Hegemony and Empire Professor Naill Ferguson 2004 In this short extract from Nail Ferguson’s recent book Colossus: The Rise and Fall of the American Empire he explores the various current definitions of terms such as hegemony, global leadership and empire. Drawing on his extensive historical research on empires he outlines in table format a Typology of Empire. This enables a comparison to be made between the current America Empire and that of other empires in particular the former British Empire. Hegemony and Empire Professor Naill Ferguson 2004 “I helped make Haiti and Cuba a decent place for the National City Bank boys to collect revenues in. I helped in the raping of half a dozen Central American republics for the benefit of Wall Street. The record of racketeering is long. I helped purify Nicaragua for the international banking house of Brown Brothers in 1909 - 1912. I brought light to the Dominican Republic for American sugar interests in 1916. I helped make Honduras ‘right’ for American fruit companies in 1903 …….. Looking back on it, I feel I might have given Al Capone a few hints. The best he could do was to operate his racket in three city districts. We Marines operated on three continents.” General Smedley D. Butler, US Marine Corps, 1935 1 Julius Caesar called himself imperator but never king. His adopted heir Augustus preferred princeps. Emperors can call themselves what they like, and so can empires. The kingdom of England was proclaimed an empire – by Henry VIII – before it became one2. The United States by contrast has long been an empire, but eschews the appellation. Define the term empire narrowly enough, of course, and the United States can easily be excluded from the category. Here is a typical example: “Real imperial power ……… means a direct monopoly over the organisation and use of armed might. It means direct control over the administration of justice and the definition thereof. It means control over what is bought and sold, the terms of trade and permission to trade …… Let us stop talking of an American empire, for there is and there will be no such thing.”3 For a generation of realist writers, eager to rebut Soviet charges of American imperialism, it became conventional to argue that the United States had only briefly flirted with this kind of formal empire, beginning with the annexation of the Philippines in 1898 and ending by the 1930s.4 What the United States did after the end of the Second World War was, however, fundamentally different in character. According to one recent formulation, it was “not an imperial state with a predatory intent”; it was “more concerned with enhancing regional stability and security and protecting international trade than enlarging its power at the expense of others.”5 If the United States was not an empire, then what was it? And what is it now that the Soviet empire it was avowedly striving to “contain” is no more? “The only superpower” – existing in a unipolar world – is one way of describing it. Hyperpuisance was the (certainly ironical) coinage of the former French foreign minister Hubert Verdine. Some writers favour more anaemic terms like global leadership,6 while Philip Bobbitt simply regards the United States as a particularly successful form of nation-state.7 A recent series of seminars at Harvard’s Kennedy School opted for the inoffensive term primacy. But by far the most popular term among writers on international relations remains hegemony8. What is this thing called hegemony? Is it merely a euphemism for empire, or does it describe the role of the primus inter pares, the leader of an alliance, rather than a ruler over subject peoples? And what are the hegemon’s motives? Does it exert power beyond its borders for its own self-interested purposes? Or is it engaged altruistically in the provision of international public goods? The word was used originally to describe the relationship of Athens to the other Greek city-states when they leagued together to defend themselves against the Persian Empire; Athens led but did not rule over the others9. In so-called world-system theory, by contrast, hegemony means more than mere leadership, but less than outright empire10. In yet another, narrower definition, the hegemon’s principal function in the twentieth century was to underwrite a liberal international commercial and financial system11. In what became known, somewhat inelegantly, as hegemonic stability theory, the fundamental question of the postwar period was how far and for how long the United States would remain committed to free trade once other economies, benefiting from precisely the liberal economic order made possible by US hegemony, began to catch up. Would Americans revert to protectionist policies in an effort to perpetuate their hegemony or stick with free trade at the risk of experiencing relative decline? This has been called the hegemon’s dilemma that Britain had faced before 191412. Yet if the British Empire was America’s precursor as the global hegemon, might not the United States equally well be Britain’s successor as an Anglo-phone empire? Most historians would agree that if anything, American economic power after 1945 exceeded that of Britain after 1815, a comparable watershed of power following the final defeat of Napoleonic France. First, the extraordinary growth in productivity achieved between around 1890 and 1950 eclipsed anything previously achieved by Britain, even in the first flush of the Industrial Revolution. Secondly, the United States very deliberately used its power to advance multilateral and mutually balanced tariff reductions under the General Agreement of Tariffs and Trade (later the World Trade Organisation). Thus the reductions of tariffs achieved in the Kennedy Round (1967) and in subsequent “rounds” of negotiation owed much to American pressures such as the“conditionality” attached to loans from the Washington-based International Monetary Fund. By contrast, the nineteenth-century spread of free trade and free navigation – the “public goods” most commonly attributed to the British Empire – were as much spontaneous phenomena as they were direct consequences of British power. Thirdly, successive US governments allegedly took advantage of the dollar’s role as a key currency before and after the breakdown of Bretton Woods. The US government had access to a “gold mine of paper” and could therefore collect a subsidy from foreigners in the form of seigniorage (by selling foreigners dollars and dollar-denominated assets that then depreciated in value)13. The gold standard offered Britain no such advantages, and perhaps even some disadvantages. Finally, the Pax Britannica depended mainly on the Royal Navy and was less “penetrative” than the “full-spectrum dominance” aimed for today by the American military. For a century, with the sole exception of the Crimean War, Britain felt unable to undertake military interventions in Europe, the theatre most vital to its own survival, and when it was forced to do so in 1914 and in 1939, it struggled to prevail14. We arrive at the somewhat paradoxical conclusion that a hegemon can be more powerful than an empire. The distinction between hegemony and empire would be legitimate if the term empire did simply mean, as so many American commentators seem to assume, direct rule over foreign territories without any political representation of their inhabitants. But students of imperial history have a more sophisticated conceptual framework than that. At the time, British colonial administrators like Frederick Lugard clearly understood the distinction between “direct” and “indirect” rule; large parts of the British Empire in Asia and Africa were ruled indirectly – that is, through the agency of local potentates rather than British governors. A further distinction was introduced by John Gallagher and Ronald Robinson in their seminal 1953 article on “the imperialism of free trade”. This encapsulated the way the Victorians used their naval and financial power to open the markets of countries outside their colonial ambit15. Equally illuminating is the now widely accepted distinction between “formal” and “informal empire”. The British did not formally govern Argentina, for example, but the merchant banks of the City of London exerted such a powerful influence on its fiscal and monetary policy that Argentina’s independence was heavily qualified16 . In the words of one of the few modern historians to attempt a genuinely comparative study of the subject, an empire is “first and foremost, a very great power that has left its mark on the international relations of an era …….. a polity that rules over wide territories and many peoples, since the management of space and multi-ethnicity is one of the great perennial dilemmas of empire …… An empire is by definition ……. not a polity ruled with the explicit consent of its peoples. [But] by a process of assimilation of peoples of democratisation of institutions empires can transform themselves into multinational federations or even nation states.”17 It is possible to be still more precise than this. In the table below I have attempted a simple typology intended to capture the diversity of forms that can be subsumed under the category “empires”. For example, an empire could be an oligarchy at home, aiming to acquire raw materials from abroad, thereby increasing international trade, using military methods, imposing a market economy, in the interests of its ruling elite, with a hierarchical social character. Another empire might be a democracy at home, mainly interested in security, providing peace as a public good, ruling mainly through firms and non-governmental organisations (NGOs), promoting a mixed economy, in the interests of all inhabitants, with an assimilative social character. The first column reminds us that imperial power can be acquired by more than one type of political system. The self-interested objectives of imperial expansion (column two) range from the fundamental need to ensure the security of the metropolis by imposing order on enemies at its (initial) borders to the collection of rents and taxation from subject peoples, to say nothing of the perhaps more obvious prizes of new land for settlement, raw materials, treasure and manpower, all of which, it should be emphasised, would need to be available at lower prices than they would cost in free exchange with independent peoples if the cost of conquest and colonisation were to be justified18. At the same time, an empire may provide “public-goods” – this is, intended or unintended benefits of imperial rule flowing not to the rulers but to the ruled and indeed beyond to third parties: less conflict, increased trade or investment, improved justice or governance, better education (which may or may not be associated with religious conversion, something we would not nowadays regard as a public good) or improved material conditions. Typology of Empires Metropolitan System Self-interested Objectives Public Goods Methods of Rule Economic System Cui Bono? Social Character Tyranny Security Peace Military Plantation Ruling Elite Genocidal Aristocracy Communications Trade Bureaucracy Feudal Metropolitan Hierarchical Oligarchy Land Investment Settlement Mercantilist Settlers Converting Democracy Raw Materials Law Market Local Elites Assimilative Treasure Governance Nongovernmental Organisations Mixed All Inhabitants Manpower Education Firms Planned Rents Conversion Delegation to Local Elites Taxation Health The fourth column tells us that imperial rule can be implemented by more than one kind of functionary: soldiers, civil servants, settlers, voluntary associations, firms, and local elites all can in different ways impose the will of the centre on the periphery. There are almost as many varieties of imperial economic system, ranging from slavery to laissez-faire, from one form of serfdom (feudalism) to another (the planned economy). Nor is it by any means a given that the benefits of empire should flow simply to the metropolitan society. It may only be the elite of that society that reaps the benefits of empire (as Lance E Davis and R. A. Huttenback claimed in the case of the British Empire)19; it may be colonists drawn from lower-income groups in the metropole; it may in some cases be subject peoples or the elites within subject societies. Finally, the social character of an empire – to be precise, the attitudes of the rulers towards the ruled – may vary. At one extreme lies the genocidal empire of National Socialist Germany, intent on the annihilation of specific ethnic groups and the deliberate degradation of others. At the other extreme lies the Roman model of empire, in which citizenship was obtainable under certain conditions regardless of ethnicity (a model with obvious applicability to the case of the United States). In the middle lies the Victorian model of complex racial and social hierarchy, in which inequalities of wealth and status were mitigated by a general (though certainly not unqualified) principle of equality before the law. The precise combination of all these variables determines, among other things, the geographical extent – and of course the duration – of an empire. With a broader and more sophisticated definition of empire, it seems possible to dispense altogether with the term hegemony. Instead, it can be argued with some plausibility that the American empire has up until now, with a few exceptions, preferred indirect rule to direct rule and informal empire to formal empire. Indeed, its cold war–era hegemony might better be understood as an “empire by invitation”20. The question is whether or not the recent, conspicuously uninvited invasions of Afghanistan and Iraq presage a transition to more direct and formal imperial structures. Adapting the terminology of the Typology of Empires table above, the American empire can therefore be summed up as follows. It goes without saying that it is a liberal democracy and market economy, though its polity has some illiberal characteristics21 and its economy has a surprisingly high level of state intervention (“mixed” might be more accurate than “market”). It is primarily concerned with its own security and maintaining international communications and, secondarily, with ensuring access to raw materials (principally, though not exclusively, oil). It is also in the business of providing a limited number of public goods: peace, by intervening against some bellicose regimes and in some civil wars; freedom of the seas and skies for trade; and a distinctive form of “conversion” usually called Americanisation, which is carried out less by old –style Christian missionaries than by the exporters of American consumer goods and entertainment. Its methods of formal rule are primarily military in character; its methods of informal rule rely heavily on nongovernmental organisations and corporations and, in some cases, local elites. Who benefits from this empire? Some would argue, with the economist Paul Krugman, that only its wealthy elite does – specifically, that part of its wealthy elite associated with the Republican Party and the oil industry22. The conventional wisdom of the Left is that the United States uses its power to impoverish people in the developing world. Others would claim that many millions of people around the world have benefited in some way or another from the existence of America’s empire – not least the West Europeans, Japanese and South Koreans who were able to prosper during the cold war under the protection of the American nuclear “umbrella” – and that the economic losers of the post-cold war era, particularly in sub-Saharan Africa, are victims not of American power but of its absence. For the American empire is limited in its extent. It conspicuously lacks the voracious appetite for territorial expansion overseas that characterised the empires of the West European seaboard. It prefers the idea that foreigners will Americanise themselves without the need for formal rule. Even when it conquers, it resists annexation – one reason why the duration of its offshore imperial undertakings has tended to be, and will in all probability continue to be, relatively short. Indeed, a peculiarity of American imperialism – perhaps its principal shortcoming – is its excessively short time horizon. “The hidden hand of the market will never work without the hidden fist. MacDonald’s cannot flourish without McDonnell Douglas …….. And the hidden fist that keeps the world safe for Silicon Valley’s technologies to flourish is called the US Army, Air Force, Navy, and Marine Corps.” Thomas Friedmann, 1999, The Lexus and the Olive Tree: Understanding Globalisation (Farrar, Strauss and Giroux, New York), p.373. Source: Colossus: The Rise and Fall of the American Empire Niall Ferguson, Penguin Books, London, 2004, Price UK£8.99 Pages: 7 - 13 ISBN 0-141-01700-7 Alternative Perspectives and Analysis: For those seeking an alternative historical perspective and analysis from the point of view of the colonised see Walter Rodney’s ground breaking and classic study on Africa: How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, Bogle-L’Ouveture Publications (Jamaica & London), 1972. And on Slavery see: Eric Williams, Capitalism and Slavery References 1 Schmidt, Hans, Maverick Marine: General Smedley D Butler and the Contradictions of American Military History (Lexington, Ky., 1987), p231. The quotation comes from an article written by General Butler – the most decorated marine of his generation – in an article he wrote for the magazine Common Sense in 1935. Davis, R.R., The First English Empire: Power and Identities in the British Isles, 1093 – 1343 (Oxford, 2000). 2 3 Ibid. 4 Schwabe, Klaus, The Global Role of the United States and Its Imperial Consequences, 18981973, in Wolfgang J. Mommsen and Jurgen Osterhammel (eds) Imperialism and After: Continuities and Discontinuities, (London, 1986) pp13-33. And in the words of Michael Mandelbaum, “was given up in the twentieth century:” Mandelbaum, M., Ideas That Conquered the World: Peace, Democracy and Free Markets in the Twenty-first Century, (New York, 2002) p87. 5 Kupchan, Charles A., The End of the American Era: US Foreign Policy and the Geopolitics of the Twenty-first Century (New York, 2002) p228. 6 Mandelbaum, M., Ideas That Conquered the World: Peace, Democracy and Free Markets in the Twenty-first Century, (New York, 2002) p88. Bobbitt sees imperialism as a thing of the past, having been one of the “historic, strategic and constitutional innovations” of the “state-nation” in the two centuries before 1713 and 1914. Bobbitt, Phillip, The Shield of Achilles: War, Peace, and Course of History (New York, 2002). 7 8 Kagan, Robert, Of Paradise and Power: America and Europe in the New World Order (New York, 2003) p88; Kupchan, Charles A., The End of the American Era: US Foreign Policy and the Geopolitics of the Twenty-first Century (New York, 2002) p266. 9 Johansson, S. Ryan, National Size and International Power: A Demographic Perspective on Hegemony, in Patrick Karl O’Brien and Armand Clesse, (eds.), Two Hegemonies: Britain 1846 – 1914 and the United States 1941 – 2001 (Aldershot/Burlington , Vt., 2002) p352. A hegemonic power was “a state ……… able to impose its set of rules on the interstate system, and thereby create temporarily a new political order,” and which offered “certain extra advantages for enterprises located within it or protected by it, advantages not accorded by the ‘market’ but obtained through political pressure” Wallerstein, Immanuel, Three Hegemonies in Patrick Karl O’Brien and Armand Clesse, (eds.), Two Hegemonies: Britain 1846 – 1914 and the United States 1941 – 2001 (Aldershot/Burlington , Vt., 2002) p357. 10 This notion can be traced back to Charles Kindleberger’s seminal work on the interwar world economy, which described a kind of “interregnum” after British hegemony, but before American. See Kindleberger, Charles, The World in Depression, 1929 – 1939 (Berkeley, Calif., 1973). 11 12 Kennedy, Paul, The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000 (New York, 1989). 13 Calleo, David, Reflections on American Hegemony in the Postwar Era, in Patrick Karl O’Brien and Armand Clesse, (eds.), Two Hegemonies: Britain 1846 – 1914 and the United States 1941 – 2001 (Aldershot/Burlington , Vt., 2002). See also Rosecrance, Richard, Croesus and Caesar: The Essential Transatlantic Symbiosis, National Interest, 72 (Summer 2003), pp31-35. O’Brien, Patrick Karl, The Pax Britannica and American Hegemony: Precedent, Antecedent or Just Another History? in Patrick Karl O’Brien and Armand Clesse, (eds.), Two Hegemonies: Britain 1846 – 1914 and the United States 1941 – 2001 (Aldershot/Burlington , Vt., 2002), pp3-64. 14 15 Gallagher, John, and Robinson, Ronald, The Imperialism of Free Trade, Economic History Review, 2nd Series, 6 (1953), pp1-15. 16 See Robert Freeman Smith, Latin America, the United States and the European Powers, 1830 – 1930, in Leslie Bethall (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin America, Vol.4 (Cambridge, 1986),p85-88 also Cain, P.J and A.G. Hopkins, British Imperialism, 1688 -2000, 2nd ed. (Harlow, 2001). 17 Lieven, Dominic, Empire: The Russian Empire and Its Rivals, (London, 2000), p.xiv. 18 See for an attempt at a formal economic theory of empire Grossman, Herschel I., and Juan Mendoza, Annexation and Conquest? The Economics of Empire Building, NBER Working Paper, 8109 (February 2001). 19 Davis, Lance E., and R. A. Huttenback, Mammom and the Pursuit of Empire: The Political Economy of British Imperialism, 1860 – 1912 (Cambridge, 1986). Lundestad, Geir, The American “Empire” and Other Studies of US Foreign Policy in a Comparative Perspective (Oxford, 1990). 20 21 Zararia, Fareed, The Future of Freedom: Illiberal Democracy at Home and Abroad (New York, 2003), p162. 22 For some recent examples, see Joseph Nye, The New Rome Meets the New Barbarians: How America Should Wield Its Power, Economist, March 23, 2002; Jonathan Freeland, Rome AD ….. Rome DC, Guardian, September 18, 2002; Robert Harris, Return of the Romans, Sunday Times, August 31, 2003