Master programme in Economic History The Euro, Theoretical Expectation versus Economic Reality? Jonathan Pike jonathan.pike.709@student.lu.se Abstract: The euro was launched to great fanfare as a physical currency in 2002 but the very idea of European Economic & Monetary Union (EMU) was and continues to be a controversial and hotly debated topic. Nine years since that date, this paper revisits the debate that took place in the lead up to the Euro and the theoretical benefits and costs that were highlighted at that time. It aims to critically analyse the track record of the single currency to see whether such costs and benefits have been borne out in the historical record. The paper argues that the Euro has failed to have the large trade and price convergence effects that were theorised. In contrast, many of the theoretical costs that were pointed to can be seen in the Euro’s history as the European Central Bank followed a monetary policy that definitively failed to suit all its different members and the currency has been a source of asymmetric shocks and trends. With previously booming periphery countries facing huge debt problems and deflationary pain, the EMU project stands at the crossroads. This paper finds that although a break up is very unlikely, steps must be taken to make the project work more optimally. Key words: Euro, Eurozone, Economic & Monetary Union EKHR11 Master thesis (15 credits ECTS) June 2011 Supervisor: Lennart Schön Examiner: Jonas Ljungberg 1 Contents 1. Introduction: ............................................................................................................... 3 2.1. The OCA theory:..................................................................................................... 4 2.2. OCA and the Eurozone: ...................................................................................... 5 3. Theoretical Benefits of the Euro: ............................................................................... 6 3.1. Full EMU will increase trade: ............................................................................. 6 3.2. The promise of price transparency...................................................................... 7 3.3. The Euro will help decrease Asymmetric shocks: .............................................. 8 3.4. Inflation discipline and Commitment Gains from it: .......................................... 9 4. Theoretical Costs of the Euro: ................................................................................. 10 4.1. One size does not fit all:.................................................................................... 10 4.2. The Euro and asymmetric shocks: .................................................................... 11 4.3. Lack of adjustment mechanism to asymmetric shocks ..................................... 12 4.4. Loss of devaluation as an instrument of economic policy: ............................... 13 5. The Euro and the historical record: .......................................................................... 13 5.1. Has EMU increased trade?................................................................................ 14 5.2. Has EMU brought price transparency? ............................................................. 16 5. 3. ECBs Inflation performance and ‘One size does not fit all’: ........................... 18 5.4. The Euro, asymmetric shocks and divergences: ............................................... 22 5.5. Lack of adjustment mechanism to asymmetric shocks: .................................... 25 5.6. Loss of devaluation and the debt issue: ............................................................ 25 5.7. Unpopularity of the single currency: ................................................................ 27 6. The Future of EMU:................................................................................................. 28 6.1. The Breakup of the Euro Area? ........................................................................ 28 6.2. Redressing Eurozone fragility........................................................................... 30 7. Conclusion: .............................................................................................................. 33 2 1. Introduction: The objective of this paper is to analyse the Euro, otherwise known as EMU (Economic and Monetary Union) to see whether the theoretical costs and benefits highlighted in the lead up to the inception of the currency have been borne out by the historical record. One can argue that over 12 years after the Euro was first introduced to financial markets and 9 since its physical introduction sufficient time has passed with the common currency to pass judgement on it. Furthermore, the fact that the Euro seems to be in trouble, with some questioning its very existence, due to the instability on its periphery, the timing of this study is particularly pertinent. The paper develops as follows. Before turning to the core issues, the Optimal Currency Area (OCA) theory, a pioneering work on the costs and benefits monetary unions, is reviewed and its role in the setting up of the Euro’s institutional and policy framework examined. It is argued that the theory was largely ignored and instead of focusing on the factor mobility that was at the OCA’s heart, the Maastricht treaty instead focused on nominal convergence. The third section outlines the theoretical benefits that were expected from the single currency. Firstly it was argued that through the elimination of transaction costs and exchange rate uncertainty, the Euro would increase intra European trade. Although the European Commission itself did not attempt to quantify such an increase, one paper in particular seen as a key study at the time, argued that the trade gains would be very large indeed. Secondly, through greater price transparency and the ‘law of one price’ a narrowing of intra Euro member price differentials was expected. Thirdly, there was evidence at the time that European business cycles were becoming more synchronized and this was a process that some argued would continue with the single currency with even greater trade integration. This would reduce the chance of asymmetric shocks which affect some members more than others and it was hoped that the EMU’s fiscal framework would contribute to Euro macroeconomic stability. Furthermore, it was argued that by anchoring to a credible monetary authority, the European Central Bank and countries with a low inflation record, member states with historically high inflation would have commitment gains brought by inflation discipline. The fourth section highlights the key theoretical costs that were outlined in the lead up to EMU. Firstly, it was argued that due to business cycle differentials, with one country or group of country growing faster than others, the ECB would have a ‘one size does not fit all’ problem in the conduct of its monetary policy. Linked to this was the so called ‘Walters Critique’ which argued that common monetary policy would be more expansionary in countries with high inflation rates and contractionary in countries with low ones. Secondly, it was argued that in the absence of political union that the Euro may actually be a source of asymmetric shocks through member states own budgetary policies. Moreover, in the event of an asymmetric shock with diverging economic growth within the Eurozone, it was contended that Europe lacked the institutional and labour market flexibility, creating an adjustment problem. Lastly, some bemoaned the loss of the devaluation policy option although this was seen as a benefit to others. The fifth section weighs such theoretical considerations against the historical record. It is argued that the theoretical benefits have largely failed to materialise whilst the costs have been borne out. For, predictions of large increases in trade were found to be wide of the mark and although some studies have found the Euro to be the source of substantial trade increases, these studies have been criticised for their methodological weakness, for example by not taking into account the effect of the single market over time. Secondly, and generally accepted by the literature, is that the Euro has not brought in a spate of price convergence. 3 Although there may be many reasons for this development, it does not change the fact that a promised benefit has not happened. Also, one can argue that the ECB’s monetary policy did not fit all as periphery PIGS (Portugal, Ireland, Greece & Spain) nations overheated and others such as France and Germany experienced slow growth. The looser than optimal ECB monetary policy contributed to the periphery’s boom and the reality of the ‘Walters critique’ can be seen in the asset price bubble of such nations. Furthermore, boosted by tax revenues from such a bubble the PIGS countries engaged in a public spending spree that the EMU’s fiscal framework allowed. Large-scale wage increases and a loss of competitiveness were the result. Such profligacy can be seen to have been a source of asymmetric shocks as when the bubble burst these countries faced a debt crisis and many have had to be bailed out by the European Union and International Monetary Fund. The lack of labour mobility can also clearly be seen in the Eurozone today as unemployment is stubbornly high in the periphery and falling in Germany for example. Moreover, with the lack of the devaluation tool and unable to issue debt in their own currency, these countries are finding it hard to repay their debts and restore competitiveness. With the Eurozone in such a state it is no surprise that the single currency’s approval ratings have declined. This state has led some to openly contemplate the prospect of a Euro breakup. However, although a country determined to leave EMU could probably do so, section 6 argues that the legal and technical barriers are huge and would be incredibly costly to overcome. EMU is indeed irreversible. Therefore, it is better to focus on ways that the Eurozone can function more optimally. Section 7 argues that a fully fledged fiscal union with automatic fiscal transfers between member states would be the best way of solving Eurozone fragility but that this looks politically impossible. Nonetheless, there are other more realistic steps that could be taken. A more permanent financial support mechanism is a step in the right direction but it is not in itself enough to offset the effects of the asymmetric trend development in recent years. National fiscal councils can play a constructive role in tempering fiscal profligacy and a joint issue of Eurobonds would help a country against a future debt crisis and bad equilibrium. Also, although linguistic and cultural barriers to labour mobility are likely to remain high, opening up labour markets by making them more flexible may nonetheless help alleviate unemployment in stagnant regions. Lastly, the ECB should allow Greece and potentially others to restructure debt as this will help the Eurozone’s stability in the long term. It remains to be seen whether European leaders can agree on such sensible proposals but the clock is ticking. 2.1. The OCA theory: Mundell’s 1961 OCA (Optimal Currency Area) theory has had a central role in monetary union debate and today, as in the past, a lot of the work on multinational currencies and their economic pros and cons are based on the theory. As such pro’s and con’s are evaluated extensively in this paper, it is worth outlining the key logic of such a theory and also its role in the creation of EMU. The central question asked by Mundell in his theory is whether countries should ‘allow each national currency to fluctuate, or would a single currency be preferable’1 despite losing two out of the three basic macroeconomic policy tools in the form of monetary autonomy and the exchange rate. 1 Mundell, (1961) ‘A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas’ American Economic Review, 51 (6): 657 4 The answer Mundell gives is that such a common currency area will be desirable if certain conditions are met. Firstly, it will be preferable if all members of the union face common symmetric shocks that treat them equally and if asymmetric shocks that affect one or few members more than the rest are limited in both time and duration. Secondly, if countries in the union feature high co-movement of economic variables vis a vis each other and thirdly if there is high factor mobility, particularly labour, that is flexible at the micro level. Mundell (1961) saw gains in the form of increased trade due to less transaction costs and increased transparency and comparability of costs and prices. Nonetheless, if countries face dominating asymmetric shocks and the factor mobility between member states is poor, they should likely preserve their own currency. Mundell later updated his OCA work in 1973 with the argument that the loss of the exchange rate as a policy tool should not be considered a drawback as ‘it was no longer considered an affective tool for adjustment, as the central bank should be concentrating on price stability and not trying to fight market forces’2. For, the exchange rate, rather than an important policy tool had in itself become an important source of asymmetric shocks. Furthermore, by eliminating such exchange rate risk this increases cross national asset diversification which ‘mitigates the impact of asymmetric shocks on the single country, making the desire for country’s individual monetary and exchange rate policies less pressing’3. However, despite this modification, it is still Mundell’s original theory which economists usually measure any currency union against and as De Grauwe (2006) notes ‘as some Euro countries have suffered competitiveness losses since the introduction of the new currency, Mundell’s 1963 ideas are coming back into fashion’4. 2.2. OCA and the Eurozone: As Wyplosz (2006) has argued ‘the view that exchange rate volatility is harmful to trade integration has been a mainstay of European official thinking ever since the 1940’s’5. Since that time there were, therefore, several attempts to fix such exchange rates within certain bands to reduce such volatility, most notably with the 1972 ‘Snake’ system and the launch of the European Monetary System in March 1979. Nonetheless, it was not until the late 1980s with the collapse of the Soviet Union, the declining US role in the European continent and likely German Unification that a new impetus was created for the further deepening of European political and economic integration. France extracted German commitment to future monetary union in exchange for such unification and backed by the continents two powerhouses, the result was the so called Maastricht treaty which formally established the concept and basic characteristics of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). It is therefore useful to see how the treaty dealt with the OCA theory. In practice, it paid scant attention to it. In the European Commission report ‘One Market, One Money’, outlining justification for monetary union, it argued ‘the OCA approach provides useful insights but cannot be considered a comprehensive framework in which the 2 Mundell (1973) quoted in Chang, M. (2009) Monetary Integration in the European Union, Palgrave Macmillan, London, p64 3 Rusek, A. (2008) ‘Euro: the engine of integration or the seed of dissolution?’ Agricultural economics –Czech, Vol. 54, No. 4, p139 4 De Grauwe (2006) quoted by Chang, M. (2009), p65 5 Wypolsz, C (2006) ‘European Monetary Union: The Dark Sides of a Major Success’, Economic Policy, Vol. 21, No. 46 p212 5 costs and benefits of EMU can be analysed’6. Indeed, as Sapir (2009) has shown, ‘whereas OCA emphasises real convergence among the candidate countries to monetary union, Maastricht instead insists on nominal convergence’7 and to this end focused on inflation, exchange rates, interest rates and public finance rather than possible asymmetric shocks due to structural differences. Wyplosz (2006) argues that the overlooking of output and employment stability, at the heart of OCA theory was ‘arguably the monetary union’s original sin’8. Ignoring the OCA theory was likely due to a number of factors, chiefly because macroeconomic shocks were seen as less likely in a monetary union and, as demonstrated later in this paper, there was an expectation that a single currency would promote greater business cycle symmetry. However, one must also take into account, as Rusek (2008) has contended, that ‘it is necessary to recognise that the Euro and its existence today is much more the result of the political will to advance European integration than the economic logic’9. Nonetheless, it is useful to carry out an economic cost benefit analysis as ‘it gives an idea of the price some countries will have to pay to achieve these political objectives’10. For, the Euro was launched virtually to great fanfare in 1999 and it was hoped it would generate large economic gains for member countries. However, sceptics were unsure of this and instead pointed to imbalances and future asymmetric shocks. An in depth analysis of such a debate is now looked at. 3. Theoretical Benefits of the Euro: 3.1. Full EMU will increase trade: One of the main benefits expected from the creation of monetary union was an increase in trade among member states of such a union. Mundell (2002) argued that ‘the basic gains from currency unification in the international sphere stem from the extension of national free trade areas to a wider unit. The larger the common currency area, the greater will be the gains from trade and lending’11. The two mechanisms that were pointed to through which monetary union could do this were fewer transaction costs and less exchange rate uncertainty. In terms of the former, transaction costs are effectively those incurred when exchanging one currency into another and is one of the most visible gains from any monetary union. Such costs are as De Grauwe (1998) demonstrated ‘a deadweight loss in that they are like a tax paid by the consumer in exchange for which he gets nothing’12. Although, savings from such costs were expected to be in the low range, around 1% of EU Gross Domestic Product (GDP) according to the European Commission (1990), it was argued that ‘since the reduction in transaction costs should stimulate intra-EU trade, the overall savings in transaction costs could actually be larger than 1% of GDP’13. EC Commission (1990) ‘One Money, One Market’ European Economy. 44, p46 Sapir, A. (2009) ‘Panel Statement on Optimal Currency Areas’ In Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany, p264 ‘ 8 Wyplosz (2006) p216 9 Rusek (2008) p140 10 De Grauwe (1998) p84 11 Mundell, R (2002) contribution to Submissions on EU from Leading Academics, in Schwarz, P. (2004) The Euro as Politics, Profile Books, London, p52 12 De Grauwe, (1998) p53 13 Gros,D. & Thygesen,N. (1998) European Monetary Integration, Longman, New York, p290 6 7 6 In terms of the effect of exchange rate variability and its effect on trade, there was not an academic consensus on such effects in the period leading up to the Euro. For, ‘exchange rate volatility will, in fact, increase average profits under standard assumptions about profit functions and should therefore serve to increase trade’14. However, a theoretical approach that Euro enthusiasts pointed to was to see trade decisions along the framework of the option theory of investment developed by Majd and Pindyck (1987)15. For, a decision to start exporting or importing will involve investment costs, such as market research and marketing and perhaps building new production capacity, costs that are only partly reversible and take place over a time period. A firm may put off expanding trade due to the positive option relating to this as the exchange rate may become more favourable, making the investment more profitable. The firm may also wait as the exchange rate becomes unfavourable in which case the investment can become unprofitable and should not be undertaken. The value of the option to wait increases with the degree of uncertainty, in other words the volatility of the exchange rate. This led some, such as Flam & Jansson (2000) to conclude that ‘uncertainty in exchange rates therefore represent an important cost element in any decision to start exporting, importing or investing in a foreign country’16. Monetary union would eliminate such a cost element. Thus, there was an economic rationale that showed that EMU was likely to boost trade but there was little attempt to quantify such a gain until Andrew Rose (2000) presented his econometric study that argued that such a gain would be rather large. Using cross-section data and controlling for a number of other variables that affect trade flows (including income, distance, trade restrictions and others), Rose found that pairs of countries which are part of a monetary union have trade flows among themselves that were, on average 200% higher than those among pairs of countries that are not part of a monetary union. His conclusion was that ‘Even after taking a host of other considerations into account, countries that share a common currency engage in substantially higher international trade’17. Rose’s findings, in the absence of other empirical studies, formed an important part of the Euro debate. Indeed even Milton Friedman (2000) who was highly sceptical of the single currency cited the study in an interview saying ‘if it (the Euro) has a major effect on trade, it may enable trade to substitute for the mobility of people’18. 3.2. The promise of price transparency Another expected gain from EMU was price transparency which was expected to contribute to price convergence in products and services across the Eurozone. This was highlighted by the European Commission in ‘One Money, One Market’ as that report argued ‘the addition of a single currency to a single market will perfect the resource allocation function of the price mechanism at the level of the Community as a whole’19. Furthermore, at the time of the Euro cash changeover of January 2002 the ECB argued ‘the introduction of Euro bank notes and coins increases price transparency across borders which in turn should increase the strength of competition and, over time, reduce price level dispersion in the Euro area’20. 14 De Grauwe, (1998) p56 See Majd, S. & Pindyck, RS. (1987) "Time to build, option value, and investment decisions," Journal of Financial Economics, Elsevier, vol. 18(1), pages 7-27 16 Flam, H. & Jansson, P. (2000), quoted in Flam, H. (2009) The Impact of the Euro and International Trade and Investment: A Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Evidence, Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies, Stockholm, p77 17 Rose, AK. (2000) “One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common. Currencies on Trade” Economic Policy 30, p27 18 Friedman, M. (2000) quoted from “An interview with Milton Friedman. Interviewed by John B. Taylor, May 2000” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 5, 2001, p128 19 EC Commission (1990) ‘One Money, One Market’ European Economy. 44, p19 20 ECB (2002) ‘Price level convergence and competition in the Euro area’, Monthly Bulletin, August 2002, p39 15 7 This expected price convergence, it was argued, was based on sound economic rationale based on the law of one price. According to that rule, the existence of national currencies can lead to large indirect costs as it can allow firms to engage in price discrimination between nations as consumers cannot easily evaluate and compare prices in different countries, even with fixed exchange rates. For, ‘these artificial differences in prices imply economic losses of economic welfare because they give a signal that is not related to the true scarcity of the good’21. However, with the advent of monetary union, such price discrimination would be much harder to achieve as consumers could easily compare prices. Thus, the prices of identical internationally tradable goods at different locations would converge. Where this was not the case risk free transactions would be possible whereby the product would be purchased at the cheaper location and then sold on at the more expensive one, this arbitrage would therefore even out any price differentials. In the lead up to the Euro’s inauguration there was little empirical evidence to substantiate the law of one price economic gain but one study that was oft pointed to was by Engel & Rogers22 (1995) who analysed the factors that influenced price differentials of the same goods in different locations in 14 North American cities. Their key finding was that consumer prices were significantly more variable, by a big margin, for pairs of cities located across the US Canadian border than for pairs of cities located within the same country, even controlling for the effect of distance. It was thus considered that ‘borders are quite powerful in introducing large variations in the movement prices and the fact that at borders moneys have to be exchanged is a significant factor in explaining why markets remain segmented’23. In other words, the different US and Canadian currencies were interpreted as a large factor behind price differentials in those countries’ cities and thus it was expected that the different currencies in Europe were having a similar effect. 3.3. The Euro will help decrease Asymmetric shocks: Asymmetric shocks are defined as ‘when something unexpected happens that affects one economy (or part of an economy) more than the rest’24. However, it was argued by some that such shocks would not be a big problem due to increased past and expected future European Business Cycle symmetry with EMU. For, in the lead up to the Euro, there was indeed some evidence that European business cycles were becoming more synchronized over time. For example, a study by Artis & Zhang (1995) found that the formation of the Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) may have bred a ‘European Business Cycle’ centred on Germany. The authors argued that ‘contemporaneous correlation shows very clearly that before the ERM was formed, most countries business cycles were linked to that of the US and that, afterwards, the group of ERM countries moved clearly into the German business cycle orbit’25. Another important contribution to the literature on such an issue was provided by Frankel & Rose (1997) who argued that, as EMU was a natural extension of the European integration process, this would boost trade integration and business cycle symmetry. Using data covering 21 industrial countries from 1959 through to 1993 their gravity model based analysis showed 21 Gros & Thygesen, (1998) p292 See Engel, C, & Rogers (1995) "How wide is the border?," International Finance Discussion Papers 498, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.). 23 De Grauwe (1998) p54 24 The Economist, Definitions Section, Available at: http://www.economist.com/research/Economics/alphabetic.cfm?term=assets (accessed 3rd May 2011) 25 Artis, MJ. & Zhang, W. (1995) ‘International Business Cycles and the ERM: Is there a European Business Cycle?’ International Journal of Finance Economics, Vol 2, p1 22 8 that there was ‘a strong positive relationship between the degree of bilateral trade intensity and the cross country bilateral correlation of business cycle activity’26. With greater integration and more synchronised cycles, the authors argued, ‘a country is more likely to satisfy the criteria for entry into a currency union ex post than ex ante’27. Thus with European Business Cycle symmetry having increased in the lead up to the Euro and with this process being expected to continue, this would indicate the fading away of the most important ‘exogenous’ source of asymmetric shocks. Furthermore, in regards to the view, that in the absence of political union, nations budgetary decisions could by themselves create asymmetric shocks, there were grounds for optimism that this would not be a big problem. For, the latter half of the 1990s saw a significant fiscal consolidation and the improvement of fiscal discipline across the soon to be Eurozone members as they sought to abide by the Maastricht conditions which would allow them to participate in EMU. This phenomenon was supposedly enhanced by the conclusion of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) in 1997 which was intended to keep deficits below 3% of GDP and debt levels below 60% of GDP as European policy makers set up a framework to ensure fiscal discipline. The rationale behind such a pact was to prevent imprudent members of EMU from imposing costs on others. For, ‘a country that allows its debt-GDP ratio to increase continuously will have increasing recourse to the capital markets of the union, thereby driving the union’s interest rate upwards’28 which therefore increases the burden of the government debts of other countries. This is a typical case of a moral hazard problem as the resistance to deficit spending is reduced and the propensity to pursue an inappropriate expansionary fiscal policy increases. To contain such a propensity the SGP stipulated that if a nation’s budget deficit exceeded the 3% limit an excessive deficit procedure would be triggered where the delinquent government would be given a warning and a timeframe in which to correct for this. If this warning was not adhered to a fine would be imposed. The SGP also contained two clauses which were hoped to be further safeguards. The ECB was independent from political pressure (Article 108) and was explicitly forbidden from financing members deficits directly and also a no bailout clause (Article 103) was established so that national governments alone were in charge of their budgets and they would be responsible for any slippage. It was argued by the European Commission at the time that such a framework ‘makes stability orientated monetary policy of the ECB possible while at the same time providing sufficient flexibility for national budgetary authorities to accommodate for asymmetric shocks’29. 3.4. Inflation discipline and Commitment Gains from it: The Maastricht treaty established the ECB as an institution free from political interference with price stability as its key goal. Article 105 outlined this in writing by stating ‘it is only without prejudice to the objective of price stability that the ECB will support the general economic policies in the community’30. Such a goal was initially defined as ‘a year on year Frankel JA & Rose, AK. (1997) ’Is EMU More Justifiable Ex Post than Ex Ante?’ European Economic Review, Volume 41, Issue 3-5, p760 27 Ibid, p760 28 De Grauwe (1998) p191 29 EU Commission (1997) quoted in Gros&Thygesen, p346 30 Maastricht treaty, quoted in Schwarz, P. (2004) The Euro as Politics, Profile Books, London, p38 26 9 HICP (Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices) increase of below 2%’31 but was later clarified in 2003 to mean an inflation objective below, but close to 2% in the medium term. Thus, with such a credible commitment to price stability, it was expected that an important benefit of joining a currency union would be a reduction in inflation rates, particularly for those nations that had a tradition of poor internal discipline and high inflation. Thus, according to Alessina & Barro (2002) ‘by joining a monetary union with a credible anchor country or set of countries, a client country eliminates the inflation bias arising from time inconsistency in monetary policy’32. In the post-war period the German Bundesbank had built up a reputation for promoting a low inflation environment and was regarded worldwide as the model of a successful policy of monetary stability. The ECB was institutionally based on the Bundesbank and given its credibility, and the fact that low inflation countries such as Germany were seen as anchors, there were supposedly good grounds to believe the ECB could deliver its price stability goal. 4. Theoretical Costs of the Euro: 4.1. One size does not fit all: One of the key arguments against EMU was that regional imbalances and the fact that different Eurozone countries will have different economic growth rates means that the European Central Bank would set an interest rate that was not appropriate for all Euro members. A simple example would be an expansion of demand in one country, say Germany and a contraction in demand of another, say France, due to non synchronization of business cycles across the two countries. In such a scenario ‘there is an output decline in France and an increase in Germany which will most likely lead to additional unemployment in France and a decline of unemployment in Germany’33. Furthermore, as output is booming in Germany, this leads to upwards pressure on its price level. Thus, as Hovell (2002) highlights ‘the interest rates need to rise in order to curtail the excess demand in Germany but fall to restore full employment in France’34. Practically speaking, The Economist (1998) argued that ‘the ECB has a very difficult task setting monetary policy’35 due to growth differentials between member states pointing out that in 1997 ‘Ireland’s economy grew by 10% whereas Germany’s grew by 2.5% strongly suggesting that Ireland needs higher interest rates than Germany’36. Linked to this ‘one size does not fit all’ problem was the Walters critique37, named after Richard Walter, a counsellor to Margaret Thatcher in the 1980s. For, in a unified bond market, nominal interest rates are equalised and therefore, in practice, real interest rates are lower when inflation is higher. Therefore with a common monetary policy the effects of this are more expansionary in countries with high inflation rates and contractionary in countries 31 ECB (1999) Monthly Bulletin, January, p46 Alessina & Barro (2002), quoted in Silva, JMC & Tenreyro, S. ‘Currency Unions in Prospect and Retrospect’ Annual Review of Economics, Vol 2, p63 33 De Grauwe (1998) p6 34 Hovell, RB (2001) ‘The Creation of EMU’ in Artis & Nixson eds. The Economics of the European Union, Oxford University Press, p248 35 The Economist (1998) ‘Can one size fit all’, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/159074 (accessed 7th May 2011) 36 Ibid 37 See Miller, M & Sutherland, A, (1991) ‘The "Walters Critique" of the EMS--A Case of Inconsistent Expectations?,’ The Manchester School of Economic & Social Studies, vol. 59(0), pages 23-37 32 10 with low rates. As a consequence of this growing divergence can occur with inflation increasing where it started higher and decreasing where it started lower. Furthermore, it was expected that countries would differ with their inflation preferences and that this introduced costs in a monetary union. Indeed on this issue, Martin Feldstein (1997) was highly sceptical. He argued that the Euro would create a situation of incompatible policy goals amongst member states between those that favoured reigning in inflation, such as Germany and those that preferred higher inflation in order to keep the level of unemployment down. According to Feldstein ‘this general conflict about the governance and character of monetary policy would be exacerbated whenever a country experienced a decline in aggregate demand that led to a cyclical increase in unemployment’38. Furthermore, he believed that such ‘conflicts over economic policies and interference with national sovereignty could reinforce long standing animosities based on history, nationality and religion’39 and he thought that this could even lead to war on the continent. Thus, differences in Eurozone economic performance with ‘a one size does not fit all’ problem and different macroeconomic preferences were seen as serious costs in EMU. However, as is outlined earlier, Euro proponents saw this as an unlikely problem due to the expected synchronization of business cycles. 4.2. The Euro and asymmetric shocks: In the lead up to the Euro there was a theoretical presumption that EMU would make asymmetric shocks less likely due to greater integration and business cycle symmetry. However, there were others such as Krugman (1991) and De Grauwe (1998) who felt that EMU could actually become a source of suck shocks. For Krugman40 greater economic integration leads to greater specialisation and regional concentration which increases the chance of asymmetric shocks. De Grauwe, meanwhile, focused on the fact that in the absence of political union, nation states would continue to exercise considerable sovereignty in various important economic areas. Chiefly, they would continue to have a large degree of discretion over their spending and tax policies. According to him ‘the fact that countries will maintain most of their budgetary powers in a future monetary union creates the possibility that large asymmetric shocks may occur in the union’41. For example, when the authorities of a country increase taxes on wage income, this only affects labour in that particular country and this will create disturbances that lead to divergent price and wage developments in that country but do not effect the others. Linked to this point about the lack of political union is that, from the Euro’s inception, there was not a system for fiscal transfers between the member states. Thus, if a member country would suffer an economic downturn, with a large fall in tax receipts and owing to this the government would struggle to meet its spending requirements; no system was in place for the Eurozone as a whole to alleviate such a fiscal crisis. Eichengreen (1997) stressed the failure of the Maastricht treaty to include extensive provisions regarding fiscal federalism posed serious problems. For him such problems could be attenuated by US style ‘interregional fiscal transfers which limits regional unemployment differentials by offsetting a portion of the decline in regional income and helping to relax the external constraint’42. Feldstein, M. (1997) ‘EMU and International Conflict’, Foreign Affairs, November/December, Vol 76. Available Online at: http://www.nber.org/feldstein/fa1197.html (accessed 25th April 2011) 39 Ibid 40 See Krugman, P. (1991) Geography and Trade, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press 41 De Grauwe (1998) p25 42 Eichengreen, B. (1997) European Monetary Unification, MIT, p48 38 11 4.3. Lack of adjustment mechanism to asymmetric shocks As argued in the OCA literature, one of the key determinants of a successful monetary union was the ability of factors of production, chiefly labour to move in response to an asymmetric shock that affected one county or number of countries more than others. However, it was argued that differences in labour market institutions and the historic lack of labour mobility in the continent would not enable this to happen, introducing significant costs for EMU. In terms of differences in labour institutions, in the event of a supply shock such as a big oil price increase De Grauwe (1998) showed that ‘wages and prices in countries may be affected differently, making it difficult to correct for these differences when the exchange rate is irrevocably fixed’43. Moreover, it was argued that rigid and protected labour markets in many European counties constrained labour mobility and Feldstein (1997) contented that ‘although the legal barriers to labour mobility within the European Union have largely been eliminated, language and custom impede both temporary and long-term movement within Europe’44. Thus, whereas in theory if domestic wages and prices are slow to adjust in regions hit by an economic slump, workers would leave such regions, alleviating unemployment problems there in practice this development would not happen in the Eurozone leaving the country that experienced the slump with persistently high unemployment. This was in contrast to the United States where ‘the American heritage of immigration and national settlement makes Americans much more willing to move internally than their European counterparts’45. Some economists did not see this as a major problem at the time. For example, Gros&Thygesen (1998) argued the theory that different labour institutions and lower mobility could be a drawback was ‘misplaced’. For, ‘international labour movements in the EU have now increased to a point where they are of an order of magnitude comparable to international migration within member countries’46. Nonetheless, in the lead up to the Euro, citing low labour flexibility in particular, De Grauwe (1998) wrote that ‘there is now a broad consensus among economists who have tried to implement the theory empirically, that the EU15 is not an optimal currency area’47. A study by Bayoumi & Eichengreen (1997) constructed an OCA index for European countries taking into account a multitude of variables such as nominal exchange rate variability, labour mobility, trade linkages and output disturbances. They found that Europe was essentially split between ‘core’ and ‘periphery’ groups. The former including Germany, the Benelux countries, Austria and Denmark were seen as a group where shocks were highly correlated and the speed of adjustment relatively fast. This may have been ‘because such countries have been closely linked to the German economy for many years’48 and these were seen as a group capable of forming a near optimal currency area. In contrast, another set of countries including Italy, Spain, Greece, Portugal, Finland and Sweden were seen as a group with little convergence towards EMU, where shocks were larger, more idiosyncratic and where the speed of adjustment was lower. This group made the EU15 as a whole not an OCA and according to Sapir (2009) would have been left ‘out in the cold if the OCA theory criteria had 43 De Grauwe (1998) p16 Feldstein, Martin, (1997), “The political economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political sources of an economic liability”, NBER Working Paper Series, no. 6150 45 Ibid, p36 46 Gros & Thygesen (1998) p310 47 De Grauwe (1998) p74 48 Bayoumi,T & Eichengreen, B. (1997) ‘Ever closer to heaven? An optimum-currency area index for European countries’ European Economic Review 41, p766 44 12 been used instead of Maastricht’49. It is important to remember this in light of the current state of the Eurozone which will be looked at in depth in Section 5 of this paper. 4.4. Loss of devaluation as an instrument of economic policy: Lastly, some economists such as Milton Friedman were critical at the prospect of EMU as this would mean losing the ability to devalue domestic currency, in other words reduce its value in terms of others. It was argued by Friedman (2000) a devaluation option ‘solves the co-ordination problem when wages and prices are out of line, sidestepping the unwillingness of workers to take pay cuts’50 as wages can be sticky on their way down during periods of economic slumps. A devaluation could thus restore competitiveness and reduce the risk of persistent unemployment and economic hardship in the time it takes for wages to adjust downwards. Indeed, looking at this issue De Grauwe (1998) argued that ‘variations in the exchange rate remain a powerful instrument to help economies to eliminate important macroeconomic disequilibria and to make the adjustment process less costly in terms of lost output and employment’51. For him the successful French, Belgian and Danish devaluations of 1982-3 which helped to re-establish external equilibrium without significant costs in terms of unemployment illustrate this point. The 1982 devaluation of the Belgian franc by 8.5%, for example, ‘led to a rapid turnaround in the current account balance of payments and that country’s recovery in employment proceeded at a pace that was not significantly different from the rest of the Community after that date’52. Nonetheless, it was argued by others like Pitchford & Cox (1997) that such devaluations can ‘quickly result in higher inflation, and are of limited usefulness to the external objective because the higher inflation would quickly eliminate the competitive advantage that the country would gain initially through devaluation’53. Also, it was presumed that devaluation by one country would generate a response from others and thus ‘a generalised resurgence of uncoordinated exchange rate policies throughout the EU, which results in widespread efforts to improve competitiveness through a weakening of the exchange rate would achieve very little since the share of trade with the rest of the world in EU GDP is rather low’54. 5. The Euro and the historical record: In brief, it seems that given the great fanfare to which the Euro was introduced in 1999, it has failed to bring the expected economic gains whilst has, in fact, been a source of instability which threatens its very future. Firstly, although there is significant debate on the issue, one can argue that the Euro has failed to generate the expected trade benefits. Less controversial is the finding that expected price transparency has not led to greater convergence among member states. Also, one can contend that some of the theoretical costs, as outlined in section 4, have happened in practice. The ECB’s one size fits all policy plainly failed to fit all, contributing to unsustainable booms in the periphery. Furthermore, the autonomous budgetary 49 Sapir (2009) p264 Friedman, M. (2000) quoted from “An interview with Milton Friedman. Interviewed by John B. Taylor, May 2000” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 5, 2001, p128 51 De Grauwe (1998) p50 52 Ibid, p33 53 Pitchford, R, & Cox, A. (1997) eds. EMU Explained: Markets and Monetary Union Reuters, London, p132 54 Gros & Thygesen (1998) p232 50 13 decisions some states have taken, despite the Stability and Growth Pact, have also been a source of instability. Such states now face high debt burdens and competiveness issues that the single currency makes harder to get out of. In the face of such disappointment, it is little wonder that the single currency has declined in popularity in recent years. 5.1. Has EMU increased trade? An expected increase in trade was one of the main theoretical benefits derived from EMU and indeed it was one of the key gains that countries which joined the Euro hoped for in the face of a loss of monetary autonomy. Furthermore, the expected trade increase was meant to deepen the integration process and increase business cycle symmetry as argued by Frankel & Rose in 1997. To what extent EMU has fermented intra Euro trade is thus a key issue and it is one that can only be answered empirically. There have been a number of econometric studies that have attempted to quantify the gains of the single currency but these took time to come through. For a number of years Andrew Rose’s study with its 200% estimate was, in the absence of other empirical studies, highlighted as a key source in the Euro debate. For example in Sweden, in the lead up to their referendum on the Euro, Rose’s estimate was cited by many of those on the ‘Yes’ campaign. On the other side of the debate, Bo Malmberg of the ‘No’ campaign provided a rebuttal to Rose in 2003 by arguing that the reasons that Rose had come up with such a high estimate was that ‘his research has been heavily focused on trade flows over large geographical distances between comparatively small nations whose trade flows started at a very low level’55. EMU however, involved bigger countries who were already fairly well integrated. In the years since the Euro’s introduction, Rose’s methodology and findings have largely been discredited. As Baldwin (2008) has noted, Rose’s paper suffered from some weaknesses key of which were omitted variables that are ‘pro trade and correlated with the currency union dummy biases the estimate upwards’56 and reverse causality in that ‘big bilateral flows cause a common currency rather than vice versa so the high estimate reflects the impact of trade on currency union, not the other way round’57. Finally, his model was mis-specified in that it compared the actual trade to such a model of what trade should have been in the case of absent common currency. By around the 5 year mark since the Euro became an accounting currency, with data having been accumulated in such a timeframe, studies started to come through that analysed the effect of the Euro on European trade patterns. The first of which was undertaken by Micco et al (2003) who adopted the gravity equation framework used by Rose to control for observable differences between a control group of countries that were not part of the Eurozone and a treatment group of Eurozone countries. Their results were that the currency had increased trade among Eurozone members by between 4 and 16%. Subsequent work has attempted to address methodological weaknesses in these authors’ work, such as the short sample period (1992 to 2002) and the 1993 break in the trade series. Indeed, overall there have been over 20 studies looking into the Euro effect on trade. Although it is not a worthwhile exercise to examine each study individually, the general finding according to De Grauwe (2009) is that the Euro has increased trade somewhat as it Malmberg, B. (2003) ‘The yes-campaign has misinterpreted its trade guru’ Available Online at: http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/arose/MalmbergE.htm (accessed 20th April 2011) 56 Baldwin, R. et al (2008) ‘Study on the impact of the Euro on Trade and Foreign Direct Investment’ European Economy. Economic Papers. 321. May 2008. Brussels, p18 57 Ibid, p18 55 14 ‘has lowered fixed and variable costs of exporting firms’58 but this increase is by far less than the one that had been estimated by Rose in 2000. The estimates for a positive Euro effect range from 2% in Baldwin (2006) to more than 70% in Gil-Pareja et al (2008) and the differences in the studies largely depend on the length of the Euro period, what countries are in the control group, the effect becomes greater by including developing countries, and on how the gravity model is specified. In a survey on this topic, Flam (2009) has argued that the period with the Euro should be as long as possible and this makes him focus on three studies, concluding that ‘trade between Euro countries is higher by 10 to 30% and trade between Euro and non countries by half as much between 2002 and 2006 due to the Euro’59. However, many of the higher estimate studies methodology can be questioned. One of the chief criticisms is that they have not taken into account sufficiently the effect of the single market. As Baldwin & Taglioni (2008) have argued ‘ it is not sufficient, as some studies do, to control for the Single Market with a time invariant dummy to capture any higher level of trade between countries participating in the Single Market. Instead, one must control for increasing effects of the Single Market over time’60. Furthermore, the most recent econometric study on this issue by Silva & Tenreyo (2010) has found little evidence of a ‘Euro effect’ on trade flows. Their analysis uses a ‘differences in differences’ approach which is based on the comparison between trade flows for the periods before and after the Euro was introduced for two groups of countries, those that joined the Euro during the observation period and those that didn’t. The former is the ‘treatment group’ while the latter is the ‘control group’. In this way, their methodology is similar to that used by Micco et al (2003) but these authors take into account limitations of that work. For example they include a ‘Euro 12 dummy equal to 1 for the pairs for which both countries are part of the Euro 12 group’ as this ‘controls for possible unobservable systematic differences in characteristics between pairs of members of the Euro 12 and other pairs’61. The authors also have the benefit of being able to examine a larger time period and to this end use a data set from the International Monetary Fund’s Trade Statistics that runs from 1993 to 2007. In short, the authors find that for the Euro 12 dummy, named Currency Union (CU) and the main regressor of interest ‘the low t-statistics62 for the coefficient of CU, coupled with the variability of its estimates across the different samples, strongly suggest that the effect of the Euro on trade is negligible’63. This is largely because before the Euro was created, trade between the Euro 12 was already intensive and comparatively stronger than between comparable countries, even those that were part of the EU. Therefore when one controls for this econometrically ‘there is little evidence that the creation of Euro has had an effect on trade’64 on a general level. Nonetheless, one can argue that although the Euro’s effect may well have been negligible in terms of overall trade in the Eurozone, the single currency’s effects in such a regard have differed from country to country. In a recent analysis, (Hogrefe, Jung & Kohler, 2010) have examined Euro induced trade affects in a disaggregate manner across member countries and chiefly, the role of currency misalignment in this process. Their methodology augments a 58 De Grauwe, P. (2009) Economics of Monetary Union, Oxford Uni Press, Oxford, p69 Flam, H. (2009) The Impact of the Euro and International Trade and Investment: A Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Evidence, Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies, Stockholm, p7 60 Baldwin & Taglioni (2008), quoted in Ibid, p30 61 Silva, JMC & Tenreyro, S (2010) ‘Currency Unions in Prospect and Retrospect’ Annual Review of Economics, Vol 2, p59 62 The ‘t’ statistic is found by dividing the coefficient by its standard error. This statistic is a measure of the likelihood that the actual value of the coefficient is not zero. The larger the absolute value of t, the less likely that the actual value of the coefficient could be zero. In this case the low t statistics mean that the actual value of the CU coefficient is more likely to be zero. 63 Silva, JMC & Tenreyro, S (2010) p60 64 Ibid, p61 59 15 traditional gravity model to incorporate nominal exchange rates, which serves as a guidance for modelling implicit currency misalignment when analysing the effect of monetary unions. Furthermore, they included a nominal cost divergence term in their regressions and interacted this with a dummy indicating Euro membership. It was argued that this was an appropriate way to ‘test the key hypothesis that cost divergence has different implications for trade between Euro area member countries, compared to countries that enjoy independent currencies and the option of nominal exchange rate adjustment’65. Their results confirm such a hypothesis in that comparing the average levels of bilateral misalignments since the start of EMU, a disaggregate view shows large country heterogeneity. For example Germany and Austria register a trade effect above 5% whereas for the Iberian countries and Netherlands a negative effect is found for their bilateral level exports. Thus, the authors conclude ‘the true impact of entering the currency union creates trade gains for some, but not for all countries. For others, the opposite holds true’66. Therefore Andrew Rose’s estimates of a tripling of Euro trade have been proven to be way out of line and his methodology is now largely discredited. It did however lay the groundwork on which future economic historians would evaluate the effect of the single currency on trade. There have been over 20 of such studies in the last decade and most have found a positive benefit of Euro membership in this regard. However, the studies that have higher estimates often do not take into account fully the effect of the single market over time and the most recent analysis by Silva & Tenreyo (2010) has found no evidence for an overall Euro induced increase in Eurozone trade. Furthermore, another recent study by Hogrefe, Jung & Kohler (2010) has shown large country differentials in terms of the Euro’s effect and that some have seen their exports increase due to the Euro whilst for others, the opposite has been found. Therefore, one can argue that thus far the role of trade in monetary integration has not gone according to expectations. Trade has undoubtedly increased significantly in the years since the Euro was introduced both as an accounting and cash currency. However, the role of the Euro in such an increase is still a matter of controversy. Also such increased trade flows have not seemingly increased price convergence which is to what we now turn. 5.2. Has EMU brought price transparency? Another of the main economic arguments behind the introduction of the Euro was that it would lead to greater price transparency which would benefit consumers and therefore increase their welfare. According to the current European Commission website (2011) ‘this is because increased price transparency has the effect of increasing competition between shops and suppliers, keeping downward pressure on prices in the Euro area’67. However, how much of this price transparency promise has been born out by the historical empirical evidence? The current spate of empirical evidence on this issue shows us that this ‘price transparency’ promise has not happened in practice. One of the first papers to look at this issue was by Engel & Rogers (2004) who used city price data from the Economist Intelligence Unit City Data. Their sample was based on 139 goods (including 101 tradable goods) from 25 cities in 17 European countries and overall found price dispersion to have narrowed from 1993 to 2003 but that most of this change occurred between 1990 and 1994 mainly due to a convergence in tradable price levels as a result of increased tax harmonisation and income dispersion. The introduction of the Euro, however, did not seem to have increased Hogrefe, J, Jung, B & Kohler, W (2010) ‘Readdressing the trade effect of the Euro: Allowing for currency misalignment’ ZEW Discussion Paper No. 10-023, April 2010, p26 66 Ibid, p24 67 European Commission website ‘Consumer Benefits’. Available Online at: http://ec.Europa.eu/economy_finance/Euro/why/consumer/index_en.htm (accessed 7th May 2011) 65 16 convergence as there was actually an increase in price dispersion post 1998. However, the authors themselves acknowledged that the observed time period may have been too short to measure the Euro’s real effects. Nonetheless, subsequent studies observing a longer post EMU period have found similar results. Wolszczak Derlacz (2006), with data up to 2005 analysed data on both the aggregate and disaggregate level, the former done by computing a price index by dividing the ‘purchasing power parity’ by the nominal exchange rate of the national currency to the Euro whereas the latter was examined by using data from the Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU). The author tested both levels for sigma convergence, shown as the standard deviation of the relative price levels across countries at a given point in time and beta convergence, the negative relation between the average growth rate of prices (inflation) and the initial price level. She found some evidence of beta convergence among prices but as Sturm et al (2009) have argued ‘whereas beta convergence only implies that countries with initially low price levels grow faster, sigma convergence implies that the countries’ prices converge to the same level and thus beta convergence is the weaker concept’68. Wolszczak-Derlacz found no evidence of sigma convergence in her results, key of which for the disaggregate level is shown in the diagram below: Figure 1: Evolution of price dispersion in the Eurozone, 1990–2005. Source: WolszczakDerlacz (2006) 0,45 mean standard deviation 0,4 0,35 0,3 0,25 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Also, with observations up to 2006 and using the EIU data set, Cuaresma et al (2007) tested for sigma convergence among 160 products in 27 European cities by comparing a ‘Eurozone group’ with that of a control group of developed European countries not part of the Eurozone. Their findings show that ‘according to the plotted series from 1990 to 2006, price dispersion decreased mostly during the early 1990s and remained flat afterward’69. EMU had no observed effect on this and in 2006 prices showed substantial differences across cities going beyond levels explained by factors such as taxation, for example ‘in 2006, one kilogram of apples cost EUR 2.68 in the German city of Mannheim but EUR 0.85 in Vienna’70. Sturm, J.E. et al (2009) ‘The Euro and prices: changeover-related inflation and price convergence in the Euro area’, European Economy. Economic Papers. 381. June 2009 (Brussels) p179 69 Cuaresma, JC et al (2007) ‘Price Level Convergence in Europe: Did the Introduction of the Euro Matter?’ Austrian Central Bank, Monetary Policy and the Economy: Issue 1 (April) p105 70 Ibid, p105. Note that this assumes that this is the same or very similar type and quality of apple 68 17 Another more recent key survey by (Sturm et al, 2009), important as it has been published by the European Commission, uses Eurostat data for 224 product groups. The authors disaggregate the data by looking at three dimensions, that of the country aggregate, time and aggregation of product groups. They argue that their findings show that ‘for the aggregation over all products, we find no evidence for convergence due to the Euro cash changeover’71. Although they find sigma and beta convergence for some product groups and categories in EMU countries as opposed to not in non EU countries such as in ‘recreation and culture’ and for single product groups such as ‘jewellery, clock and watches’, these are exceptions to the rule. Reasons put forward for this observed lack of price convergence are diverse. Cuaresma et al (2007) posit that ‘most product market integration took place in the early 1990s, so that no second convergence was to be expected’72. However, as aforementioned the ECB in 2002 had indeed expected price convergence to increase in the aftermath of the introduction of the Euro and one can doubt that consumer market integration was saturated by the introduction of the Euro given the wide price differentials observed in the studies. Other factors pointed to include information barriers between local and foreign consumers hampering competition between producers and distributors. Differences in the development of distribution costs in the Eurozone was highlighted as a major reason of washing machine divergence in a survey by the Deutsche Bundesbank (2009) as ‘the price level was highest in those countries where labour costs have risen most sharply since the launch of EMU and conversely a very low price level prevails in those countries where the growth in unit labour costs remained small’73. Linguistic differences have also been highlighted by Bris & Micola (2008) who have argued that ‘cities in which similar languages are spoken tend to have more similar prices than those in which very different languages are spoken’74. Therefore, such factors together may have outweighed the possible price transparency effects of EMU as a common currency. Therefore, there are a number of reasons why price transparency has not occurred in the Eurozone and these were always going to be difficult barriers to overcome. Nonetheless, the fact remains that such transparency was sold in the 1990s to European electorates and indeed continues to be highlighted as an economic gain from EMU. The evidence shows that such a gain has not materialised. 5. 3. ECBs Inflation performance and ‘One size does not fit all’: The ECB’s inflation performance since the inception of the Euro has been of considerable debate. On one side, some have argued that it has been a resounding success. The ECB website itself unsurprisingly argues that its policies have ‘established an environment of price stability in the Euro area, exerting a moderating influence on price and wage-setting’75. Furthermore, Harry Flam (2009) has argued that ‘the inflation record of the Eurozone is outstanding and it is a great achievement for a new central bank to have established a strong low inflation reputation in such short a time span’76. Looking at the aggregate level of 71 Sturm, JE et al (2009) p180 Cuaresma, JC et al (2007) p111 73 Deutsche Bundesbank (2009) ‘Price convergence in the Euro area’ Monthly Report, March 2009, p45 74 Bris, A & Micola, A.R. (2008) ‘Separated by a common currency? Evidence from the Euro changeover’ Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Economic Working Paper No. 1086, p37 75 ECB website (2011) ‘Benefits of the Euro’ Available Online at : http://www.ecb.int/ecb/educational/facts/euint/html/ei_007.en.html (accessed 5th May 2011) 76 Flam, H eds. (2009) EMU at ten: Should, Denmark, Sweden and the UK Join? SNS Economic Policy Group Report, Stockholm, p19 72 18 inflation of the Eurozone as a whole, it might well look as if the ECB’s monetary policy was indeed a great success. For, according to Julian Callow (2010), European economist at Barclay’s Capital, the average yearly Eurozone inflation rate has been 1.96%77 since the start of EMU, firmly in line with the ECB’s ‘below or close to’ 2% objective. Furthermore, Otmar Issing (2010), who was on the Executive Board of the European Central Bank between 1998 and 2006 has argued that ‘business cycle synchronisation has increased since the 1990’s and is currently at a high level and thus from the business cycle perspective, the ECB’s single monetary policy poses no major problems’78. However, this argument seems hard to substantiate given the large inflation and growth differentials between Euro member states in the years of the Euro’s existence. For, although to meet the Maastricht conditions, Eurozone countries narrowed their inflation rate differentials in the years leading up to the Euro, Silva & Tenreyo (2010) have shown that ‘after the launching of the Euro inflation rate differentials increased with Germany at the lower bound of the inflation range and Ireland at the upper bound’79. Although differences in productivity growth and catch-up effects were pointed to as reasons not to worry about such inflation differences, in hindsight it appears that the ECB’s monetary policy was far from optimal for all Euro member states. Indeed looking at the past few years, there is an undeniable argument, supported by Baldwin & Gros (2010) that ‘the one size monetary policy plainly failed to fit all’80. Although different monetary policy preferences have, as yet not been the source of the kind of international conflict that Feldstein predicted in 1997, differing economic outcomes have been a source of concern in the Euro’s brief history due to the ‘one size does not fit all’ problem. For, the old deutschmark bloc (Germany, France, Austria, Netherlands, Belgium and Luxembourg) tended to experience lower than average growth and inflation and could have done with more expansionary monetary policy whereas the reverse was true for the European Periphery. The so called PIGS (Portugal, Ireland, Greece and Spain) countries boomed and this was accompanied by prices and wages that rose much more than average. As De Grauwe (2009) has shown, ‘inflation differentials between the lowest and highest inflation countries regularly exceeded 3%’81 and furthermore between 2000 and 2007 ‘the cumulative excess inflation was 10 percentage points for Ireland and 8 points for Greece and Spain’82. Such inflation differentials can clearly be seen in Figure 2 on the following page83 with France, Germany and Austria (Group A) regularly having inflation rates below the Eurozone average whilst the PIGS (Group B) having much higher rates than such an average. If these states were to have had control of their own currency, it is hard to argue that their central banks would not have run a tighter monetary policy. Callow, J. (2010), Figure taken from ‘Eurozone inflation undershoots ECB target’ Financial Times 5th January 2010, Available Online at: http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/44d97fba-f9eb-11de-adb400144feab49a.html#axzz1NZ0mCNnu (accessed 25th May 2011) 78 Issing, O. (2010) The Birth of the Euro, Cambridge University Press, p208 79 Silva, JMC & Tenreyro, S (2010) p63 80 Baldwin, R. & Gros, D (2010) ‘The Euro in Crisis – What to do?’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London, p4 81 De Grauwe (2009) p194 82 Ibid, p4 83 Figures from Eurostat (2011) ‘Annual Inflation rate database’, Available Online at http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&language=en&pcode=tsieb060&tableSelection=1&footno tes=yes&labeling=labels&plugin=1 (accessed 2nd August 2011) 77 19 Figure 2: Inflation differentials in the Eurozone, Source: Eurostat (2011) Absolute inflation deviation from Eurozone average for Group A -2 -2 -3 -3 -4 -4 Germany France Austria Portugal Ireland Greece Spain Related to this is that one can indeed see symptoms of the so called ‘Walters critique’ in the housing price booms of the European periphery. For, as the critique goes ‘uneven inflation rates with a uniform policy interest rate can produce real interest rate differences that prompt divergent trends’84. As Kevin O’Rouke (2011) has argued when Ireland joined EMU ‘overnight interest rates were cut from roughly 7% to 3%’85 and with high inflation rates, real interest rates were low in that country and for the other booming periphery nations. To give an example De Grauwe (2009) shows that with average inflation of 3.3% during 1999-2008 and the long term nominal interest rate of 4.8%, Ireland had a real interest rate of 1.5% whereas Germany had a real interest rate of 3.3% over the same time period86. Thus, the negative real interest rate Ireland and others on the periphery experienced encouraged borrowing fuelled investment in assets such as housing whilst Germany’s relatively high real interest rates had the opposite effect. The result of this was that between 1997 and 2008 ‘house prices more than doubled in Spain, and more than tripled in Ireland. In contrast, German house prices barely moved’87. This can be seen in the Figure 388 on the next page: 84 Ibid, p6 O’Rourke, KH (2011) ‘Ireland in crisis: a European problem that requires a European solution’, Interview by Viv Davies. Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6017 (accessed 26th April 2011) 86 Figures from De Grauwe (2009) p197 87 De Grauwe (2009) p198 88 Figures from The Economist (2008) ’Global House Prices: Popping Sounds’ Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/12725898?story_id=E1_TNSNVRJR (accessed 22nd May 2011) 85 20 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 -1 1998 2010 2009 2008 2007 -1 2006 0 2005 0 2004 1 2003 1 2002 2 2001 2 2000 3 1999 3 1998 4 1997 4 1997 Absolute inflation deviation from Eurozone average for Group B Figure 3: House price indices (% change over 1997-2008) Source: The Economist, Dec 06 2008 250 200 150 100 50 0 Germany Italy Netherlands Belgium Spain Ireland An insight into this issue can be seen concerning the Taylor rule, named after the US economist John Taylor. In brief, ‘this rule describes how the central bank reacts (by adjusting its policy interest rate) to changes in the deviation of the actual rate of inflation from target, and the divergence of output from its long term potential (the output gap)’89. The rule was designed to give central banks recommendations at how to set short-term interest rates as economic conditions change and also to achieve both their short-run goal for stabilizing the economy and long-run goal for inflation. Although not without its critics, the Taylor rule ‘is conceptually of great interest to central banks as it can provide indications as to the current stance of monetary policy and to that extent act as a kind of guide’90. An analysis by Taylor himself shows how loose monetary policy contributed to the housing boom in the periphery Euro countries. Figure 491 shows the change in housing investment among Eurozone members 2001-06, related to the sum of the differences between the interest rate target implied by the Taylor rule and the actual policy rate. It shows, unsurprisingly, that it was the periphery booming countries with the largest deviations from the Taylor rule that had the biggest change in housing investment as a share of GDP. 89 Issing,O (2010) p89 Ibid, p90 91 Taylor, J. (2009), Getting Off Track, Hoover Institution Press, Stanford, California, p9 90 21 Figure 4: Housing Investment versus Deviations from the Taylor Rule in Europe during 2001–6, Source: Taylor,J. (2009) Thus with the PIGS countries facing a looser monetary policy than was needed, these countries, according to Ubide (2010) ‘should have been running fiscal surpluses of the order of 5-6% of GDP to offset the negative real interest rate its borrowers enjoyed’92. However, political pressure to increase welfare and infrastructure spending made this politically impossible and instead such countries ran a looser than optimal fiscal policy. It can be argued that this has been a source of asymmetric shocks within the monetary union. 5.4. The Euro, asymmetric shocks and divergences: One can argue that the Euro has actually increased asymmetric shocks and actually created asymmetric divergences in competitiveness. Although Krugman’s 1991 argument that greater integration would lead to greater economic specialisation and subsequently more asymmetric shocks is hard to substantiate, member’s budgetary decisions have indeed been the source of suck shocks. Despite the Stability and Growth pact, Euro states had a high amount of discretion over what fiscal policy measures they could undertake and the argument that this could be a source of asymmetric shocks seems to have been born out in the years since the Euro’s introduction. For, in essence the Pact failed to achieve what it set out to do. As The Economist (2009) notes ‘the emphasis on the costs to others of fiscal indiscipline meant that Ubide, A ‘The European bicycle must accelerate’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London, p45 92 22 countries were careful to behave no worse than their peers, rather than being prudent on their own behalf’93. Thus, with electorates that wanted to reap the benefits of the good times, public finances often added to rather than subtracted from demand pressures and ‘fiscal policy often worked against the monetary sort rather than complementing it, as the pact intended’94. The PIGS countries in particular had tax revenues and subsequent spending requirements that were heavily reliant on transaction based taxes in the booming property sector that negative real interest rates had played a key role in bringing about. Moreover, in the booming period capital gains tax receipts were also high during a period of large-scale property price increases. As a result of the windfall revenues that had come from such tax receipts ‘Ministers had been able to insist that their fiscal policies were sound because they fitted in with the pact’s narrow guidelines’95 and therefore underlying fiscal weakness was masked. Indeed, as Baldwin & Gros (2010) have noted ‘the failure of deficit discipline meant that almost half the Eurozone nations entered the crisis period of 2008 onwards with high debt ratios, many well above the Maastricht limit’96. Thus, when the global financial crisis hit in September 2008, several countries were already in weak budgetary positions but found themselves in a situation where they had to take on more debt. Firstly, the property market bubbles burst. As Krugman (2011) has shown ‘in 2007, construction accounted for roughly 13% of total employment in the PIGS countries, so when the building booms came to a screeching halt, employment crashed’97. This precipitated a recession with automatic stabilisers in the form of unemployment benefits and other social spending at a time when tax receipts were falling with a downfall in property market related taxes. This inevitably led to faster public debt accumulation which was further worsened by the bailout of overleveraged banks and their toxic assets which turned private into public debt. This was particularly the seed of Ireland’s crisis. Baldwin & Gros (2010) have argued ‘if the fiscal discipline elements of the Eurozone’s policy framework had worked better prior to the crisis, low national debt ratios would have provided the room to absorb this sort of additional pressure’98. However, such a framework plainly failed to ensure that member states would have such room and as a result many have had to take on huge budget deficits in recent years as shown by Figure 5 on the following page99. Such external debt problems would not have been evident if the Eurozone had a fiscal union in that income would have automatically been transferred from stronger countries such as Germany to weaker members. However as Krugman (2011) has demonstrated ‘Europe isn’t fiscally integrated; German taxpayers don’t automatically pick up part of the tab for Greek pensions or Irish bank bailouts’100. Fiscal transfers between member states are very small and ‘the EU wide budget is 1.06% of the combined EU GDP compared to the US federal budget of over 20% of GDP’101. In the absence of such fiscal transfers, struggling to pay for such deficits and at risk of insolvency some countries have had to agree to EU and IMF sponsored bailouts, Greece was the first to accept this in May 2010 followed by Ireland in November of that year and now Portugal, all agreeing to large austerity measures in an attempt to bring their public finances back in line. The Economist (2009) ‘A special report on the Euro area: Holding together’, Print edition June 11th 2009. Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/13767371?story_id=13767371 (accessed 10th March 2011) 94 Ibid 95 Ibid 96 Baldwin, R. & Gros, D (2010) p13 97 Krugman, P (2011) ‘Can Europe be saved?,’ New York Times, January 12th 2011. Available Online at: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/16/magazine/16Europe-t.html (accessed 6th March 2011) 98 Baldwin, R. & Gros, D (2010) p11 99 Figures from AMECO but diagram taken from Jungen, K. ‘How vulnerable is Italy’, Available Online at: http://www.roubini.com/affiliate/google-news/40869daed0ec7c06fffdf5356d9daae5f69db104/analysis/143257.php (accessed 15th May 2011) 100 Krugman, P (2011) ‘Can Europe be saved?,’ New York Times, January 12th 2011. Available Online at: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/16/magazine/16Europe-t.html (accessed 6th March 2011) 101 Rusek (2008) p137 93 23 Figure 5: Primary Deficit (% of GDP), Source: AMECO The Competitiveness Issue: Furthermore, one can contend that the Euro has also produced asymmetric trends, most clearly in competitiveness that has threatened the cohesion of EMU. The PIGS countries experienced high economic growth in the period following the Euro’s introduction this produced what De Grauwe (2010) calls ‘animal spirits’ as ‘the optimism prevailing in peripheral countries led to booms in economic activities which in turn triggered wage and price increases in these countries’102. This occurred at a time when Germany followed a tight policy of wage moderation. Thus, a few years of booming activity brought prices and wage costs of some countries, namely the PIGS, out of line with the Eurozone and they have seen a large loss of competitiveness relative to Germany. This can be seen in Figure 6 below103 that shows the evolution of the relative unit labour costs in the Eurozone since 1999 but selects the average over the period 1970-2010. Using 1999 as the base year exaggerates divergence as it assumes 1999 was a year when Eurozone countries were in equilibrium, which was not the case. Although the divergence is less pronounced than when 1999 is selected, one can clearly see the upward divergence from the PIGS countries. Figure 6: Relative unit labour costs in Eurozone (average 1970-2010 = 100) Source De Grauwe (2010) 102 De Grauwe, P (2010) The Financial Crisis and the Future of the Eurozone, Bruges European Economic Policy Briefings No 21, p6 103 Ibid, p6 24 Thus, it can be demonstrated as Rusek argued in 2008 that ‘the large and growing divergences in the internal competiveness are equivalent to an increased frequency and duration of asymmetric shocks’104. This lack of competitiveness played a big role in contributing to significant current account deterioration for the PIGS countries whereas others, namely Germany and Austria saw a large improvement. 5.5. Lack of adjustment mechanism to asymmetric shocks: One can argue that the lack of labour mobility in the Eurozone countries have worsened the crisis. In this regard Krugman (2011) draws a comparison between Nevada, which is a state in a country, the US, that does have high labour mobility and Spain in the EU. He argues that ‘Nevada’s unemployment problem will be greatly alleviated over the next few years by outmigration, so that even if the lost jobs don’t come back, there will be fewer workers chasing the jobs that remain’. Thus, he argues, due to the American labour market flexibility and the communality of labour market institutions across US states, ‘emigration will bring Nevada’s unemployment rate back in line with the US within a few years’. This is in stark contrast to a country like Spain, whose economy has higher unemployment, at 20%, much higher than the EU average. However, although in theory European workers have the legal right to move freely to look for jobs, in practice this does not happen due to institutional, cultural and linguistic barriers. Unemployment thus remains persistently high in Spain and the increased social welfare payments that country has to spend worsen its fiscal situation. 5.6. Loss of devaluation and the debt issue: In a single currency it is harder to become more competitive and repay debts and this poses a big problem for the heavily indebted countries of the Eurozone. For, in a monetary union, it is evidently not possible to gain competiveness and correct current account imbalances by currency depreciation. Thus, ‘the only way is to reduce costs, relative to countries inside and outside the currency area through what economists call internal devaluation’105. This effectively involves a deflation strategy with declining prices and wages and is the current strategy of the countries that have accepted EU and IMF sponsored bailouts. Greece’s austerity measures, for example, involve a freeze on all public sector pay with cuts for some and also the scrapping of bonuses and job losses for public sector contract workers. In this case, the government hoped at the time of the bailout that such measures would cut Greece’s public deficit from the current level of 13.6% to less than 3% by 2014106. The problem with such a strategy is that it can create a vicious circle as The Economist, (2010) notes ‘the more wages and prices fall, the bigger debt burdens become in real terms’107. For, if highly indebted economies continue to have negative GDP growth, there is less income for them to service such debts. Indeed, Irving Fisher pointed out almost 80 years ago, the collision between deflating incomes and unchanged debt can greatly worsen Rusek, A. (2008) ‘Euro: the engine of integration or the seed of dissolution?’ Agricultural economics –Czech, Vol. 54, No. 4, p143 105 The Economist (2010) ‘All pain, no gain?’ Print edition December 9th 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17673268 (accessed 9th March 2011) 106 Figures from BBC (2011) ‘Greece’s austerity measures’, Available Online at http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/10099143 (accessed 15th May 2011) 107 The Economist (2010) 104 25 economic downturns. This is currently most seen in Greece. That country has continued to experience a recession and tax revenues have proved disappointing. It has missed its deficit reduction targets and as The Economist (2011) notes ‘Greek government debt at the end of last year was close to 145% of GDP and the deficit for 2010 was a colossal 10.5% of GDP, well above the original target of 8.1%’108. It looks likely that government will have to force through even greater austerity measures to free up the new spate of IMF/EU aid from the bailout package. Related to this debt problem is the fact that EMU members lose their capacity to issue debt in a currency over which they have full control and this creates vulnerability. As De Grauwe (2011) notes ‘as a result, a loss of confidence of investors can in a self fulfilling way drive the country into default which is not so for countries capable of issuing debt in their own currency’. He shows this mechanism by drawing a distinction between the UK and Spain in a situation where investors start to have doubts about such nation’s insolvency. For the UK such investors would sell their UK government bonds and would have pounds to sell in the foreign exchange market. Therefore, the price of the pound would drop until somebody would buy these pounds and therefore ‘the UK money stock would remain unchanged’109. Moreover, the Bank of England can always provide liquidity to the state to avoid default. In contrast, for Spain ‘the investors who have acquired Euros are likely to decide to invest these Euros elsewhere and as a result the Euros leave the Spanish banking system’110. Thus the money supply in Spain shrinks and the government experiences a liquidity crisis. The Bank of Spain cannot buy government debt and although the ECB can provide liquidity ‘if investors think that the Spanish government might reach this end point, they’ll sell Spanish bonds in a way that turns fear into reality’111. Thus, this mechanism helps explain why, despite the fact that Spain’s debt and deficit are significantly lower than UK ones, The Spanish government pays roughly 200 points more on its 10 year bonds than the UK government (shown below112). This scenario evidently does not help that county’s debt problems. Figure 7. 10-year government bond rates Spain and UK, Source: De Grauwe (2011) The Economist (2011) ‘Europe’s debt saga’ Print edition May 14th 2011, p77 De Grauwe P. (2011) ‘The governance of a Fragile Eurozone’, Centre for European Policy Studies, Working Document, No 346, p4 110 Ibid, p5 111 Ibid, p5 112 De Grauwe, P. (2011) ’ Managing a fragile Eurozone’, Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6484 (accessed 16th May 2011) 108 109 26 This situation has inevitably led many to bemoan the lack of having one’s own currency and the devaluation policy option that one has with this. O’Rourke has recently argued in regards to Ireland ‘I think the major lesson of history is that it would be really, really helpful if we could have a devaluation and in the absence of this with major budget deficits, that’s a major, major problem for us right now’113. For that country, as Krugman (2011) has noted in the current crisis ‘it took Ireland two years of severe unemployment to achieve about a 5% reduction in average wages but in 1993 a devaluation of the Irish punt brought an instant 10% reduction in Irish wages measured in German currency’114. As aforementioned though, the loss of competitive devaluations was actually seen as an advantage of EMU as these were seen to be inflationary at least to some extent. Indeed, Beetsma & Giuliodori (2010) have recently argued that ‘it seems likely that EMU has prevented one or more rounds of competitive devaluations that in the longer run would have merely produced higher inflation and that could have undermined co-operation among EU countries in other areas’115. However, one can contend that increased inflation in the face of a devaluation that has initially helped restore competitiveness and alleviated debt problems may be much more preferable than the vicious circle of bigger real debt which greatly increases the chance of default and insolvency. As De Grauwe (2011) notes ‘the whole adjustment process involving currency depreciation is likely to boost output and inflation, thereby improving the solvency of the sovereign’116. 5.7. Unpopularity of the single currency: Public Sentiment is an important factor to take into account in viewing the EMU. For, as aforementioned the European integration movement has been driven by political and security considerations whereas economic considerations have sometimes taken a backseat. EMU was seen as the biggest achievement of such a movement and it was hoped my many to be another step to greater political unification. The backing of member states population’s is vital in any such process. However, one can reasonably argue that the Euro has had some surprising unintended political consequences. For, the Euro has had a striking loss of public approval in the wake of the financial crisis and subsequent debt problems that many states are experiencing. This declined support has been found by many recent polls but a recent survey by Transatlantic Trends (2010) which polled 1,000 people in each country with possible 3% sampling error, illustrates such a point fittingly. It found that when respondents of Euro member states were asked if the Euro was a good or bad thing, views were mostly negative. For ‘ with few exceptions, the majorities in the Eurozone countries in the survey said the Euro has been a bad thing for their economy, including the two economic powerhouses of Europe, France (60%) and Germany (53%), but also Spain (53%) and Portugal (52%)’117. Indeed, only the Dutch (52%) and the Slovaks (64%)118 had clear majorities saying the single currency had been good for their country. This is a stark contrast to opinions at the time of the Euro’s introduction in 2002 when an average O’Rourke, KH (2011) ‘Ireland in crisis: a European problem that requires a European solution’, Interview by Viv Davies. Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6017 (accessed 26th April 2011) 114 Krugman, P (2011) ‘Can Europe be saved?,’ New York Times, January 12th 2011. Available Online at: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/16/magazine/16Europe-t.html (accessed 6th March 2011) 115 Beetsma, R. & Giuliodori, M. (2010) ‘The Macroeconomic Costs and Benefits of the EMU and Other Monetary Unions’ Journal of Economic Literature 48 p614 116 DeGrauwe P (2011) The governance of a Fragile Eurozone, April 2011, p14 117 Transatlantic Trends (2010) ‘Key Findings’ Available Online in pdf format at: http://trends.gmfus.org/doc/2010_English_Key.pdf, p12 (accessed 10th May 2011) 118 Ibid, p12 113 27 of 59% of member state citizens considered the Euro ‘advantageous overall’ in a Euro barometer survey119. Reasons for this unpopularity are widespread. Mongelli & Wyplosz (2009) have argued that much of it stems from the ECB’s lack of transparency and the fact that it does not publish board meetings minutes has resulted in ‘the impression of a disconnect between policy decisions and their justification’120. However, it seems far fetched that the publishing of ECB minutes would make the single currency popular. More likely reasons are that Eurozone citizens have responded to the lack of tangible benefits from the currency, particularly in the face of the pre-Euro hype. Moreover, some suspect the Euro has not helped their nations relatively weak economic performance in recent years and some blame the Euro for playing a negative role in the financial crisis with the lack of devaluation policy making debt repayment harder as aforementioned. Nonetheless, whatever the reasons, as Caselli (2009) has argued ‘disappointment with the Euro has fed into political opposition to further steps towards European integration, including political unification’121. Such disappointment has even led to new calls for the abandonment of the whole EMU project. 6. The Future of EMU: 6.1. The Breakup of the Euro Area? The possibility of a Euro member withdrawing from EMU is not a new concept but has not been taken seriously for most of the Euro’s short history. However, in light of the current financial difficulties that the PIGS countries are experiencing, this spectre has gained new poignancy and no longer seems like the nonsensical prospect it seemed only a few years ago. Indeed on May 7th 2011 the Euro fell by 1% against the dollar following an article in the German Magazine ‘Der Spiegel’ that reported that a Euro minister meeting was going to take place about Greece readopting its own currency122, reflecting investor worries of this happening. For, in the absence of the devaluation economic policy tool, with high debt burdens and struggling to restore competitiveness some have argued that the PIGS countries may find ‘an exit from the Eurozone the only realistic option for recovery’123. For a country may be tempted to exit the single currency in order to devalue and to bring its wages closer in line with workers productivity and also to boost its exports to address its current account imbalance. In such a scenario ‘a government could simply pass a law saying that the wages of public workers, welfare cheques and government debts would henceforth be paid in a new currency, converted at an official fixed rate’124 and other financial dealings such as mortgages, stock prices and bank loans amongst others would have to be redenominated into this new currency. Moreover, as Rodrik notes ‘a breakup of the Eurozone may not doom it forever as 119 Eurobaromter Survey (2002) quoted from Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) (2009) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany, p43 120 Mongelli, F.P. & Wyplosz, C. (2009) ‘The Euro at ten – unfulfilled threats and unexpected challenges’ in Ibid, p42 121 Caselli, F. (2009) Comment on "The Euro at ten: unfulfilled threats and unexpected challenges". In Ibid, p64 122 BBC (2011), ‘Euro falls on rumours Greece is to quit the Eurozone’ Available Online at: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-13317770 (accessed 8th May 2011) 123 Rodrik, D. (2010) ‘Thinking the Unthinkable in Europe’ Available Online at: http://www.projectsyndicate.org/commentary/rodrik51/English (accessed 10th April 2011) 124 The Economist (2010) ‘Breaking up the Euro area: How to resign from the club’ Print edition Dec 2nd 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17629757 (accessed 2nd March 2011) 28 countries can rejoin, and do so credibly, when fiscal, regulatory and political prerequisites are in place’125. However, how realistic is such a breakup? In truth, despite investor worries to the contrary, it seems very unlikely that an ‘irreversible’ currency union such as the Euro will breakup predominantly due to the huge technical, legal and political hurdles and factors any country thinking about leaving would experience. Firstly, Eichengreen (2007) has argued in an influential article on this subject that the technical difficulties are very large as ‘computers will have to be reprogrammed, vending machines modified and notes and coins will have to be positioned around the country’126. It took 3 years in physical preparation for the Euro and importantly such a period was accompanied by little reason to expect change in exchange rates. This would not be true for the new currency which would invite large-scale and destabilising currency speculation. Furthermore, households and firms, uncertain as to the strength of the new currency would shift their deposits to other Euro area banks and ‘in the worst case a system wide bank run could follow’127. In response to this the government would impose capital controls, suspending operation of the bond market and also likely introduce limits on bank withdrawals. As The Economist (2010) notes this would ‘strangle commerce and leavers may be cut off from foreign finance, perhaps for years, further starving their economies of funds’128. Also, one must take into account legal and political factors. Contracts would be changed into the new currency and this would likely generate legal challenges that may invalidate such a redenomination. As Eichengreen contends ‘cases involving suits against the leaver’s debtors in the courts of other European countries and in the European Court of Justice could be messy’129. In the political domain, it seems unlikely that a country leaving EMU would be allowed to simply rejoin at a later date as Rodrik argued. For, such a country would be viewed as having unilaterally disregarded its commitments to Europe as a whole. With other European countries resentful at the artificial devaluation that would ensue, ‘a country that reintroduced its national currency at levels that stepped down its labour costs by 20% might be required to pay a 20% compensatory duty when exporting to other members of the EU’130 and it would lose the privileges of the single market. Also, it would not be welcome in future discussions regarding EU policy priorities ‘insofar as member states value their participation in these political discussions, they would incur significant costs’131. Lastly, one must remember that the EMU project, whatever, its economic results, has been one of the most visible and championed achievements of the whole European integration movement. Allowing any member to leave would risk that country becoming a pariah, exporting pain to its neighbours which could ‘detonate a chain reaction that would threaten the fabric of the single market and the EU itself’132. Thus, it seems very unlikely that the European ‘core’ countries of France and Germany amongst others, which have invested much in the integration movement in recent decades, would risk such a possibility. 125 Rodrik, D. (2010) Eichengreen, B. (2007) ‘The Breakup of the Euro Area’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 13393, p17 127 Ibid, p17 128 The Economist (2010) ‘The future of the Euro: Don’t do it’, Print edition Dec 2nd 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17629661 (accessed 2nd March 2011) 129 Eichengreen, B. (2007) p20 130 Ibid, p11 131 Ibid, p35 132 The Economist (2010) ‘The future of the Euro: Don’t do it’ 126 29 6.2. Redressing Eurozone fragility Thus, the costs of a Euro breakup would be hugely disruptive and look unlikely at present. Nonetheless, despite EMU’s inherent flaws over its lifetime and unpopularity, there are numerous positive steps that European policy makers could take which would improve the running of the single currency in the future. Indeed the ongoing Eurozone crisis and fragility can be seen as a unique opportunity to do just this. Firstly, economists have long argued that the Euro would work much more efficiently if Euro states moved towards political union much like the United States. De Grauwe (2011) has argued that a fiscal union transferring resources to countries hit by economic shocks and the creation of a common fiscal authority that can issue debt would ‘protect member states from being forced into default by financial markets and protects monetary union from centrifugal forces that financial markets can exert on the union’133. One can argue that this would be one of the best ways of preventing future Euro crises as resources would naturally go from stronger members to weaker ones, greatly alleviating their debt concerns. However, one only needs to look at the current state of EU budget negotiations to see that there is little desire to go in this direction with most major European players such as France and Germany wanting a freeze in the EU budget until 2020. Any type of fiscal union within Europe looks politically impossible any time soon. Nonetheless, some saw the May 2010 European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), a €440 billion “stabilisation fund” for Euro-zone countries that have trouble financing their debts, as a step in the right direction. However, as De Grauwe (2010) points out ‘it fails short of an automatic insurance mechanism mainly because it is a network of bilateral loan agreements, making it possible for individual countries to pull out in the future’134. Attempts to create a more permanent fund have taken place. The recent Eurozone summit of March 24-25th 2011, saw EU leaders agree on such a permanent European Stability Mechanism (ESM) which boosts the lending capacity of its precursor, the EFSF to 600bn Euros. However, a decision of how to pay for such a fund was delayed as The Economist (2011) notes because ‘German Chancellor Merkel refused to put up money her finance minister had pledged’135. Moreover, when the ESM is launched in 2013, at present, ‘countries that apply for financing from it will be subjected to a tough budgetary austerity program as a condition for obtaining finance’136. This will mean pro cyclical budgetary policies that could make a recession worse. Thus, a financial support mechanism is indeed something that could help but a more integrated, efficient EMU but the conditions attached to the ESM according to De Grauwe (2011) have ‘transformed it into an institution that is unlikely to produce more stability in the Eurozone’137. These conditions should be revised before the ESM is launched. Along with a more permanent insurance mechanism, there are other reforms in the institutional field that would strengthen the single currency. As has been argued, the Stability and Growth pact has plainly failed to provide the fiscal stability that it was supposed to achieve and was a weak barrier against the fiscal profligacy of the PIGS countries. Thus, as Wyplosz (2010) has argued ‘restoring fiscal discipline requires Europe to tackle this political De Grauwe (2011) ‘The governance of a Fragile Eurozone’ p16 De Grauwe, P. (2010) ‘How to embed the Eurozone in a political union’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London, p31 135 The Economist (2011) ‘The Eurozone's periphery: They're bust. Admit it’, Print edition March 31st 2011, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/18485985 (accessed 7th April 2011) 136 De Grauwe (2011) ‘The governance of a Fragile Eurozone’ p20 137 Ibid, p21 133 134 30 failure head on by adopting institutions that bind the budgetary process’138. Although there are many suggestions on how to do this, the establishment of national fiscal councils has gained widespread academic approval of late. Lane (2010) has argued that ‘an independent fiscal council can help identify the stabilisation risks facing the economy, estimate the appropriate cyclical position for the annual budget and estimate the optimal future path of fiscal balances that will ensure fiscal sustainability’139. It works by having formal fiscal rules that specify the medium term path for the structural fiscal balance whilst allowing flexibility in the presence of a large macroeconomic shock. A current example of such a system is evident in Sweden today, which Fatas & Mihov (2010) have argued shows ‘how an independent body can allow for flexibility in times when there is a clear trade off between sustainability and stabilisation’140. Although it may be too early to judge the Swedish example an unequivocal success, Calmfors & Wren Lewis (2011) have contended that it has played a significant positive contribution to that country’s strong fiscal position. For example ‘the council’s call to the political parties in the 2010 parliamentary election campaign to avoid committing to measures that would permanently worsen the budget balance received widespread media attention and likely strengthened fiscal discipline’141. A joint issue of Eurobonds which would mean participating countries becoming jointly liable for the debt they have issued together is another step in strengthening EMU and as De Grauwe (2011) argues, it would be ‘an important mechanism of internalizing the externalities of the Eurozone’142. Nonetheless, such a proposal has met considerable opposition due to a number of problems. For, it creates problems of moral hazard where an incentive is created for countries to rely on this implicit insurance and to issue too much debt. Also, some countries in stronger budgetary positions such as Germany will be reluctant to pay potentially higher interest on their debt that a Eurobond involving countries with poorer credit ratings would bring. Therefore, such a Eurobond system must be designed ‘as such to eliminate the moral hazard risk and must produce sufficient attractiveness for the countries with favourable credit ratings’143. One way of doing this might be to charge fees on such bonds relative to their fiscal positions so that those with higher debt levels would face a higher fee and vice versa. In any case, a successful Eurobond would create a large new bond market with a lot of liquidity and would be ‘a collective defence system against the vagaries of euphoria and fears that regularly grip financial markets, leading to centrifugal forces in a monetary union’144 Furthermore, labour mobility between Euro member states is still weak compared to other currency unions such as that of the United States. Reform in this area has been near non existent in the period since the Euro’s introduction. Nonetheless, one can argue, along OCA theory, that reforms increasing the degree of flexibility of labour markets regarding real wages and labour mobility ,although difficult to implement, are necessary to turn the Eurozone into a better functioning monetary union. As Eichengreen (2007) has noted ‘regulations to ensure that French ski resorts extend equality of treatment to instructors trained in other European countries and more generally removing residual barriers to the mutual recognition of technical credentials, the portability of pensions and the receipt of social services in the new labour market will relieve the pressure on countries with depressed labour markets’145. For such measures should better address such countries unemployment problems as workers can more easily more around the Eurozone, creating new job Wyplosz, C. (2010) ‘The Eurozone’s levitation’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds, p 35 Lane, PR. ‘Rethinking national fiscal policies in Europe’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds, p61 140 Fatás, A, & Mihov,I. (2010) ‘Fiscal policy at a crossroads: The need for constrained discretion’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds, p71 141 Calmfors, L and S Wren-Lewis (2011), “What Should Fiscal Councils Do?”, CESifo Working Paper No. 3382, p45 142 De Grauwe P. (2011) ‘The governance of a Fragile Eurozone’, p21 143 Ibid, p22 144 De Grauwe, P. (2011) ’ Managing a fragile Eurozone’, Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6484 (accessed 16th May 2011) 145 Eichengreen, B. (2007) p27 138 139 31 possibilities in those countries. However, up to now there has been little suggestion that European politicians are prepared to move in this direction as such measures are indeed politically divisive domestically. Lastly, as has been mentioned the PIGS countries current strategy of internal devaluation risks a downward spiral where it becomes harder to repay their large debt and this will only get harder with the ECB’s recent decision to increase interest rates. Thus according to Daniel Rodrik (2010) ‘the need for debt restructuring is an unavoidable reality’146 for Greece in particular as such debts must be reduced for the austerity measures that such countries are currently undertaking to not doom them to years of stagflation. Eichengreen (2010) has recently made a similar argument and has laid out a reasonable plan. He argues that governments ‘should offer a menu of new bonds worth some fraction of their existing obligations so that bondholders have a choice between par bonds with a face value equal to their existing bonds but a longer maturity and lower interest rate and discount bonds with a shorter maturity and higher interest rate but a face value that is a fraction of existing bond’s face value’147. For such a measure to succeed the IMF and German government should guarantee that such bonds are adequately collaterised and banks that suffer losses as a result of such restructurings must have their balance sheets reinforced. European level co-operation and political will from Germany, in particular, is needed which must ‘convince their constituents that using public money to provide sweeteners for debt restructuring is essential to the internal devaluation strategy that they insist their neighbours follow’148. Of course practically speaking a restructuring will mean large losses for bondholders of the restructured nation’s government debt and would indeed cause losses of tens of billions of dollars at Europe's commercial banks. However, in the Greek case, that country is on an unsustainable path facing its third straight year of recession and rising government debt. Restructuring debt is thus necessary but unfortunately such a scenario looks bleak at present for as The Economist (2011) has noted ‘Europe’s leaders won’t hear of debt reduction now, but insist that any country requiring help from 2013 may then need to have its debt restructured and that new official lending will take priority over bondholders’149. The result of this is that the aforementioned debt ‘downward spiral’ gets worse for the PIGS countries in the meantime and ‘the risk that investors could face a haircut in two years time keeps yields high today, which in turn blights the rescue plans’150. As the Barrons newspaper (2011) recently put it ‘the choice for Greece's bondholders, as we see it, is to accept 50 cents on the Euro now -- or 30 cents or worse down the road’151. Rodrik, D. (2010) ‘Thinking the Unthinkable in Europe’, Available Online at: http://www.projectsyndicate.org/commentary/rodrik51/English (accessed 10th April 2011) 147 Eichengreen, B. (2010) ‘Europe’s Inevitable Haircut’, Available Online at: http://www.projectsyndicate.org/commentary/eichengreen25/English (accessed 10th April 2011) 148 Ibid 149 The Economist (2011) ‘The Eurozone's periphery: They're bust. Admit it’, Print edition March 31 st 2011, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/18485985 (accessed 7th April 2011) 150 Ibid 151 Racenelli, VJ (2011) ‘How to Fix Greece’ Barrons, Available Online: http://Online.barrons.com/article/SB50001424053111903548904576343340195494116.html?mod=TWM_pastedit ion_1 (accessed 28th May 2011) 146 32 7. Conclusion: Thus, this paper has attempted to analyse the Euro single currency by comparing the theoretical benefits and costs which were highlighted in the lead up to the advent of EMU (Economic & Monetary Union) with what has actually happened in practice. It has been argued that, in short, the evidence shows that many of the benefits have failed to come about whereas, in contrast, many of the costs have. The Euro was meant to increase trade through the elimination of transaction costs and the elimination of exchange rate risk and also to increase price convergence through expected price transparency and the law of one price. The evidence has shown that neither has happened. The prediction by Andy Rose that monetary union could increase trade for participant members by up to 200% now looks ridiculous and is discredited. Moreover, studies that have found the Euro to have had a substantial effect on trade have methodological problems amongst them that they do not take into account the effect of the European single market over time. Also, although the evidence shows that there was price convergence before the Euro’s inception, there has been no significant narrowing of price differentials over the Euro’s short history. It was also hoped that the Euro would through greater trade integration promote business cycle symmetry make asymmetric shocks less likely. Furthermore, by anchoring themselves to a credible institution such as the ECB and low historic inflation countries, previously inflationary countries and indeed the whole of the Eurozone would be able to benefit from a low inflationary environment. Some have argued that looking at the ECB’s overall record, it has indeed succeeded, by large, in promoting such an environment. However, taking a disaggregate look paints a different picture. For, the Euro has actually experienced a period of business cycle asymmetry and a classic ‘one size does not fit all’ problem in the conduct of its monetary policy. For, the overheating economies of the periphery, namely the PIGS, could have done with a stricter monetary policy whereas the sluggish economies of France and Germany could have done with a looser one. With a looser than optimal interest rate, the PIGS countries experienced an asset price fuelled boom. This may not have been such a problem if such countries had pursued sensible fiscal policy. However, one can argue that the Eurozone member’s profligate policies have, in themselves, been a source of asymmetric shocks. For, still abiding by the Eurozone’s fiscal rules, these countries engaged on a public spending spree with much revenue coming from taxes related to the asset price boom. When this bubble burst, these countries debts soared and they had to rely on EU and IMF sponsored bailouts. Moreover, with the lack of the devaluation policy tool and unable to issue debt in their own national currencies, these countries will find it harder to repay such debt and restore competitiveness. Years of deflationary pain await. Given this, it is little wonder that the Euro has experienced a stark decline in popularity in recent years. Thus, with the Eurozone in such dire straights, some have argued that a country may be tempted to leave EMU and devalue. However, this paper has argued that such a prospect is unlikely due to the huge technical and legal barriers that a country would have to overcome. Instead of focusing on this unlikely prospect, it is thus better to focus on ways that will make EMU more stable in the future. This paper has argued that a fiscal union would be the most optimal way of doing this but that it looks politically impossible anytime soon. Nonetheless there are positive steps that can be taken. A more permanent insurance mechanism, independent fiscal councils to ensure budgetary discipline and the joint issuing of Eurobonds have all been highlighted. A new focus on making labour markets more flexible would also help solve the adjustment problem as pointed to in the OCA literature. Finally, the ECB 33 should allow Greece and possibly other PIGS countries in the future to restructure their debt as with negative economic growth and with high debt burdens the crisis is likely to get worse rather than better for that country in particular in the near future. Nonetheless, with the entire ‘Euro’ project so unpopular and with domestic concerns, it is as yet unclear whether politicians will take some of the aforementioned steps which would make the Eurozone function more optimally. As Wolfgang Münchau has recently written ‘a breakup of the Euro is unlikely, but another outcome – a perpetually malfunctioning and divided monetary union seems increasingly on the horizon’152. Münchau, W. (2011) ‘Original sin: The seeds of the Euro crisis are as old as the Euro itself’ Foreign Policy, Available Online at: http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2011/04/07/original_sin (accessed 10th April 2011) 152 34 Bibliography: Artis, MJ. & Zhang, W. (1995) ‘International Business Cycles and the ERM: Is there a European Business Cycle?’ International Journal of Finance Economics, Vol 2, pp. 1-16 Baldwin, R. & Gros, D (2010) ‘The Euro in Crisis – What to do?’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London Baldwin, R. et al (2008) ‘Study on the impact of the Euro on Trade and Foreign Direct Investment’ European Economy. Economic Papers. 321. May 2008. Brussels Bayoumi,T & Eichengreen, B. (1997) ‘Ever closer to heaven? An optimum-currency area index for European countries’ European Economic Review 41, pp. 761-770 BBC (2011) ‘Greece’s austerity measures’, Available Online at http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/10099143 (accessed 15th May 2011) BBC (2011), ‘Euro falls on rumours Greece is to quit the Eurozone’ Available Online at: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-13317770 (accessed 8th May 2011) Beetsma, R. & Giuliodori, M (2010) ‘The Macroeconomic Costs and Benefits of the EMU and Other Monetary Unions’ Journal of Economic Literature 48 pp. 603-641 Bris, A & Micola, A.R. (2008) ‘Separated by a common currency? Evidence from the Euro changeover’ Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Economic Working Paper No. 1086 Callow, J. (2010), taken from ‘Eurozone inflation undershoots ECB target’ Financial Times 5th January 2010, Available Online at: http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/44d97fba-f9eb-11deadb4-00144feab49a.html#axzz1NZ0mCNnu (accessed 25th May 2011) Calmfors, L and S Wren-Lewis (2011), “What Should Fiscal Councils Do?”, CESifo Working Paper No. 3382 Caselli, F. (2009) Comment on "The Euro at ten: unfulfilled threats and unexpected challenges". In Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) (2009) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany Chang, M. (2009) Monetary Integration in the European Union, Palgrave Macmillan, London Cuaresma, JC et al (2007) ‘Price Level Convergence in Europe: Did the Introduction of the Euro Matter?’ Austrian Central Bank, Monetary Policy and the Economy: Issue 1 (April) pp. 100-113 De Grauwe P. (2011) ‘The governance of a Fragile Eurozone’, Centre for European Policy Studies, Working Document, No 346 De Grauwe, P (2010) The Financial Crisis and the Future of the Eurozone, Bruges European Economic Policy Briefings No 21 De Grauwe, P. (2009) Economics of Monetary Union, Oxford Uni Press, Oxford 35 De Grauwe, P. (2010) ‘How to embed the Eurozone in a political union’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London De Grauwe, P. (2011) ’ Managing a fragile Eurozone’, Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6484 (accessed 16th May 2011) Deutsche Bundesbank (2009) ‘Price convergence in the Euro area’ Monthly Report, March 2009, pp. 33-47 EC Commission (1990) ‘One Money, One Market’ European Economy. 44 ECB (1999) Monthly Bulletin, January ECB (2002) ‘Price level convergence and competition in the euro area’, Monthly Bulletin, August 2002, pp. 39-49 ECB website (2011) ‘Benefits of the Euro’ Available Online at : http://www.ecb.int/ecb/educational/facts/euint/html/ei_007.en.html (accessed 5th May 2011) Eichengreen, B. (1997) European Monetary Unification, MIT Eichengreen, B. (2007) ‘The Breakup of the Euro Area’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 13393 Eichengreen, B. (2010) ‘Europe’s Inevitable Haircut’, Available Online at: http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/eichengreen25/English (accessed 10th April 2011) Engel, C, & Rogers (1995) "How wide is the border?," International Finance Discussion Papers 498, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.) European Commission website ‘Consumer Benefits’. Available Online at: http://ec.Europa.eu/economy_finance/Euro/why/consumer/index_en.htm (accessed 7th May 2011) Eurostat (2011) ‘Annual Inflation rate database’, Available Online at http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=table&language=en&pcode=tsieb060&tabl eSelection=1&footnotes=yes&labeling=labels&plugin=1 (accessed 2nd August 2011) Fatás, A, & Mihov,I. (2010) ‘Fiscal policy at a crossroads: The need for constrained discretion’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London Feldstein, M. (1997) ‘EMU and International Conflict’, Foreign Affairs, November/December, Vol 76. Available Online at: http://www.nber.org/feldstein/fa1197.html (accessed 25th April 2011) Feldstein, Martin, (1997), “The political economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political sources of an economic liability”, NBER Working Paper No 6150 Flam, H eds. (2009) EMU at ten: Should, Denmark, Sweden and the UK Join? SNS Economic Policy Group Report, Stockholm 36 Flam, H. (2009) The Impact of the Euro and International Trade and Investment: A Survey of the Theoretical and Empirical Evidence, Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies, Stockholm Frankel JA & Rose, AK. (1997) ’Is EMU More Justifiable Ex Post than Ex Ante?’ European Economic Review, Volume 41, Issue 3-5, pp. 753-760 Friedman, M. (2000) quoted from “An interview with Milton Friedman. Interviewed by John B. Taylor, May 2000” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 5, 2001, pp. 101–131 Gros,D. & Thygesen,N. (1998) European Monetary Integration, Longman, New York Hogrefe, J, Jung, B & Kohler, W (2010) ‘Readdressing the trade effect of the Euro: Allowing for currency misalignment’ ZEW Discussion Paper No. 10-023, April 2010 Hovell, RB (2001) ‘The Creation of EMU’ in Artis & Nixson eds. The Economics of the European Union, Oxford University Press Issing, O. (2010) The Birth of the Euro, Cambridge University Press Jungen, K. ‘How vulnerable is Italy’, Available Online at: http://www.roubini.com/affiliate/googlenews/40869daed0ec7c06fffdf5356d9daae5f69db104/ analysis/143257.php (accessed 15th May 2011) Krugman, P. (1991) Geography and Trade, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press Krugman, P (2011) ‘Can Europe be saved?,’ New York Times, January 12th 2011. Available Online at: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/16/magazine/16Europe-t.html (accessed 6th March 2011) Lane, PR. ‘Rethinking national fiscal policies in Europe’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) (2009) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany Majd, S. & Pindyck, RS. (1987) "Time to build, option value, and investment decisions," Journal of Financial Economics, Elsevier, vol. 18(1), pp. 7-27 Malmberg, B. (2003) ‘The yes-campaign has misinterpreted its trade guru’ Available Online at: http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/arose/MalmbergE.htm (accessed 20th April 2011) Miller, M & Sutherland, A, (1991) ‘The "Walters Critique" of the EMS--A Case of Inconsistent Expectations?,’ The Manchester School of Economic & Social Studies, vol. 59(0), pp. 23-37 Mongelli, F.P. & Wyplosz, C. (2009) ‘The Euro at ten – unfulfilled threats and unexpected challenges’ In Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) (2009) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany Münchau, W. (2011) ‘Original sin: The seeds of the Euro crisis are as old as the Euro itself’ Foreign Policy, Available Online at: http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2011/04/07/original_sin (accessed 10th April 2011) 37 Mundell, (1961) ‘A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas’ American Economic Review, 51 (6): pp. 657-65 O’Rourke, KH (2011) ‘Ireland in crisis: a European problem that requires a European solution’, Interview by Viv Davies. Available Online at: http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/6017 (accessed 26th April 2011) Pitchford, R, & Cox, A. (1997) eds. EMU Explained: Markets and Monetary Union Reuters, London Racenelli, VJ (2011) ‘How to Fix Greece’ Barrons, Available Online: http://Online.barrons.com/article/SB50001424053111903548904576343340195494116.html? mod=TWM_pastedition_1 (accessed 28th May 2011) Rodrik, D. (2010) ‘Thinking the Unthinkable in Europe’ Available Online at: http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/rodrik51/English (accessed 10th April 2011) Rose, AK. (2000) “One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common. Currencies on Trade” Economic Policy 30, pp. 7-46 Rusek, A. (2008) ‘Euro: the engine of integration or the seed of dissolution?’ Agricultural economics –Czech, Vol. 54, No. 4, pp. 137-149 Sapir, A. (2009) ‘Panel Statement on Optimal Currency Areas’ In Mackowiak, B, Mongelli, FP, Noblet, G & Smets, F. (eds.) The Euro at ten: lessons and challenges. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany Schwarz, P. (2004) The Euro as Politics, Profile Books, London Silva, JMC & Tenreyro, S (2010) ‘Currency Unions in Prospect and Retrospect’ Annual Review of Economics, Vol 2 pp. 51-74 Sturm, J.E. et al (2009) ‘The Euro and prices: changeover-related inflation and price convergence in the Euro area’, European Economy. Economic Papers. 381. June 2009 (Brussels) Taylor, J. (2009), Getting Off Track, Hoover Institution Press, Stanford, California The Economist (1998) ‘Can one size fit all’, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/159074 (accessed 7th May 2011) The Economist (2008) ’Global House Prices: Popping Sounds’ Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/12725898?story_id=E1_TNSNVRJR (accessed 22nd May 2011) The Economist (2009) ‘A special report on the Euro area: Holding together’, Print edition June 11th 2009. Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/13767371?story_id=13767371 (accessed 10th March 2011) The Economist (2010) ‘All pain, no gain?’ Print edition December 9th 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17673268 (accessed 9th March 2011) The Economist (2010) ‘Breaking up the Euro area: How to resign from the club’ Print edition Dec 2nd 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17629757 (accessed 2nd March 2011) 38 The Economist (2010) ‘The future of the Euro: Don’t do it’, Print edition Dec 2nd 2010, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/17629661 (accessed 2nd March 2011) The Economist (2011) ‘Europe’s debt saga’ Print edition May 14th 2011 The Economist (2011) ‘The Eurozone's periphery: They're bust. Admit it’, Print edition March 31st 2011, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/node/18485985 (accessed 7th April 2011) The Economist, Definitions Section, Available Online at: http://www.economist.com/research/Economics/alphabetic.cfm?term=assets (accessed 3rd May 2011) Transatlantic Trends (2010) ‘Key Findings’ Available Online in pdf format at: http://trends.gmfus.org/doc/2010_English_Key.pdf (accessed 10th May 2011) Ubide, A ‘The European bicycle must accelerate’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London Wypolsz, C. (2006) ‘European Monetary Union: The Dark Sides of a Major Success’, Economic Policy, Vol. 21, No. 46, pp. 208-261 Wyplosz, C. (2010) ‘The Eurozone’s levitation’ In Baldwin, R, Gros, D & Laeven, L. eds (2010) Completing the Eurozone Rescue: What More Needs to Be Done? Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), London 39