Efficient Fare and Value Capture A Unified Theoretic Approach YING, Jiang Qian Faculty of Regional Studies Gifu University Yanagido 1-1 Gifu 501, Japan Tel: +81-58-2933306 Fax: +81-58-2933118 Email: ying@cc.gifu-u.ac.jp Abstract Due to the existence of economies of scale in public transit systems, efficient marginal cost pricing brings about a deficit to the supplier. Based on an examination of the composition of the travel demand for public transit, we study the economic implications of average cost pricing and marginal cost pricing with various demand compositions. As a result, the bundling of passengers with third party beneficiaries of public transit is suggested as a potential method for improving the fiscal performance of transit systems. This serves as a rigorous economic theoretic foundation for marketing techniques for increasing public transit ridership. 1. Introduction There are two main causes of fiscal problems in public transit systems: the first is that a large part of the benefit of public transit is accrued to third parties other than the passengers and the transit supplier, e.g., businesses, retailers and owners of properties in the proximity of public transport facilities, which is difficult to be sufficiently captured by the supplier; the second is that there exist economies of scale in public transit systems due to which efficient marginal cost pricing brings about a deficit to the supplier. Therefore, any public policy that aims to improve the performance of public transport systems and to alleviate the fiscal stress in transport investment and operation, should effectively increase the use of public transit and should have a mechanism to collect the lost benefit back from the third party beneficiaries. Indeed, these two approaches have been adopted in practice and have been a theme of extensive research. See Transportation Research Board (1999 a, b), Taylor et al. (2002), and Nuworsoo (2004) for the methods for increasing the use and hence revenues of public transit, and Smith and Gihring (2006) for a review of the literature on benefit capture issues. The purpose of this paper is to establish a unified economic theoretic foundation for these two approaches. In this paper, the composition of the travel demand for public transport systems is examined. The relationship between average cost pricing and marginal cost pricing with various demand compositions will be studied. Based on this, efficient pricing schemes will be examined. It will be shown that the conventional efficiency-oriented marginal cost pricing based fare scheme lose benefit simply because transit passengers do not belong to a single organization. Thus as a complementary of conventional hostile instrument of value capturing, fare programs aimed at the organizing of passenger groups may serve as a friendly value capturing instrument. In Section 2, the theoretical and practical issues regarding economies of scale and value capture problems in public transport will be reviewed. In Section 3, the composition of travel demand on public transport is analyzed. Economic implications of average cost pricing and marginal cost pricing are examined. In 2 Section 4, we discuss how these theoretical results are related to practical instruments for improving the fiscal performance of public transit. 2. Economies of Scale and Value Capture in Public Transport In this section we review the formulations of marginal cost pricing and average cost pricing and their economic implications in a public transit system with economies of scale. We then briefly review the theory and practice of value capture, and marketing techniques for promoting transit use. 2.1. Economies of Scale, Average Cost Pricing and Marginal Cost Pricing In this paper, the cost of a public transit system refers to the cost of building the transit system and providing transit services. Therefore, average cost denotes the total supply cost divided by the number of passengers, marginal cost denotes the extra cost for providing travel service to a marginal passenger. Due to the fact that the fixed costs invested in public transit are usually very high, the supply of public transit services exhibits significant economies of scale (Savage 1997). In this case, average cost pricing in general does not yield the optimal level of patronage of the system. Let p be transit fare level, q be the transit demand. Let D(p) denote the demand function and D 1 (q) its inverse. Let MC(q) and AC(q) denote the marginal cost function and the average cost function, respectively. As shown in Figure 1, let E be the intersection of marginal cost curve MC(q) with inverse demand curve D 1 (q) , F the intersection of the average cost curve AC(q) with D 1 (q) , and G the point on MC corresponding to the demand at point F. Under the average cost pricing program, the demand is smaller than the optimum level and a deadweight loss of surplus equal to the area EFG occurs. On the other hand, if the marginal cost pricing scheme is enforced, then the patronage will achieve an optimal level (point E), but it will be accompanied by a fiscal deficit of the transit supplier because the average cost at the demand level of E is greater than the marginal cost (Hotelling 1938). 2.2. Who Benefits from Marginal Cost Pricing? 3 Although marginal cost pricing yields the most efficient use of the transit system, it brings about a deficit. This also has negative impact on social equity because some tax payers who do not use the public transit and do not benefit from the transit system also have to pay for the deficit through taxation. According to Vickrey (2001), the total cost for urban public transit investment and operation differs from the revenue collected based on marginal cost pricing by an amount which is capitalized into “site-values” in the relevant area. Vickrey proposed that “the subsidy should be covered by a tax on site values--the value of urban locations.” 2.3 Conventional Value Capturing Schemes The above logic justifies the proposal of collecting fees from the beneficiaries (Vickrey 2001, Batt 2001, Smith and Gihring 2006). In reality, part of such benefit is actually captured through taxation, including property tax, corporate tax, sales tax, and employment tax. Excess charges to property owners and companies in the form of benefit assessment have also been conducted. See Stopher (1993) for the case of Los Angeles. However, the effect of hostile benefit assessment has its limitations. This is because in reality there are unknown and uncertain factors which make the precise evaluation of the benefit accrued to the properties in the proximity of public transit facilities (e.g., rail stations, etc.) very difficult. In fact, it has been observed that public transit facilities do not raise property values in a uniform manner, and that there are also cases where such facilities even decrease the values of properties in their proximity (Cervro and Duncan 2002). All these factors prevent the smooth implementation of benefit assessment schemes (Stopher 1993). An effective measure for value capturing is joint development or development by the transit agency in the relevant areas (Hayashi 1989). However, this method requires that the transit agency has control of the land near transit lines. 2.4. Increasing Revenues by Marketing Methodology 4 In cases where the marginal cost is low, the critical method for reducing the deficit is to promote transit ridership and increase revenues. Key factors for promoting transit ridership include service and amenity improvements, marketing, partnerships and community collaborations (Taylor et al. 2002). In particular, the combinations of the price differentiation technique with the cooperation with businesses, universities, residential communities, are well established practical methods. Typical methods are various discount pass programs. For instance, with employer-based pass programs, companies purchase transit passes for employees or subsidize their purchase. It is reported that such programs are very effective in both promoting transit ridership and in increasing transit fare revenues (Taylor et al. 2002 and Nuworsoo 2004). 2.5. Relationship between Economies of Scale and Value Capture As reviewed above, while in theory the need for value capture is credited primarily to the economies of scale of public transit systems, in practice the techniques for value capture are not related to economies of scale, and the techniques for transit ridership promotion are not related to value capture. This might be accounted for by the fact that the mechanism of how the benefit lost due to marginal cost pricing is accrued to third parties has not been explicitly investigated in the literature. In the following section this mechanism will be explored based on an examination of the compositions of the demand for public transit. 3. Transport Demand Curve and Pricing Principles With very few exceptions where people simply enjoy “trips” either by using public transit or by car, the travel demands of most people are derivatives of other activities: commutation, shopping, excursion, tourism, and so on. According to the purpose of their travel, passengers can be grouped by the entities accommodating their activities at their destination or origin (Figure 2). For example, commutation can be seen as an input factor into a production sector. In some countries, commuting travel costs are actually paid by the employers. For instance, about 5 91% of Japanese companies pay the commutation costs for their employees (Japan Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare 2005). This means that subsidies to public transit use are eventually accrued to employers and other third party beneficiaries. This then raises the question: instead of charging the marginal cost based fares and managing to capture the lost values by other hostile measures, why not charge passengers the average costs, if the transit fares are eventually owed by the potential beneficiary third parties? We shall see that the answer to this question depends on the composition of the travel demand. We will develop our theoretic analysis with the following two assumptions. First, there are no congestion externalities in the public transit. This means that the marginal cost for providing transit service to a marginal passenger is equal to the marginal social cost of the whole transit system. Second, externalities of alternative transport mode (auto transport, in most cases) are efficiently priced. The primary benefits of a public transit system, including the reduction of road congestion and the improvement of safety and environment, all arise from the shift of auto travel to transit travel. Therefore the second assumption means that the benefits of the public transit can be measured from the demand functions for the transit system. Under these assumptions, it will be shown that marginal cost pricing creates a gap between the benefit of a group of passengers and their total cost, which is exactly the value lost to the third party beneficiaries and is to be captured by applying innovative group pricing methods advocated in the this paper. 3.1 Marginal Cost Pricing when Passengers Belong to a Single Group Suppose that public transit passengers are solely employees of a single firm and that it pays for the fares for its employees who commute by public transit. The sum of fares is a function TF(q) in the number q of transit commuters. The employees may have alternative modes of commuting, which may be costly. For example, the firm has to provide parking facilities for employees who commute by car. Suppose that by having q employees commuting by the transit system, the firm receives a benefit B(q). The demand q is determined by the following 6 condition. q arg max q {B(q) TF (q)} . (1) This requires that B(q) TF (q) . Obviously, the curve depicted by the marginal benefit function B(q ) is exactly the inverse travel demand curve for the group of passengers affiliated to the firm, i.e., D 1 (q) B(q) . Suppose that B(q) is concave, so that the marginal benefit B(q ) is decreasing. In this case, if the fare is set equal to the average cost of the transit system, then TF (q) (qAC (q)) TC (q) MC (q) . (2) The net benefit function B(q) TF (q) ( D1 (q) MC(q))dq (3) is equivalent to the social surplus (consumer surplus plus supplier surplus) up to an integral constant. Therefore we have the following proposition: Proposition I. If the firm pays for the total transit fares for its employees, then the average cost pricing scheme imposed on individual passenger results in the optimal state (where the use of the transit system is most efficient) as if marginal cost pricing is imposed on the market demand of transit ridership. If the transit agency does not negotiate with the firm, and simply sets the fare equal to the marginal cost MC(q) based on revealed market demand q, which is paid directly by the passengers, then the firm saves an amount TC(q)-qMC(q) which is exactly the benefit accrued to the firm and is exactly the value to be captured. If the transit agency negotiates with the firm and charge the total cost, then it will break even and still realize the efficient use of the transit system. This yields the same result as the conventional method of setting marginal cost pricing to individual passengers and collect an amount equal to the deficit back from the firm. 3.2. The Case of Multiple Passenger Groups—Average Cost Pricing Suppose that there are m firms each with an identical collective transit travel 7 benefit function Bi ( qi ) , i 1 , m; , j 1 m qj . q The travel cost shared by firm i is TCi qi q TC (q) , i 1,m . (4) With the other firms choices fixed, implying that q0 j i q j is given fixed, the choice of firm i is determined by dBi TCi . dqi qi (5) The following formula can be derived dBi TCi q AC (q) i MC(q) AC (q) . dqi qi q (6) dBi q AC (q) i MC(q) AC (q) means that the supply price curve confronted by dqi q group i is p AC (q) qi MC(q) AC (q) , rather than the “average cost” AC(q). q This price curve lies in between the AC and the MC curves (Figure 4). When qi q is small, that is, when the size of each passenger group associated with a firm is small, average cost pricing yields the same results as conventional average cost pricing. Let Di ( p ) be the demand function of group i, that is, the inverse function of Bi / qi , that is, Di (dBi dqi ) qi . Then the equilibrium demands are given by dBi pi , qi Di ( pi ), i 1, dqi pi AC (q ) , m; qi MC (q) AC (q) , i 1, q , m; (7) D ( p ) q. i i i When scale economies exist, MC(q) AC (q) , a small-size group faces a large deviation of price from marginal cost, yielding insufficient use of the system. If there are a lot of passenger groups represented by potential “third party” 8 beneficiaries who are mutually irrelevant, average cost pricing results in a loss of efficiency. This serves as a partial answer to our earlier question “why not charge the passengers the average costs, if the transit fares are eventually owed by the potential third party beneficiaries?” Suppose that two distinct groups i and j jointly determine their use of transit. Their aggregated demand will be determined so that their aggregated benefit is maximized. By Proposition II to be established in Section 3.3, it can be seen that their common price curve will be pi p j AC (q) qi q j q MC(q) AC(q) . (8) This is closer to the marginal cost curve than each of the price curves of individual groups was. This implies that under the average cost pricing scheme, the grouping of small groups into large ones will increase transit use, because larger groups will face with a lower price curve. A deeper exploration on the effect of grouping will be undertaken in Section 3.4. 3.3 The Case of Multiple Passenger Groups—Optimal State In the case where there are multiple passenger groups, if there exists some mechanism of cooperation among them, the optimal state can still be realized by average cost pricing. This can be shown as follows: Let W i 1 Bi TC (q) be the total benefit of all the groups minus total transport m cost. If there is a mechanism for redistributing benefit among the groups, then the total travel demand is determined by the condition that W i 1 Bi TC (q) is m maximized. Consider the following maximum total net benefit function W (q) max m B (qi ) TC (q) subject to i 1 i m q i 1 i q. (9) The Lagrangean for the maximization problem is L m i 1 Bi (qi ) TC (q) ( m q i 1 i 9 q) . (10) The conditions L qi 0 imply that dBi dqi , i 1, ,m . By the Envelop Theorem (Takayama 1985, p.137, and Varian 1992, p. 490) we have W q L q MC (q) . (11) W q dBi dqi MC (q) , i 1,, m . (12) Therefore we have The optimal q is determined by the following equations W q dBi dqi MC (q) 0, i=1,…,m, or dBi dqi MC (q), i=1,…,m m q i 1 i and (13) q. Note that dBi dqi is actually the inverse demand function of the individual passenger group i . Therefore we have the following proposition. Proposition II. If total cost is shared by the whole passenger groups and the union of the groups maximizes the sum of their net benefits, then the pricing system just yields the same result for each passenger group as marginal cost pricing schemes are applied to individual groups. In other words, the optimal state of the use of the transit can be realized by applying a pricing scheme satisfying dBi dqi MC (q), i=1,…,m. The optimal state can actually be achieved by the following incremental pricing mechanism. The incremental pricing scheme charges group i the cost which could be avoided had it not used the transit system: Ci TC (q) TC (q qi ) . (14) If each group independently decides its amount qi of use of the system, then qi is determined by dBi dqi Ci qi TC (q qi ) qi MC (q) . (15) Proposition III. If the passengers are divided into multiple groups, with perfect cooperation within each group but without any cooperation among the groups, 10 then the optimal state can be achieved by imposing separate incremental cost pricing schemes on each of the groups. A special case is that each group consists of one passenger. In this case incremental cost pricing is exactly the conventional marginal cost pricing. Another extreme case is the single group case where average cost pricing results in the most efficient use of the transit system. However, as expected by the incremental pricing scheme, if scale economies exist and there are multiple groups, then the transit system runs into deficit. This can be shown as follows: As the transit exhibits economies of scale, the average cost is a decreasing function. We have AC (q qi ) i 1 i 1 m m TC (q qi ) TC (q) AC (q ) q qi q TC (q qi ) i 1 m (16) q qi TC (q) (m 1)TC (q) q Ci i 1 (TC (q ) TC (q qi )) m mTC (q ) i 1TC (q qi ) TC (q ) m (17) 3.4 The Effect of Grouping As was seen above, in the case of multiple passenger groups, while the incremental cost pricing scheme is optimal but yields a deficit, the average cost pricing scheme has a loss of efficiency. Most realistic pricing program lies in between these two schemes. Suppose that the transit fare is set as p0 , and that the transit agency receives a lump sum subsidy to break even. If the lump sum subsidy is fixed, then the transit system can be regarded as being operated with a kind of average cost pricing scheme, where the average cost curve confronted by passengers lies below the original true average cost curve (see Figure 5). Suppose that at this stage two distinct groups i and j are organized into one, by 11 certain instrument, then they face with a common price curve pi p j AC (q) qi q j q MC(q) AC(q) , which lies below the original price curves pi AC (q) q qi MC (q) AC (q) and p j AC (q) j MC (q) AC (q) . q q Therefore, the unified groups can expand their demands qi q j to improve their benefits. This also has an effect to decrease the average cost. If the fare imposed on the rest groups is fixed at p0 , then the transit supplier will get a surplus, which contributes to the reduction of the deficit of the transit system. 4. Implication for Practice—Passengers Groupings In Section 3, we have seen that: (i) If there is a complete cooperative mechanism among all the passengers, then the average cost pricing scheme will yield the most efficient state for the use of the transit system. (ii) If the passengers are divided into multiple groups, without any cooperation among them, then the optimal state can be achieved by imposing separate incremental cost pricing schemes to each of the groups. (iii) The grouping of smaller passenger groups into larger ones can simultaneously improve the efficiency of transit use and reduce deficit. In conclusion, the design of proper fare structures and the organization of large groups of passengers contribute both to the efficient use of public transit and to the reduction of deficit. The key instrument toward this purpose is the coordination of public transit agencies with third parties which have a direct relationship with potential passengers, such as businesses, universities, housing developers, retailers, and so on. There are two different situations for the organization of passengers that may require different techniques. The first situation is that the group of potential 12 passengers (for example, employees of a firm, students of a university, or residents in a housing complex) can be identified. The literature reveals that in such cases conventional instruments such as discount pass programs are effective. See, Nuworsoo 2004, Transportation Research Board 1999 (b), and Taylor et al. 2002 for scheme design and case studies of these techniques and their effectiveness. The second is the situation where the potential passengers are unspecified, e.g., the street or shopping mall customers. In this case, the organization of passengers can be realized by applying advanced electronic technologies. For instance, if a disposable or permanent card is available for the payment of both transit fares and shop purchases, shopping customers can be grouped using this payment system. Such transaction techniques are actually being implemented in some countries (Smart Card Alliance, 2003)—mainly due to user convenience. Based on our theoretical analysis, a scheme for making full use of this coordinated payment technique in order to further promote transit ridership is shown in Figure 6. In this scheme, a retailer buys in bulk from the transit agency discounted “e-tokens”, i.e., tokens that can be stored electronically on a transit-shopping payment card. The retailer may present the customer with a transit token according to the amount purchased, in lieu of a rebate on items purchased in the shop. For the transit agency, this scheme has the same effect as employer-based or university-based pass programs. On the other hand, retailers can provide their customers with a premium at a lower cost. Two assumptions were made for the theoretical analysis: there are no congestion externalities in the public transit system, and externalities of alternative mode are efficiently priced. For the practical situation in which the main concern is the increase of revenue, congestion could not be so severe, otherwise the pricing strategies should be accompanied with the expansion of existing facilities. If the externalities of the alternative auto transportation mode are not priced, the total social value of the transit system is greater than the value enjoyed by the groups of passengers, by an amount equal to the benefit of reduction of the negative externalities in alternative mode. This amount should not be charged to the groups of passengers for using the transit system, and should be 13 paid for by local public finance as a subsidy. In this situation, the target of the grouping strategies advocated in this paper is to recover the total transit system costs except this subsidy. 5. Concluding Remarks This paper analyzed the composition of the demand for public transit and examined the implications of average cost pricing under various demand compositions. As a result, the grouping of potential passengers is proven to be a key instrument for promoting transit use and increasing revenue. The primary contribution of this work is that it provides a rigorous economic theoretic foundation for innovative transit fare programs that have been proven effective in practice. Furthermore, it has also shown that based on this theoretical foundation, novel transit fare schemes can be designed to promote transit use and increase revenues. It was assumed in our theoretic analysis that there are no congestion externalities in the public transit system and that the externalities of alternative auto transportation mode are efficiently priced. In practical situations without these assumptions being strictly satisfied, the grouping strategies still partially apply, as discussed in last section. Nevertheless, the development of a unified multimodal analytic framework in which these externalities are explicitly addressed is an important research topic to be studied in future. Acknowledgements: I would like to thank my colleague, Professor John Gordon Russell, who carefully read an earlier draft of this paper and gave detailed suggestions to improve the paper. I am also grateful to an anonymous referee whose comments have improved the clarity of this paper. References Batt, H. W. (2001) “Value Capture as a Policy Tool in Transportation Economics: An Exploration in Public Finance in the Tradition of Henry George,” 14 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Volume 60, Issue 1, pp. 195-228. Cervero, R. and Duncan, M. (2002) Land Value Impacts of Rail Transit Services in Los Angeles County, Report prepared for National Association of Realtors Urban Land Institute. Hayashi, Y. (1989) “Issues in Financing Urban Rail Transit Projects and Value Captures,” Transportation Research 23A (1) pp. 35-44. Hotelling, H. (1938) “The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Taxation and of Railway and Utility Rates,” Econometrica 6 (3), pp. 242—269. Japan Ministry of Health, Labor and Welfare, Survey on Employment Condition, 2005, Labor Statistics Handbook, E32 (In Japanese) http://wwwdbtk.mhlw.go.jp/toukei/youran/data17r/E-32.xls Nuworsoo, C. K. (2004) Deep Discount Group Pass Programs as Instruments for Increasing Transit Revenue and Ridership, Ph. D. Dissertation, Institute of Transportation Studies, University of California, Berkeley. Savage, I. (1997) “Scale Economies in United States Rail Transit Systems,” Transportation Research 31A (6) pp. 459-473. Smart Card Alliance (2003) Transit and Retail Payment: Opportunities for Collaboration and Convergence, Smart Card Alliance Report, Princeton Junction, NJ. Smith, J. J. and Gihring, T. A. (2006) Financing Transit Systems Through Value Capture: An Annotated Bibliography, Victoria Transport Policy Institute, Victoria, BC, Canada. Stopher, P. R. (1993) “Financing Urban Rail Projects: The Case of Los Angeles,” Transportation 20, Springer, pp. 229-250. Takayama, A. (1985) Mathematical Economics, Second Edition, Cambridge University Press. Taylor, B., Haas, P., Boyd, B., Hess, D. B., Iseki, and H., Yoh, A (2002) Increasing Transit Ridership: Lessons from the Most Successful Trasnit Systems in the 1990s, MTI Report 01-22, Mineta Transportation Institute (MTI), San Jose, CA. Transportation Research Board (1999 a) A Handbook of Proven Marketing Strategies for Public Transits, Transit Cooperative Research Program (TCRP) 15 Report 50, National Academic Press, Washington D.C. Transportation Research Board (1999 b) A Guidebook for Marketing Transit Services to Business, Transit Cooperative Research Program (TCRP) Report 51, National Academic Press, Washington D.C. Varian, H. (1992) Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd Edition, Norton, New York. Vickrey, W. S. (2001) “Site Value Taxes and the Optimal Pricing of Public Services,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Volume 60, Issue 5, pp. 85-96. 16 Figure 1. Deficit p F AC(q) E MC(q) G D 1 (q) q 17 Figure 2. Passengers Public Business, University, Transit Developer, Retail, etc. 18 Figure 3. p MC(q) D 1 (q) B(q) q 19 Figure 4. p MC(q) TCi qi AC(q) )) dBi dqi q 20 Figure 5. Original AC(q) p0 AC(q) MC(q) q 21 Figure 6. Discounted e-Tokens Transit Retailer Agency e-Tokens Custome r Custome r Custome r 22 Captions for figures. Figure 1. Pricing schemes and demand. Figure 2. Passengers can be grouped by the entities accommodating their activities. Figure 3. D 1 (q) B(q) is the inverse demand curve. Figure 4. In general, the curve TCi qi lies in between the AC and the MC curves. Figure 5. With a lump sum subsidy, the transit is operated with the average cost pricing scheme. Figure 6. Organizing passengers through retailers. 23