 22 (1999). 12 LEWIS MANDELL, THE CREDIT CARD INDUSTRY: A HISTORY at xii (1990). 13 CALDER, supra note 11, at 38. 6 sharks and forerunners to today’s and “payday” or “wage assignment” lenders.14 Pawn shops proliferated—in some neighborhoods virtually the entire population had a pawn ticket at all times and as many as twelve in the winter when factories typically closed down.15 These various unlicensed lenders charged interest rates that approach 300 percent annually and resorted to embarrassing and aggressive collection practices to enforce repayment of these illegal debts.16 Counterproductive usury regulations made operations unprofitable for legitimate lenders thereby driving many urban consumers into the hands of illegal lenders.17 It was estimated in 1911 that 35 percent of New York City’s employees owed money to illegal loan sharks. 18 Reviewing the credit market of this era, former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan has described the plight of lower-income wage earners subject to aggressive and overreaching creditors as one of “virtual serfdom.”19 Consumer credit expanded following World War I. Credit unions, small local savings banks, and a national network of licensed consumer finance companies such as the Beneficial Industrial Loan Corporation and the Household Finance Corporation, provided consumer loans.20 These were installment loans (often referred to as buying on 14 CALDER, supra note 11, at 49-50. CALDER, supra note 11, at 44-48. 16 See CALDER, supra note 11, at 48-54. Interest rates on these loans were comparable to modern payday lenders. 17 Alan Greenspan, Remarks, Economic Development Conference of the Greenlining Institute (Oct. 11, 1997), available in http://www.federalreserve.gov/BoardDocs/Speeches/1997/19971011.htm (hereinafter Greenspan, Greenlining Remarks). 18 CALDER, supra note 11, at 118. 19 Greenspan, Greenlining Remarks, supra note 17. 20 Greenspan, Greenlining Remarks, supra note 17; Tom Brown & Lacey Plache, Paying with Plastic: Maybe Not So Crazy, 73 U. CHICAGO L. REV. 63, 72 (2006). 15 7 “time”) meaning that the consumer borrowed a fixed sum (plus interest) with an obligation to repay the loan over a fixed period in equal installments.21 Beginning with Singer sewing machines, installment credit soon spread to furniture, pianos, and household appliances, and finally automobiles.22 By the 1930s, the majority of sales of household furniture, appliances, radios, cameras, and jewelry were credit sales, as were a substantial percentage of rugs, hardware, sporting goods, and books (such as encyclopedia and other book sets).23 Financing these purchases through credit made it possible to acquire and use the goods immediately, rather than having to save for long periods of time to afford them. Between 1900 and 1939, total consumer nonmortgage installment debt quadrupled in real dollars, increasing 2-1/2 times during the decade of the 1920 alone. Martha Olney refers to this unprecedented twin boom in the purchase of consumer durables and consumer credit the “consumer durables revolution.”24 David Caplovitz’s study of low-income households, published in 1963, found that retailers of consumer durables made on average 75 to 90 percent of their sales on installment credit.25 Two-thirds of families who relocated into public housing projects in the 1960s purchased their new furniture and major appliances on credit.26 Caplovtiz also found that more than 70 percent of households used credit to purchase a television set and that lower and higher-income families were just as likely to use credit to do so.27 21 For example, in a typical installment credit arrangement the debtor may finance a new dining room set through the furniture store by borrowing $5000 at 8% interest (which may be imputed in the purchase price rather than explicitly stated) repayable over 60 months in equal payments of $101.38, with the loan secured by a purchase money security interest in the dining room set itself. 22 MARTHA L. OLNEY, BUY NOW, PAY LATER: ADVERTISING, CREDIT, AND CONSUMER DURABLES IN THE 1920S at p. 85 (1991); MANDELL, supra note 12, at xii. 23 OLNEY, supra note 22, at 100-01 Table 4.4. 24 See OLNEY, supra note 22, at 87-89. 25 DAVID CAPLOVITZ, THE POOR PAY MORE: CONSUMER PRACTICES OF LOW-INCOME FAMILIES 16 (1963). 26 CAPLOVITZ, supra note, at 96. 27 Id. at 88. 8 Overall, Caplovitz found that 81 percent of low-income families in his study made use of some sort of credit (including installment loans, revolving credit for clothing, buying from peddlers, or outstanding personal loans), and that 60 percent had consumer debts at the time of his interview with them.28 The expressions of concern heard today about credit cards were presaged in similar paternalistic comments about the spread of installment credit.29 Installment selling was criticized for allegedly inducing overconsumption by American shoppers, especially supposedly vulnerable groups such as “the poor, the immigrant, and the allegedly math-impaired female.”30 Rapacious installment sellers were accused of extending credit to unworthy borrowers, leading them to purchase unnecessary products and generating debts beyond their means to repay.31 Department stores were criticized for “actively goad[ing] people into contracting more debt.”32 In 1873 the New York Times expressed concern that Americans were “Running in Debt” and by 1877 warned that Americans were “Borrowing Trouble.”33 In 1873 a labor leader bemoaned the improvidence of America’s consumers, “Has not the middle class its poverty? Very few among them are saving money. Many of them are in debt; and all they can earn for years, is, in many cases, mortgaged to pay such debt.”34 An 1899 report concluded that installment selling “‘lured thousands to ruin’ encouraging people to buy what they could not pay for and making debt ‘the curse of countless families.’”35 28 CAPLOVITZ, supra note, at 101. CALDER, supra note 11, at 211. 30 CALDER, supra note 11, at 166. 31 See CALDER, supra note 11, at 182. 32 CALDER, supra note 11, at 217. 33 Quoted in DAVID S. EVANS AND RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC: THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING 101 (2d ed. 2005). 34 CALDER, supra note 11, at 59 (quoting Ira Steward). 35 CALDER, supra note 11, at 213. 29 9 And not merely the poor and improvident were lured into ruin, but upstanding middle class families as well, as they engaged in a heated rivalry of conspicuous consumption with their neighbors.36 In 1949 Business Week asked, “Is the Country Swamped with Debt?” and by 1959 U.S. News and World Report worried that “Never Have So Many Owed So Much.” In 1940 Harper’s even feared that “Debt Threatens Democracy.”37 The criticisms of mid-century installment credit mirrored those of credit cards today: easy access to installment credit allegedly generated overconsumption, overindebtedness, and finally bankruptcy. Credit customers bought more goods than cash customers38 and retailers were criticized for enabling shoppers to buy more on credit than they normally would on cash.39 Installment selling was considered a “menace” that trapped Americans in “a morass of debt” and was the “first step toward national bankruptcy,” a further overture to today’s criticisms of credit cards.40 “The youngest families,” Caplovitz writes, “Are apt to turn to stores for installment credit; as their debts mount and the payments become increasingly more difficult to meet, they are apt to obtain loans to pay off their other debts. In this way they obtain relief in the form of smaller monthly payments at the cost of a longer period of indebtedness.”41 Moreover, although most Americans believed that installment selling was a “good idea” in general CALDER, supra note 11, at 215. The term “conspicuous consumption” was coined over a century ago. See THORSTEIN VEBLEN, THE THEORY OF THE LEISURE CLASS: AN ECONOMIC STUDY OF INSTITUTIONS (1899). Veblen argues that one effect of conspicuous consumption is a tendency for households to reduce savings and to rely on debt to live beyond their means. 37 Quoted in EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 101. 38 CALDER, supra note 11, at 200. 39 CALDER, supra note 11, at 220; compare MANN, supra note. Caplovitz notes that consumers tended to pay a higher prices for televisions when purchasing on credit than on cash. CAPLOVITZ, supra note, at 88. 40 CALDER, supra note 11, at 221. The use of debt to purchase consumption goods such as food was thought to be especially irresponsible. CALDER, supra note 11, at 225. 41 CAPLOVITZ, supra note, at 100. 36 10 and were confident in their own ability to use it responsibly, three out of four also thought that their neighbors used installment credit excessively42—a judgment mirrored in modern surveys of consumers about credit card use, in which most consumers assert confidence in their own ability to use credit cards responsibly but express concern about the ability of others to do the same.43 And as consumer bankruptcy filings rose during the 1960s, some commentators and politicians pointed the finger of blame at profligate installment lending.44 These criticisms of installment credit provide ironic reading today in light of the modern claim that the ubiquity of credit cards—which have come to displace installment credit for many consumer transactions—allegedly has produced a psychology of consumer overconsumption.45 B. Early Credit Cards Credit cards were born in the early twentieth century with the introduction of the first “charge plates” or “charga-plates,” the forerunners of the modern credit card.46 “Open book” credit accounts were long a staple of retailers, especially for the purchase of nondurables such as groceries, and charge plates formalized those practices. In the postWorld War II era, prototype credit cards emerged, aimed at traveling businessmen, such as gasoline, hotel, and airline cards.47 42 CALDER, supra note 11, at 235. Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Cards: Use and Consumer Attitudes, 1970–2000, 86 FED. RES. BULL. 623,628-30 (2000). 44 See Wage Earner Plans Under the Bankruptcy Act: Hearing on H.R. 1057 and H.R. 5771 Before the House Committee on the Judiciary, 90th Cong. (1967). 45 See, e.g., MANN, supra note 2, at 46; Richard L. Wiener, et al., Consumer Credit Card Use: The Roles of Creditor Disclosure and Anticipated Emotion, 13 J. EXPERIMENTAL PSYCHOLOGY: APPLIED 32 (2007). 46 CALDER, supra note 11, at 72. 47 MANDELL, supra note 12, at xii. Greenspan reports that hotels began using credit cards as early as 1900 and gasoline cards and large retail department stores were issuing credit cards by 1914. Greenspan, Greenlining Remarks, supra note 17. 43 11 The formation of Diners Club in 1949 laid the foundation for modern bank cards. Diners Club was a universal card, in that it was a payment mechanism honored by many merchants, unlike earlier cards tied to specific retailers of goods and services. It was also a third-party card, in that Diners Club extended the credit to the customer and paid the merchant, rather than the merchant issuing the credit directly. Diners Club thus was the bearer of the risk of nonpayment rather than the restaurant. In return for this assured payment and the convenience to customers of being able to use Diners Club at a large number of locations, accepting merchants paid a 7% fee to Diners Club for each use. But universal third-party cards were slow to take off. The consumer credit market remained dominated by retail store credit cards through the 1970s. This continued domination by retail issuers was primarily because of the presence of usury restrictions that restricted certain types of consumer lending during this period. Usury regulations generally produce three types of unintended consequences. First, they encourage lenders to “reprice” other terms of their credit contracts in order to try to offset the inability to charge market rates of interest, such as by requiring larger downpayments, higher upfront fixed fees or annual fees, shorter grace periods, or a myriad of other terms. Second, usury regulations lead to product substitution, such as by debtors unable to acquire unsecured credit card credit to switch to less-preferred types of credit, such as pawn shops or payday lenders. Third, to the extent that it is impossible to fully reprice terms or substitute to alternative lenders, the end result will be credit rationing, as some borrowers may be unable to get any legal credit on any terms. All three phenomena appear to have resulted from the usury regulations imposed in the 1970s. 12 Credit issuers repriced other terms to evade usury regulations, but retailers were able to do this more effectively than banks. A rapid rise in underlying interest rates in the 1970s combined with usury caps made credit card operations for banks unprofitable during this period, thus bank-type credit card operations remained modest in scope.48 Banks were able to avoid some of the restrictions by altering other terms of the cardholder agreement or bundling lending with other services. Banks in states with strict usury regulations restricted their hours of operation, reduced customer service, tied their lending operations to other products and services not restricted in price (such as requiring checking or savings accounts), or imposing higher service charges on demand deposit accounts or checking account overdrafts.49 Most importantly, to evade usury regulations credit card issuers imposed annual fees on credit cards, usually ranging from $30-$50.50 Credit card issuers adjusted other terms of the credit contract to compensate for the inability to charge a market rate of interest, including adjusting grace periods and using alternate methods for calculating interest charges.51 Credit card issuers also rationed credit card privileges to only the most credit worthy consumers.52 48 Todd J. Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, 3 CHAPMAN L. REV. 79, 151-55 (2000). A. CHARLENE SULLIVAN, EVIDENCE OF THE EFFECT OF RESTRICTIVE LOAN RATE CEILINGS ON PRICES OF FINANCIAL SERVICES (Credit Research Center Working Paper No 36, 1980); see also RICHARD PETERSON & GREGORY A. FALLS, IMPACT OF A TEN PERCENT USURY CEILING: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE 33 (Credit Research Center Working Paper No. 40, 1981). 50 See Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 152. Because this fee was assessed on revolvers and transactors alike, it effectively resulted in transactors subsidizing lower interest rates for revolvers. 51 DAVID EVANS & RICHARD SCHMALENSEE, PAYING WITH PLASTIC: THE DIGITAL REVOLUTION IN BUYING AND BORROWING 28 (1st ed. 2000); OLNEY, supra note 22, at 132 (“State usury laws were ineffective; lenders managed to increase effective rates of interest through various fees, penalties, required insurance, and so on.”). 52 Glenn B. Canner & James T. Fergus, The Economic Effects of Proposed Ceilings on Credit Card Interest Rates, 73 FED. RES. BULL. 1, 2 (1987). 49 13 Consumers who were unable to get a general-purpose bankcard instead continued to rely on retail store cards.53 Revolving credit was used primarily for non-durable consumer purchases, such as clothing, groceries, and milk54 Credit-issuing department stores had an even more effective way of evading usury restrictions—they could simply bury the credit losses in the price of the goods they offered and sell the bundled product.55 The main purpose of department store credit operations was ancillary to retail operations, such as to build customer loyalty and making shopping more convenient.56 Retailers were willing to and usually did absorb losses in their credit operations, so long as they furthered these larger goals.57 Cross-subsidization of retail operations by credit operations by increasing the price of the goods to evade usury restrictions on credit was an easy step. This provided large retailers with a substantial comparative advantage over smaller retailers who could not afford to establish and maintain their own credit operations.58 Although usury regulations thus capped interest rates, they did not prevent consumers from having to pay high total prices for credit or dramatically reduce access to credit. Instead, usury regulations transferred wealth from credit issuers who had less ability to evade usury restrictions (such as small retailers) to issuers (like department stores) who could evade usury restrictions more easily, such as those who could more 53 PETERSON & FALLS, supra note 49. CAPLOVITZ, supra note, at 99. 55 See HOMER & SYLLA, supra note 9, at 428; see also CALDER, supra note 11, at 177 (noting practice of door-to-door peddlers in early-twentieth century America who catered to immigrant families and marked up the price of the goods sold to cover implied high interest rates). Similarly, pawn shops can simply adjust the discount price of the goods that are pawned as collateral. 56 MANDELL, supra note 12, at xviii. 57 MANDELL, supra note 12, at xviii; Canner & Fergus, supra note 52, at 2 (“The studies indicated that on average—not considering profits on associated merchandise sales—such credit card plans consistently operated at a loss.”) 58 Christopher C. DeMuth, The Case Against Credit Card Interest Rate Regulation, 3 YALE J. ON REG. 201, 238 (1986). 54 14 effectively conceal the real cost of credit in the price of the goods and from higher-risk to lower-risk borrowers.59 For instance, in those states with the strictest usury restrictions, consumers also paid significantly higher prices for major appliances, almost all of which were purchased with installment retail credit.60 Retailers in states with strict usury regulations also reduced their services to consumers, such as charging for delivery and gift wrapping or offering fewer choices in their stores.61 C. Credit Cards Today In 1978 the Supreme Court decided Marquette National Bank v. First of Omaha Corp., which effectively deregulated interest rates on credit cards by holding that the applicable interest rates for nationally-chartered banks would be the home state of the issuing bank, rather than the consumer.62 The results have been dramatic. In 1970, only 16% of American households had a general-purpose bank-type card; today 71% do. Ownership of retail store cards initially rose as well through the 1970s, increasing from 45% of households in 1971 to 58% in 1983. This growth reflects the comparative advantage of retail stores during the high-interest rate 1970s in repricing credit terms to evade usury caps. Ownership of retail store cards peaked in 1989 at 61% and has declined steadily since then, reaching 44% by 2004. Ownership of specific use credit 59 See DeMuth, supra note 58, at 238; Daniel J. Villegas, The Impact of Usury Ceilings on Consumer Credit, 56 S. ECON. J. 126, 140 (1989); William J. Boyes, In Defense of the Downtrodden: Usury Laws?, 39 PUBLIC CHOICE 269, 272 (1982). 60 Canner & Fergus, supra note 52, at 11. 61 Peterson & Falls, supra note 49, at 35 n.5. 62 439 U.S. 299 (1978). 15 cards, such as gasoline and travel and entertainment cards, have shown similar declines in popularity over this period as they have been supplanted by general use bank cards.63 By effectively eliminating usury regulations, Marquette eliminated the incentives to engage in term repricing. Beginning in the early 1990s, credit cards eliminated annual fees on standard cards making pricing more efficient, more consumer-friendly, and enabling consumers to hold multiple cards simultaneously which spurred heated competition that has led to lower interest rates, the general elimination of annual fees, and a proliferation of card benefits. In 1971, households were almost three times as likely to own a retail store card as a bank-type card; today, that ratio is almost reversed and many households hold multiple cards.64 The rapid growth in popularity of general purpose credit cards following deregulation should not be surprising. Consumers historically had to choose among a limited number of consumer credit alternatives: family and friends, high-interest payday lenders or check cashers, pawnshops, personal finance companies, rent-to-own retailers, or illegal loan sharks.65 All of these types of credit have obvious and significant 63 See Brian K. Bucks, Arthur B. Kennickell, and Kevin B. Moore, Recent Changes in U.S. Family Finances: Evidence from the 2001 and 2004 Survey of Consumer Finances, FED. RES. BULLETIN at p. A31 (2006) (noting that in 2004 95% of credit card holders have bank-type credit cards, while the percentage of those holding store, gasoline, or travel and entertainment cards have fallen); Kenneth A. Carow & Michael E. Staten, Plastic Choices: Consumer Usage of Bank Cards Versus Proprietary Credit Cards, 26(2) J. ECON. & FIN. 216 (Summer 2002); Kenneth A. Carow & Michael E. Staten, Debit, Credit, or Cash: Survey Evidence on Gasoline Purchases, 51 J. ECON. AND BUS. 409 (1999); see also Ana M. Aizcorbe et al., Recent Changes in U.S. Family Finances: Evidence from the 1998 and 2001 Survey of Consumer Finances, 89 FED. RES. BULL. 1, 25 (2003) (noting 5.2% increase in percentage of families with bank cards, and 4.8% reduction in percentage with store cards and 3.1% decrease in percentage of households with gasoline cards over three year period). 64 See Durkin, Credit Cards, supra note 43, at 624. The average American household holds over four credit cards, which includes store and other cards as well as bank-type cards. See FED. RES. BD., THE PROFITABILITY OF CREDIT CARD OPERATIONS OF DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS 5 (June 1999). 65 Empirical evidence suggests that stricter regulation of consumer credit (and thus reduced access to legal sources of consumer credit) is correlated with higher levels of illegal borrowing. See POLICIS, THE EFFECT OF INTEREST RATE CONTROLS IN OTHER COUNTRIES (2004); POLICIS, ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL RISKS OF CONSUMER CREDIT MARKET REGULATION (2006). 16 drawbacks associated with them when compared to credit cards. Examining the alternatives available to consumers indicates why consumers have so readily substituted toward credit cards. The primary source of short-term credit for lower-income Americans through history has been friends and family.66 A recent survey of households in low and moderate-income areas of Los Angeles, Chicago, and Washington found that 53 percent of respondents said they would rely on friends or family to borrow $500 for three months.67 Angela Littwin’s survey of credit use by low-income women found that 93% had actually borrowed money from friends and family in the past and many had lent money to friends and family as well.68 Ten percent of her subjects have borrowed only from friends and family.69 But friends and family may not be able or willing to lend when needed or in the amounts needed—a reality reinforced by the fact that most social networks are limited in scope, and so most of the friends and family of low-income individuals are also low-income and thus have limited funds to lend. Payday lenders charge annual interest rates as high as 300 percent and generally require that the borrower have a bank account, which many low-income households do not.70 Payday loan customers are low to middle-income, relatively young, and less likely 66 CALDER, supra note 11, at 60-64. ELLEN SIEDMAN, MOEZ HABABOU, AND JENNIFER KRAMER, A FINANCIAL SERVICES SURVEY OF LOWAND MODERATE-INCOME HOUSEHOLDS (2005). 68 Angela Littwin, Beyond Usury: A Study of Credit Card Use and Preference Among Low-Income Consumers, at 8. 69 Littwin, Comparing Credit Cards, supra note, at 36. 70 LENDOL CALDER, FINANCING THE AMERICAN DREAM; JOHN P. CASKEY, FRINGE BANKING: CHECKCASHING OUTLETS, PAWNSHOPS, AND THE POOR 37-67 (1994); Gregory Elliehausen, Consumers’ Use of High-Price Credit Products: Do They Know What They are Doing? Networks Financial Institute at Indiana State University Working Paper 2006-WP-02 (May 2006); see also Ronald J. Mann & Jim Hawkins, Just Until Payday (working paper, Aug. 2, 2006). It should be noted that even this high rate of interest on a payday loan may be lower than the implied APR for the fees imposed for a bounced check, which may be the alternative to a payday advance loan. Se Michael W. Lynch, Legal Loan Sharking or Essential 67 17 to own a home than the average American family.71 Payday loan customers generally are aware of the prices charged on payday loans, but use payday lenders either to avoid more expensive problems, such as bounced check fees (which can amount to $50 or more when the fees of the merchant and bank are combined) or because of an absence of attractive alternatives, such as credit cards.72 For instance, over half of payday loan customers who have bank cards had refrained from using them in the past year because they would have exceeded their credit limit.73 The behavior of payday loan customers suggests that they are concerned about access to credit and fear being rejected by other lenders.74 Those who use payday lenders report a relatively high level of satisfaction with the service.75 Despite the seemingly high cost of payday loans there is no indication that payday lenders are earning economic profits off their activities once risk is taken into account.76 In fact, increased competition among payday lenders in a given market tends to reduce Service? The Great “Payday Loan” Controversy, REASON (2002); Michael S. Barr, Banking the Poor, 21 YALE J. ON REG. 121, 155 (2004). 71 Barr, supra note 70, at 153. 72 See Donald Morgan and M. Strain, Payday Holiday: How Households Fare after Payday Credit Bans, FED. RES. BANK OF N.Y., Staff Report no. 309 (Nov. 2007); Gregory Elliehausen & Edward C. Lawrence, Payday Advance Credit in America: An Analysis of Customer Demand, GEORGETOWN UNIVERSITY, MCDONOUGH SCHOOL OF BUSINESS, CREDIT RESEARCH CENTER (April 2001). 73 Elliehausen & Lawrence, supra note 72; see also Angela Littwin, Comparing Credit Cards: An Empirical Examination of Borrowing Preferences Among Low-Income Consumers (working paper); available in http://ssrn.com/abstract=1014460 (citing Michael S. Barr, et al., Consumer Indebtedness in the Alternative Financial Services Market U. Mich. Law, Working Paper, April 2007) (noting that payday loan users use credit cards at same rate as others but were more likely to pay only minimum balance on credit cards and to have paid late fees). 74 See Paige Marta Skiba & Jeremy Tobacman, Measuring the Individual-Level Effects of Access to Credit: Evidence from Payday Loans, Working Paper (July 3, 2007). Half of pawnshop borrowers had been rejected for credit in the past year, 73% of payday advance customers and 46.5 percent of refund anticipation loan customers were turned down or limited in the past five years. Almost half of payday loan customers and three-fourths of refund loan customers said that during the past year they thought about applying for credit but did not because they thought that they would be turned down. Elliehausen, supra note 70, at 21. 75 Elliehausen & Lawrence, supra note 72. 76 See Paige Skiba & Jeremy Tobacman, The Profitability of Payday Loans, Working Paper (Dec. 7, 2006). 18 the price of payday loans77 and payday loans appear can serve an important role in improving consumer welfare and quality of life78. Pawnbrokers require parting with personal items, a hardship in itself, exacerbated by the fact that those goods often possess little economic value, thus the value received is less than the replacement cost of the goods.79 Pawn loans are also expensive, with interest rates of over 200 percent per year.80 Default rates are high.81 In addition, because the value of the loan is limited by the value of the personal goods pawned, pawn loans tend to be quite small ($76 on average).82 Jewelry and consumer electronics are the goods most frequently pawned.83 Those who borrow from pawnbrokers do so because they generally do not own homes (thus home equity loans are not available) and have limited alternative sources of borrowing, which primarily include friends or checkcashers.84 In particular, pawn shop borrowers typically have been turned down for a 77 Donald P. Morgan, Defining and Detecting Predatory Lending, FEDERAL BANK OF NEW YORK STAFF REPORTS, Staff Report No. 273 (January 2007); see also Philip Bond, David K. Musto, & Bilge Yilmaz, Predatory Lending in a Rational World, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper 06-2 (Nov. 2006). 78 Adair Morse, Payday Lenders: Heroes or Villains?, Working Paper (Nov. 20, 2006). Morse finds that access to payday lending improves welfare across numerous quality-of-life margins, including health outcomes, reduced crime, and other variables. See also Dean Karlan & Jonathan Zinman, Expanding Credit Access: Using Randomized Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts (working paper, June 25, 2007) (finding in study of South African consumers that access to high-cost credit provided significant benefits for borrowers across a wide range of economic and “well-being” outcomes, such as higher-quality diet, improved physical well-being, and more stable employment). 79 CALDER, supra note 11. 80 JOHN P. CASKEY, FRINGE BANKING: CHECK-CASHING OUTLETS, PAWN SHOPS AND THE POOR 36 (1994). Skiba and Tobacman find that pawn loans have a ninety-day term, with a monthly interest rate of 20 percent on loans from $1-$150 and 15 percent on loans above $150. Skiba & Tobacman, Measuring, supra note 74. 81 Skiba & Tobacman, Measuring, supra note. 82 Skiba & Tobacman, Measuring, supra note; see also Robert W. Johnson & Dixie P. Johnson, Pawnbroking in the U.S.: A Profile of Customers 16 (Credit Research Ctr., Monograph No. 34, 1998) (average loan of $70 with typical range from $35-$260); CASKEY, supra note, at 44 (finding average pawnshop loan of $50-$70). The average payday loan, by contrast, is $300. Skiba & Tobacman, Measuring, supra note. 83 CASKEY, supra note, at 37. 84 See PETERSON & FALLS, supra note 49; see also Robert W. Johnson & Dixie P. Johnson, Pawnbroking in the U.S.: A Profile of Customers 47 (Credit Research Ctr., Monograph No. 34, 1998) (finding that 65.4% of Americans own their homes, but only 34.6% of those who borrow from pawnshops do so). This absence 19 payday loan, making pawnbrokers a lender of last resort for many. 85 Today, the basic pawn shop model has been expanded to include automobile title lenders, which operate similarly to traditional pawn shops.86 Some department stores and retailers of goods such as furniture, appliances, hardware, lumber, and jewelry, continue to be a source of credit for the purchase of their goods. These transactions often have high imputed interest rate (often reflected in a higher price for the goods purchased than would otherwise be the case) and, typically, the consumer must give a purchase-money security interest in the goods purchased, permitting their repossession in the event of default. A modern and highly-popular form of retail credit among low-income consumers is mail-order catalogue shopping, most notably Fingerhut, which sells a wide variety of household goods on credit.87 Fingerhut’s prices appear to be much higher than the price for similar goods at traditional retailers.88 Reliance on retail store credit limits consumers’ shopping choices by limiting them to those sellers who will also offer them credit, restricting choice and price competition for goods and services.89 Historically, a popular variation for those unable to get store credit was layaway.90 General bank-type credit cards enable the retail transaction be unhooked from the credit transaction, thereby facilitating competition in both markets and of home ownership has a secondary consequence, in that it leads renters to change addresses more often, which counts as a negative factor in some credit scoring models. Id. 85 Skiba & Tobacman, Measuring, supra note 74. Morgan quotes a CEO of a major pawnshop chain who states that the rise of payday lending has hurt his company. Morgan, Defining & Detecting, supra note, at 5-6. 86 See Barr, supra note 70, at 164-66. 87 See Littwin, Comparing Credit Cards, supra note, at 41-42. Fingerhut’s customer base has an average household income below $30,000 and sells almost exclusively on credit, especially to those who have difficulty obtaining credit elsewhere. Id. 88 Littwin, Comparing Credit Cards, supra note, at 56. 89 Consider, for instance, the ubiquitous used car dealerships that offer credit to those with “bad credit”: the purchase price of the car usually imputes a very high interest rate into the sales price of the car. 90 Under layaway, the consumer did not obtain possession of the item until it was fully paid for. Layaway has been largely discontinued today. 20 permitting a better match of consumer preferences, such as with on-line or catalogue shopping. Rent-to-own is another alternative.91 Instead of structuring a transaction as a secured transaction, rent-to-own transactions are leases with an option to buy at the end. The interest rate is imputed into the lease payment and the overall prices of the goods is typically 2 to 2.5 times what one would pay in a retail store.92 Styled as a lease rather than a secured transaction, foreclosure is easier upon default. In fact, rent-to own may be the true “lender” of last resort (leaving aside illegal loan sharks), as the idea was originally introduced by a retail appliance store owner for those customers who were denied credit for appliance purchases.93 This is still the case today, as rent-to-own arrangements continue to be used primarily by low-income consumers, who are unable to get other forms of credit at comparably better terms (if at all).94 Rent-to-own customers are also lower-income, younger, and less likely to be homeowners than others.95 91 See Jim Hawkins, Renting the Good Life, University of Texas School of Law, Law and Economics Research Paper No. 111. A survey of rent-to-own customers found that that 67% of rent-to-own customers intended to purchase the merchandise when they began a rent-to-own transaction and 87 percent of those intending to purchase actually did, suggesting that many consumers use rent-to-own as an alternative to secured sale. FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION BUREAU OF ECONOMICS STAFF REPORT, SURVEY OF RENT-TOOWN CUSTOMERS (2000). Seventy-five percent of rent-to-own customers reported being satisfied with their experience with rent-to-own transactions. Id. 92 Signe-Mary McKernan et al., Empirical Evidence on the Determinants of Rent-to-Own Use and Purchase Behavior, 17 ECON. DEV. Q. 33, 34 (2003). 93 See Susan Lorde Martin & Nancy White Huckins, Consumer Advocates v. The Rent-to-Own Industry: Reaching a Reasonable Accommodation, 34 AM. BUS. L.J. 385 (1997). In fact, rent-to-own appears to have come into being in response to legal bans on cross-collateral clauses for consumer goods, such as in Williams v. Walker-Thomas. 94 See McKernan et al., supra note 92, at 51; James P. Nehf, Effective Regulation of Rent-to-Own Contracts, 52 OHIO ST. L.J. 751, 752 (1991); Eligio Pimentel, Renting-To-Own: Exploitation or Market Efficiency?, 13 LAW & INEQ. J. 369, 394 (1995) (“Consumers who enter in [rent-to-own] transactions have usually been denied credit by other businesses. They typically resort to the [rent-to-own] arrangement in a final effort to obtain the merchandise they desire.”). 95 FTC RENT-TO-OWN STUDY, supra note 91. Forty-four percent of rent-to-own customers have credit cards, but it is not clear how many of them would have exceeded their credit limits had they tried to use them instead of rent-to-own. 21 The most attractive type of general consumer credit, especially for middle class borrowers, was an unsecured loan from a personal finance company or local bank.96 Personal loans historically charged interest rates marginally lower than those on credit cards, but since the early 1990s the interest rates on personal loans have been comparable to credit cards (both are unsecured loans and therefore the fundamental risk is similar).97 Personal loans also charge higher initiation and underwriting fees than credit cards, which typically charge no up-front fees.98 The cost of underwriting a personal loan also placed a practical limitation on the minimum size and duration of a loan to a few thousand dollars and a multi-year repayment term, even if the consumer only needed a few hundred dollars for a short period of time, such as to finance a car repair or for a student to buy books until her student loan check arrives. Eventually, commercial banks entered the industry as a competing source of consumer credit, especially for installment loans for the purchase of major consumer durables, such as automobiles.99 In addition to cost, consumers value the flexible borrowing and repayment terms of credit cards.100 Federal Reserve Board Economist Thomas Durkin has observed that credit cards have largely replaced the installment-purchase plans that were important to the sales See CALDER, supra note 11, at 148. Many loans by “industrial lenders” and personal finance companies were consolidation of outstanding installment loans. Id. at 151. 97 See infra at Figure 9. 98 Credit cards typically have no origination fee and no minimum loan size while personal finance company loans have substantial up-front original costs. Brito and Hartley reported, “A senior bank officer told us that the costs to the bank of processing a loan are so high that they cannot afford to make a loan of less than $3,000 for one year except at interest rates above those charged on credit cards.” They also note, “inquiries in Houston in February 1992 revealed rates ranging from 17 percent and a $100 fixed fee for a collateralized 1-year loan at a branch of a major national finance company to over 50 percent for small loans ($300 maximum) at a local finance company.” 98 Bank loans of similar size and duration “either do not exist or are available only at terms more onerous than those offered by credit card issuers.” Dagobert L. Brito & Peter R. Hartley, Consumer Rationality and Credit Cards, 103 J. POL. ECON. 400, 402 (1995). Applying for a credit card is also easier and more convenient than applying for a personal loan. 99 See OLNEY, supra note 22, at 108. 100 Thomas A. Durkin, Consumers and Credit Disclosures: Credit Cards and Credit Insurance, FED. RES. BULLETIN 201, 205 (April 2002) (73% of consumer survey respondents state that flexibility of expenditure and repayment with credit cards makes managing finances easier). 96 22 volume at many retail stores in earlier decades, especially for the purchase of appliances, furniture, and other durable goods.101 Former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan similarly observed, “[T]he rise in credit card debt in the latter half of the 1990s is mirrored by a fall in unsecured personal loans.”102 In fact, consumer debt for nonautomobile durable goods, home improvement loans, and “other” nonrevolving credit (such as unsecured personal loans) declined from a total of about 20 percent of total household consumer debt in 1977 to 10 percent in 2004.103 Thus, although personal loans are not as comparatively unattractive as other traditional credit alternatives, they are still higher cost and less convenient for both consumers and lenders, thus it is not surprising that credit cards have generally supplanted personal loans.104 Pawn shops, layaway plans, payday lenders, check cashers, personal finance companies, retail store credit, rent-to-own, loan sharks, friends and family—all have served as important sources of consumer credit in American history.105 Credit cards are plainly superior to all of these traditional types of consumer credit. And in fact, research has demonstrated that those who use these high-priced and inconvenient lending products do so because they are unable to get a credit card at all or have reached their credit limit 101 Durkin, supra note 43, at 623-24; see also FED REPORT, supra note 6, at 5 (June 2006) (hereinafter FED REPORTS) (noting that revolving consumer credit has “partly replaced certain types of closed-end installment credit, principally those types classified as non-automobile durable goods credit, home improvement loans, and ‘other.’”). 102 Alan Greenspan, Understanding Household Debt Obligations, Remarks Given at the Credit Union National Association 2004 Governmental Affairs Conference (Feb. 23, 2004), available at http://www.federalreserve. gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20040223/default.htm. 103 FED REPORT, supra note 6, at 5 and Table 4. 104 Arthur B. Kennickell et al., Family Finances in the U.S.: Recent Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances, 83 FED. RES. BULL. 17 (1997) (noting that many lenders have stopped offering general unsecured lines of credit). 105 Credit cards are also used more frequently in high-crime geographic areas, as credit cards are less vulnerable to risk of theft than cash. See David B. Humphrey, Lawrence B. Pulley, and Jukka M. Vesala, Cash, Paper, and Electronic Payments: A Cross-Country Analysis, 28(4) J. MONEY, CREDIT AND BANKING 914, 934 (1996). 23 maximum.106 For instance, although 68% of American households have a bank-type card and 73% have any credit card, less than half of pawnbroker, rent-to-own, and refund anticipation loan customers, and only slightly over half of payday advance customers have credit cards.107 Moreover, 61% of payday loan customers who have a bank card and a third of tax refund anticipation loan customers with a bank card reported that they had refrained from using their credit card because they would have exceeded their credit limit.108 It thus appears that consumers use high-cost lenders only because they are unable to get access to credit cards and other attractive loan products.109 Plainly, there has been a massive substitution effect of the introduction of credit cards into the American economy, leaving only the question of how large this substitution effect has been as opposed to causing an increase in household indebtedness. II. Models of the Relationship Between Credit Cards and Bankruptcy Several scholars have found a correlation between credit card debt and bankruptcy. Domowitz and Sartain, for instance, conclude that “the largest single contribution to bankruptcy at the margin is credit card debt.”110 Ausubel also finds a 106 Elliehausen, supra note 70, at 19. Angela Littwin similarly finds that low-income consumers would like to have credit cards, especially to deal with emergencies, but are often unable to get them. See Littwin, supra note 68, at 5-6. 107 Elliehausen, supra note 70, at 19-20. 108 Id. at 21. 109 For instance, as younger households mature and gain greater credit experience they begin to gain access to credit cards, at which time they substitute away from these other high-price loans (such as payday loans and refund anticipation loans) to using credit cards for borrowing small amounts for short periods of time. Elliehausen finds that low-income consumers who revolve debt on bank cards tend to be older than those who use payday loans and refund anticipation loans, suggesting that many younger households are unable to get credit cards and that when they finally do, they prefer them to those sources of credit that they previously used. Elliehausen, supra note 70, at 21. 110 Ian Domowitz & Robert L. Sartain, Determinants of the Consumer Bankruptcy Decision, 54 J. FIN. 403, 414 (1999). 24 correlation between credit card defaults and bankruptcy.111 Providing a causal explanation, however, has proven elusive. Three different models have been postulated to explain the observed correlation between credit cards and bankruptcy: (1) The “substitution” model, (2) the “distress” model, and (3) the “strategic” model. The substitution model predicts that bankruptcy filings could rise as a result of credit cards even if the overall consumer debt burden is held constant. The distress model postulates that increased use of credit cards will raise the consumer debt burden and thereby increase consumer bankruptcies. The strategic model predicts that credit card debt will rise in anticipation of bankruptcy filing, although it is ambiguous about the overall effect on consumer indebtedness. Consider each model and its implications. A. Substitution Model The substitution model begins with the observed correlation between the increased use of credit cards and increased bankruptcy filings, but hypothesizes that this may be explainable simply by the substitution of increased credit card debt for other traditional types of consumer credit, such that borrowers are more willing or able to file bankruptcy and discharge their debt—even holding total consumer debt constant. Even if overall debt burdens do not rise as the result of credit cards, credit card debt is generally dischargeable unsecured debt, unlike traditional types of credit which were either practicably nondischargeable (such as loans from family members or illegal loan sharks) or secured (such as a loan to finance the purchase of furniture or an appliance). Consumers also may be more willing to discharge debts owed to national institutional 111 See Lawrence M. Ausubel, Credit Card Defaults, Credit Card Profits, and Bankruptcy, 71 AM. BANKR. L.J. 249 (1997). 25 lenders, such as Citibank, rather than local businesses. Thus, even if credit cards are simply a substitute for these other types of consumer credit bankruptcy filings may rise if the interaction between the bankruptcy laws and developments in consumer credit result in increased incentives to discharge credit card debt than these other types of credit. Increased credit card use may be correlated with increased bankruptcy filings, but in contrast to the distress model, the increased credit card debt does not cause the increase in bankruptcy filings through the intermediate step of increased debt burdens, but that the substitution increases the propensity to file, holding debt burdens constant. In contrast to the strategic model, the increase in consumer credit card debt may be largely exogenously driven and thus not necessarily a strategic “loading up” decision. The substitution model implies that the correlation between credit card debt and bankruptcy filings is a two step decision-making process. First, the debtor may increase her use of credit card debt for reasons unrelated to a later bankruptcy filing, such as its comparatively lower interest rate (relative to other available options) or greater convenience, but not increase her overall debt burden, if the credit card debt is merely a substitute for other types of debt. Then second, when the debtor is confronted with the option of filing bankruptcy, the debtor may find bankruptcy to be a more attractive choice than would be the case in the past. In this model, the mere substitution of credit card debt for other kinds of consumer debt could result in an increased propensity to file bankruptcy, holding overall consumer debt levels constant and thus even if it does not increase the need to file bankruptcy: Credit Card Substitution Increased Benefit to Bankruptcy Increased Bankruptcy 26 B. Distress Model The “distress model” (or “overindebtedness model”) argues that widespread access to credit cards has led to an increase in consumer indebtedness and financial distress and through this to increased consumer bankruptcy filings. Credit cards, it is argued, lead to a greater rate of overindebtedness compared to earlier ages because of profligate lending to riskier borrowers or irrational borrowing by consumers in general. The distress model predicts a causal relationship between increased credit card borrowing and increased bankruptcy filings through the intermediate step of increased debt. In the distress model, in contrast to the substitution model, an increase in credit card debt leads to an increase in bankruptcy filings indirectly, by first increasing overall consumer indebtedness and thereby subsequently increasing the need for consumers to file bankruptcy. So the chain of causation may be described as follow: Credit Card Debt  Increased Debt Increased Distress Increased Bankruptcies C. Strategic Model The “strategic” model essentially reverses the chain of causation from the distress model. In the strategic model, credit card debt rises in anticipation of bankruptcy.112 Because of information asymmetries, consumers are more aware of their likelihood of filing bankruptcy than are lenders. Credit cards are uniquely prone to problems of moral hazard and adverse selection, as once granted they provide cardholders with a line of credit to draw upon at their discretion with no further approval from the lender. Unlike many other types of loans, credit cards can be used to finance services and consumption 112 David B. Gross & Nicholas S. Souleles, An Empirical Analysis of Personal Bankruptcy and Delinquency, 15 REV. FIN. STUD. 319, 324 (2002). 27 and is generally unsecured debt that can be fully discharged in bankruptcy without surrendering any property. The strategic model draws on these problems of adverse selection and moral hazard to posit that the correlation between bankruptcy and credit cards results from the debtor strategically increasing her credit card borrowing in the prebankruptcy period by “loading up” on credit card debt in order to purchase goods and services in anticipation of later discharging those debts in bankruptcy. Like the distress model, a rise in credit card debt temporally precedes a bankruptcy filing and may be reflected in an increase in total debt; unlike the distress model, however, the rise in credit card debt cannot be said to have “caused” the bankruptcy filing. Instead, it is because the debtor has the option to file bankruptcy and discharge the debt effectively causes the rise in credit card debt, as the debtor strategically loads up his credit cards in anticipation of discharging those debts: Expected Bankruptcy Filing Increased Credit Card Debt Bankruptcy D. Predictions Distinguishing among these various hypotheses for purposes of testing can be difficult, as each predicts that an increase in bankruptcy filings will be preceded by an increase in credit card debt, with only the direction of causation in question. Nonetheless, certain data findings would be inconsistent with the predictions of one or another model. For instance, for the distress model to be correct there must be both an increase in consumer debt burdens that is caused by a rise in credit card debt, and in turn, this rise in consumer debt burden must cause a rise in bankruptcy filings. This fundamental prediction of a rise in credit card-induced consumer debt burdens is an 28 essential condition of the distress model; thus, a failure to find it would be fatal to the model. The substitution model predicts a rise in credit card debt burden over time, but a relatively constant overall consumer debt burden, as the rise in credit card debt is largely offset by a decline in other types of consumer debt. The strategic model would be consistent with either prediction regarding overall consumer debt burdens (rising or constant) but may be distinguished primarily by the timing of rising consumer debt burdens. Under the strategic model, one would expect to observe a rapid rise in credit card debt in the period immediately preceding bankruptcy evidencing a conscious choice to pay some debts rather than others, or to increase credit card borrowing. The other models predict no such obvious timing pattern but tend to suggest that credit card debt accumulation will be more gradual. Both the substitution and strategic models also predict that defaults on credit cards will not be the same as defaults on secured consumer loans, such as home mortgages where default will result in foreclosure. The remainder of this article examines each of these three hypotheses in turn. Although the distress model of credit card use is widely-accepted in the law review literature it finds few adherents among economists.113 An examination of the available data fails to support the predictions of the distress model. Available evidence points toward the validity of the substitution model as the most plausible model of the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy with some marginal effect of the strategic theory. Contrary to conventional wisdom, credit cards do not appear to have caused an increase in total household financial distress because although consumers have increased their use of credit cards as a borrowing medium, this has been primarily a 113 See, e.g., FED REPORT, supra note 6. 29 substitution of credit card debt for other high-interest consumer debt. The increased use of credit cards thus has changed the composition of household debt, but has not increased its overall burden. This substitution of credit cards for traditional types of consumer credit, however, has had the unintended consequence of making bankruptcy more attractive to consumers as a response to financial distress and thereby to increase bankruptcy filing rates. Thus, although credit cards have not spurred an increased need for bankruptcy (indeed, they may have done the opposite, by making a given level of indebtedness easier to manage because of their lower cost and flexible repayment terms), they have increased the incentive for indebted consumers to elect bankruptcy as a response to their financial difficulties, thereby increasing the propensity to file bankruptcy. III. Substitution Model The first hypothesis regarding the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy is the substitution model. The substitution model rests on the premise that a mere substitution of credit card debt for other forms of consumer debt may lead to increased bankruptcy filings even holding total consumer debt burden constant, if that substitution increases the incentives or willingness of consumers to file bankruptcy. In particular, the substitution model posits that the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy as a two step process. First, credit card use may rise for reasons exogenous to the question of bankruptcy, such as the greater convenience of credit cards or their lower cost relative to alternatives, and the growth in credit card debt may simply substitute for other types of debt (such as retail store credit) or informal loans, changing the 30 composition of the household debt portfolio but not increasing financial distress. But second, this substitution could cause an increased propensity to file bankruptcy in response to financial distress. A. Have Credit Cards Increased Household Debt Burdens? It is obvious that there has been a substantial substitution of credit cards for other types of consumer debt. Yet, although credit card debt seems ubiquitous, revolving card debt is only about seven percent of total household indebtedness. 114 One-half to two- thirds of American households do not revolve credit card debt or rarely revolve credit card debt from one month to another.115 As a result, the median credit card debt burden for American households is zero.116 Of households that do revolve credit card debt, the median balance is about $2,100, a fairly modest figure when compared to mortgage and automobile debt. Of course, there are some households with a lot of credit card debt, but as a first approximation they are the exception. The best available measure of the household debt burden is the debt-service ratio. The typical measurement of consumer debt is the debt-to-income ratio, which computes the ratio of household income to the total amount of consumer debt outstanding. But this 114 See Federal Reserve Release G.19 and Federal Reserve Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States. Indebtedness on home mortgages constitutes about 83 percent of outstanding household indebtedness. Installment credit, such as auto loans and student loans, constitute the remainder. 115 See Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 101; Aizcorbe et al., supra note 63, at 25 (reporting that 55.3% of households pay their credit card bills in full each month); Joanna Stavins, Credit Card Borrowing, Delinquency, and Personal Bankruptcy, NEW ENG. ECON. REV., July/Aug. 2000, at 15, 20 (58% of households in Survey of Consumer Finances stated that they paid their credit cards in full each month in the past year); see also Thomas F. Cargill & Jeanne Wendel, Bank Credit Cards: Consumer Irrationality Versus Market Forces, 30 J. CONSUMER AFF. 373, 379 (1996) (68% of credit card users “nearly always” pay their full balance every month); FEDERAL RESERVE, REPORT TO CONGRESS, supra note, at 6 (noting that 56 percent of households nearly always pay their balance in full each month). 116 Anne Kim, Adam Solomon, Bernard L. Schwartz, Jim Kessler, and Stephen Rose, The New Rules Economy: A Policy Framework for the 21st Century, THE THIRD WAY MIDDLE CLASS PROJECT 9 (Feb. 2007). 31 measurement is misleading because it fails to account for changes in interest rates and loan maturity rates, which are obviously relevant to one’s ability to pay debt, as well as the amount that will be borrowed.117 The debt-service ratio measures the amount the debtor must pay on his debt each month out of his current income and thus does account for these factors that are ignored by the debt-to-income ratio.118 Households change their borrowing behavior in response to changes in interest rates—thus a one percentage-point rise in credit card interest rates is estimated to induce a $70 reduction in total household credit card debt each month.119 Higher interest rates also lead consumers to more aggressively shift balances among cards in order to minimize interest payments.120 Historically low interest rates during the past several years have enabled consumers to borrow more (by taking on great principle obligations), but without increasing their debt service burden. As a result of competition, lower interest rates, and the substitution effect of shopping for lower interest rates, the household debt service ratio has been largely consistent over time. Disaggregating the debt service ratio into its constituent elements 117 For an extended discussion of the problems with the traditional measures, see Todd J. Zywicki, An Economic Analysis of the Consumer Bankruptcy Crisis, 99 NORTHWESTERN L. REV. 1463 (2005). 118 The household debt service ratio is the ratio of household debt payments to disposable income and is analogous to “equity insolvency” in corporate law. For revolving debt, the assumed required minimum payment is 2-1/2 percent of the balance each month. See Household Debt Service and Financial Obligations Ratios, About the Release, http://zentralbank.us.releases.housedebt/about.htm. Most consumer installment loans require payment of 2-3 percent of the balance each month, thus at recent interest rates, the minimum required payment on a credit card loan would be 13 percent less than the payment on a personal loan of the same size. Thus, even though the interest rates are similar, the credit card loan has a payment equivalent to a personal loan with a maturity almost one year longer than that of the typical personal loan. See Kathleen Johnson, Recent Developments in the Credit Card Market and the Financial Obligations Ratio, FED. RES. BULLETIN 473, 482 (Autumn 2005). This longer implied maturity is irrelevant to the debtservice ratio, of course, although it would be relevant to a calculation of household net worth. Thus it is significant that there is no evidence that household net worth (which is equivalent to “bankruptcy” or “balance sheet” insolvency) has worsened during this period either. See discussion infra at note 129 and accompanying text. 119 David B. Gross and Nicholas S. Souleles, Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data, 117 Q. J. ECON. 148 (Feb. 2002). 120 Id. 32 illustrates the substitution of revolving credit card debt for nonrevolving installment debt over time, as shown in Figure 1: Figure 1 Debt Service Ratio by Type of Debt: 1980-2007 0.16 0.14 Proportion of Income Total DSR 0.12 Mortgage DSR 0.1 0.08 NonRevolving DSR Revolving DSR 0.06 0.04 0.02 20 07 q1 20 04 q1 20 01 q1 19 98 q1 19 95 q1 19 92 q1 19 89 q1 19 86 q1 19 83 q1 19 80 q1 0 Year Source: Federal Reserve As Figure 1 indicates, even though the bankruptcy rate surged from 1980 to 2000, the debt service ratio was largely constant, before beginning a slight rise since 2000. In fact, the Total household DSR—even including the mortgage debt service ratio—was actually lower in 1993 than in 1980—even though the bankruptcy filing rate doubled during that period. Total DSR was lower in 1998 than in 1987, but the bankruptcy rate almost tripled during that period. Since 2000, there has been an upward movement in the debt-service ratio—caused by an increase in mortgage debt—but this upward trend has occurred just as the bankruptcy filing rate was leveling off after a period of rapid increase. 33 Moreover, it is evident that this rise in the debt service ratio in the past few years has been in the mortgage debt service ratio, not in consumer credit, and not revolving debt, for which the debt service ratio has been constant since the mid-1990s.121 This rise in the mortgage debt service ratio reflects the dramatic expansion of home ownership during this period as a result of the growth of the subprime lending market, as home ownership rose from 64% to 69% of families during this period, reaching an all-time high.122 According to Federal Reserve economists, “[F]ully 100 percent of the increase in aggregate debt relative to income since 1983 has taken the form of debt on households’ primary residences…. Meanwhile, aggregate debt associated with credit cards, consumer installment loans, and other borrowing stayed just below 0.30 of aggregate household income throughout the last quarter-century.”123 Most of these new home buyers were marginal purchasers with lower-incomes and higher debt service ratios that tended to raise the average debt service ratio. During this period, downpayments fell as well, increasing the amount financed and housing prices generally.124 The end result was that millions of households moved from renting to owning their houses thereby 121 See Andrew Kish, Perspectives on Recent Trends in Consumer Debt, Payment Cards Center Discussion Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia 24 (June 2006); see also Alan Greenspan, The Mortgage Market and Consumer Debt, remarks presented at America’s Community Bankers Annual Convention, Washington, D.C., Oct. 19, 2004, available in http://www.federalreserve.gov/boardDocs/Speeches/2004/20041019/. 122 United States Census Bureau, Housing Vacancies and Homeownership, Table 14. Homeownership Rates for the U.S. and Regions: 1965 to Present, available in http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/housing/hvs/historic/histt14.html 123 Karen E. Dynan and Donald L. Kohn, The Rise in U.S. Household Indebtedness: Causes and Consequences at p. 14, Federal Reserve Board, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs 2007-37 (emphasis added)). 124 See Francois Ortalo-Magne & Sven Rady, Housing Market Dynamics: On the Contribution of Income Shocks and Credit Constraints, 73(April) REV. ECON. STUDIES 459 (April 2006). The loan to value ratio for mortgages has risen during this period as well. See Wenli Li, Moving Up: Trends in Homeownership and Mortgage Indebtedness, Q1 2005 BUSINESS REV. Q1 at 26, 28 (Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank, 2005). This too has been largely driven by low-income households, which increased their LTV much faster than the population at large. Id. At 29-30. 34 acquiring a new wealth accumulation vehicle125 but which also led to a measured increase in the debt service ratio.126 In fact, even though housing prices rose rapidly during this period, interest rates plummeted even more rapidly—with the end result being that consumers could afford more expensive houses at the same or lower monthly payment.127 In addition, the Financial Obligations Ratio for non-homeowners for Fourth Quarter 2007 was lower than in 1986 and only slightly higher than in 1980, further suggesting that the rise in household indebtedness was for new homeowners rather than extant homeowners.128 To identify the impact of credit cards on the debt service ratio, we can more specifically isolate the impact of all consumer debt (revolving and nonrevolving) from mortgage debt. Removing mortgage DSR from the equation clearly demonstrates the substitution effect of revolving consumer debt for traditional installment consumer debt, as shown in Figure 2: Figure 2 125 See Mark Dorns & Meryl Motika, The Rise in Homeownership, 2006-30 FRBSF ECON. LETTER (Nov. 3, 2006). 126 See Karen Dynan, Kathleen Johnson, and Karen Pence, Recent Changes to a Measure of U.S. Household Debt Service, FED. RES. BULLETIN 417 (2005). 127 U.S. Housing Market Conditions, Table 11 “Housing Affordability Index,” Department of Housing and Urban Development. Interest rates on 30-year fixed rate mortgages fell from 8.05 percent in 2000 to 5.8 percent in 2003-05 before rising to 6.4 percent in 2006. Id. at Table 14 “Mortgage Interest Rates, Average Commitment Rates, and Points, 1973-Present.” In 2000 the average price of existing homes nationwide was 143,600 and by 2005 the average price was $219,600. In some areas of the country prices almost doubled. Id. at Table 9, “Existing Home Prices.” Points fell as well during this period. Id. at Table 15. Nor does it appear that consumers have been shifting substantial consumer debt into home equity loans. Home equity loans are a relatively small portion of total home mortgage debt—ten percent or less—and this ratio has been largely constant over the past decade. Federal Reserve Board, Flow of Funds Report, Table L.218 “Home Mortgages.” In 2005 total mortgage liabilities were over $9 trillion whereas total home equity loans were about $900 billion. From 2000 to 2005, the percentage of household asset value has remained largely constant, varying between 56-58% during that period. Id.; see also Christopher L. Cagan, Mortgage Payment Reset: The Rumor and the Reality 3 (Feb. 8, 2006). In addition, the definition of “consumer debt” includes things such as medical expenses and student loans. 128 See Federal Reserve, Household Debt Service and Financial Obligations Ratios. 35 Non-Mortgage Debt Service Ratio 0.075 Proportion of Income 0.07 0.065 0.06 0.055 0.05 20 07 q1 20 04 q1 20 01 q1 19 98 q1 19 95 q1 19 92 q1 19 89 q1 19 86 q1 19 83 q1 19 80 q1 0.045 Year As Figure 2 illustrates, the overall debt service ratio for all consumer, nonmortgage debt (consumer revolving plus nonrevolving debt) has fluctuated in a fairly narrow band during the period 1980 to 2006—between about 5%-7% of income during this entire period. In fact, the non-mortgage debt service ratio was actually slightly higher at the beginning of the data series in 1980 (0.0633) than at the end in the first quarter of 2006 (0.0616) with local peaks and troughs throughout. There is no upward trend in the debt service ratio that can explain the quintupling of the bankruptcy filing during that period. Further isolating non-mortgage consumer debt into revolving and nonrevolving components visually illustrates the substitution effect, as shown in Figure 3: Figure 3 36 Consumer Non-Mortgage Debt Service Ratio: 1980-2007 0.06 Proportion of Income 0.05 0.04 Non-Revolving DSR 0.03 0.02 Revolving DSR 0.01 1 07 q 1 20 04 q 1 20 01 q 1 20 98 q 1 19 95 q 1 19 92 q 1 19 89 q 1 19 86 q 1 19 83 q 19 19 80 q 1 0 Year Examining Figure 3, several points can be noted. First, from the 1980s into the 1990s, there is a clear inverse trend between the revolving debt service ratio and the nonrevolving debt service ratio, illustrating the substitution effect. Second, from the mid1990s to the present, both the nonrevolving and the revolving debt service ratios have leveled off and been largely constant, thus the substitution effect appears to have reached a sort of equilibrium by the mid-1990s. Thus, the overall debt service ratio has remained largely unchanged during this period. Moreover, even though this data alone shows a clear substitution effect between revolving and nonrevolving debt, because of peculiarities in the way that the debt service ratio is measured, even this measurement overestimates the contribution of revolving debt to the debt service ratio. First, wealth has risen more rapidly than income over the past few decades, first because of the rise in financial wealth from the roaring stock market of the late-1990s, 37 and then the rapid appreciation in housing values into the 2000s.129 When wealth increases, consumers rationally borrow against and consume some of it. This is known as the “permanent income hypothesis”130 or “life cycle model”131 of consumption. According to the permanent income hypothesis, consumers choose their consumption patterns based on long-term income expectations and not just their current income. An increase in wealth that is perceived to be permanent is functionally equivalent to an increase in future income. As a result, consumers will base their consumption on their wealth and expected permanent income, whether wealth takes the form of intangible (financial) assets, tangible assets (real property), or human capital (such as investments in education that raise your expected income stream in the future). An increase in wealth that is expected to be permanent increases long-run expected income and will therefore boost consumption today. To the extent that this wealth is otherwise illiquid (such as human capital or retirement assets) consumer credit is one mechanism for borrowing against this wealth to increase consumption today, especially when long-term wealth grows more rapidly than short-term income. In fact, non-mortgage consumer debt has been about 4% of household wealth for several decades.132 During periods of rapidly increasing household wealth (such as during the 1990s) consumers increase their consumption and consumer debt in order to liquefy some of this accumulated wealth to finance consumption. But because these are See Greenspan, The Mortgage Market and Consumer Debt, supra note 121, at 3 (noting that “the ratio of households’ net worth to income has risen to a multiple of more than five after hovering around four and one-half for most of the postwar period”); see also Zywicki, supra note 117, at 1483-92. 130 See MILTON FRIEDMAN, A THEORY OF THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION (1957). 131 See Albert Ando & Franco Modigliani, The “Life Cycle” Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests, 53 AM. ECON. REV. 55 (1963); IRVING FISHER, THE THEORY OF INTEREST (1930). An accessible summary of the empirical evidence is available in Tullio Japelli, The Life-Cycle Hypothesis, Fiscal Policy, and Social Security, working paper (Feb. 2005), available in http://www.csef.it/papers/modigliani.pdf. 132 Thomas A. Durkin, Discussion, THE IMPACT OF PUBLIC POLICY ON CONSUMER CREDIT 40 (Thomas A. Durkin & Michael E. Staten eds., 2002). 129 38 capital gains and not earned income, the debt service ratio excludes them from its calculations, even though it adjusts for the liquefying of the wealth holdings through increased consumption and taxes. The marginal propensity to consume out of wealth is larger for increases in house values than financial wealth—every dollar of increased housing wealth generates about a 6-8 cent increase whereas the marginal propensity to consume out of financial wealth is only about 2 cents of every additional dollar.133 Thus, during periods of wealth growth, and especially rapid increases in real estate equity such as in recent years, consumers tend to borrow against that wealth in order to increase consumption today, in order to preserve a more stable pattern of consumption through time. By borrowing against their accumulated wealth holdings to finance consumption (with no corresponding increase in measured income) this will tend to lead to an overestimation of the debt service ratio. Second, the Federal Reserve overestimates the revolving credit debt service ratio because its methodology inadvertently counts some transactional use as revolving.134 The Federal Reserve measures the debt service ratio on revolving credit by the amount of revolving credit outstanding at the end of a given month. As a result, the data measures as part of the outstanding balance on revolving credit, and thus as part of the DSR, those balances on transactional accounts that will be paid in full at the close of the billing cycle 133 Raphael Bostic, Stuart Gabriel, and Gary Painter, House Wealth, Financial Wealth, and Consumption: New Evidence from Micro Data, working paper, University of Southern California (Dec. 2005); see also John D. Benjamin, Peter Chinlov, and G. Donald Jud, Real Estate Versus Financial Wealth in Consumption, 29(3) J. REAL ESTATE FINANCE AND ECON. 341-354 (2004) (estimating marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth as 8 cents per dollar and 2 cents per dollar for financial wealth). See Greenspan & Kennedy, supra note 126, at 3-6 (summarizing studies). 134 Kathleen W. Johnson, Convenience or Necessity? Understanding the Recent Rise in Credit Card Debt, finance and economics Discussion Series, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs, Federal Reserve Board, Working Paper 2004-47; see also Kathleen W. Johnson, The Transactions Demand for Credit Cards, 7 B.E. J. OF ECON. ANALYSIS & POL’Y, Issue 1, Article 16 (2007), available in http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/vol7/iss1/art16; see also William Hempel, Discussion, in THE IMPACT OF PUBLIC POLICY ON CONSUMER CREDIT, supra note 132, at 66, 67. 39 but happen to be outstanding at the time of reporting. Moreover, this measurement error has been exacerbated over time because transactional or “convenience” use of credit cards has been rising more rapidly than true revolving credit. During the past 15 years, transactional use grew by approximately 15% per year (primarily because of various incentives such as frequent flier or rebate programs), whereas the amount borrowed on credit cards grew only about 6 ½% per year. The percentage of credit card transactions that are paid off at the end of each month also has risen as has the percentage of credit card holders who are transactors.135 In addition, the median monthly charge amount for transactional users has risen over four times more rapidly for transactional users than for revolvers.136 The overestimation that results from measuring transactional credit card use as credit card borrowing for purposes of the debt service ratio tends to overstate the revolving credit debt service ratio by approximately ten percent, an effect that has doubled in the past decade as a result of the rapid rise of transactional use relative to revolving.137 In addition, because transactional users do not have to pay for their purchases until the end of the billing period plus the grace period after receiving their bill, they have the opportunity to take advantage of interest rate “float” during the time between their purchase and actual payment of the obligation, which may be as long as 45-60 days.138 During that period, a transactional user essentially receives a free loan from the credit 135 The percentage of convenience users relative to revolvers has risen steadily over time as credit cards have replaced checks and cash as a transaction medium. See Johnson, Transactions Demand, supra note 134; see also Delinquency on Consumer Loans: Testimony Before the House Comm. on Banking and Fin. Servs., 104th Cong. 1 (1996) (statement of Lawrence B. Lindsey, Member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys.). 136 Johnson, Convenience or Necessity?, supra note 134. 137 See Johnson, Convenience or Necessity?, supra note 134. It may be as high as fifteen percent. See Kish, supra note, at 31. 138 If, for instance, a purchase is made at the beginning of a new billing period but the bill is not paid until the end of the grace period. 40 card issuer at zero percent interest during which time those same funds can be invested in assets that generate a positive return, even if only a money market account or similar safe, short-term investment.139 Revolvers are more likely to make use of debit cards than are nonrevolvers, which can be explained by the fact that revolvers do not receive the benefit of interest-rate float because they are required to pay the full interest on the account, so they rationally use debit cards instead.140 The greater ability to plan the timing of expenditures also enables those with credit cards to carry smaller precautionary balances in their checking accounts than those without credit cards, enabling them to invest their money in interest-bearing accounts during the period of the interest-free float.141 In fact, despite these factors that that bias toward an overestimation of credit card credit, there still is no discernible increase in the debt service ratio for nonmortgage consumer debt over the past 25 years.142 Indeed, the DSR for installment credit would have fallen still further over time, but for an unexpected jump in installment debt around 139 Technically the interest rate is slightly negative because of the time value of money. Jonathan Zinman, Debit or Credit? (Working Paper, Dartmouth College Aug. 10, 2006). Researchers have found similar results in Australia: transactors use credit cards for payments almost twice as frequently than revolvers (22 percent of transcations compared to 12 percent) and revolvers are substantially more likely to use debit cards than transactors. See David Emery, Tim West, and Darren Massey, Household Payment Patterns in Australia, in RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA, PROCEEDINGS OF PAYMENT SYSTEMS REVIEW CONFERENCE 139, 158-59 (Nov. 29, 2007), available in http://203.34.60.68/PaymentsSystem/Publications/PaymentsInAustralia/PaymentsSystemReviewConferenc e/2007/index.html. Brown and Plache find that 62 percent of revolvers who have a general purpose debit card actually used that card whereas only 37 percent of nonrevolvers used their debit card. See Tom Brown & Lacy Plache, Paying with Plastic: Maybe Not So Crazy, 73 U. CHICAGO L. REV. 63, 84 (2006). 141 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 91-93; Johnson, Transactions Demand, supra note 134, at 3. A full accounting of the revolving credit DSR would include the ability to earn interest by maintaining smaller precautionary balances. 142 See Hempel, supra note 134, at 67 (“[C]onsumer credit has been fairly constant relative to income over the past 30 years, but the composition has changed.”). Some of the growth in credit card credit also may have been a substitution away from informal types of credit that traditionally have been poorly measured, thus if the substitution is to better-measured types of credit, this would tend to artificially inflate the debtservice ratio as well. A recent study of low and moderate-income households found that 15 percent of those in the study reported that they had previously obtained financing from institutions generally excluded by aggregate statistics, such as pawn shops, payday lender, and rent-to-own establishments. See SIEDMAN, ET AL., supra note 67. 140 41 2000, caused by two developments on margins where credit cards are poor substitutes for installment loans. First, the low-interest rate environment in the economy, combined with promotional zero and low interest rate deals on automobile loans beginning around 2000 led to many consumers who had been leasing automobiles to switch to purchasing automobiles, thereby leading to an increase in automobile installment debt.143 The majority of installment borrowing today is for vehicle purchases.144 Thus, there was a slight increase in the total amount of household installment credit for automobiles beginning around 2000, but this was offset by a corresponding decline in automobile lease commitments, thus there was no worsening of household financial condition, even though this too tended to inflate the debt service ratio for installment debt.145 Second, there has been a dramatic rise in student loan obligations (which are installment loans) over time.146 From 1977 to 2004, total outstanding balances on student loans rose from one percent of outstanding balances on consumer nonmortgage credit accounts to 21 percent, a level almost equal to total outstanding balances on credit cards with both trailing only automobile loans as a percentage of household nonmortgage consumer debt.147 Leaving aside automobiles and mortgages, student loan debt rose from 28% of 143 See Aizcorbe et al., supra note 63, at 24. The growing popularity of sport utility vehicles, which were both more expensive and depreciate more slowly than cars, simultaneously increased indebtedness and increased household assets. Id. at 17. 144 See Bucks, et al., supra note 63, at p. A30. From 2001 to 2004 the percentage of nonmortgage consumer debt attributable to vehicle purchases rose form 54.8 percent to 55.5 percent. 145 See Dynan, et al,, supra note 126, at 421; see also Federal Reserve Release G.20 “Finance Companies” (noting peak in outstanding receivables on motor vehicle leases in August 2000, followed by decline over next several years). 146 See Aizcorbe et al., supra note 63, at 24. From 2001 to 2004, balances on student loans rose from 22.2 percent of household installment debt to 26.0 percent. 147 FED REPORT, supra note 6, at 8, Table 4. Credit card balances rose from 1970 to 1995 reaching 26% of total outstanding household debt before falling from 1995 to 2004 from 26% to 22%. Id. 42 outstanding consumer credit to 58%.148 By contrast, personal loans fell from 28% to 8% of nonauto, nonrevolving consumer loans, as they were “replaced” by credit card debt.149 Average interest rates on consumer loans generally fell steadily during this period as well, thereby reducing the debt service ratio, even as total indebtedness rose.150 Thus, there is no evidence that the increase in credit card debt has made households worse off, as low interest rates and the substitution effect have kept the debt service ratio largely constant for 25 years. Evidence of the substitution effect is also found among bankruptcy filers. Consider the following data drawn from Sullivan, et al.: Figure 4 Debt of Bankruptcy Filers 80000 70000 60000 Dollars 50000 Total Debt Secured Debt 40000 Unsecured Debt 30000 Credit Card Debt 20000 10000 0 1981 1991 Year 1997 148 Dynan, et al., supra note 126, at 418. Id. 150 Id. at 419. 149 43 As illustrated in Figure 4, from 1981 to 1997 the average amount of total debt held by bankruptcy filers remained constant, but the ratio of credit card debt to total unsecured debt increased, suggesting a substitution between credit card debt and other unsecured debt. Sullivan, et al., find that in 1981, total debt for bankruptcy filers was $68,154, of which unsecured debt was $27,365.151 By 1997, mean total debt among bankruptcy filers had actually fallen slightly to $61,320 and unsecured debt rose slightly to $29,529. Although total debt and total unsecured debt remained relatively constant, mean credit card debt among bankruptcy filers rose from $3,635 to $14,260 during this period and median credit card debt rose from $2,649 to $9,345.152 Thus, the substitution effect is evident among bankruptcy filers specifically, as credit card debt has risen even as total debt and total unsecured debt have remained largely constant. Credit card debt nonetheless remains a small fraction of overall household debt for bankruptcy filers. B. Credit Cards and Substitution by Low Income Families Some have suggested that even if credit cards haven’t increased the consumer debt burden for all or the average family, greater access of low-income and riskier borrowers to credit cards has increased the prevalence of economic distress and bankruptcy among this subclass of consumers.153 Economic theory and available data are inconsistent with this hypothesis. Again, this appears to be because the use of credit 151 See SULLIVAN, ET AL., FRAGILE, supra note 2, at 66, Table 2.4. All values are in 1997 dollars. Id. at 122, Table 4.1. The 1981 figures include only bank-type cards whereas the 1997 figures include all credit card debt. As noted, during this period there was a general substitution from other types of credit cards to bank-type cards, thus the 1981 figures may underestimate total credit card debt. In 1991, the mean debt for bank-type cards only among bankruptcy filers was $11,529, thus using the same category as 1981 there was plainly a large increase in bank-type card debt during the 1980s. 153 See Warren, supra note 2, at 1083; Susan L. DeJarnatt, Once is Not Enough: Preserving Consumers’ Rights to Bankruptcy Protection, 74 IND. L.J. 455, 499 (1999); Bernard R. Trujillo, The Wisconsin Exemption Clause Debate of 1846: An Historical Perspective on the Regulation of Debt, 1988 WISC. L. REV. 747, 749 (1998). 152 44 cards among low-income consumers has resulted from a substitution from other types of credit, rather than an increase in debt burdens. As a report of the Chicago Federal Reserve Bank concluded, “The increase in the credit card debt burden for the lowest income group appears to be offset by a drop in the installment debt burden. This suggests that there has not been a substantial increase in high-interest debt for low-income households, but these households have merely substituted one type of high-interest debt for another.”154 Bird, Hagstrom, and Wild similarly conclude that although credit card ownership among lowest-income households doubled between 1983 and 1995 and the average balance for those who revolved increased substantially as well, “the data reveal little direct evidence that the increase in [credit card] debt has caused an increase in economic distress, either for poor households or households at large.”155 Indeed, they found that credit card delinquencies among poor households fell during this period.156 Two studies have empirically examined the hypothesis that rising bankruptcies reflected increased lending to riskier borrowers and found little support. The first, by economists Donald P. Morgan and Ian Toll, concludes, “If lenders have become more willing to gamble on credit card loans than on other consumer loans credit card chargeoffs should be rising at a faster rate [than non-credit card consumer loans] . . . . Contrary to the supply-side story, charge-offs on other consumer loans have risen at virtually the same rate as credit card charge-offs.”157 This “suggest[s] that some other force [other 154 Wendy M. Edelberg & Jonas D. M. Fisher, Household Debt, CHI. FED. LETTER, Nov. 1997, at 1, 3 (1997); see also id. at 4 (“[I]ncreases in credit card debt service of lower-income households have been offset to a large extent by reductions in the servicing of installment debt.”). 155 Edward J. Bird, Paul A. Hagstrom, & Robert Wild, Credit Card Debts of the Poor: High and Rising, 18 J. POL’Y ANALYSIS & MANAGEMENT 125, 132 (1999). 156 Id. 157 Donald P. Morgan & Ian Toll, Bad Debt Rising, CURRENT ISSUES ECON. & FIN. (Research & Mkt. Analysis Group, Fed. Reserve Bank, New York, N.Y.), Mar. 1997, at 1, 3. Consistent with the argument presented in the text here, Morgan and Toll conclude that increased consumer demand for credit cards 45 than extension of credit cards to high-risk borrowers] is driving up bad debt.”158 A second study, by David B. Gross and Nicholas S. Souleles, concludes that changes in the risk-composition of credit card loan portfolios “explain only a small part of the change in default rates [on credit card loans] between 1995 and 1997,” finding instead that rising bankruptcies occurred entire population of borrowers became more risky and prone to filing bankruptcy over that time period.159 Compared to the population at large, low-income and younger households face a limited number and variety of credit options, thus credit cards are an especially attractive compared to available alternatives. Research by economist Gregory Elliehausen finds that users of high-price credit products such as pawnbrokers, rent-to-own, automobile title loans, and tax refund anticipation loans “are more likely than higher income groups to have limited discretionary income after necessities and be more vulnerable to unexpected expenses.”160 These are precisely the types of high-cost loans that consumers substitute away from when given the opportunity, as well as other non-“fringe” types of credit, such as layaway, retail store credit, and personal finance companies. Available data also supports the hypothesis that the growth in credit card use by low-income households has been a substitution away from these comparatively lessattractive types of consumer credit. The Federal Reserve’s debt service ratio data does not provide disaggregated data by income or other subgroups. The Survey of Consumer relative to other forms of consumer credit is driving the increase in credit card debt, not a supply-side shift. Id. 158 Id. at 4. 159 Gross & Souleles, supra note 112. 160 Gregory Elliehausen, Consumers’ Use of High-Price Credit Products: Do They Know What They are Doing? Networks Financial Institute at Indiana State University Working Paper 2006-WP-02 at p.18 (May 2006). 46 Finances, however, does provide a picture of the debt service ratio of households by income group, as shown in Figure 5: Figure 5 Debt Service Ratio (Lowest Quintile) and Bankruptcy 20.0 Debt Service Ratio 18.0 12 17.0 10 16.0 15.0 8 14.0 6 13.0 12.0 Bankruptcies/1000 Households 14 19.0 DSR Lowest Quintile Bankruptcies per 1000 Households 4 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2006 Year Source: Survey of Consumer Finances As can be seen, over the past 15 years the debt service ratio for lowest income quintile households has fluctuated between 16-19 percent, with no discernible trend. Nor is there any obvious relationship with bankruptcy filings—the DSR for lowest-quintile households rose from 1992 to 1995, while the bankruptcy filing rate actually fell slightly during that period. Then the DSR for this group fell from 1995 to 2001, even though the bankruptcy filing rate jumped. Over the decade from 1992 to 2001 the DSR for lowest income households actually fell, even though the overall consumer bankruptcy filing rate rose substantially. Moreover, the growth in the DSR of low income households from 2001-2004 years is attributable to the rapid growth in home ownership among low- 47 income families during that time, thus the growth primarily has been in the mortgage component of the DSR rather than the consumer credit DSR.161 In fact, the percentage of households carrying a balance on their credit cards actually declined between 2001-2004 for the lowest two income groups, the lowest wealth group, the youngest age group, and nonwhite or Hispanic families.162 The ratio of household debt payments to income for lowest quintile households is also similar to that for all other income ranges except the highest decile.163 The Survey of Consumer Finances also calculates the percentage of households that are in “financial distress” as measured by the number of households for which 40 percent or more of their income is dedicated to servicing debt. By this measurement, there is no discernible evidence that the percentage of low-income households in distress has risen over the past 15 years as a result of greater access to credit cards; indeed, in 2004 the percentage of low income households in financial distress was at its lowest level of any time during this period, even though the overall bankruptcy rate had risen dramatically during that time, as shown in Figure 6: Figure 6 161 See discussion in sources cited in note 121 and accompanying text. Bucks, Kennickell, & Moore, supra note 144, at p. A30. 163 See Brian W. Cashell, Rising Household Debt: Background and Analysis, CRS REPORT FOR CONGRESS 11 (Apr. 20, 2007). 162 48 Lowest Income Quintile Households with Financial Distress 30.5 16 30.0 14 29.5 12 29.0 10 28.5 28.0 8 27.5 6 Lowest Quintile Households with DSR > 40% Bankruptcy Filing Rate 27.0 4 26.5 2 26.0 25.5 0 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2006 Again, there is no obvious relationship between the percentage of low-income households in financial distress and the bankruptcy filing rate, suggesting that the increased access to credit cards has not led to an increase in financial distress. Consider one indicia of whether risk composition has changed, the delinquency rate on credit card loans, as shown in Figure 7: Figure 7 49 Delinquency Rate, Credit Card Loans Delinquency Rate 6 5.5 5 4.5 4 3.5 20 07 Q1 20 05 Q1 20 03 Q1 20 01 Q1 19 99 Q1 19 97 Q1 19 95 Q1 19 93 Q1 19 91 Q1 3 Year Source: Federal Reserve As can be seen in this chart, delinquency rates have fluctuated over time, but there is no upward trend in delinquency rates, and, in fact, there is a slight downward trend over the course of the reported data, depending on the starting point.164 Credit card delinquencies closely follow the business cycle. Similarly, the pattern in credit card delinquency rates is comparable to delinquency rates on other consumer loans over the same time period, suggesting that the riskiness of credit card borrowers is comparable to that for other types of credit, as shown in Figure 8165: Figure 8 164 The Federal Reserve did not compile data on credit card delinquency rates until 1991. Other measures of delinquency on credit card loans also fail to find a discernible upward trend in delinquencies on credit card loans over time, as one would expect if credit was being extended to riskier borrowers. See Bucks, Kennickell, & Moore, supra note 144, at p. A34 & n. 49. 1991 was a recession year, so delinquency raters were higher during that period, as with during the 2001-02 period, so whether the trend is actually downward depends on the starting point. On the other hand, as noted, there is no discernible upward trend over the period that could account for the dramatic rise in bankruptcy filings during this era. 165 As can be readily observed, delinquency on credit card loans is systematically higher than other consumer loans for reasons unrelated to the risk composition of the pool of borrowers, such as the greater difficulty in collection, the unsecured nature of credit card credit, and greater problems of moral hazard and adverse selection. 50 Delinquency Rate Consumer Loans Delinquency Rate 6 5 Credit Card 4 All Consumer 3 Non-Credit Card 2 1 20 07 Q1 20 05 Q1 20 03 Q1 20 01 Q1 19 99 Q1 19 97 Q1 19 95 Q1 19 93 Q1 19 91 Q1 0 Year Source: Federal Reserve A report of the Federal Reserve concludes that improvements over time in riskscreening technology by card issuers and account management techniques, such as controls on credit limits, have enabled credit card issuers to continually extend credit to wider swaths of society while at the same time effectively controlling risk.166 Professor Angela Littwin argues, however, that there has been a “low degree of substitution” between credit cards and fringe lending for lower-income households.167 She reaches her conclusion through interviews of low-income women who express a preference for the use of fringe lending products such as pawnshops and payday lenders instead of credit cards. From this she infers that low-income consumers have not substituted much borrowing activity from fringe lending products to credit cards, and thereby concludes that the substitution hypothesis is invalid. 166 167 FED REPORT, supra note 6, at 10. Littwin, Comparing Credit Cards, supra note, at 18-19. 51 But while providing interesting insights into the preferences of low-income consumers, Littwin’s analysis does not actually address the substitution hypothesis. The substitution hypothesis is not a theory of consumer preferences, but rather an explanation for fact-based observations that appear anomalous—credit card debt has increased substantially over time but that overall consumer debt burdens have not increased as a result. Littwin does not appear to question the fact that credit card borrowing by lowincome consumers has risen (notwithstanding their expressed dislike for credit cards), and it is unclear whether she believes the overall consumer debt burden has risen. Thus, her analysis doesn’t actually speak to the validity of the substitution hypothesis. Professor Littwin’s argument seems to be that low-income consumers have not substituted much debt from fringe lending products to credit cards, which she takes as rebutting the substitution hypothesis. Her exact argument is a bit opaque, but there seem to be two possible constructions. Neither is consistent with available data. First, Littwin may be arguing that the substitution hypothesis is invalid because low-income consumers use both fringe lending and credit cards, so increased use of credit cards has not led to a decreased use of fringe lending products. Thus, she may be arguing that credit card borrowing has been additive to fringe borrowing, not a substitute; or alternatively, that credit cards and fringe lending are substitutes, just not on a one-to-one basis such that a one dollar increase in credit card borrowing does not result in an equal decrease in fringe borrowing.168 But if this is so, then the increase in credit card 168 This may be what Littwin has in mind when she refers to fringe lending and credit cards as being “complements” rather than “substitutes,” which is that credit card borrowing is additive to fringe lending rather than a one-to-one substitute. “Complements” are those goods such that increasing the price of one good reduces demand for the other, e.g. a negative cross-price elasticity on the margin. Classic examples of complements include peanut butter and jelly or coffee and Cremora—i.e., if the price of peanut butter rises, demand will fall not just for peanut butter but also for jelly because they go together. “Substitutes” are those goods such that increasing the price of one good increases demand for the other. For instance, 52 borrowing should be reflected in an increase in the overall consumer debt burden. But Littwin provides no evidence contrary to the data reported above that indicates that the debt-service burden for consumer credit has remained constant over time. Second, she may be arguing that the cross-elasticity of demand between credit cards and fringe lending is low (i.e., inelastic) and there has been minimal substitution from fringe borrowing to credit card borrowing among low-income households, which would explain the minimal increase in measured consumer debt burdens. If this is her argument, then it would be consistent with the data indicating that there has been no increase in the overall consumer debt-service burden. But this seems to be inconsistent with the apparent increase in the use of credit card use by low-income households over the past 25 years. Again, this is a statistical question, not one of expressed consumer preferences. Nor does she provide an explanation as to why the this subset of society would hold preferences that deviate so dramatically from the preferences of other socioeconomic groups, such as the middle class, for which credit cards are immensely popular. Moreover, the finding that consumers use both credit cards and other types of consumer credit not only is consistent with the substitution hypothesis, but is exactly what the hypothesis would predict—consumers will hold portfolios of all types of credit products and will switch among them depending on their relative prices. So if the cost of credit card borrowing goes up, consumers at the margin will switch from credit cards to fringe borrowing products and vice-versa. As noted, there is some evidence that suggests increasing the price of driving (such as by increasing the cost of parking) will increase demand for taking the bus, which is a substitute for driving. A “complements” model of consumer credit, therefore, would predict that an increase in the price of fringe borrowing would lead to a decrease in the use of credit card borrowing, and that a decrease in the price of fringe borrowing would also lead to a decrease in demand for credit card borrowing. This doesn’t see to be a plausible model of consumer credit usage. 53 that consumers who use both credit cards and fringe borrowing generally use their credit cards first, but that when they run up against their credit limits and would face over-limit charges, they switch over to fringe borrowing. Without knowing the pattern of consumer use—e.g., do they use their credit cards more or less when the price of fringe lending rises—Professor Littwin cannot determine the degree of substitutability among different products.169 C. Understanding the Substitution Effect The growth of credit card credit thus has resulted from a substitution by consumers of credit cares for other, less-attractive forms of consumer credit. Nonetheless, many commentators nonetheless insist that the growth in credit card use as a source of revolving credit is irrational in light of the “high” interest rates charged on credit cards. But this is based on a misunderstanding of the reasons for the growth in credit card use. Figure 9 displays interest rates for credit cards (both generally and for those accounts actually assessed interest) and their most competitive comparable credit option, a 24-month personal loan: Figure 9 169 Her regression data provides no information on cross-elasticities of demand nor do her data include any sort of price change or analytically similar change in supply or demand conditions that would allow identification of a cross-price effect. 54 Credit Cards v. Personal Loans 20 19 Interest Rate 18 24 Month Personal Loan 17 16 All Credit Card Accounts 15 Credit Card Accounts Assessed Interest 14 13 12 19 72 19 -02 74 19 -02 76 19 -02 78 19 -02 80 19 -02 82 19 -02 84 19 -02 86 19 -02 88 19 -02 90 19 -02 92 19 -02 94 19 -02 96 19 -02 98 20 -02 00 20 -02 02 20 -02 04 20 -02 06 -0 2 11 Year As can be seen, over time the difference between interest rates on short-tem personal installment loans and credit card accounts is small and has narrowed over time. Indeed, in recent years the interest rate on credit card accounts has frequently fallen below that of short-term personal loans, and the interest rates on those accounts actually assessed interest frequently is even lower than for all accounts.170 Moreover, once initiation and application fees on personal loans are taken into consideration the total cost of personal loans is almost certainly higher overall.171 Some commentators nonetheless have argued that this substitution by consumers to greater reliance on credit cards is evidence of widespread consumer irrationality rather 170 See also Brown & Plache, supra note 20, at 80 (noting that higher percentage of nonrevolvers have credit cards with APRs greater than 10% than do revolvers). Further anecdotal evidence is a survey published each Friday in the Washington Times of area consumer banking rates each Friday, which show similar results. On September 14, 2007, for instance, the prevailing interest rate in the Washington, D.C., area on personal loans was one percentage point higher than on credit cards (10.75% for personal loans versus 9.75% for credit cards); at various other times the spread has been larger but reported credit card rates consistently have been lower. See WASHINGTON TIMES, p. C10 (Sept. 14, 2007). 171 See supra note 98. 55 than a beneficent process of market competition.172 But these arguments ignore the very possibility of a substitution effect, implicitly assuming that all debt has been piled upon preexisting consumer debt burdens. It also is implicitly assumed that there must have been an increase in debt burdens, both because of an increase in indebtedness as well as a belief that credit cards impose higher interest rates than the types of credit that they replaced. Moreover, as illustrated in Figure 9, the substitution of relatively lower-cost credit cards when compared to available alternatives is perfectly consistent with consumer rationality. Professor Mann does consider the substitution effect and generally finds that increases in credit card debt do not generate increases in overall consumer debt, a finding that is consistent with the substitution hypothesis, but not the distress hypothesis.173 It is also asserted that credit cards are uniquely prone to consumer irrationality and overspending. But this argument usually is not based on a comparison to the alternative types of consumer credit that they replaced, such as installment or “open book” store credit or even retail store credit cards, which were widely-owned in the 1970s and which were subject to identical criticisms in earlier generations.174 Professor White argues that credit cards are more prone to biases of “hyperbolic discounting” than installment credit.175 This hypothesis is possible—White provides no evidence to support it—but it is not particularly plausible. Why would a consumer be more prone to hyperbolic discounting bias when a purchase is made on a credit card with the full 172 See Bar-Gill, supra note 4. Bar-Gill offers no empirical support for his contentions and his theoretical model rests on some problematic assumptions. See Joshua D. Wright, Behavioral Law and Economics, Paternalism, and Consumer Contracts: An Empirical Perspective, 2 N.Y.U. J. LAW & LIBERTY 470, 48588 (2007). 173 See MANN, supra note 2, at 57, Table 4.3. 174 See discussion supra at note 47 and accompanying text. 175 White, supra note 2, at 181-82. 56 balance to appear on the statement and become due in full the next month as opposed to an installment loan where the full price of the loan is concealed in monthly payments that may stretch out over many months or even years, especially when the price of credit is obscured in the price of the goods?176 White argues that the difference is that the payments under installment loans are regularized, but if there is a question of hyperbolic discounting presumably it would be salient at the time the loan is made, not when it is repaid, especially when the payments are to be made two or three years into the future. Student loans, for instance, are installment loans but it would be difficult to argue that students anticipate the full cost of those loans more rationally than for credit cards. Moreover, unlike many installment loans, credit card loans can be easily refinanced for a better interest rate by switch balances to lower-rate cards. As a pure matter of theory, installment loans seem, if anything, more prone to hyperbolic discounting than credit cards. The realities of installment loans reinforce this conclusion. As previously noted, installment credit was criticized by contemporaries on precisely the same grounds that credit card credit is criticized today—that it led consumers into a treadmill of debt. The realities of consumer installment lending practices tended to reinforce this conclusion. By requiring monthly or even weekly repayment schedules, merchant installment lenders created multiple opportunities to interact with the customer. For example, Caplovitz observed that merchant lending contracts often required weekly payments which the 176 For instance, consumers are often unable to understand the full cost of traditional installment loans such as the APR and related terms. See JAMES M. LACKO & JANIS K. PAPPALARDO, FED. TRADE COMM’N., IMPROVING CONSUMER MORTGAGE DISCLOSURES: AN EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF CURRENT AND PROTOTYPE DISCLOSURE FORMS 35 (2007); Jinkook Lee and Jeanne M. Hogarth, The Price of Money: Consumers’ Understanding of APRs and Contract Interest Rates, 18 J. PUB. POL’Y AND MARKETING 66 (1999); Diane Hellwig, Comment, Exposing the Loansharks in Sheep’s Clothing: Why Re-Regulating the Consumer Credit Market Makes Economic Sense, 80 NOTRE DAME L. REV. 1567, 1591-92 (2005) (summarizing studies). 57 customer usually would bring to the store and pay in person. Caplovitz observes that this served several functions for the merchant.177 First, by dividing the repayment into weekly payments it rendered the actual payments relatively small, which helped “to create the illusion of ‘easy credit.” Although the concept of “hyperbolic discounting” had not been labeled at that time, Caplovitz argues that this structure of payments reflected that concept, because “Consumers are apt to think more of the size of the payments than of the cost of the item or the length of the contract.”178 Caplovitz also argues that those who shopped with installment credit had diminished levels of self-restraint and were less able to defer gratification than others.179 Caplovitz also notes that those repeated interactions also enables merchants to get to know their customers better, thereby making it easier to monitor changes in their risk profiles.180 But Caplovitz notes another implication of the installment system—each time the consumer would enter the store to make a payment that provided another opportunity for the merchant to sell additional items to the consumer, a transaction that is made that much easier because the customer is already in the store “where he can look at the merchandise.”181 As a result, critics of the installment system claimed that it tended to promote an endless cycle of debt by consumers, made all the easier by the way in which the merchant-customer interaction was structured. This is a completely different relationship from the merchant-customer relationship when credit cards are involved. As noted, complaints about the perceived irrationality or short-sightedness of “other consumers” is as ubiquitous as credit itself, whether the product was installment 177 DAVID CAPLOVITZ, THE POOR PAY MORE: CONSUMER PRACTICES OF LOW-INCOME FAMILIES 24 (1963). Id. 179 Id. at 118. 180 Id.at 24. 181 Id. at 25. 178 58 loans in mid-Twentieth Century America or credit cards today. Consumers today surely are at least as sophisticated at using and shopping for credit as in the past and the ubiquity of credit advertising has made informed shopping easier than ever.182 In fact, consumer behavior involving credit cards appears to be generally consistent with rational economic behavior. Revolvers are more aware of their interest rates and more likely to comparison shop among cards on that basis than others, and those who carry larger balances are even more likely to be aware of their interest rate and comparison shop on this term than those who revolve smaller balances.183 Revolvers are more likely than convenience users to read credit card solicitation material, and a larger proportion of revolvers said that they would apply for a card with a lower rate if it were offered, and the larger the outstanding balance the more likely the cardholder would be apply for a lower-rate card.184 Revolvers are more likely to hold a credit card with an annual fee but a lower interest rate than are transactional users.185 In fact, as illustrated above in Figure 9 and as others have found, this competition is so intense that credit card pricing today actually illustrates an inversion of interest rates—revolvers actually tend to have interest rates that are lower on 182 Johnson notes, for instance, that over the past decade credit card users have become less myopic in terms of their household financial planning. See Johnson, Transactions Demand, supra note 134, at 13-15. Moreover, as noted, increased competition among payday lenders tends to decrease the price of these loans, suggesting some degree of shopping behavior even among those borrowers. See supra note 77, and accompanying text. In a hyper-competitive environment such as the credit card environment, shopping is even easier for consumers. 183 See Thomas A. Durkin, Credit Card Disclosures, Solicitations, and Privacy Notices: Survey Results of Consumer Knowledge and Behavior, FEDERAL RESERVE BULLETIN p. A 109, 112-A115 (2006) (80% of revolvers examine APR frequently compared to 40% of transactors); Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 104-09; Randall J. Pozdena, Solving the Mystery of High Credit Card Rates, 42 FRBSF WEEKLY LETTER 2 (1991). 184 Durkin, supra note 183, at A117; Glenn B. Canner & Charles A. Luckett, Developments in the Pricing of Credit Card Services, 78 FED. RES. BULL. 652, 663 (1992); Paul Calem & Loretta Mester, Consumer Behavior and the Stickiness of Credit card Interest Rates, 85 FED. RES. BULLETIN 333 (1988); see also Darryl E. Getter, Consumer Credit Risk and Pricing, 40 J. CONSUMER AFFAIRS 41, 57-60 (2006); Sha Yang, Livia Markoczy, & Min Qi, Unrealistic Optimism in Consumer Credit Card Adoption, 28 J. ECON. PSYCH. 170, 177 (2007). 185 See Brown & Plache, supra note 20, at 79-80. 59 average than nonrevolvers.186 According to the Survey of Consumer Finances the median interest rate on the household credit card with the largest balance was 11.5 percent in 2004, a drop of 3.5% from 2001.187 Consumers also have become increasingly savvy about exploiting “teaser rate” offers by “card surfing” from one teaser rate card to the other.188 Those who do not revolve balances, by contrast, tend to focus on other terms of credit card contracts, such as the grace period for payment, benefits such as frequent flier miles, and whether there is an annual fee, just as standard economic theory would predict.189 There also is no evidence that borrowers systematically underestimate their likelihood of credit card borrowing or the cost of it.190 Most consumers choose the credit card plan that is most suitable for their needs and those who do not tend to learn fairly rapidly from their mistakes and switch to a more appropriate card, with those who made the biggest mistakes being the ones most likely to switch.191 In fact, with respect to credit cards empirical research indicates that where consumers err, they do so by overestimating their likelihood of revolving rather than underestimating.192 Consumers are less likely to 186 Brown & Plache, supra note 20; Howard Beales & Lacey L. Plache, Rationality, Revolving, and Rewards: An Analysis of Revolving Behavior on New Credit Cards, Working Paper (April 2007). 187 Daryl E. Getter, The Credit Card Market: Recent Trends, Funding Cost Issues, and Repricing Practices, CRS REPORT FOR CONGRESS 2-3 (Feb. 27, 2008). 188 See Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 107-08. 189 Durkin, supra note 183, at A112; Canner & Luckett, supra note 184. 190 Canner & Luckett, supra note 184 , at 665; Cargill & Wendel, supra note 115, at 386. 191 See Brown & Plache, supra note 20; Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Chunlin Liu, & Nicholas S. Souleles, Do Consumers Choose the Right Credit Contracts?, Fed. Res. Bank of Chicago Working Paper WP 2006-22 (Oct. 23, 2006); Sumit Agarwal, John C. Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, & David Laibson, Stimulus and Response: The Path from Naivete to Sophistication in the Credit Card Market, Working Paper (Aug. 20, 2006). This “learning” phenomenon has been observed with other consumer contracts as well. See Eugenio Miravete & Ignacio Palacios-Huerta, Rational Attention in a Repeated Decision Problem, Working Paper (Sept. 2004). 192 Agarwal, et al., find that consumers rarely erred in choosing the no-annual fee, higher interest rate cards, correctly predicting that they would not revolve. Instead, they disproportionately erred in choosing the high-fee, low-interest rate card, and then failing to revolve enough debt to justify the payment of the annual fee. Agarwal, et al., Do Consumers Choose, supra note 191, at 8-12. One study that purports to find an “unrealistic optimism” bias in credit card borrowing did not try to determine whether there is also 60 revolve on higher-APR credit cards and are more likely to revolve where they pay an annual fee in exchange for a lower interest rate.193 Those who pay no annual fee are the least likely to revolve balances, indicating that consumers are not stockpiling credit cards on which they are later induced to resolve balances.194 When a consumer obtains a new credit card, the primary predictor of whether she will revolve on that card is whether she revolved on the old card, suggesting that getting a new credit card does fundamentally change consumer behavior or “seduce” consumers into revolving. Moreover, a cardholder becomes less likely to revolve balances the longer they hold their card. In addition, consumers who hold rewards cards are less likely to revolve than those who do not, thereby suggesting that the promise of these rewards does not induce a borrower to short-sightedly “overconsume” and thereby unconsciously pile up debt. It is also asserted that credit cards are an “expensive” form of consumer credit. The basis for this claim is unclear, as those who assert it rarely state what alternatives they are comparing. This belief may be the residue of an older concern that credit card interest rates historically were “stickier” than other forms of consumer credit, in the sense that underlying changes in the cost of funds were not reflected in the interest rates on credit cards. This led some to conclude that there was a failure of competition in the credit card market that led to large economic profits for credit card issuers. 195 In fact, credit card interest rates were “stickier” in prior eras. But this was best explained by unrealistic pessimism or the relative frequency of optimism and pessimism bias. See Yang, et al., supra note 184. 193 Beales & Plache, supra note 186. 194 Beales & Plache, supra note 186. 195 Ausubel, Failure of Competition, supra note 4. 61 standard economic factors, not because of a failure of competition in the credit card industry or consumer irrationality.196 First, it is assumed that the interest rate is the only margin on which credit card issuers compete, so that changes in the cost of funds will be directly reflected in changes in credit card interest rates. But a majority of American households are transactional users who rarely or never revolve balances on their cards, and thus would prefer decreased fees, better customer service, or increased benefits such as frequent flyer miles rather than a cut in the interest rate.197 Second, credit cards have higher operating costs than other types of credit, including costs for activities such as ongoing customer support, account acquisition, dispute resolution services, fraud protection, account administration, and the administrative burden of processing a large number of relatively small transactions. For credit cards, the cost of funds are approximately 30-40% of total costs, with charge-offs amounting to as much as 30-40% and operating costs 20-30%.198 By contrast, the cost of funds account for 60 percent of total expenses for installment consumer lending, about 70 196 See Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 110-28 from which this discussion is drawn. See supra note 115; FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD, THE PROFITABILITY OF CREDIT CARD OPERATIONS OF DEPOSITORY INSTITUTIONS 3 (Aug. 1998); see discussion in Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 101-04. 198 Canner & Luckett, supra note 184, at 658; see also William F. Baxter, Section 85 of the National Bank Act and Consumer Welfare, 1995 UTAH L. REV. 1009, 1016 (1995) (“[T]he cost of funds for credit card lending comprises less than half, and possibly as little as one-quarter, of total costs (compared with sixty to eighty percent of total costs for other types of bank lending) . . . .”); Johnson, Recent Developments, supra note 161, at 477 n.7 (Autumn 2005) (citing reports in Credit Card News); GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE, CREDIT CARDS: INCREASED COMPLEXITY IN RATES AND FEES HEIGHTENS NEED FOR MORE EFFECTIVE DISCLOSURES TO CONSUMERS 100 (Sept. 2006) [“GAO REPORT”]. Average operating expenses for credit card lenders, as a percentage of total assets for banks, are over 9 percent versus 3.44 percent average for other consumer lenders. Id. at 101. The actual ratios depend primarily on the charge-off rate, which is higher during recessions. See EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 224. 197 62 percent for commercial lending, and nearly 80 percent for mortgage lending. 199 Thus, as a purely mathematical matter, credit card interest rates would be expected to be less responsive to a change in the cost of funds than other types of consumer credit because those costs comprise less of the final price. In fact, credit card interest rates traditionally were much less responsive to changes in cost-of-funds rates than other forms of consumer lending, such as personal loans, car loans, and mortgages, regardless of whether the cost of funds was rising or falling.200 Third, credit card loans are inherently riskier than other types of consumer credit. Charge-off rates are higher and thus comprise a larger percentage of credit card operations. Thus, when credit card charge-offs increase, the spread charged between the underlying cost of funds and the interest rate increases.201 The percentage of credit card charge-offs resulting from bankruptcy increased from 10 percent of all charge-offs in 199 Canner & Luckett, supra note 184, at 658; see also id. at 657; ALEXANDER RASKOVICH & LUKE FROEB, HAS COMPETITION FAILED IN THE CREDIT CARD MARKET? 5 (U.S. Dep’t of Justice, Economic Analysis Group Discussion Paper EAG 92-7, 1992). 200 See Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 111-19. This regularity is not unique to credit cards. Interest rates on small loans of shorter duration have always been higher than longer-term, higher-value loans, primarily because of the need to recoup the costs associated with granting and servicing the loan. Thus, credit card interest rates are no stickier than the rates on other consumer loans, once adjustments are made for differences in loan default rates. RASKOVICH & FROEB, supra note 199, at 6-11. Even in the Middle Ages the interest rates charged by pawnshops (including publicly endowed pawnshops) were much higher than interest rates charged on long-term loans secured by farms or estates. HOMER & SYLLA, supra note 9, at 424-25. See also HOMER & SYLLA, supra note 9, at 427; see also DeMuth, supra note 58, at 228; James M. Ackerman, Interest Rates and the Law: A History of Usury, 1981 ARIZ. ST. L.J. 61, 89 (1981) (”Administrative costs, however, are not directly related to loan size; it costs nearly as much to do the paper work on a $100 loan as on a $100,000 loan. . . . Thus, small loans are more costly to make and require a higher rate of interest.”). 201 See Adam B. Ashcraft, Astrid A. Dick, and Donald P. Morgan, The Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act: Means-Testing or Mean Spirited? Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank New York (Dec. 19, 2006). This cost-based stickiness was reinforced by consumer demand decisions that further reinforced this stickiness. When the cost of funds rate falls, interest rates on other types of consumer loans fall faster than interest rates on credit cards. This causes low-risk borrowers to substitute away from credit cards to these other types of loans, such as home equity loans. This leaves the remaining pool of credit card borrowers riskier than before, which leads to increased charge-offs, which dampens the downward trend in interest rates. Thus, for credit card lending, the charge-off rate will tend to be inversely related to the cost of funds rate. See RASKOVICH & FROEB, supra note 199, at 7-9. 63 1982 to 50 percent in 2002.202 Credit card debts also are more difficult to collect than other types of loans in the event of default.203 Almost all credit card debt is unsecured and given the small value of most credit card purchases and the consumptive nature of many of them (food, travel, and entertainment) it is simply not feasible for the credit to take a security interest in most of the things purchased with credit cards. Moreover, credit card issuers will have little ability to collect any judgment against the debtor,204 and at least prior to BAPCPA, credit card issuers collected little of their debt in bankruptcy.205 Moreover, because credit cards provide a standing line of credit that can be drawn upon at the debtor’s discretion, they present particularly difficult problems of moral hazard and adverse selection. Credit card issuers issue credit to a consumer based on the consumer’s financial condition at that time, and often a given consumer will be a very good risk at the time the card and the line of credit are issued. But consumers are most likely to draw on credit cards as a source of credit at precisely the moment where they receive a financial setback that causes them to switch from being low-risk to high-risk borrowers, such as job loss or an unexpected large liability. 206 This option for a debtor to be able to switch his risk profile at his option raises problems of moral hazard and adverse selection that appear to be more severe than for other types of credit.207 202 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 225. Canner & Luckett, supra note 184, at 657; EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at p. xi. 204 Although the credit card lender can use the threat of impaired credit ratings as an ex ante device to reduce the incentives for debtor misbehavior, threats to impair the credit rating of a borrower who has already defaulted does not assist in the actual recovery of outstanding balances. Pozdena, supra note 183, at 2. 205 Edith H. Jones & Todd J. Zywicki, It’s Time for Means-Testing, 1999 B.Y.U. L. REV. 177, 185-192 (summarizing studies). 206 Pozdena, supra note 183, at 2. 207 Mortgage or automobile lenders, for instance, use collateral to limit the threat of similar opportunism by debtors. 203 64 Nevertheless, despite the historic stickiness of credit card interest rates, beginning in the early-1990s credit cards in fact did become much more responsive to changes in the cost of funds. In the first quarter of 1991 credit card interest rates hit their all-time high of an average rate of 18.28%, but by the trough in the cost of funds rate in 2003 credit card interest rates fell to about 12%. The Federal Reserve further notes that in 1991 only 11 percent of responding banks reported interest rates below 16 percent on their largest credit card plans, but by 2005 80 percent did so.208 Moreover, changes in credit card interest rates have become much more closely correlated with changes in the underlying cost of funds.209 Evans and Schmalensee observe that credit card interest rates were about ten times more responsive to the cost of funds in the past decade than during the 1980s.210 What happened during this period to make credit cards more responsive to changes in general market conditions? First, the initial wave of post-Marquette competition led to the elimination of annual fees on credit cards and increased consumer benefits, rather than competition on interest rates. Annual fees disappeared quickly and today few standard cards charge them—ubiquitous before 1990 by 2002 only two percent of customers not enrolled in a 208 FED REPORT, supra note 6, at 7. For the period 1972-2006, the correlation coefficient between interest rates on 30-year mortgages and the cost of funds rate has been 0.865; the correlation coefficient between 48-month automobile loans and the federal funds rate has been 0.866. The correlation coefficient during that same period for interest rates on 24-month personal loans has been 0.727. By contrast, the correlation coefficient on credit cards loans during that period has been only 0.633. Beginning with the final quarter of 1994 to the present, the correlation coefficient on credit card interest rates and the cost of funds rate rose to 0.88, and for credit card accounts actually assessed interest, the correlation coefficient was even slightly higher. See also Johnson, Recent Developments, supra note 161, at p. 477 (noting that correlation between credit card interest rates and the prime rate was only 0.09 during the 1980s and early 1990s but has risen to 0.90 from mid-1990s to present). 210 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 239-40. 209 65 rewards program paid an annual fee.211 Annual fees are an especially unpopular form of credit card term pricing among consumers. A recent survey found that “no annual fee” was the most important term on which consumers selected credit cards—higher than any other single term, including the interest rate.212 The unpopularity of annual fees is evidenced by the fact that when annual fees were first imposed in 1980, consumers canceled over nine million bank cards that year, amounting to some 8% of the outstanding total.213 Because issuers were competing on annual fees because of their unpopularity with consumers, interest rate competition was minimal during this time, and interest rates remained relatively sticky. This led to a second wave of price innovation in credit cards—more aggressive competition on interest rates. At the same time, credit card issuers began to develop more sophisticated risk-assessment models that enabled them to more accurately offer interest rates more closely-tailored to different risk tranches. This heightened competition on interest rates eventually led to a gradual introduction of adjustable rate credit cards into the market, with the interest rate tied to a change in some underlying interest rate. In 1989, variable rate credit cards accounted for only about three percent of credit card accounts. By 1994 that share had grown to about 60 percent and by 2005 approximately 93 percent of cards had variable interest rates.214 Revolutionary changes in communications technology also have reduced the processing costs associated with credit card transactions. Electronic processing of credit card receipts supplanted 211 JONATHAN M. ORSZAG & SUSAN H. MANNING, AN ECONOMICS ASSESSMENT OF REGULATING CREDIT CARD FEES AND INTEREST RATES (Oct. 2007); Mark Furletti, Credit Card Pricing Developments and their Disclosure, FED. RES. BANK OF PHILADELPHIA DISCUSSION PAPER (Jan. 2003). 212 EVANS & SCHMALENSEE, supra note 33, at 218; see also Durkin, supra note 100, at 203 (95% of survey respondents report that amount of annual fee “very” or “somewhat important” compared to 91% for interest rate). 213 MANDELL, supra note 8, at 78. 214 GAO REPORT, supra note 198, at 15; Johnson, Recent Developments, supra note 161, 477-78 66 traditional paper receipts during this period, dramatically reducing the processing costs of transactions and loan servicing. Improvements in credit scoring and other individual risk assessment models may also have tended to permit greater tailoring of interest rates to actual risk, as rather than merely charging one interest rate to all borrowers it has become increasingly easy to discriminate among different borrowers based on risk characteristics. A third wave of credit card pricing innovation followed the adoption of variable interest rates, namely an increase in behavior-based pricing terms such as increased use of late fees, overdraft charges, and similar fees tailored to the borrower’s actual risk profile rather than relying solely on interest rates. Interest rates are one term that can be adjusted in light of borrower risk, but they are only an ex ante prediction of riskiness, thus they are an imperfect price term. Risk-based fees, by contrast, are based on the ex post level of observed behavior, thus ameliorating the extreme problems of adverse selection and moral hazard previously discussed.215 The only systematic empirical study of these fees to date concludes that these fees are risk-based and complement interest rates for efficient risk pricing.216 They find that a one standard deviation increase in bankruptcy per capita leads to an increase in penalty fees of $0.62 to $1.31. Similarly, a one standard deviation change in the chargeoff ratio was found to change late fees in a range of $4.35 to $7.57. In addition, they find that a 1 basis point reduction in card interest rates will result in an increase in penalty fees of between 0.88 and 4.11 cents. Thus, in their study, a one standard deviation in credit card interest rates (273 basis points) was estimated to change late fees by $2.40. Moreover, 215 See Testimony of Professor Todd J. Zywicki before United States House of Representatives, Financial Services Committee, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit, Hearing on “Credit Card Practices: Current Consumer and Regulatory Issues,” April 26, 2007. 216 See Nadia Massoud, Anthony Saunders, and Barry Scholnick, The Cost of Being Late: The Case of Credit Card Penalty Fees, working paper (January 2006); see also GAO REPORT, supra note 198, at 103. 67 they found no evidence that assessed penalties were larger for low-income borrowers, after controlling for risk. This use of more sophisticated and risk-based pricing techniques has made possible more flexible interest rates as well. In addition, consumers who pay these fees do not appear to be surprised by their existence, but generally are aware of them before they enter into the transaction that triggers the fee.217 The spread between credit card interest rates and the underlying cost of funds has narrowed over time as well, a trend that has accelerated in recent years as the combination of more flexible interest rates and greater use of risk-based behavioral fees has allowed credit card issuers to more accurately price risk.218 These behavior-based fees appear to be motivated by efficient risk pricing and are not simply a new form of consumer abuse. Return on assets for credit card banks have been largely constant over the past two decades, suggesting that the tradeoff between greater use of behavior-based fees and lower interest rates has not been driven by a desire to “fool” consumers with hidden fees that result in economic profits in the banking industry.219 Return on assets in the credit card industry have been stable even though 217 See Durkin, Credit Card Disclosures at p. A114. See Zywicki, Testimony, supra note 215; see also Getter, supra note 184. Block-Lieb and Janger argue that this narrowing of spreads during a period of rising bankruptcy filings evidences a failure of competition in the credit card market, as spreads should increase as bankruptcies increase. See Susan Block-Lieb & Edward J. Janger, The Myth of the Rational Borrower: Rationality, Behavioralism, and the Misguided “Reform” of Bankruptcy Law, 84 TEX. L. REV. 1481 (2006). But this analysis misses the point for several reasons. First, more sophisticated economic analysis has found a relationship between default rates on credit cards and the interest rate spread. See supra note 201, and accompanying text. Second, costs on other elements of credit card operations were declining, notably a drop in the cost of processing transactions because of advances in information technology, leading to a reduction in costs at the same time that bankruptcy losses were rising. Thus, Block-Lieb and Janger’s prediction would be correct only if all other costs remained constant. Third, as noted, there has been a change in price terms as credit card lenders have engaged in greater price discrimination such as imposing behavior-based fees on demonstrated riskier borrowers rather than using the crude instrument of interest rates. Thus, Block-Lieb and Janger’s observation is questionable both theoretically and empirically. See also Wright, supra note 172, at 485-88. 219 See Wright, supra note 172, at 476-77 (noting logical condition of a zero-profit equilibrium). 218 68 there has been a steady rise in the returns of other bank commercial and consumer lending activities during this period.220 Issuers have fundamentally changed their pricing models many times in the past 25 years: beginning with generally-assessed annual fees and high fixed interest rates, then to more risk-based but fixed interest rates, and finally to more flexible interest rates in combination with the use of behavior-based fees. Each of these pricing innovations appears to be more efficient risk-based pricing than the mix of terms they replaced. D. The Substitution Hypothesis of Credit Cards and Bankruptcy The best available evidence thus suggests that the growth in credit card debt over the past decades has been a substitution away from other types of consumer credit and that this dynamic holds equally for lower-income households as well as others. This result is tentative, of course, and the discussion in this article has relied primarily on broad macroeconomic data. Nonetheless, it appears that the substitution theory has the strongest explanatory power, both as an explanatory and empirical matter. But to observe that the substitution effect best explains the growth of credit card debt over time raises the subsequent question of how this translates into increased bankruptcy filings. In general, the rise in consumer bankruptcy filings resulted from three factors: changes in the economic costs and benefits of bankruptcy that provided increased incentives to file bankruptcy, changes in social norms that reduced the social 220 See GAO REPORT, supra note 198, at 76; ORSZAG & MANNING, supra note 211, at 29. For a discussion of the special difficulties in inferring credit card “profits” from the standard analysis of “return on assets” used in the banking industry, which is an accounting measure of profit not an economic measure, see Zywicki, The Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 128-46. Although the return on assets is not the same as economic profits, it is being used to examine trends over time not the absolute level of “profits” thus the constant return on assets in the consumer banking industry for credit card operations suggests an absence of economic profits as a result of shifting price terms over time. 69 opprobrium or “stigma” associated with filing bankruptcy, and changes in the nature of consumer credit toward more national and impersonal credit relations that increased the willingness of borrowers to file bankruptcy.221 Credit card substitution independently contributes to several of these three factors by explaining how increased use of credit cards can generate increased bankruptcy filings even holding total household debt burdens constant, so I will briefly focus on those particular factors here even though a more general discussion of the causes of the rise in bankruptcy filings goes beyond the scope of this article. First, in contrast to credit cards, many of the traditional types of credit that were replaced were secured debt or otherwise nondischargeable, such as pawn shops. Credit card debt, by contrast, is unsecured thus consumers can file bankruptcy and keep the goods and services purchased. Bankruptcy also will be of little use in dealing with informal loans, such as from friends and family, as the obligation to repay those debts is usually moral and extralegal rather than legal. This substitution of dischargeable unsecured debt for various forms of secured or de facto nondischargeable debt increases the benefit of filing bankruptcy. Moreover, the decline in credit card interest rates relative to other types of credit has permitted consumer to borrow (and thereby consume) more with a given amount of income and wealth, thus consumers have larger amounts of debt that they can discharge than in the past. Second, developments in consumer credit markets have made the negative consequences of filing bankruptcy may be less severe today than in the past. Traditionally it was perceived that filing bankruptcy would cripple the ability to acquire 221 See Todd J. Zywicki, Institutions, Incentives, and Consumer Bankruptcy Reform, 62 WASHINGTON & LEE L. REV. 1071 (2005). 70 new credit following bankruptcy. Today, however, there have been changes in credit markets that have made credit more available to former bankruptcy filers. One survey from the early 1990s found that over 16% of bankruptcy filers were able to gain unsecured credit within one year after filing bankruptcy and over 55% within five years.222 A survey from the late 1990s found that three-quarters of bankruptcy filers have at least one credit card within a year after filing223 and a more recent study also finds that most bankrupts can gain access to credit cards soon after filing bankruptcy.224 Bankruptcy filers are able to gain access to a broad cross-section of revolving credit as well as installment lenders.225 Filing under chapter 7 for bankruptcy creates a multi-year bar to refilling, making many bankruptcy filers lower-risk than those otherwise similarlysituated.226 This increase in competition not only reduces the negative effects of filing bankruptcy but also makes it more difficult for creditors to “ostracize” those who file bankruptcy. Creditors face a collective action problem in withholding credit from borrowers who file bankruptcy. Lenders may prefer as a group to ostracize borrowers who file bankruptcy, but in practice each lender has an individual incentive to lend to a debtor who files bankruptcy at the right price.227 Consistent with this collective action problem, bankruptcy filers who reacquire credit are more likely to obtain credit 222 See MICHAEL STATEN, THE IMPACT OF POST-BANKRUPTCY CREDIT ON THE NUMBER OF PERSONAL BANKRUPTCIES 10–11, (Credit Research Ctr., Krannert Graduate Sch. of Mgmt., Purdue Univ., Working Paper No. 58, 1993) (arguing that for various reasons this estimate probably underestimated access to credit at that time), available at http://www.msb.edu/prog/ crc/pdf/wp58.pdf. 223 VISA, CONSUMER BANKRUPTCY: ANNUAL BANKRUPTCY DEBTOR SURVEY (1997). 224 Katherine Porter, Bankrupt Profits: The Credit Industry’s Business Model for Postbankruptcy Lending, Working Paper (2007). 225 STATEN, supra note 222, at 11–12. 226 BAPCPA extends the bar period for refilling from six years to eight years. 227 This problem is exacerbated when the existing group cannot restrain entry by new lenders who can enter the market to serve those ostracized by incumbents. See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW § 8.5 (6th ed. 2003) (discussing the free-rider problem that can arise in the enforcement of social norms). 71 from a new lender rather than a prebankruptcy lender. 228 Moreover, barriers to entry are low in consumer credit markets, especially with the invention of nonbank finance companies, and, in recent years, the greatest amount of entry appears to have occurred in the subprime market, which specializes in lending to consumers with previous bankruptcies and tarnished credit.229 Moreover, credit and retail sales traditionally were tied together, such that a borrower who failed to pay his credit bills also would be unable to purchase goods on credit in the future. The unhooking of credit from goods sales means that consumers can be less concerned that filing bankruptcy will prevent them from obtaining necessary goods and services. Third, credit cards have made consumer credit relations less “personal” in nature, decreasing the sense of trust and moral obligations associated with paying debts. Consumer credit historically was a highly localized and personalized transaction, for example, a local department store or Main Street tailor selling goods to their customers on credit.230 Borrowers were often familiar with the owner of the lending store or bank in a personal and social setting. Where the credit relationship is embedded in a context of a social and economic relationship, it is more likely that a trust relationship will arise between the parties that will bring with it a moral obligation.231 Credit card transactions, by contrast, are conducted with large national banks and South Dakota and Delaware based credit card issuers such as Citibank and MBNA.232 228 Staten, supra note 222, at 12. Nor did it make a difference whether a debtor discharged his debts in Chapter 7 or filed Chapter 13 and presumably attempted to repay some of his pre-petition debts. Id. at 16. See also Porter, supra note 224. 229 Zywicki, Economics of Credit Cards, supra note 48, at 128–29. 230 See CALDER, supra note 11, at 37–42 (discussing the rise of retail credit). 231 Rafael Efrat, The Moral Appeal of Personal Bankruptcy, 20 WHITTIER L. REV. 141, 159 (1998). 232 See Jeremy Shearmur & Daniel B. Klein, Good Conduct in the Great Society: Adam Smith and the Role of Reputation, in REPUTATION: STUDIES IN THE VOLUNTARY ELICITATION OF GOOD CONDUCT 29 (Daniel B. Klein ed., 1997). 72 Impersonal credit relations, such as dealing with these institutional lenders, are less likely to evolve into high-trust relationships, and these weaker extralegal constraints make individuals more willing to breach those contractual promises.233 An individual is less likely to feel himself bound in a trust relationship with his credit card issuer than he would be if he purchased a suit on store credit from his local tailor, where he knows the owner and employees personally and thus will be more aware of the hardship imposed by a breach of trust by failure to pay his debt.234 Low-trust relationships such as between modern credit card issuers and consumers therefore are more prone to opportunism than high-trust relationships. Bankruptcy filers acknowledge that although they generally feel guilty about not being able to pay their debt to their creditors, “many had less guilt feelings about not paying large creditors or creditors they did not know personally.”235 Indeed, as David Skeel observes, part of the impetus for the 1898 Bankruptcy Act was the concern of merchants who engaged in interstate commerce that when debtors ran into financial trouble they “played favorites” with their creditors, preferring “family members and local creditors, not the out-of-state merchants.”236 There is also a widely-shared impression that there has been a change in social norms regarding bankruptcy such that bankruptcy has become a less shameful act, which also would reduce the social sanction and disincentive for filing. 237 233 For Efrat, supra note 231, at 159. Efrat, supra note 231, at 159. This same analysis could apply to the development of trust relationships by creditors, but the primary constraint on lender opportunism are contracts and other more formal institutions, including legislation and regulation, as well as repeat-dealing and reputation effects, thus trust seems much less relevant on the lender’s side of the transaction. 235 Rafael Efrat, The Evolution of Bankruptcy Stigma, 7 THEORETICAL INQUIRIES IN LAW 365 (2006) (citing VISA, QUALITATIVE RESEARCH: BANKRUPTCY PROCESS 9 (1997)). 236 DAVID A. SKEEL, JR., DEBT’S DOMINION: A HISTORY OF BANKRUPTCY LAW IN AMERICA 36 (2001). 237 See Rafael Efrat, Bankruptcy Stigma: Plausible Causes for Shifting Norms, 22 EMORY BANKRUPTCY DEVELOPMENTS J. 481, 485-89 (2006). But see Teresa A. Sullivan, Elizabeth Warren, & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, Less Stigma or More Financial Distress: An Empirical Analysis of the Extraordinary Increase 234 73 instance, a 1960s study found almost 25% of petitioners felt ashamed about filing bankruptcy,238 a figure that fell to 10% in a 1995 survey 239. This decline in stigma regarding bankruptcy is consistent with broader social trends since the 1960s that have tended to shift blame for individual failure away from personal responsibility to environmental factors 240 as well as a variety of other bankruptcy-specific factors, such as the decision in the 1978 Code to replace the traditional pejorative term “bankrupt” with the more neutral term “debtor... as a means of reducing the stigma connected with the term bankrupt.”241 Bankruptcy attorneys may also have played a role in changing norms about bankruptcy, especially with respect to credit cards. In general, debtors’ attorneys seem to be somewhat more hostile toward creditors than are their clients and are especially dismissive of the belief that there is a moral, as opposed to purely legal, obligation to repay creditors, especially institutional lenders such as credit card issuers. One lawyer observed, “Some people feel there is a moral issue; frankly I don’t.”242 Another lawyer stated, “My attitude is—the law is there. The credit card companies charge 20% interest. Discharge is a risk of doing business. I don’t feel bad about it. Some debtors feel so harassed. Some debtors say they feel bad about discharging debt, and I wonder if they do. Some are overly emotional, and I’m thinking, ‘What’s the big deal?’ Especially with in Bankruptcy Filings, 59 STANFORD L. REV. 213 (2006) (concluding that there has been no measurable decline in social stigma associated with bankruptcy), compare TERESA A. SULLIVAN, ELIZABETH WARREN & JAY WESTBROOK, AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS: BANKRUPTCY & CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA 337 (1989) (suggesting that a decline in social stigma might explain rising bankruptcy filing rates). 238 See DAVID T. STANLEY & MARJORIE GIRTH, BANKRUPTCY: PROBLEM, PROCESS, REFORM 67-68 (1971). 239 Tahira K. Hire & Kyle L. Kostelecky, Pilot Study of Consumer Debtors Provides New Insight—What Influences Debtors’ Attitudes? 14 AM. BANKR. INST. J., Apr. 1995, at 28, 36, available at 14-APR AMBKRIJ1 (Westlaw). 240 See Efrat, supra note 235, at 490. 241 S. REP. NO. 95-589, at 23 (1978), as reprinted in 1978 U.S.C.C.A.N. 5787, 5809. 242 Jean Braucher, Lawyers and Consumer Bankruptcy: One Code, Many Cultures, 67 AM. BANKR. L.J. 501, 523 (1993). 74 credit cards—it’s not like a friend or a relative.”243 Many attorneys persuade clients that the sacrifices required to repay debts will impose an undue hardship on their families, and thus discharge of debts is morally appropriate.244 IV. The Distress Model There is little doubt that some consumers overborrow on credit cards and as a result are forced into filing bankruptcy, just as some members of earlier generations overused installment credit or pawnbrokers. In this sense, there is nothing inherently new about credit cards—they are simply another type of consumer credit that the overwhelming number of consumers use responsibly and to improve their lives, but some percentage of consumers overuse. For the distress model to be able to explain the rise in bankruptcy filings over the past 25 years, therefore, it must be demonstrated that greater use of and more widespread access to credit cards has created some new systematic tendency for consumer overindebtedness relative to prior eras. But, as noted, increased access to and use of credit cards is not reflected in an increase in household debt service burdens and thus the factual predicate seems to be absent. In general, expositors of the distress theory of credit cards have failed to address two important threshold issues. First, they generally have been silent or unaware of any substitution effect, thus they have provided no explanation for why credit cards are a unique contributor to consumer financial distress. White cites the dramatic rise in credit card use over the past two decades245 as does Sullivan, et al.246 but neither mentions the 243 Id. Id. at 509. 245 White, supra note 2. 244 75 offsetting decline in installment debt. Moss and Johnson simply assert that the rise in consumer bankruptcies has been driven by increased credit card lending to lower-income and riskier borrowers, but do not consider the substitution effect.247 A second problem with prior studies is that they generally assert—but do not demonstrate—that any correlation between credit card debt (or credit card defaults) and bankruptcy is caused by increased financial distress. Ausubel, for instance, finds a correlation between credit card defaults and bankruptcy and assumes that the credit card defaults cause the subsequent bankruptcy, or alternatively that the credit card defaults evidence underlying financial distress caused by excessive credit card debt that then causes the subsequent bankruptcy.248 A study of trends in credit cards and bankruptcy in Canada similarly asserts the direction of causation and thus suffers from similar flaws.249 Both the substitution model and the distress model are consistent with the observed correlation between credit card debt and bankruptcy. Given that the direction of causation is indeterminate as an a priori matter, the causal relationship between credit cards and bankruptcies must be demonstrated, not merely assumed. Establishing a causal Sullivan, et al., observe that “credit card usage has grown fastest in recent years among debtors with the lowest incomes,” but do not make any mention of whether this increased credit card usage has resulted from a decrease in the usage of other types of consumer credit. See SULLIVAN, ET AL., FRAGILE, supra note 2, at 136. They do not ask, for instance, whether retailers or personal finance companies were previously servicing these consumers. As noted above their own data strongly indicates the presence of a substitution effect from other types of consumer credit. See supra at Figure 4. 247 David A. Moss & Gibbs A. Johnson, The Rise of Consumer Bankruptcy: Evolution, Revolution, or Both?, 73 AM. BANKR. L.J. 311, 314 (1999). Moss and Johnson acknowledge that bankruptcies have increased more rapidly than consumer indebtedness in recent years and simply assume—but do not demonstrate—that this acceleration in the so-called multiplier effect between debt and bankruptcy is caused by an increase in credit card lending to higher-risk borrowers. They offer no support for this assertion. The finding of an increased multiplier effect is consistent with the substitution hypothesis. 248 Ausubel, supra note 111. Ausubel also notes that credit card defaults are closely correlated with the business cycle. Ausubel, supra note 111, at 253. But there is actually an inverse relationship between credit card borrowing and unemployment rates—consumers are actually less likely to revolve credit card balances when they suffer unemployment, thus the likelihood of default as a result of unemployment is not preceded by an increase in indebtedness. See Beales & Plache, supra note 193. 249 Dianne Ellis, The Effect of Consumer Interest Rate Deregulation on Credit Card Volumes, Charge-Offs, and the Personal Bankruptcy Rate, BANK TRENDS (Pub. Info. Ctr,, Fed. Deposit Ins. Corp., Washington, D.C.), Mar. 1998, at 1, available at http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/bank/bt_9805.html. 246 76 link is difficult because of the endogenous nature of the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy. Although higher levels of credit card debt may cause higher levels of bankruptcy filings, more liberal bankruptcy laws increase the willingness of debtors to borrow, and to borrow on unsecured debt such as credit cards in particular.250 The relative ease with which a debtor anticipates that she can discharge debt ex post in part causes the level of borrowing ex ante. To establish the distress model it is necessary to control for this problem of endogeneity in determining the nature of the causal relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcy. The only scholar to acknowledge and try to address the problems of endogeneity and the substitution effect is Professor Ronald Mann. Mann claims to find a strong causal relationship between credit card debt and personal bankruptcy at the macroeconomic level, thereby supposedly demonstrating the validity of the distress model.251 Mann collected annual cross-sectional data on credit card debt, credit card spending, consumer debt, and consumer bankruptcy for 12 or 13 years for five countries—Australia, Canada, Japan, United Kingdom, and the United States. He then ran ordinary least squares regressions to test various relationships among the data. Mann concludes that his statistical analysis demonstrates the validity of the distress model of credit cards. In fact, however, there are several major problems with Mann’s statistical analysis as well as his interpretation of his own findings. Although he claims to have established a causal relationship, and not merely correlation, he has failed to do so. And, of course, a “softer” bankruptcy regime makes lenders less likely to extend unsecured credit, so the overall equilibrium level of borrowing is ambiguous as an a priori matter. In this sense, the tradeoff involving the rigor of the bankruptcy regime is identical to that regarding contract enforcement generally, with the only difference being that contract rules govern the enforceability of contracts ex ante whereas bankruptcy laws govern the option to nullify a contract ex post. See Charles Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Enforcing Promises: An Examination of the Basis of Contract, 89 YALE L.J. 1261 (1980). 251 MANN, supra note 2. 250 77 Indeed, to the extent that any supportable conclusions can be drawn from his data set and statistical analysis, his findings actually tend to support the substitution model rather than the distress model. Mann acknowledges the endogeneity problem and his study is specifically designed to try to address it. Mann’s proffered solution is to test the relationship between credit card debt (CCD) lagged by one, two, or three years, and bankruptcy filings (BKR). When Mann performs these regressions, he finds a statistically significant relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcies, both in the same period, but also when lagged for each of the three periods.252 Mann asserts that lagging the CCD variable solves the endogeneity problem, thereby enabling him to draw inferences about the causal direction of the relationship between CCD and bankruptcies. But lagging the observations on CCD in this data set does not solve the problem of endogeneity in his data.253 To understand why not, consider the following exercise. To test whether lagging CCD establishes a determinate relationship on the direction of causation to BKR, I used Mann’s same data set and simply reversed the hypothesized statistical relationship, specifying BKR as the independent variable and CCD as the dependent variable lagged by one, two, and three years. If it is true that regressing lagged CCD against bankruptcies solves the endogeneity problem as a statistical matter, then it should not be possible to reverse the equation and get meaningful results. The results are presented in Table 1: Table 1: Bankruptcy and Credit Card Debt 252 MANN, supra note 2, at 70, Table 5.1. Several of the theoretical and empirical problems with Mann’s analysis are discussed in Wright, supra note 172, at 489-91. For instance, Wright notes that the data itself is merely a scatterplot of 65 observations—as if each point is a separate country—and is neither a panel regression of country-level data nor a country-specific time series. Id. So it is not clear what it means to impose a “lag” with this data. 253 78 Coeff CONSTANT N R2 *** p<0.001 No LAG 0.492*** (.024) -(191.210) 62 .87 LAG1 0.513*** (.025) -(182.750) 59 .87 LAG2 0.533*** (.027) -(172.42) 54 .87 LAG3 0.557*** (.029) -(162.96) 49 .87 As can be seen in Table 1 regressing bankruptcies (lagged 1, 2, and 3 years) on credit card debt consistently produces strongly statistically significant results. Moreover, the rsquared values for these regressions are virtually identical to the r-squared values in Mann’s reported regressions. In other words, if it is true that simply “lagging” the independent variable (in this case bankruptcy filings) solves the endogeneity problem as a statistical matter, then Table 1 demonstrates that bankruptcy filings “cause” subsequent credit card indebtedness one, two, and three years later with an increasing causal effect as the lag increases.254 The explanation for this incongruous finding is obvious— contemporaneous and lagged credit card debt are collinear (as are contemporaneous and lagged bankruptcies), thus adding a lag does not resolve the problem.255 I should stress that Table 1 should not be read to suggest that an increase in bankruptcies “causes” increases in credit card debt one, two, or three years later, but rather to demonstrate the statistical point that the endogeneity problem in the credit card-bankruptcy relationship by asserting CCD to be independent and attaching lags to assumed independent variables. As a statistical matter, both Professor Mann’s results and those in Table 1 are equally valid—or invalid—in establishing the direction of causation.256 254 This is how Professor Mann interprets his analogous findings. See MANN, supra note 2, at 64-65. The correlation coefficient among CCD, d1CCD, d2CCD, and d3CCD with one another is 0.99 256 Professor Mann suggests that the endogeneity issue can be resolved as a matter of a priori logic. See MANN, supra note 2, at 68. But it is precisely because a priori reasoning cannot resolve the endogeniety problem that it must be addressed statistically, not logically. 255 79 Professor Mann’s approach illustrates the well-known post hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy in economics.257 Simply because one observation in a data series comes prior to a later observation does not mean that the earlier observation causes the later. Where expectations about future events are incorporated into today’s actions—a concept known as “rational expectations” in economics—merely lagging the variable that is asserted to be independent will not solve the endogeneity problem because it actually is not independent.258 So if borrowers incorporate their expected willingness to file bankruptcy in the future into their borrowing decisions today, the level of debt will still be endogenous to the subsequent bankruptcy decision. Consider an example to illustrate the fallacy. BAPCPA was signed into law in April 2005 but most of its provisions did not become effective until October 17, 2005. In the two weeks preceding BAPCPA’s effective date, roughly 500,000 Americans filed bankruptcy, including 350,000 in the week before the effective date alone, over 10 times the typical weekly filing rate. If one were simply to lag bankruptcy filings by one or two weeks preceding BAPCPA then one would infer that this spike in bankruptcy filings “caused” BAPCPA, when of course, causation ran in the exact opposite direction— bankruptcy filings rose because it was anticipated that BAPCPA was about to become 257 James Tobin, Money and Income: Post Hoc Ergo Propter Hoc?, 84 Q. J. ECON. 301, 302–03 (1970). The phrase literally translates as “after this, therefore because of this.” It “assumes or asserts that if one event happens after another, then the first must be the cause of the second.” As one commenter observes, it “is a particularly tempting error because temporal sequence appears to be integral to causality. The fallacy lies in coming to a conclusion based solely on the order of events, rather than taking into account other factors that might rule out the connection.” Post hoc ergo propter hoc, WIKIPEDIA, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Post_hoc_ergo_propter_hoc (visited August 21, 2007). 258 See Thomas J. Sargent, Rational Expectations, in THE CONCISE ENCYCLOPEDIA OF ECONOMICS, available in http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/RationalExpectations.html. 80 effective. Thus, even though BAPCPA temporally came subsequent to the filing wave, it seems quite clear that BAPCPA nonetheless caused the prior filing spike.259 In addition to these methodological issues there are problems with Mann’s interpretation of his results in that there are almost certainly relevant variables omitted from his regression and the failure to account for them causes spurious statistical results. In particular, both credit card debt and bankruptcy may be correlated with one another or are both causally endogenous to some other variable or variables. The presence of omitted variables might explain, for instance, why the regressions can be specified with either bankruptcies or credit card debt as the dependent variable and still generate statistically significant results. Further evidence of the probable presence of omitted variable bias is the very large coefficient values on the constants in his regressions and the unusually high r-squared value generated in these extremely simple linear regressions with only 13 observations from five different countries with such variable borrowing and bankruptcy patterns.260 An examination of the data reveals that one source of omitted variable bias is a simple upward trend line that may be a proxy for some omitted variable that is correlated with both bankruptcies and the various consumer credit variables, such as income.261 To consider the possibility of an omitted trend variable, using Mann’s data I ran regressions using YEAR as the independent variable, first with levels of credit card debt (CCD) then with bankruptcy levels (BKR) as the dependent variable. In both regressions YEAR 259 Nor is this just randomness or irrational panic by consumers One study of the effects of BAPCPA observed that no similar filing wave preceded the enactment of the 1978 bankruptcy code, suggesting that consumers rationally (and correctly) perceived that the 1978 law would make it easier to file bankruptcy. See Ashcraft, et al., supra note 201. 260 See Wright, supra note 172, at 490. 261 Japan appears somewhat anomalous compared to the other countries in Mann’s data set as both consumer credit and credit card debt rise over the first half of the period under examination and then fall steadily afterwards, yet bankruptcies rise throughout the entire period. 81 turned out to be statistically significant at the 95% level of confidence, suggesting the possible presence of some exogenous trend variable that has caused both CCD and BKR to increase over time. A second possible source of omitted variable bias is the presence of countryspecific factors that may be causing particular relationships between CCD and BKR, such as differences in the countries’ respective bankruptcy regimes, consumer credit policies, or cultural attitudes regarding debt and bankruptcy. To test for this using Mann’s data, I ran a regression with only the country dummy variables as the independent variable and BKR as the dependent variable. Each country dummy variable was extremely significant at the 0.000 level with an r-squared value of 0.8786. In short, a regression that uses only country dummy variables and excludes all of Mann’s consumer credit variables produces a high degree of statistical significance and an r-squared value virtually identical to the rsquared value he found in his regression of CCD on BKR. I then combined these two possible sources of omitted variable bias into a regression that specified just these two variables—YEAR and the country dummy variables—as the independent variables and BKR as the dependent variable (and excluded all consumer credit variables). Under this specification, all of the country dummies remain significant at the 0.000 level, YEAR is borderline significant at the 0.059 level, and the r-squared value is 0.9382. In short, accounting for only the upward trend lines in the data and country dummy variables, and omitting every consumer credit variable from the regression, the r-squared value is substantially higher than Mann finds for his linear regressions on CCD and approximates that of his most extensive regression. I then added the country GDP variable (included in Mann’s data) to the regression and 82 ran it again omitting all consumer credit variables. The r-squared value was 0.9425. The country dummy variables all remained statistically significant at a 0.000 level of significance, YEAR was equally significant, and GDP was statistically significant at the .01 level of significance. I took the simple model with a time trend (YEAR) and country dummy variables and added in CCD. Under this specification of the model, the r-squared value is 0.9503, but all of the independent variables are statistically insignificant, including CCD. I then added to this same regression GDP—regressing YEAR, country dummies, CCD, and GDP as independent variables and BKR as the dependent variable—and somewhat surprisingly, GDP returned a statistically significant value (at the .01 level) although the other variables—including CCD—remained statistically insignificant.262 In other words, after controlling for a trend line and country differences, CCD becomes statistically insignificant when added to the regression. Again, I wish to stress that this discussion should not be interpreted to suggest that it disproves the hypothesis that increases in credit card debt leads to increases in bankruptcy filings or proves that country-specific or GDP variables predict changes in 262 Mann does not report this particular regression in his book. In Table 5.5, he reports a similar regression with all three consumer credit variables—CCD, level of credit card spending (CCS), and level of consumer debt (COND). He finds borderline significance for CCD in that regression. This result seems to be an artifact of a curious and unexplained relationship between CCS and CCD in his data. When CCS and CCD are run separately, they consistently generate positive and significant results on bankruptcies. When they are run together in the same regression, the sign on CCS switches to negative and borderline significance and CCD remains positive and significant. As noted, running CCD without CCS in the regressions with country dummies and macroeconomic variables results in CCD being statistically insignificant. It is only when CCS is included in the regression, with its peculiar negative coefficient, that CCD becomes statistically significant. There may be multicollinearity in the data between those two variables that is creating a spurious significance for CCD when they are run together, e..g, the negative coefficient on CCS increases the positive coefficient on CCD. Mann reports variance inflation factor (VIF) values with mean values of approximately 6 and an examination of the data indicates maximum VIF values in a similar range. Statistics books indicate that a “rule of thumb” is that multicollinearity is present when the mean VIF value exceeds unity or the maximum VIF exceeds 10. See CHRISTOPHER F. BAUM, AN INTRODUCTION TO MODERN ECONOMETRICS USING STATA 85 (2006). 83 bankruptcy filing rates, but to recognize that the data set and simple linear regression techniques that Professor Mann uses simply cannot establish the statistical relationships that he is seeking.263 Mann’s conclusion that his empirical analysis demonstrates a determinate causal relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcy appears to be a a spurious result caused by one or more omitted variables. But in addition to these statistical problems there is also a logical difficulty in Mann’s interpretation of his findings. Mann finds that “[even if] credit card spending and consumer debt are held constant, an increase in credit card debt—a shift of consumer borrowing from noncard borrowing to card borrowing—is associated with an increase in bankruptcy filings.”264 From which he concludes, “[T]he data… bear out the idea that credit cards are unique contributors to the overindebtedness problem, an idea that is inconsistent with the view that credit cards merely substitute for other less efficient forms of consumer lending. The data indicate that credit card debt correlates with subsequent increases in consumer bankruptcy, even when overall borrowing is held constant.”265 But this conclusion simply misinterprets the statistical findings. If consumer debt is being held constant, then by definition increased indebtedness cannot explain the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy. In fact, in some of the more extensive forms of his regressions Mann finds no statistically significant correlation between credit card debt and consumer indebtedness, but only between credit cards and bankruptcy directly—a finding that, if true, actually supports the substitution theory not the distress theory.266 263 See Wright, supra note 172, at 491. One conventional solution to the simultaneity problems here would be to use an instrumental variable estimator instead of simple linear techniques. See id. at 490 n.64. 264 MANN, supra note 2, at 66 & 71 Table 5.3. 265 MANN, supra note 2, at 182 (emphasis added). 266 MANN, supra note 2, at 57 Table 4.3. Again, it should be cautioned that both the limitations of the data set itself as well as the crude linear regression techniques that are used suggest extreme caution in interpreting the results. Indeed, this caveat is especially appropriate here, as at one point Mann finds the 84 Despite the widespread acceptance by legal scholars of the distress model of the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy, there is no solid evidence to support the purported causal relationship. Most adherents have failed to address or even acknowledge the substitution effect or the problem of endogeneity and the one effort addressed to those problems fails to deal with them effectively, and the only effort that does actually ends up supporting the substitution theory to the extent that it establishes statistically valid results at all. V. Strategic Model A third hypothesis to explain the observed correlation between credit cards and bankruptcy is the strategic model or the “loading up” hypothesis.267 The strategic model is essentially the inverse of the distress model—rather than excessive credit card debt causing a subsequent rise in bankruptcy filings the strategic model argues that credit card debt rises in anticipation of an anticipated bankruptcy filing. Strategic behavior involving credit cards may manifest itself in three ways. First, debtors will have an incentive to “load up” their credit card on the eve of bankruptcy, especially by purchasing goods and services that can be consumed or retained in coefficient on the relationship between lagged credit card spending and bankruptcies to be negative (and significant at the 0.10 level on a two-year lag) which would suggest that an increase in credit card spending causes a reduction in bankruptcy filings two years later. Professor Mann avoids this absurd conclusion by quite sensibly noting that this finding probably reflects consumer expectations about economic conditions that lead them to spend more when they are optimistic about their economic situation. MANN, supra note 2, at 67. But applying a rational expectations interpretation to explain this particular anomaly undercuts his entire methodological approach of assuming that a lag cures the endogeneity problem without reference to expectations. 267 See Carol C. Bertaut & Michael Haliassos, Credit Cards: Fact and Theories, in THE ECONOMICS OF CONSUMER CREDIT (Giuseppe Bertola, Richard Disney, and Charles Grant eds., Forthcoming 2007) (surveying theoretical and empirical literature). 85 bankruptcy.268 Credit cards are an open line of credit that can be drawn against at the borrower’s discretion and that generally can be discharged in bankruptcy. By contrast, some unsecured debts are not dischargeable in bankruptcy,269 and secured debts, such as home and auto loans are minimally affected. Second, a debtor who is unable to pay all of his bills can consciously choose which of his many debts to pay in the pre-bankruptcy period, and specifically can choose to pay secured or nondischargeable debts while electing to allow dischargeable debts, such as credit card debt, to go unpaid. Third, a debtor can increase the value of her exempt assets (such as increasing exempt equity in her home) rather than pay outstanding credit card bills.270 Regardless of the scenario, a core prediction of the strategic model is that an increase in credit card debt will occur in the pre-bankruptcy period. Some behavior involving credit cards and bankruptcy can be explained by strategic behavior. Gross and Souleles, for example, find that in the year before bankruptcy borrowers significantly increase the use of their credit cards versus earlier periods, running up their balances rapidly in the period leading up to bankruptcy. 271 This finding is inconsistent with those who identify credit cards as presenting a special problem for consumers because of the gradual, subconscious, and “insidious” manner in 11 U.S.C. §523(a)(3) creates a presumption of nondischargeability incurred for the purchase of “luxury goods and services” above a certain threshold within a certain number of days preceding a bankruptcy filing. Debts incurred for non-luxury goods and services are unaffected, of course, as are even those charges incurred for luxury goods outside of the 90 day window (70 days for cash advances). In one notable example a debtor charged several discretionary car repairs and purchase new tires a few weeks before filing bankruptcy then discharged the credit card debts in bankruptcy. See Manuel Perez-Rivas & Martin Weil, Massie Filed for Bankruptcy; Montgomery Schools Halt Consideration of Finalist, WASH. POST, May 4, 1999, at A1; Bernard Dagenais, Bankruptcy: Not Quite a Free Ride, WASH. TIMES, May 10, 1999, at D3. Although the timing of the repairs plainly was strategic it was nonetheless dischargeable. 269 See 11 U.S.C. §523(a). This includes debts for things such as taxes, alimony and child support, fraudulently-induced debts, student loans, and others. 270 See ANDREAS LEHNERT & DEAN M. MAKI, CONSUMPTION, DEBT, AND PORTFOLIO CHOICE: TESTING THE EFFECT OF BANKRUPTCY LAW, at 33 (Fed. Res. Bd., Working Paper No. 2002-14, 2002). Conversion of nonexempt assets to exempt assets is generally permissible under the Bankruptcy Code. 271 Gross & Souleles, supra note 112, at 338. 268 86 which credit card debt purportedly accumulates over time.272 That the rise in credit card debt is rapid and concentrated in the period immediately preceding bankruptcy suggests that credit card indebtedness does not cause bankruptcy in some cases, but that the debtor is already on the way toward bankruptcy when the credit card borrowing begins, and is either acting strategically or is tapping her credit line of last resort.273 Andreas Lehnert and Dean Maki also find some evidence to support the strategic model, concluding that generous bankruptcy exemptions tend to lead to increased statelevel bankruptcy filing rates but also to a greater tendency of households to simultaneously hold more low-return liquid assets and to owe high-cost unsecured debt, such as credit cards.274 This suggests that these households could pay down some of their credit card debt but choose not to and, absent the ability to file bankruptcy it would be rational to use some of their low-return savings to reduce their high-cost debt obligations. With bankruptcy as an option, however, consumers can retain their assets through exemptions while discharging their unsecured debt, thereby providing an incentive to make the strategic decision to simultaneously carry both more assets and more unsecured debt, as the strategic model would predict. In fact, households in states with higher exemptions are more likely to simultaneously hold liquid assets and higher unsecured debt. Paula Lopes similarly finds that some consumers borrow strategically with the 272 See supra note 3 and accompanying text. The conclusion that the debtor is acting strategically is, of course, subject to an endogeneity critique as well, as the debtor may be taking on credit card debt to try to avoid filing bankruptcy. If this is the case, then the relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcy is spurious, in that it suggests that the debtor was heading toward bankruptcy as a result of other factors and that the ability to borrow on credit cards simply temporarily postponed the inevitable bankruptcy filing but did not cause it. 274 Andreas Lehnert and Dean M. Maki, Consumption, Debt and Portfolio Choice: Testing the Effect of Bankruptcy Law, working paper (Feb. 20, 2002). 273 87 intention of defaulting in the near future and that their likelihood of strategic borrowing depends on the relative generosity of exemptions.275 Ning Zhu also finds support for the strategic model of credit card use.276 He finds that bankruptcy filers exhibit consumption patterns similar to those who do not file bankruptcy, but that the pattern of credit use for bankruptcy filers differs from that of non-bankruptcy filers. Twenty-six percent of the debt reported by bankrupt households is credit card debt as compared to 15% for non-bankrupt households. By contrast, only 5% of the credit for bankrupt households is bank credit versus 21% for non-bankrupt households.277 This suggests that even though there has been a general substitution of credit card credit for bank credit among American households, this substitution has been greater for those households that file bankruptcy than for others.278 This may reflect a strategic decision on the part of bankrupt households to make greater use of credit card credit in anticipation of bankruptcy. Moreover, Zhu finds that the median mortgage debt for bankrupt and non-bankrupt households is similar as are their median house values. Some general data also support the strategic model. For instance, although credit card defaults have risen in tandem with bankruptcy filings,279 defaults on secured home and auto loans remained steady during most of this period.280 In fact, over the past 25 years, the general trend on chargeoffs on credit card loans has been upward over time; by contrast, the charge-off rate on residential real estate (mortgages and home equity lines of 275 Paula Lopes, Credit Card Debt and Default over the Life Cycle, Working Paper, Financial Markets Group, London School of Economics (2003). 276 Ning Zhu, Household Consumption and Personal Bankruptcy, working paper (Feb. 2007). 277 Id. at 16. 278 See also SULLIVAN, ET AL., FRAGILE, supra note 2, at 120. Zhu interprets these findings as supporting the strategic model, but they also could be consistent with the substitution model if it is simply the result of decisions to substitute credit card debt for other debt in light of an absence of attractive alternatives. 279 See Ausubel, supra note 111, at 249. 280 See Durkin, Discussion, supra note 132, at 38-39. 88 credit) have generally trended downward, even with the recent rise in chargeoffs in the residential real estate market, as shown in Figure 10: Figure 10 9 0.5 0.45 0.4 0.35 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 8 Credit Cards 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Credit Card Mortgage 20 07 Q1 20 05 Q1 20 03 Q1 20 01 Q1 19 99 Q1 19 97 Q1 19 95 Q1 19 93 Q1 19 91 Q1 0 Mortgages Chargeoffs Trends: Credit Cards v. Mortgages Year Source: Federal Reserve. Figure 10 identifies trends in charge-off rates for residential real estate on one hand and credit card loans on the other.281 As is seen, until the mid-1990s, the charge-off rates on the two types of loans tended to move in tandem. During the period of rapidly rising bankruptcies in the mid to late-1990s, however, the charge-off rate on credit card loans rose dramatically, even as the charge-off rate on residential real estate loans declined. If households were filing bankruptcy because of economic distress they presumably would be unable to pay both credit card loans and mortgages, and thus charge-off rates should move in tandem with one another. 281 Linear trendlines have been added for clarity. 89 Instead, the trends are observed to be moving in opposite directions, suggesting that consumers have become more likely to default on credit card loans than on residential real estate loans. One plausible explanation for these divergent trends is that, when forced to choose, stressed consumers have consciously chosen to pay their secured mortgages rather than their dischargeable unsecured credit card debts in the pre-bankruptcy period. Moreover, if rising credit card charge-offs reflected an increase in financial distress, then charge-offs would be expected to be correlated with a rise in delinquency rates on credit card loans. But as indicated in Figure 6 above, the delinquency rate on credit cards has shown no similar upward trend over time, and has actually trended slightly downward since 1991, suggesting that the rise in credit card charge-offs have not been the result of an increasing number of consumers behind in their payments or otherwise struggling to pay their credit card bills. Like mortgages, default rates on student loans, which are largely nondischargeable under the Bankruptcy Code, have also declined dramatically over time from a peak of over 22% in 1990 to 5.1% in 2004282 even though there has been a dramatic rise in outstanding student loan debt during this period.283 The declining default rate on this nondichargeable debt obligation, compared to the rise in credit card chargeoffs, is also consistent with the strategic model.284 282 See United States Department of Education, Official Cohort Default Rate for Schools, http://www.ed.gov/offices/OSFAP/defaultmanagement/defaultrates.html. 283 See supra notes 146-147 and accompanying text. 284 Mann purports to disprove the strategic model in his statistical analysis, finding that the coefficient value on credit card debt (CCD) as a predictor of bankruptcy filings increases as he extends the lag period on his regression. MANN, supra note 2. But this conclusion is not supportable from his finding. He does not establish that the coefficient values on his lags differ in a statistically significant manner from one another, meaning that the data do not disprove the hypothesis that they are statistically equivalent to one another. In fact, a series of pairwise tests of the various coefficient values finds the coefficient value on each LAG term to be within the confidence interval for surrounding coefficients, raising doubt about whether they could be shown to be statistically different from each other. Testing Mann’s conclusion is 90 Overall, this all provides some support for the strategic hypothesis. More generally, it seems clear that consumers have become more sophisticated over time at pre-bankruptcy planning and deciding which debts to pay and which ones on which to default, as evidenced by the rising charge-off rates on credit card loans while mortgages and student loans default rates have fallen. Moreover, credit card charge-offs have risen over time, even though credit card delinquencies have not. Although this suggests that strategic credit card use explains some of the relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcy it seems obvious that some consumers are forced into bankruptcy by excessive credit card debt thus it still seems unlikely that the strategic model can explain the full relationship. VI. BAPCPA and Credit Cards If the substitution theory is correct, then it suggests that an important byproduct of the growth of credit card use and borrowing will be an increase in the bankruptcy filing rate, holding everything else constant. This substitution itself may be the result of factors fundamentally unrelated to bankruptcy, such as the lower operating costs of credit cards for issuers and consumer demand for credit cards relative to other traditional types of consumer credit. The substitution effect, therefore, will increase the demand for bankruptcy and lead to an increase in bankruptcy filing rates. difficult because of his unorthodox specification of the regression, which rests on his decision to specify each sequential LAG term as a separate regression, notwithstanding the extremely high degree of multicollinearity among them. Using the more conventional statistical technique of testing all lag terms simultaneously to control for multicollinearity results in the two longer lag terms being statistically insignificant and the shorter terms borderline statistically significant. The relevant p values for the variables are CCD=0.064, d1CCD=0.084, d2CCD=0.233, d3CCD=0.810. 91 If this is so, then there are several logical consequences that follow. First, although higher bankruptcies will likely result as a byproduct of increased credit card lending, it would be economically inefficient to adopt policies that will encourage credit card lenders to restrict the issuance of credit, especially to lower-income borrowers. Doing so would have the unintended consequence of encouraging borrowers to shift back from credit card lending to various higher-cost types of installment and other lending, with negative welfare effects. Although this would likely have the effect of reducing bankruptcy filing rates it would be an inefficient way of bringing this about, as it uses a restriction in the supply of credit to try to solve what is fundamentally an issue of bankruptcy policy. A more efficient response would be to amend the bankruptcy code directly to address the unintended consequences that have led to an increase in bankruptcy filings. Under this approach amending the Bankruptcy Code can be understood as an institutional response to address the various factors that have raised the incentives for filing bankruptcy in recent decades.285 This would preserve the general social benefits associated with widespread access to credit cards but restrain the problems of opportunism, moral hazard, and adverse selection that have accompanied this growth of credit card lending. The latter approach is the one chosen by BAPCPA, which addresses the problems created for the bankruptcy system by increased use of credit cards. This Part of the article addresses the impact of BAPCPA on the treatment of credit cards in bankruptcy. A. 285 The Effects of BAPCPA on Credit Cards in Bankruptcy See Zywicki, Institutions, supra note 221. 92 BAPCPA makes several changes to the treatment of credit cards in bankruptcy, all of which are designed to address the problems of moral hazard and adverse selection associated with credit card use and bankruptcy. First, BAPCPA provides a variety of new safeguards to reduce fraud in bankruptcy, such as requiring debtors to file tax returns, pay advices, and other financial information that will make it easier to detect fraud and concealment of assets by debtors.286 Second, before a debtor can file a bankruptcy petition he must first attend consumer credit counseling to determine whether he should enroll in a debt management plan instead of filing bankruptcy.287 Third, the United States Trustee is given greater powers to investigate and pursue fraud through enhanced powers to conduct random audits of debtors’ cases.288 Fourth, BAPCPA imposes a new system of “means-testing” eligibility for chapter 7 relief.289 Under BAPCPA, a debtor who makes above the state median income (adjusted for family size) and has the ability to repay a substantial portion of his or her non-priority unsecured debt in a chapter 13 repayment plan would be presumed to have to file under chapter 13 rather than chapter 7 unless he or she can show extraordinary circumstances that make chapter 13 inappropriate. Although this provision was estimated to affect only about 10% of bankruptcy filers, by targeting those with the highest repayment capacity, it was estimated that this provision would recover $4 billion in bankruptcy that was previously discharged.290 Fifth, BAPCPA makes nondischargeable more credit card debt for cash advances and for the purchase of “luxury goods and services” in the pre-bankruptcy period, lengthening the relevant period and reducing the threshold amount to trigger the 286 Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005 §315. BAPCPA §106. 288 BAPCPA §603. 289 BAPCPA §102. 290 See Jones & Zywicki, supra note 205, at 186-92 (summarizing studies). 287 93 nondischargeability presumption.291 Sixth, BAPCPA places new limits on abusive homestead exemptions, reducing the ability of debtors to protect assets in bankruptcy.292 Finally, BAPCPA expands the protection for credit card issuers in situations where debtors use credit cards to pay debts that would be nondischargeable, such as for taxes.293 Each of these provisions will tend to increase the collection of credit card debts in bankruptcy.294 B. Implications of BAPCPA for Credit Cards and Bankruptcy BAPCPA, therefore, makes some credit card debt more difficult to completely discharge, both directly and indirectly. BAPCPA thus should have two expected economic results. First, it should increase the ex post financial recovery by credit card issuers from those consumers who file bankruptcy and are impacted by the various provisions related to means-testing, reduced fraud, and more stringent restrictions on loading-up behavior of “luxury goods and services” and cash advances. Second, these protections should reduce the incentives to file bankruptcy, and by reducing the risk of lending to certain categories of debtors it should lead to reduced credit card interest rates and increased credit supply to certain categories of borrowers. On the other hand, this reduction in interest rates and increased supply of unsecured BAPCPA §310. Credit card debt is generally dischargeable unless incurred for the purchase of “luxury goods or services” within a short period preceding bankruptcy. 11 U.S.C. §523(a)(2)(C). Prior to BAPCPA, the luxury goods or services had to be owed to a single creditor and aggregate more that $1,225 on or within 60 days of bankruptcy, or cash advances aggregating more than $1,225 within 60 days of bankruptcy. BAPCPA amends this section to reduce the threshold for “luxury goods and services” to $500 days and extends the period length to 90 days, and reduces the cash advances threshold to $750 and extends the period to 70 days. 292 BAPCPA §§308, 322. 293 BAPCPA §314. 294 Other provisions will have the likely effect of reducing collections for credit card issuers. In particular, BAPCPA increases the rights in bankruptcy of certain secured creditors (notably automobile lenders) and for certain priority debts, such as collection of domestic support obligations and taxes. The improved position of these senior creditors will reduce the amounts available for distribution to unsecured creditors. 291 94 credit theoretically could lead to an increase in indebtedness and a subsequent increase in bankruptcies. As a result, the overall impact of BAPCPA on bankruptcy filings is ambiguous as an a priori matter, and must be resolved empirically. 1. The Effect of BAPCPA on Bankruptcy Filings Each of the different theories discussed generate different predictions about the likely impact of BAPCPA on bankruptcy filing rates. Most straightforwardly, the substitution model predicts that by reducing the incentives to file bankruptcy ex post, BAPCPA will be expected to reduce the number of bankruptcy filings by encouraging debtors confronted with financial distress to consider alternatives. The distress theory, by contrast, predicts that BAPCPA will have little impact on bankruptcy filing rates or may even have the unintended consequence of increasing bankruptcy filing rates. At its simplest, the distress theory assumes that bankruptcy filings are fundamentally involuntary in nature in that the “overwhelming majority of filers are in such distress that they are all but compelled to file” and thus will have no impact on bankruptcy filing rates.295 Others have argued that by reducing the risk of lending BAPCPA may actually have the unintended consequence of actually increasing the number of bankruptcy filings.296 Those who take this position argue that by reducing lender risk in bankruptcy, BAPCPA will encourage lenders to extend credit to Ronald J. Mann, Bankruptcy Reform and the “Sweatbox” of Credit Card Debt, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 375 (2007). 296 See Robert L. Lawless, The Paradox of Consumer Credit, 2007 U. ILL. L. REV. 347 (2007). 295 95 increasingly risky borrowers, which in turn will increase in the number of consumers in financial distress and therefore to an increase in the number of bankruptcy filings.297 Although BAPCPA has been in operation only about two years, bankruptcy filings have fallen dramatically since it became effective and are still only about half of pre-BAPCPA levels despite problems in the economy and consumer credit markets. At the same time, there is no evidence that BAPCPA is spawning hardship by making it unduly difficult for needy filers to be able to file. This sharp decline in filing rates is difficult to reconcile with the distress model but is consistent with the substitution model which predicts that reducing the incentives to file bankruptcy will result in fewer filings. The most likely reason for the inability of the distress model to accurately predict this development is the failure of the adherents to the distress model to fully and accurately understand the actual provisions of BAPCPA and the impact they are likely to have on consumers. Those borrowers whose behavior will be affected by BAPCPA are not those typically considered to be riskier marginal consumers. Instead, the relevant provisions of BAPCPA dealing with credit cards are aimed at higher-income borrowers impacted by means-testing and those borrowers likely to be affected by the more stringent requirements related to the purchase of “luxury goods or services” or those with large cash advances in the pre-bankruptcy period. The likely reason for the decline in filings is that BAPCPA’s provisions address problems of opportunism by a particular segment of Ausubel, supra note 111, at 269 (“Paradoxically, we conclude that the likely effect of further limiting the dischargeability of credit card debt in bankruptcy is an increase in the frequency with which consumers are buried under mountains of credit card debt”); id. at 270 (“[N]ew limitations on the dischargeability of credit card debt are likely to have unintended consequences and will probably only worsen the problem of consumer overextension.”); Gene Koretz, Reform That Could Backfire: Why Bankruptcies Will Increase, BUSINESS WEEK (May 21, 2001), available in http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/01_21/c3733035.htm; Mark M. Zandi, Easy Credit, Profligate Borrowing, Tough Lessons, REGIONAL FIN. REV. 16 (Jan. 1997) (cited in NATIONAL BANKRUPTCY REVIEW COMMISSION, REPORT Chapter 1 (Oct. 20, 1997). 297 96 borrowers—those higher-income debtors most prone to opportunism—rather than simply reducing risk across the board for all borrowers. This latter group is likely to be composed disproportionately of higher-income borrowers as well, who are likely to have sufficiently high credit lines and opportunities to consume “luxury goods and services.” As a result, these provisions are not likely to have a substantial effect of leading to increased bankruptcies as BAPCPA alone is not likely to spur a substantial increase in lending to higher-risk consumers. To the extent that it might have such a result, as with previous consumer lending innovations BAPCPA will likely result in some substation away from alternative higher-cost loans to credit cards, thereby resulting in no increase in financial distress. 2. The Effect of BAPCPA on Credit Cards in Bankruptcy Ronald Mann argues that the primary effect of BAPCPA will not be to reduce filings by reducing fraud and abuse, but rather to transfer wealth from debtors to credit card issuers by substantially prolonging the length of time necessary before individuals can file bankruptcy, a period during which a financially-stressed debtor will be accruing interest and presumably other fees on her account. Mann refers to this period as the bankruptcy “sweatbox.”298 He writes, “[T]he most important effect will be to slow the time of inevitable filings by the deeply distressed, allowing issuers to earn more revenues from these individuals before they file.”299 Mann does not explain how exactly credit card issuers will be earning “more revenues” from deeply distressed consumers during the “sweatbox” period. 298 299 It seems to follow from his premise that the borrowers in Mann, supra note 295. Id. at 379. 97 question are so distressed as to be unable to pay their debts at all, suggesting that the overwhelming impact of the accrual of new interest and fees will be to simply increase the eventual bankruptcy claims of credit card issuers—and other creditors who remain unpaid during the same time period—not to actually increase the receipts of credit card issuers. But Mann’s reasoning here is a bit unclear. He states that borrowers “often pay until close to the bankruptcy date” but also that most debtors are in hopeless financial distress at the time they file.300 These two claims seem to be inconsistent. More importantly, although Mann asserts that BAPCPA will substantially delay the ability of distressed debtors to file bankruptcy, his claim is based largely on generalized assertions about the effects of BAPCPA rather than a concrete analysis of its provisions. He enumerates several provisions of BAPCPA that increase the costs or delay of filing bankruptcy, such as increasing the period between repeat chapter 7 filings from six to eight years, raising the costs of filing bankruptcy, increasing some of the administrative hurdles (such as requiring pre-filing credit counseling), and by reducing the benefits of filing bankruptcy. He makes little effort to distinguish those reforms that may be justified by legitimate efforts to reduce fraud and abuse, such as increasing the period between repeat filings or administrative burdens to improve the integrity of the system, from those reforms that arguably are designed solely to increase the heat of the “sweatbox.”301 He asserts that the combined impact of all of these provisions would be to create a delay of “several months” before distressed households could actually file 300 .Id. at 397 & n. 106. It appears that Mann simply dismisses the legitimacy of any of these reforms on the basis that they are unfounded because of an absence of fraud or abuse in the system. See id. at 379-84. 301 98 bankruptcy.302 He predicts that BAPCPA will have “only a minor effect on the number of people who choose to file, although it will have a notable effect on when they file.”303 Mann offers little detailed theory or empirical evidence to support the sweatbox theory—indeed, he acknowledges that his discussion is “speculative” and “depends on a variety of empirical assumptions about the behavior of distressed borrowers that are difficult to verify empirically.”304 To date, there is no evidence that BAPCPA has either prevented needy filers from filing or substantially delayed them from filing, which would be necessary for the sweatbox effect.305 First, Mann’s theory rests on the premise that BAPCPA makes bankruptcy more difficult and a more extended process for many filers. Many of the reforms affect post-filing behavior, thus they seem to have no relevance to the pre-filing “sweatbox.” For those that do affect pre-filing behavior, Mann overestimates the costs that they impose. Although BAPCPA adds some new complexity or delay for some filers, for the vast majority of filers the increases are quite small. For example, Mann notes the requirement of pre-bankruptcy credit counseling as a precondition for filing bankruptcy.306 In practice, however, this requirement is not onerous and it is doubtful that it has deterred or slowed many consumers from seeking bankruptcy relief. According to a study by the General Accounting Office, the cost and delay associated with seeking consumer credit counseling has been minimal.307 Ninety percent of bankruptcy clients fulfill the requirement on the spot by telephone or Internet 302 Id. at 393. Id. at 397. 304 Id. at 396. 305 See Testimony of Professor Todd J. Zywicki, Testimony before United States Senate, Committee on the Judiciary, Subcommittee on Administrative Oversight and the Courts, “Oversight of the Implementation of the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act” (Dec. 5, 2006). 306 Id. at 395. 307 See GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE, BANKRUPTCY REFORM: VALUE OF CREDIT COUNSELING REQUIREMENT IS NOT CLEAR (April 2007). 303 99 with little inconvenience or delay.308 Many lawyers have even set aside rooms, telephones, and computers in their offices to permit debtors to fulfill the credit counseling requirement with minimal delay and disruption.309 Although the typical fee for credit counseling and a bankruptcy certificate is $50, many indigent filers have these fees waived (as high as 26% for some counseling agencies).310 Counseling agencies have been almost uniformly prompt and competent in fulfilling their responsibilities. Other obligations under BAPCPA, such as the requirement of filing tax returns and pay advices with one’s petition, increase paperwork burdens but it’s not clear why that would necessarily increase delay. Similarly, the extension of the refilling bar from six to eight years will likely affect only a small number of filers.311 Available data also is inconsistent with Mann’s theory. One logical prediction of Mann’s theory would be that post-BAPCPA credit card delinquencies would rise rapidly as the predicted effect of BAPCPA should be to create a growing class of debtors who need to file bankruptcy (or at least would have been able to file bankruptcy pre- 308 Id. at 21. Recent research indicates, somewhat surprisingly, that the efficacy of credit counseling is not affected by whether it is conducted by telephone versus in person. See Michael Staten and John Barron, Evaluating the Effectiveness of Credit Counseling, Phase One: The Impact of Delivery Channels for Credit Counseling Services (May 31, 2006); but see Noreen Clancy & Stephen J. Carroll, Prebankruptcy Credit Counseling 17 (2007) (concluding that the “literature generally, but not always, suggests that in-person counseling is more effective than other modes of delivery). 309 GAO, CREDIT COUNSELING, supra note 307, at 37. The GAO expressed concern about the marginal value associated with consumer credit counseling, especially in these situations, but this is distinct from the concerns of the “sweatbox” theory, which contends that the requirement substantially increases the marginal cost of filing bankruptcy. 310 GAO, CREDIT COUNSELING, supra note 307. 311 There are a relatively modest number of repeat chapter 7 bankruptcy filers and although it is not known exactly how many people would need to refile more than six years but less than eight years after an initial filing, it is difficult to imagine that this will impact a substantial number of bankruptcy filers. See Jean M. Lown, Serial Bankruptcy Filers No Problem, 26 AM. BANKR. INST. J. 36 (June 2007) (estimating that about 4 percent of bankruptcy filers are repeat filers). On the other hand, many of those who are repeat filers are actually serial filers who file many times. See Jean M. Lown, Serial Bankruptcy: A 20-Year Study of Utah Filers, 25 AM. BANKR. INST. J. 24 (Feb. 2006). 100 BAPCPA), but are unable to do so post-BAPCPA.312 This dynamic should be captured in a growing number of delinquent debtors who are struggling to make their payments. In fact, delinquency rates on credit card loans post-BAPCPA appear to be comparable or lower than delinquency rates for many pre-BAPCPA.313 VII. CONCLUSION This article has examined the conventional belief that the growth in the availability of credit cards over time has caused a direct increase in consumer bankruptcy filing rates by increasing the frequency of household financial distress. Analysis of available data and empirical studies fail to support the hypothesis. Instead, the growth in credit card debt over the past three decades reflects a substitution of credit cards for more expensive and less attractive alternative forms of credit such as personal finance companies, pawn shops, and retail store credit, have now found themselves with a general purpose credit vehicle that can be tapped whenever necessary. As a result, there has been a general increase in credit card credit and availability, but no evident increase in overall consumer indebtedness (as measured by the debt service ratio) or risk. On the other hand, by substituting unsecured debt for secured debt and nationalized and depersonalized types of consumer credit for traditional forms of credit embedded in local relationships, the substitution to credit cards has increased the propensity of consumers to file bankruptcy in response to financial distress. 312 Efforts to isolate the possible impact of BAPCPA on credit card delinquency are confounded because on January 1, 2006—the first quarter after BAPCPA became effective—new federal regulatory guidelines requiring higher mandatory minimum payments on credit cards went into effect, dramatically increasing the mandatory minimum. See Credit Card Minimum Payments Set to Double Beginning January 1, 2006, http://www.send2press.com/newswire/2005-12-1205-005.shtml. Credit card delinquencies jumped a small amount after this regulatory guidance became effective, but have remained largely constant since 2006Q1. 313 See Figure 6 supra (current delinquency rates on credit card loans are lower than many earlier periods). 101 Strategic behavior by borrowers also may explain some of the rise in credit card debt and the relationship between credit card debt and bankruptcy. Because of problems of asymmetric information borrowers know their likelihood and timing of bankruptcy better than creditors. As such, the strategic theory predicts that debtors would increase their use of dischargeable credit card debt in the period immediately preceding bankruptcy as well as disproportionately choosing to default on credit card debt relative to secured and nondischargeable debt. In fact, credit card chargeoffs have risen over time even as chargeoffs on household mortgages and nondischargeable student loans have fallen. Bankruptcy filers also make greater use of credit card debt than other households. All of this suggests some support for the strategic model. Finally, this article has examined the impact of BAPCPA’s reforms on credit cards. Critics of BAPCPA argued that because it failed to address the underlying causes of the rise in bankruptcies, namely the extension of excessive credit card debt to high-risk borrowers, BAPCPA would have minimal effect on bankruptcy filings or even result in higher filings. Two and a half years after BAPCPA became effective, however, filings are still approximately one-half of their steady-state level pre-BAPCPA. Critics of BAPCPA also argued that even if BAPCPA did not reduce filings, by making it more difficult for borrowers to file, thereby drawing out their period of default and their time in the “bankruptcy sweatbox.” These predictions also appear unfounded to date. These predictions, however, seem to have been based on a misunderstanding of the actual terms of BAPCPA. Credit is as old as human society. And as old as credit is the concern expressed by some that “other people” cannot be trusted with credit and that they are being tempted 102 into overconsumption and overindulgence and pining for a “golden age” of purported frugality and aversion to consumer debt. This golden age never existed, at least in America. The criticisms heard today of credit card issuers are identical to those of installment lenders of the 1940s and before that still other perceived irresponsible use of consumer credit. It is time to move beyond the conventional wisdom and to understand how Americans actually use consumer credit and why they have rationally chosen to increase their use of credit cards. Only then will we fully understand the relationship between credit cards and bankruptcy and ensure that any reforms will increase consumer welfare. 103