1 The long-term impact of mergers and the emergence of a merger wave in pre-World-War I Germany Gerhard Klinga a University of Southampton THIS IS NOT THE FINAL (POST-REVIEW) VERSION YOU FIND THE FINAL VERSION HERE: Kling, G. (2006) The long-term impact of mergers and the emergence of a merger wave in pre-World War I Germany, Explorations in Economic History 43(4), 667-688 Using annual data on mergers for 35 leading German companies from 1870 to 1913, my study tries to explain the first merger wave that emerged 1898. My panel probit model that accounted for economies of scale, macroeconomic conditions, success of former mergers, and market structure revealed that previous mergers made subsequent mergers more likely. The propensity to merge was higher for larger companies that increased their market power. In the banking industry, managers imitated mergers, although these mergers were not successful, and hence followed the minimax regret principle. Rational information-based herding caused the serial dependency of mergers in other industries. Keywords: merger, pre-World-War I, merger wave, minimax regret, herd behavior 2 1. Introduction During the first phase of globalization that lasted from 1895 to 1914,1 the first merger wave occurred and changed the industrial structure in Europe and the U.S. remarkably. Famous companies like U.S. Steel, DuPont, General Electric, and Eastman Kodak are a product of these early mergers.2 Merger waves are a recurrent phenomenon, for five waves occurred so far, and the burst of the “New Economy Bubble” ended the last merger mania in 2000. The emergence of the next merger wave is just a matter of time; hence, it is of great importance to assess why merger waves started and whether shareholders benefited from them. Merger waves occurred under different regulatory and institutional frameworks during the last century – but what were the common driving forces. As the human nature did not change over time, its limitations concerning rationality might explain this puzzle. My study tries to find answers to these questions by using historical evidence of mergers from 1870 to 1913 in Germany. During this period, the new exchange law in 1896 changed the regulatory framework for German companies and could have triggered the first merger wave. Economic historians concentrated mostly on debates about the interrelation between the expansion of large-scale enterprises, external growth, and mergers.3 Maintenance of size and survivorship were seen as major factors of success. This way of looking at success was probably motivated by several cross-country studies that pointed out that size was essential. Especially, large German enterprises were seen as a main guarantee for superior economic 1 Williamson (1996) and Tilly (1999) besides others coined the term `first phase of globalization´; however, the exact location of this period, which exhibited an increase in international integration, is disputable. 2 3 I refer to Nelson (1959) and Chandler (1990). Tilly (1982, 1986), Gerschenkron (1962), Huerkamp (1979), and Feldenkirchen (1988) discussed the concentration process in different lines of business for Germany. Davis (1966), Nelson (1959), Eis (1979), Hannah (1974), and Chandler (1977) conducted similar studies for the U.S. and UK case. 3 development in the pre-World-War I period.4 After reviewing new statistical material, however, Kinghorn and Nye (1996) corrected the picture regarding the superiority of German large-scale enterprises. They found evidence that German firms were smaller compared to U.S. or French companies, and the concentration process was less developed.5 Besides these astonishing results, additional doubts emerged regarding the alleged superiority of large enterprises. Baten (2001a, b, c) showed that small firms exhibited larger total factor productivity and provided evidence that the median of firm size stayed stable over time. This contradicted the common opinion that firm size increased between 1895 and 1912.6 Accordingly, mergers that increased firm size were often seen as successful, regardless whether they reduced share prices: this view changed in the literature. Mergers occurring in the 1980s and later periods were regarded as successful if they increased shareholder value. Based on principal-agent theory, Jarrel and Poulsen (1989) stated that managers favor shareholder value-destroying mergers to increase firm size, as a larger company reduces the possibility for shareholders to monitor the management effectively. Shleifer and Vishny (1988) argued that mergers are driven by `empire building´, as managers enjoy controlling a larger company. The definition of success seems to be crucial, and my study concentrates on shareholder value as relevant indicator for success. Thus, my empirical model tries to quantify 4 I refer to the most famous contribution made by Chandler (1990). For late Victorian Britain, Elbaum and Lazonick (1986) argued in favor for large enterprises that had the ability to adopt the modern form of corporation. They stressed that the high firm size in Germany and the U.S. contributed to countries’ success. 5 Kinghorn and Nye (1996) calculated the number of workers in different industries for Germany, U.S., and France and showed that German companies were relatively small. Especially, in the iron and steel industry, U.S. companies employed on average about two times more workers than German counterparts. 6 Due to data availability, his research is restricted to the state `Baden´; however, his empirical evidence can also be interpreted as a general statement regarding firm size. An exception, however, are some regions in which large-scale enterprises (iron and steel, mining etc.) predominated the industrial structure. 4 the change in total stock returns due to mergers.7 Generally, the impact of mergers on stock characteristics was seldom studied for historical periods.8 My estimates of the success of mergers were used as variable for explaining the emergence of the first merger wave. Theoretical models for explaining merger waves are still in an `infant stage’. In particular, theoretical approaches to understand horizontal mergers – typical for the first merger wave – were seldom developed.9 An exception, however, is Boeckem’s (2002) game theoretical model – but there is no way to transfer her heterogeneous Cournot game into an empirical model.10 The driving force for her horizontal merger wave stems from the heterogeneity in marginal costs. Yet measuring marginal costs is an unsolvable task, especially for the banking industry that is mainly responsible for the merger wave. The recent contribution by Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004) modeled the positive interrelation between market valuation and mergers, and Maksimovic and Phillips (2001) among others confirmed that mergers were more likely in periods of overvalued stocks. My empirical model accounts for the market valuation of stocks. Schenk (2001) tried to explain merger waves by a game theoretical model in which managers apply the minimax-regret decision rule. He argued that a booming economy is the prerequisite for starting a merger wave. The first merger creates incentives to imitate this decision and trigger additional mergers irrespective of the success of the first merger. This 7 Total stock returns account for changes in share prices and dividend payments. 8 Exceptions are the studies of Borg et al. (1989), Borg and Leeth (1994, 2000), and Banerjee and Eckard (2001) that analyzed U.S. data. These event-studies measured the impact of mergers on shareholder value. 9 Boeckem (2002) stated that this is mainly due to the lacking profitability of horizontal mergers in a simple Cournot setting with homogenous goods if more than two firms interact, as a free-rider problem arises. Hence, cost asymmetry is necessary to induce profitable mergers in the case of more than two firms (see Salant et al., 1983, Levin, 1990, and Farrell and Shapiro, 1990). 10 Consider that Boeckem’s (2002) model assumed that the firm with the lowest marginal costs moves first. So the merger wave is not explained endogenously, which makes empirical proofs difficult. 5 behavior follows the assertion that one prefers to fail conventionally than to succeed unconventionally. Correspondingly, imitating unsuccessful mergers causes less regret than overlooking the opportunity for a successful merger. Palacios-Huerta (2003) suggested that detecting serial dependency of mergers would confirm that managers follow the minimaxregret principle. However, serial dependency of mergers could be due to rational herding behavior and is not necessarily a hint for the minimax-regret principle. Reputation and compensation-based herding is not relevant for the pre-1914 period – but information-based herding apply to this period, as mergers were observable, and imperfect information could be assumed.11 Banerjee (1992), Bikhchandani et al. (1992) and Welch (1992) developed theoretical models for information-based herding, and Avery and Zemsky (1998) modified these models for explaining herding behavior on financial markets. Observing mergers of other companies can be used to learn something about the private information and signals that these companies received; hence, it is rational to imitate others’ decisions. When decisionmakers enter such an information cascade, they tend to imitate previous mergers – but they overlook their own private information and signals, which creates a negative externality. How can one distinguish between managers that follow the minimax-regret principle and managers that enter an information cascade? Schenk’s (2001) minimax-regret game predicts that mergers are imitated even if previous mergers were not successful. As the success of mergers can be observed, information-based herding does not support imitating unsuccessful mergers. My paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the method of sampling, which is oriented towards Baltzer and Kling (2004). Thereafter, a panel vector autoregression (VAR) reveals the long-lasting impact of mergers on total stock returns. As mergers were not always 11 Information-based herding requires imperfect information, i.e. not everyone can observe specific signals about the market valuation of a potential target firm. Even if all decision-makers have full access to information, Simon (1955) pointed out that “bounded rationality” suggests that economic agents do not have unlimited information processing capabilities. This “lack of brainpower” justifies imitating the decision of others. 6 profitable for shareholders during the whole period, rolling regressions allow time-varying coefficients. To uncover motives for merging, a panel probit model controls for macroeconomic conditions, economies of scale, market structure, regulatory changes, success of previous mergers, and firm specific effects. The decision to merge exhibited serial dependence; hence, decision-makers imitated the behavior of other companies. Finally, I discuss whether my empirical findings fit to the minimax regret principle or to informationbased herd behavior. 2. Method of sampling 2.1 Constructing a representative sample for German companies Sampling in economic history means meticulous work. Therefore, there are two commonly applied methodologies to draw a sample in historical periods, namely choosing a limited period of time and collecting all available information during this period, or selecting companies that fulfill specific criteria, i.e. firm size, to limit the number of cross-sectional units. For a long-term study, the latter procedure is more appropriate, and hence my sampling follows Tilly (1982), Weston (1953), and Huerkamp (1979). The former studies by Tilly (1982) and Huerkamp (1979) focused on surviving companies, and I do the same, albeit I am aware of a potential survivorship bias. The appendix shows that the survivorship bias is not relevant for my results. My aim is to construct a sample consisting of 35 leading companies listed on the Berlin stock exchange from the early 1870s to the beginning of the First World War in 1914. The data set contains only acquiring companies, as targets were not observable after mergers. Restricting the sample to the largest companies ensures that I captured the most active 7 acquirers.12 A simple approach that includes the 35 largest companies would lead to an overrepresentation of banks, and newly developing industries like the chemical industry would be neglected. Thus, it is essential to construct weights for different industries to guarantee that infant industries are represented. To obtain weights of industries, I divided all listed companies into four major sectors. This procedure is in line with the contemporary division made in `Saling’s Börsen-Papiere´ since the early 1870s, namely banks, mining companies, transport, and the other-industries-sector.13 Moreover, I refined the other-industries-sector into seven sub-sectors: breweries, real estate companies, chemical industry, metalworking industry, mechanical engineering, textile industry, and other minor industries. The insurance sector exhibited very illiquid trading due to regulations and hence was not considered for my sample.14 To determine weights for these four main industries, I have to think about criteria that reflect the importance of the respective category. Paid-in nominal capital could be used as criterion – but it changed during the 44 years decisively. Most notably, the transport industry and the other-industries-sector underwent a pronounced development. Due to the nationalization of nearly all railway companies, the contribution of the transport sector to the total amount of nominal capital decreases considerably from about 30% to 10%. In contrast, the more and more diversifying other-industries-sector exhibited an increase from 15% in 1873 to more than 40% in 1912. Table 1 provides an overview with regard to the change in 12 Tilly (1982) argued that the companies’ laws of 1884 and the new exchange law established 1896 favored the acquisition of smaller companies by larger companies. This assertion can be justified by the legal requirement that the minimum issue volume had to exceed one million Mark. Hence, a larger company had advantages to finance acquisitions by issuing new shares. 13 Strictly speaking, Saling (1874-1876) combined the mining sector and the other-industries-sector into one category. However, considering the overwhelming importance of the mining industry in the pre-World-War I economy, I prefer to build up an own category for mining companies. 14 Changes of ownership had to be announced and permitted by the board of directors of the respective company. 8 nominal capital of the four main industries. Relying solely on nominal capital as criterion would not guarantee an appropriate representation of infant industries like the chemical industry. Accordingly, I follow Tilly (1982), who used the number of listed companies for determining industry weights. Table 1 shows that the other-industries-sector played the biggest role in 1873 as well as in 1912, when one considers the number of companies. (Insert Table 1) Besides technological progress, the legal environment paved the ground for new industries. The new law concerning the foundation of companies passed in 1870 caused a real flood of new companies. During the subsequent period, which is called `Gruenderboom’, more than 50% of the founded companies belonged to the expanding other-industries-sector. These companies possessed only a low amount of paid-up nominal capital, as the new law admitted that investors could pay only a fraction of the `official´ nominal capital. In 1873, the turning point was reached on the stock market accompanied by decreasing founding activities in the following years. To capture this wave of newly founded companies from 1870 to 1873, I fixed the year 1873 as reference year to collect the data for both criteria, namely the number of listed companies and paid-in nominal capital, from `Saling’s Börsenpapiere (1874-1876)´. To take the changes during the whole period into account, I fixed the year 1912 as second reference point, which is close to the end of my investigated period. The `Vierteljahreshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs (1913)´ provided data for 1912. Based on these criteria, my sample consists of 11 banks, 4 mining companies, 5 transport companies, and 15 firms belonging to the other-industries-sector. After determining industry weights, the largest companies – based on nominal capital – in every main industry were selected. These `blue chips´ should represent the most actively traded stocks on the Berlin stock exchange. `Saling’s Börsen-Jahrbuch (1913/1914)’ and the `Handbuch der deutschen Aktiengesellschaften (1900/1901 and 1913/1914)’ provided 9 information on mergers, annual share prices, dividends and nominal capital for these 35 `blue chips´. Table 2 summarizes the merger activity in my sample. (Insert Table 2) 2.2 Inflation and economic growth rates Considering that my investigation covers 44 years, time series should be deflated – but which price deflator should be used. Jacobs and Richter’s (1935) price index was constructed from wholesale prices, whereas Hoffmann (1965) calculated his private consumption index using a larger base of time series. Despite the discussible weak points in constructing the data for the 1870s (see Fremdling, 1991), Tilly (1992) used Hoffmann’s (1965) private consumption index for deflating his indicator for asset returns of the German stock market. Tilly (1992) concluded that the almost identical course of nominal and real series pointed to the fact that the development of prices did not dominate the time series. Encouraged by Tilly (1992), I used Hoffmann’s (1965) private consumption index. A comparison of my real and nominal data supports Tilly’s (1992) view, which is not surprising because the Mark was tied to the Gold Standard. Prices increased only by 30% over the whole period, and the average annual inflation rate reached 0.62%. Nevertheless, inflation rates exhibited tremendous fluctuations during this period. Besides inflation rates, I also used a time series of economic growth rate provided by Hoffmann (1965).15 15 Burhop and Wolff (2003) tried to correct for some biases of the Hoffmann (1965) time series. However, using these corrected time series leads to similar outcomes. My impression is that the differences among alternative price series are more important in levels than in first differences. 10 2.3 Merger activity during the investigation period from 1870 to 1913 My descriptive finding deviates from Tilly (see p.634, table 1, 1982) in that my data show that mergers were centered on a peak in 1906. This finding, however, is in line with Huerkamp (1979), who uncovered a strong increase in merger activities from 1887 to 1907. In contrast to Tilly (1982) and my study, she also included firms that were not listed on stock exchanges. Tilly (1982) did not include the banking industry, which accounted for 70% of all mergers in my sample, and he covered only the period from 1880 to 1913. It is unclear why his sample size varied from 38 to 49. To take the changing sample size into account, Fig.1 reports the number of mergers divided by the sample size, which can be regarded as merger intensity. (Insert Fig.1.) 3. Panel vector autoregression with macroeconomic variables and mergers Decision-makers could observe the success of former mergers, which could affect their decisions concerning future expansions. Hence, knowing whether mergers were shareholder value creating during the pre-1914 period is crucial. For that purpose, a panel VAR analysis is conduced using first differences in nominal capital and total stock returns as endogenous variables. Inserting macroeconomic time series controls for their influence on share prices and dividends, which in turn affected total stock returns.16 As Germany joined the Gold Standard in the first half of the 1870s, “inflation illusion” discussed by Modigliani and Cohn (1979) seems to be likely. The “inflation illusion” hypothesis stated that higher inflation rates reduce 16 It is possible to show by applying Granger causality tests that macroeconomic variables can be treated as exogenous in this setting (see Baltzer and Kling, 2004). 11 real stock returns.17 Besides this alleged influence of inflation rates, one should control for economic growth rates, as good economic conditions increase earnings, which enables higher dividend payments and higher share prices. Event-studies, i.e. Magenheim and Mueller (1988),18 were quite common to investigate the long-term effect of mergers – but there are two main limitations: first, Morse (1984) showed that the statistic power of event studies declines when the frequency of data is reduced, i.e. annual instead of daily stock returns; second, omitted variable bias would turn inference into a risky venture because event studies cannot control for macroeconomic shocks. Almost all event studies are based on daily stock returns and measure the market response triggered by merger announcements. On a daily basis, macroeconomic shocks could be neglected – but not for measuring the long-term impact of mergers. Thus, an event-study approach should be replaced by more sophisticated methods that allow to separate different kinds of shocks, namely mergers and macro-level shocks. The first step is to test for stationarity, which is a prerequisite for applying a panel VAR approach. For the sake of increasing the number of observations, unit-root tests can be applied to panel data. In the literature, two different kinds of tests are common that differ with regard to the null hypothesis.19 The Hadri (2000) LM test has as null hypothesis that all series are stationary, whereas the pooled ADF test by Levin et al. (2002) and the procedure by Im et al. (1997) use the null hypothesis that all series exhibit a unit root and are hence non-stationary. If both tests point in the same direction, the result is clear. The outcomes for total stock returns and changes in nominal capital presented in Table 3 are unambiguous. The Levin et al. 17 Baltzer and Kling (2004) confirmed the “inflation illusion” hypothesis for pre-1914 Germany. 18 Armitage (1995) wrote a detailed survey on event studies and their limitations. 19 Ho (2002) stated that ADF and KPSS tests should be used jointly to compare the results. 12 (2002) and the Im et al. (1997) test reject the null hypothesis, and the Hadri (2000) LM test cannot reject that all series are stationary.20 (Insert Table 3) The prerequisite of a VAR model is fulfilled; thus, I can estimate a simple VAR model in reduced form.21 p Δz it Σ 0 Σ j Δz it Ξg t Mmit η it (1) j 1 The vector Δzit contains the total stock returns returnsit and the change in nominal capital Δnit, the vector gt captures economic growth rates (gdpt) and inflation rates (inflationt), and the binary variable mit takes the value one if firm i merged in year t. The lag length p of the VAR model is determined by information criteria that are calculated based on Hamilton (1994). The Akaike criterion favors five lags, whereas the Schwarz and the Hannan Quin criteria prefer a simpler model with three lags. For the sake of simplicity, I choose three lags, and table 4 summarizes the outcomes of the VAR analysis. (Insert Table 4) Generally, macroeconomic variables possessed a considerable impact on stock characteristics. Mergers increased the expansion of nominal capital, as new shares were issued to finance mergers. Yet mergers did not affect total stock returns directly – but mergers triggered higher nominal capital, and higher nominal capital in turn had a negative impact on total stock returns. Hence, there was an indirect effect on total stock returns – but this effect was economically small. Putting these outcomes in other words, my model confirms Tilly’s (1982) finding that mergers played an important role for the expansion of enterprises. 20 For growth rates of net national product and inflation rates, I carry out standard KPSS and ADF tests. Both time series are stationary. 21 Consider that a VAR has the advantage that total stock returns and nominal capital can influence each other. In a standard regression model, one has to specify the dependent variable. 13 Interestingly, mergers did not increase total stock returns during the whole period – but mergers were not shareholder value destroying as found by Borg et al. (1989) for the second merger wave in the 1920s. The success of mergers might have changed from 1870 to 1913; hence, I used rolling regressions for model (1) to determine the partial impact of mergers on total stock returns for every year of my investigation period.22 Mergers that occurred not in the banking industry were very successful from 1898 to 1904. This coincides with my descriptive finding that the merger wave started around 1898. Noteworthy, banks that were the most active acquirers during this period did not have high benefits from mergers in term of higher total stock returns for their shareholders. Fig. 2 plots the coefficients of the variable mit for the banking industry and the rest of the sample. These time-varying coefficients were inserted as explanatory variable into the probit model that tries to explain the decision to merge. (Insert Fig.2.) 4. What drives merger during the first phase of globalization in Germany? 4.1 Constructing proxies for market structure and economies of scale During the first merger wave without effective regulations, mergers could be used to gain market power; hence, the market structure of the respective industry might play a predominant role for explaining merger activity.23 However, it is difficult to obtain good proxies for market structure of industries, as information about market shares (i.e. sales) is not available on an annual basis and severe forms of collusive behavior, i.e. syndicates and 22 I construct a five year window that is shifted forward after each estimation by one year; thus, the impact of mergers on total returns can be determined for every year. 23 Stigler (1950) called the first merger wave `merging for monopoly’ and stressed the lack of regulations as a ground for the merger wave. 14 pooling agreements (`Interessengemeinschaften´) were common – but difficult to measure.24 The relative size measured by nominal capital of a company divided by the 25% percentile (the smallest companies in the industry) serves as proxy for market structure.25 Jensen (1988) among others stressed the importance of economies of scale for conducting mergers, for cost advantages related to firm size generate benefits from mergers. When one focuses on shareholder value, total stock returns of companies relative to total stock returns of the smallest companies (25% percentile) can be regarded as a proxy for economies of scale. An alternative approach applied by Spoerer (1996) is to quantify the return to equity, which requires a thorough balance-sheet analysis. Based on the data provided by Spoerer (1996) and my stock market data, I calculated correlations between returns to equity and performance indices for different industries.26 This is, however, a crude proof, as the samples do not match perfectly. The correlation reached 0.63 for the mining industry and 0.60 for the otherindustry-category. Henceforth, a company with high returns to equity exhibited a high total stock return – but the relationship indicates that either the stock market was not highly informationally efficient or the reliability of balance-sheet data for the pre-1914 period was not sufficient – or both problems existed. Due to the reliability of data, I decided to use the relative deviation of total stock returns as proxy for economies of scale. Fig. 3 depicts the 24 25 See also Feldenkirchen (1988). Besides this proxy, I constructed alternative proxies based on the “Vierteljahreshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs”. As data before 1895 were not available for all industries, I used self-collected industry data from Baltzer and Kling (2004) based on “Saling’s Börsen-Papiere, 1874-1876” for 1870 to 1874. With these initial values, the Holt-Winter (1966) method can replace missing values. For the banking industry, “Der Deutsche Oekonomist” provided data from 1883 to 1913. These data sources only allow determining the average firm size in an industry; thus, one can divide individual firm size by the average size to obtain proxies. Interestingly, these proxies are highly correlated (>0.80) with the proxy based on the 25% percentile that I used for my empirical models. 26 The indices were value-weighted using market capitalization as weight. 15 economies of scale for the banking industry and all other industries and it shows that both time series exhibited a strong comovement. Over the whole period, however, the banking industry had very low economies of scale, as total returns were only 0.96% higher compared to the smallest companies. In contrast, when one aggregates all other industries and calculates average economies of scale, these industries outperformed the smallest companies by 17.95%.27 (Insert Fig.3.) 4.2 Model selection of a dynamic panel probit model with random effects The decision to undertake a merger can be analyzed as count data model because companies could acquire more than one target within the same year. However, such multiple acquisitions were seldom; hence, it seems to be appropriate to model the binary decision – “to merge or not to merge” – of a company. As I deal with panel data, a panel discrete choice model should be applied. Fortunately, in recent years considerable progress in estimating panel probit and logit models was made.28 Random or fixed-effects model can account for company specific effects that are inherent when using panel data. As fixed-effects model do not indicate jointly significant coefficients and log-likelihood ratio tests reveal the relevance of random effects, I propose a panel probit model with random effects. Lagged explanatory variables up to lag p are permitted. The intuition behind the model with lagged variables is that the decision “to merge or not to merge” may depend on current and past macroeconomic, industry, and company specific factors as well as behavioral aspects, namely the imitation of previous 27 Total stock returns also reflected other stock characteristics and not just economies of scale; thus, I thought about using alternative proxies. “Der Deutsche Oekonomist” provided balance-sheet data for the banking industry, and one can determine total assets. Yet proxies based on total assets are highly correlated with proxies based on nominal capital (correlation coefficient > 0.9). 28 Hsiao (1992) provided an excellent overview of panel probit models. 16 mergers. Based on this probit model, one can predict mergers and the probability to merge for different companies and industries.29 p p p k 0 k 0 k 0 m it βk x t k k m t k k B success jt k B D1896 BD1896 ui it (2) The binary variable mit takes the value one if company i executed a merger in year t and zero otherwise. The column vector xt contains inflation rates (inflationt), growth rates of net national product (gdpt), economies of scale (scaleit), market structure (structureit), and previous success of mergers in industry j (successjt). As the success of mergers in the banking industry deviated strongly from other industries shown in Fig. 2, it is reasonable to allow a shift in the slope coefficient for banks by inserting the interaction term Bsuccessjt. Schenk (2001) stressed that good macroeconomic conditions are a prerequisite for starting a merger wave; hence, economic growth rates are included. As discussed in the previous section on the long-term success of mergers, inflationary shocks could affect the real valuation of companies. Modigliani and Cohn (1979) argued that higher inflation trigger a period of real undervaluation of stocks, as real share prices fall more than real dividends. The valuation of a company is relevant for the merger process, and it is commonly believed that overvalued markets make a merger wave more likely.30 When stocks of an acquirer are overvalued, an 29 Granger causality tests indicate that mergers did not influence the explanatory variables used in my panel probit model. Particularly, mergers did not Granger cause inflation (p-value: 0.655), economic growth (p-value: 0.578), success (p-value: 0.684), the interaction term (banks and new exchange law 1896) (p-value: 0.598), the number of mergers (p-value: 0.485), economies of scale (p-value: 0.829), and market structure (p-value: 0.963). The lacking impact of mergers on these explanatory variables shows that there is no causality problem, when I use explanatory variables without lags (k=0) in my panel probit model. 30 Recently, Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004) constructed a theoretical model that explains the emergence of a merger wave by high market valuations. As standard cointegration tests and panel cointegration tests rejected a long-term equilibrium of price-dividend ratios, I inserted inflation rates to control for the real valuation of companies, instead of using price-dividend ratios. 17 acquisition becomes cheaper, as the company can use its own overvalued stocks to finance the expansion. To test the hypothesis that decision-makers imitated the behavior of other companies, the number of mergers m t conduced by the 35 companies in the previous year enters the equation on the right-hand side. Regulatory changes during my investigation period could affect the probability to merge. In particular, the new exchange law established in the year 1896 contributed to the creation of the German universal banking system, which is widely discussed in the current literature.31 Without any doubts, there are some good qualitative arguments why the exchange law should affect the concentration process especially in the banking industry. For instance, the restrictions regarding forward dealings on exchanges imposed by the new law created a new profitable niche for large banks to conduct their own forward trading. Furthermore, the required minimum issue volume for new share was one million Mark; thus, Tilly (1982) argued that acquisitions by larger companies were favored. To quantify the impact of the new exchange law in 1896, I specify a dummy variable D1896 that takes the value one for the period after the year 1896 and zero otherwise. To test whether the banking industry had a higher propensity to merge over the whole period, I include a dummy for banks (B). The interaction term between both dummies (BD1896) controls for alleged special advantages of banks because of the new regulatory environment. To determine the lag length of this dynamic model, I carry out the maximum likelihood estimation of model (2) with different lag specifications. Thereafter, the Akaike and the Schwarz criteria are calculated together with the log likelihood of the respective model. To ensure reliable comparisons among different lag structures, the relevant sample is fixed. Table 5 reports the outcomes of model (2) with different lag length p. The Akaike and Schwarz criteria reach their minimum in the case of the model without lags; thus, lags are not required. 31 By far the most elaborate study on this issue is Fohlin’s (2002) contribution. 18 Moreover, log-likelihood ratio tests indicate that random effects matter, for the null hypothesis of no random effects can be rejected in all cases. (Insert Table 5) My findings point out that macroeconomic conditions and economies of scale did not affect the probability to merge, in spite of the assertion mentioned by Schenk (2001) that good macroeconomic surroundings are the prerequisite for starting merger waves. Yet economic conditions were not bad during the first merger wave – but not mainly responsible for the increase in merger activity. Rosenberg (1967) among others divided the period before 1914 into a depressive period from 1873 to 1897 characterized by deflationary tendencies and a period of economic growth from 1898 to 1914. Market structure mattered in that mergers were more likely if the company was large relative to the smallest companies (25% percentile); hence, gaining more market power was a strong motive for merging. The previous success of mergers in the respective industry had a positive impact on merger activity; however, the banking industry differed in that respect, as the interaction term (Bsuccessjt) is significant at least on the 10% level of significance. Consequently, banks conducted more mergers, in spite of the lacking success of former mergers. The new exchange law in 1896 was only relevant for the banking industry, as the interaction term (BD1896) is highly significant, and the insignificant dummy D1896 does not demonstrate an impact on other industries. Thereby, the new law supported mergers among banks, while doing little for other industries. Imitating behavior can be confirmed, for former mergers ( m t ) in the economy triggered future transactions. Accordingly, one can state that mergers made subsequent mergers more likely, and hence the first merger wave emerged. This imitating behavior of decision makers can be due to the minimax-regret principle or to rational information-based herding. As mergers in the banking industry were more likely even if previous mergers were not successful, one can state that banks followed the minimax-regret principle. In contrast, previous mergers increased total stock returns in other industries and were successful. The 19 coefficient of the successjt variable is positive and significant on the 5% level of significance; consequently, successful mergers made future mergers more likely. The imitating behavior in other industries could be explained by rational information-based herding because only successful mergers created incentives to imitate. To illustrate the probit model, I calculated one-step-ahead forecasts regarding the probability that a firm will merge in the next year. The model provides for every year and every company forecasted probabilities. Fig. 4 depicts the average probability of the whole sample for the respective year based on the model without lags shown in table 5. To highlight whether other economic factors, i.e. market structure, justified imitating behavior, I derived forecasts without imitation by excluding the number of previous mergers ( m t ) as explanatory variable. By comparing these two series, one can evaluate whether imitating the move of others was a good strategy in that other economic factors like market structure and the success of previous mergers stimulated additional mergers in future. Since 1898 – two years after the new exchange law was introduced – to 1904, rational economic factors caused a high probability to merge. The model with imitating behavior predicted lower probabilities than the model without imitation. During the starting phase of the merge wave imitating other mergers was justified by economic factors (i.e. mergers increased total stock returns) – but from 1904 to 1913 imitating behavior led to mergers not justified by economic surroundings. Fig. 2 shows that after 1906 mergers were no longer profitable for shareholders, and imitating yielded shareholder value destroying mergers. Accordingly, in the beginning of a merger wave like in the case of other bubbles and manias on stock markets `riding the wave’ by imitating others was profitable. This finding is in line with the literature on rational herd behavior, as decision-makers that imitate others and neglect their own information create a negative externality. In the end of such an information cascade, the information content of previous mergers declines rapidly; thus, imitation might lead to bad decisions. (Insert Fig.4.) 20 5. Conclusion Based on my descriptive findings, I confirm the emergence of the first merger wave in Germany that started around 1898 accompanied by the introduction of the new exchange law in 1896. The panel VAR model uncovers that mergers were not successful over the whole period, albeit periods of successful mergers can be identified applying rolling regressions. From 1898 to 1904, mergers affected total stock returns positively – but shareholders of banks did not benefit from mergers. This period coincided with the beginning of the merger wave and points to the fact that banks merged, in spite of generating losses for their shareholders. The panel probit model reveals that mergers were more likely when the company was large compared to the smallest companies (25% percentile) in the industry; hence, mergers could be used to increase market power further. Interestingly, the previous success of mergers had a positive influence on merger activity – except for the banking industry. This means that even if previous mergers were not successful, banks tended to increase their merger activity. As the number of previously executed mergers increased the probability for merging in future, serial dependency between merger decisions can be confirmed. Palacios-Huerta (2003) argued that this is already a confirmation that decision-makers follow a minimax-regret principle – but serial dependency might be caused by rational information-based herd behavior.32 As the success of previous mergers could be observed by decision-makers, imitating unsuccessful mergers cannot be justified by rational information-based herding – but is an indication that Schenk’s (2001) minimax-regret principle can explain this firm behavior. Correspondingly, one can distinguish between the imitating behavior in the banking industry and in other industries. Banks tended to imitate unsuccessful mergers, and hence bank managers followed the minimax-regret principle because they valued potential failures less 32 I refer to Banerjee (1992), Bikhchandani et al. (1992), Welch (1992) and Avery and Zemsky (1998). 21 than the regret to overlook attractive mergers. Contrarily, in the case of the three other main industries mergers were more likely if former mergers increased total stock returns; consequently, rational information-based herd behavior can explain the behavior of these companies. Noteworthy, the introduction of the new exchange law in 1896 only increased the probability of merging in the banking industry and contributed to the emergence of the merger wave of banks. This historical example underlines the importance of imitating behavior motivated by the minimax-regret principle, information-based herding and bounded rationality for the emergence of the first merger wave. Institutions and laws might change – but the human nature remains the same. Henceforth, the next merger mania will occur with certainty. 22 References Armitage, S., 1995, Event study methods and evidence on their performance, Journal of Economic Surveys 9, 25-52. Avery, C. and P. Zemsky, 1998, Multidimensional uncertainty and herd behavior in financial markets, American Economic Review 88, 724-748. Baltzer, M. and G. Kling, 2004, Resiliency of the pre-World War I German stock exchange: Evidence from a panel vector autoregression, conference proceedings of the 5th World Congress of Cliometrics 2004, 169-180. Banerjee, A., 1992, A simple model of herd behavior, Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 992-1026. Banerjee, A. and E.W. Eckard, 2001, Why regulate insider trading? Evidence from the first Great Merger Wave (1896-1903), The American Economic Review 91, 1329-1349. Baten, J., 2001a, Produktivitätsvorteil in kleinen und mittelgroßen Industrieunternehmen, Sicherheit in Großunternehmen? Die Gesamtfaktorproduktivität um 1900, Tübinger Diskussionsbeitrag 217. Baten, J., 2001b, Große und kleine Unternehmen in der Krise von 1900-1902, Tübinger Diskussionsbeitrag 216. Baten, J., 2001c, Expansion und Überleben von Unternehmen in der `Ersten Phase der Globalisierung´, Tübinger Diskussionsbeitrag 215. Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D. and I. Welch, 1998, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades, Journal of Political Economy 100, 992-1026. Boeckem, S., 2002, Merger mania or after you - a theory of endogenous merger waves, Working Paper, Universität Dortmund. Borg, J.R. and Leeth, J.D., 2000, The impact of takeovers on shareholder wealth during the 1920s merger wave, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35, 217-238. 23 Borg, J.R. and Leeth, J.D., 1994, The impact of mergers on acquiring firm shareholder wealth: The 1905-1930 experience, Empirica 21, 221-244. Borg, J.R., Borg, M.O. and Leeth, J.D., 1989, The success of mergers in the 1920s: A stock market appraisal of the second merger wave, International Journal of Industrial Organization 7, 117-131. Burhop, C. and G. Wolff, 2003, A compromise estimate of the net national product and the business cycle in Germany, 1851 – 1913, conference proceedings of the 5th World Congress of Cliometrics 2004, 97-108. Chandler, A.D., 1990, Scale and scope: The dynamics of industrial capitalism, Cambridge. Chandler, A.D., 1977, The visible hand, Cambridge. Davis, L., 1966, The capital markets and industrial concentration; the US and the UK, a comparative study, Economic History Review 19, 255-272. Elbaum, B. and W. Lazonick, 1986, An institutional perspective on the British decline, in: The decline of the British Economy, Elbaum, B. and W. Lazonick (ed.), Oxford. Eis, C., 1971, The 1919-1930 merger movement in American industry, Arno Press, New York. Farrell, J. and C. Shapiro, 1990, Horizontal mergers: An equilibrium analysis, American Economic Review 80, 107-126. Feldenkirchen, W., 1988, Concentration in German industry, 1870-1939, in: The concentration process in the entrepreneurial economy since the late 19th century, Pohl, H. (ed.), Steiner-Verlag, Wiesbaden. Fohlin, C., 2002, Regulation, taxation and the development of the German universal banking system, 1884-1913, European Review of Economic History 6, 221-254. Fremdling, R., 1991, Productivity comparison between Great Britain and Germany, 18551913, Scandinavian Economic History Review 39, 28-42. Gerschenkron, A., 1962, Economic backwardness in historical perspective, Cambridge. 24 Hadri, K., 2000, Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data, The Econometrics Journal 3, 148-161. Hamilton, J.D., 1994, Time series analysis, Princeton, Princeton University Press. Hannah, L., 1974, Mergers in British manufacturing industry, 1880-1918, Oxford Economic Papers 26, 1-20. Ho, T., 2002, A panel cointegration approach to the investment-saving correlation, Empirical Economics 27, 91-100. Hoffmann, W.G., 1965, Das Wachstum der deutschen Wirtschaft seit der Mitte des 19. Jahrhunderts, Berlin. Hsiao, C., 1992, The econometrics of panel data: Handbook of theory and applications, Advanced Studies in Theoretical and Applied Econometrics, vol. 28. Norwell, Mass. and Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic. Huerkamp C., 1979, Fusionen der 100 größten Unternehmen von 1907 zwischen 1887 und 1907, in: Horn and Kocka (ed.), Recht und Entwicklung der Grossunternehmen, Goettingen. Im, K., Pesaran, M.H. and Y. Shin, 1997, Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. unpublished working paper, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge. Jacobs, A. and H. Richter, 1935, Die Großhandelspreise in Deutschland von 1792 bis 1934, Hamburg. Jarrel, G.A. and A.B. Poulsen, 1989, The returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: Evidence from three decades, Financial Management 18, 12-19. Jensen, M.C., 1988, Takeovers: Their causes and consequences, Journal of Economic Perspective 2, 21-48. 25 Kinghorn, J.R. and J.V. Nye, 1996, The scale of production in western economic development: A comparison of official industry statistics in the United States, Britain, France, and Germany, 1905-1913, Journal of Economic History 56, 90-112. Kocka, J. and H. Siegrist, 1979, Die hundert größten Industrieunternehmen im späten 19. und frühen 20.Jahrhundert. Expansion, Diversifikation und Integration im internationalen Vegleich, in: Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20.Jahrhundert, Horn, N. and J. Kocka (ed.), Vandenhoeck&Ruprecht, Göttingen. Levin, A., Lin, C. and C. J. Chu, 2002, Unit Root Tests in Panel Data: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties, Journal of Econometrics 108, 1-24. Levin, D., 1990, Horizontal mergers: The 50-percent benchmark, American Economic Review 80, 1238-1245. Magenheim, E.B. and Mueller, D.C., 1988, On measuring the effect of acquisitions on acquiring firm shareholders’, in Coffee, J.C., Lowenstein, L. and S. Rose-Ackerman (eds.), Knights, raiders, and targets: The impact of the hostile takeover, New York, NY, Oxford University Press. Maksimovic, V. and G. Phillips, 2001, The market for corporate assets: Who engages in mergers and asset sales and are there efficiency gains? Journal of Finance 56, 2019-2065. McFadden, D., 1974, The measurement of urban travel demand, In Zarembka, P. (ed.), Frontiers in econometrics, New York, Academic Press. Modigliani, F. and R.A. Cohn, 1979, Inflation, rational valuation and the market, Financial Analysts Journal 35, 24-44. Morse, D., 1984, An econometric analysis of the choice of daily versus monthly returns in tests of information content, Journal of Accounting Research 22, 605-623. Nelson, R.L., 1959, Merger Movements in American Industry 1895-1956, Princeton University Press; Princeton, New Jersey. 26 Palacios-Huerta, I., 2003, Professionals play minimax, Review of Economic Studies 70, 395-415. Rhodes-Kropf, M. and S. Viswanathan, 2004, Market valuation and merger waves, Journal of Finance 59, 2685-2718. Rosenberg, H., 1967, Große Depression und Bismarckzeit: Wirtschaftsablauf, Gesellschaft und Politik in Mitteleuropa, Berlin. Salant, S., Switzer, S. and R. Reynolds, 1983, Losses from horizontal mergers: The effect of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot-Nash equilibrium, Quarterly Journal of Economics 98, 185-199. Schenk, H., 2001, Mergers and the economy: Theory and policy implications, presented at the workshop entitled `European Integration, Financial Systems and Corporate Performance´, UN University, Institute for New Technologies Kasteel Vaeshartelt. Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny, 1988, Value maximization and the acquisition process, Journal of Economic Perspective 2, 7-20. Simon, H.A., 1955, A behavioral model of rational choice, Quarterly Journal of Economics 69, 99-118. Spoerer, M., 1996, Von Scheingewinnen zum Ruestungsboom: Die Eigenkapitalrentabilitaet der deutschen Industrieaktiengesellschaften 1925-1941, Stuttgart. Stigler, G. J., 1950, Monopoly and oligopoly by merger, The American Economic Review 40, 23-34. Tilly, R., 1999, Globalisierung aus historischer Sicht und das Lernen aus der Geschichte, Köln. Tilly, R., 1992, Der deutsche Kapitalmarkt und die Auslandsinvestitionen von 1870 bis 1913, in: ifo Studien 38, 200-225. Tilly, R., 1986, German banking, 1850-1914. Development assistance for the strong, Journal of European Economic History 15, 113-152. 27 Tilly, R., 1982, Mergers, external growth, and finance in the development of large-scale enterprise in Germany, 1880-1913, Journal of Economic History 42, 629- 658. Welch, I., 1992, Sequential sales, learning, and cascades, Journal of Finance 47, 695-732. Weston, J. F., 1953, The role of mergers in the growth of large firms, Berkeley. Williamson, J. G., 1996, Globalization, convergence and history, Journal of Economic History 56, 277-306. Williamson, J. G., 1996, Globalization, convergence and history, Journal of Economic History 56, 277-306. Winters, P. R., 1966, Forecasting sales by exponentially weighted moving averages, Management Science 6, 324-342. Data sources Der Deutsche Oekonomist, 1883-1913, Berlin. Handbuch der deutschen Aktien-Gesellschaften, issue 1900/1901 and 1913/1914, volume I and II. Kaiserliches Statistisches Amt, 1911/1912, Vierteljahreshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs – Ergänzungsheft zu 1913, II, Berlin. Saling’s Börsen-Jahrbuch, 1913/1914, Ein Handbuch für Kapitalisten und Effektenbesitzer. 2nd ed., Berlin, Leipzig. Saling’s Börsen-Papiere, 1874-6, vol. 1-5, 4th ed., Berlin. Vierteljahreshefte zur Statistik des Deutschen Reichs, 1892-1912, Berlin.