HOW FIRMS SHAPE MANAGERS: THE INFLUENCE OF FIRM DEVELOPMENT ACTIVITY ON TOP MANAGERS’ TURNOVER Freek Vermeulen London Business School Regent’s Park London NW1 4SA United Kingdom E-mail: FVermeulen@london.edu Phone: +44 (0)20 7262 5050 Fax: +44 (0)20 7724 7875 & Harry Barkema Department of Organization & Strategy Tilburg University PO Box 90153 5000 LE Tilburg The Netherlands E-mail: Barkema@kub.nl Phone: +31 (0)13 466 2315 Fax: +31 13 (0)13 466 2875 We thank Maayke Brants for data collection, and seminar participants at London Business School for useful comments. HOW FIRMS SHAPE MANAGERS: THE INFLUENCE OF FIRM DEVELOPMENT ACTIVITY ON TOP MANAGERS’ TURNOVER Abstract: An increasing body of literature suggests that the personal characteristics of top managers influence the strategic development of the firms they head. In this paper, we wish to add a new perspective to this literature, and argue that the development path of a firm will also shape the manager. Involvement in strategic activities geared towards the internal development of the firm makes managers build up commitment and emotional investment in the organization. In contrast, managers who spend a lot of time buying and selling off businesses will build up little social capital within the firm. We apply this perspective to examine the influence of firm development activity on top managers’ turnover, using event history analysis on the tenure of 437 top managers. The results show that internal reorganizations, as well as organic expansion decrease the likelihood that top managers will exit, irrespective of the firm’s performance. Engaging in divestitures, as well as engaging in acquisitions increases the probability that a top manager will leave the firm. Overall, the results help paint a more complete picture of the relationship between top management and firm strategy. 2 In response to the body of research that examines organizations from the perspective of population ecology, pioneered by the work of Hannan and Freeman (1977), and the resulting questions in the literature whether management actually matters (e.g. Thomas, 1988), a stream of literature has emerged over the last decade that examines the relationship between the characteristics of top managers and the strategic decisions made by their firms. This research has made clear that individual managers may have considerable influence on the strategic direction a firm takes. Characteristics in terms of managers’ prior experiences, personality, and background have been shown to determine their perceptions of strategic opportunities (Sutcliffe, 1994; Tyler and Steensma, 1998), investment decisions (Barker and Mueller, 2002; Young, Charns, and Shortell, 2001), tendency to innovate and diversify (Bantel and Jackson, 1989; Wiersema and Bantel, 1992), choice of organizational structure (Lewin and Stephens, 1994; Miller and Droge, 1986) and, ultimately, financial performance (e.g., Daily, Certo, and Dalton, 2000;Norburn and Birley, 1988). In addition to this insight that different individuals make different strategic decisions, research by for instance Hambrick and Fukutomi (1991) and Miller and Shamsie (2001) indicated that the same manager may also make different choices at different points in time; strategic decisions are influenced by the life and career stage of the executive; a claim supported by research by Boeker (1997a) and Finkelstein and Hambrick (1990), which also showed that executive tenure has an important influence on the strategic actions of companies, what they do, and how successful they are. A complementary topic, which has received attention in both the Finance (e.g. Furtado and Karan, 1990; Weisbach, 1995) and Management literatures (e.g. Boeker, 1997b; Miller, 1993), dealt with the consequences of top management turnover, and found it to have considerable impact on both the state and performance 3 of a firm. Taken together the overall picture that these different bodies of research paint is clear: different managers make different decisions, at different points in their tenure and, therefore, if these top executives are changed, firms often undergo strategic change as well. Notwithstanding these findings, we, however, believe that this picture is a bit too static, or better, too uni-directional. Surely, individual managers may have a considerable impact on the strategic development of an organization but we believe that the relationship runs the other way around as well; the particular development stage a firm is in (Quinn and Cameron, 1983; Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001) will affect what kind of work the executive is doing and what sorts of actions he or she is undertaking. As a result of this, managers will develop different forms and levels of commitment towards their organization. Particularly, in this paper, we argue that the time spent on internal affairs, such as managing organic growth and reorganizations, which we will call “cultivation”, will create internal networks for managers and increases their commitment to the organization, making it more likely that executives will choose to stay at the firm. External dealings, i.e. buying and selling off businesses, which we will label “compilation” activities, creates more social capital outside the firm, making it more easy for a top manager to switch positions and leave the firm. Hence, we argue that top management and top management turnover are not only the drivers of strategic actions, but that the particular strategic development activities that they command in turn also influence the likelihood of their turnover. In particular, in this paper, we will present an event history analysis where different variables measuring cultivation activities and variables measuring compilation activities will be regressed on the probability that a top manager will leave the firm. Modelling top management turnover is a logical choice since our theory emphasizes the 4 consequences of organizational actions for the commitment of an executive to the firm. Commitment, in social psychology, has been conceptualized as “a psychological state, or mind-set, that increases the likelihood that an employee will maintain membership in an organization” (Meyer and Allan, 1991). Therefore, we will build hypotheses on how organizational actions, such as organic growth, reorganizations, acquisitions, and divestitures, will influence the likelihood that top managemers will maintain or terminate their tenure at their firms. We will test these predictions using a longitudinal database on 437 top managers, tracked over a period of over three decades (1966-1999). The results strongly corroborate a key implication of our theory; that the particular strategic actions that a manager experiences will impact his or her commitment to the firm and ultimately, with it, their likelihood of departure. HOW FIRM DEVELOPMENT PATHS DRIVE TOP MANAGERS’ TURNOVER Organizational Commitment. The form and level of commitment of an employee to an organization has received considerable attention as a topic in social psychology research. Commitment is seen as a person’s inclination to retain membership of an organization (Meyer and Allan, 1991). Indeed, a number of studies have observed strong relations between psychological measurements of organizational commitment and actual turnover (for a review, see Mathieu and Zajac, 1990). In a series of studies by Allen and Meyer (1990; Meyer and Allen, 1984; 1991) commitment was conceptualized as consisting of three different types; affective commitment, continuance commitment, and normative commitment, which was empirically validated in later research by, for instance, Hackett, Bycio, and Hausdorf (1994), 5 Allen and Meyer (1996), and Herscovitch and Meyer (2002). Affective commitment refers to a person’s emotional attachment to, identification with, and involvement in the organization. Because individuals have an affective attachment to the organization, they are committed to pursue its goals. Individual with strong affective commitment to a firm enjoy membership of the organization (Allen and Meyer, 1990; McFarlane Shore and Wayne, 1993). Continuance commitment, in contrast, refers to commitment based on the costs that someone associates with leaving the organization. It is more calculative, and a reflection of recognized, accumulated interests (e.g. pensions, seniority, etc.). Finally, normative commitment refers to a person’s feelings of obligation to stay with the organization. Although commitment to an organization may partly be determined prior to an individual’s entry – for instance, feelings of normative commitment may result from the internalization of normative pressures exerted on the person through familial or cultural socialization – most commitment will be build up following entry, through organizational investments and socialization (Hackett, Bycio, and Hausdorf, 1994). Hence, the specific experiences that individuals go through in an organization and the actions that they undertake will shape their level of commitment to the firm (Dickter, Roznowski, and Harrison, 1996). For instance, the commitment of top managers who spend much time inside their organizations will form differently than managers who are heavily involved in activities outside the firm. Thus, the concept of commitment is related to issues of social capital and the value of internal and external networks (Garguilo, 1993; Ibarra, 1993; Tsai and Ghoshal, 1998). Managers who are actively involved in the internal development of their organization will interact with many people inside the firm, and will build up firm-specific knowledge and internal networks. This will make it costly for them to switch organizations, since they would 6 loose this firm-specific social capital, which would take considerable time and investment to rebuild in a new organization. In contrast, managers who spend a considerable amount of time outside the firm, heavily involved in deal-making, do not build up these firm-specific investments. Moreover, they will obtain contacts outside the firm, which may facilitate their changeover to a different employer. Thus, commitment is driven by the experiences that people go through in their organizations. For top managers this means that the strategic activities that a firm is involved in as a whole, will shape the networks and social capital that they build and, with it, their commitment to the organization. Management as Cultivation versus Management as Compilation We know from research on organizational life cycles (Greiner, 1972; Quinn and Cameron, 1983) and firm development paths (Noda and Collis, 2001; Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001) that firms go through different stages during their existence. Some periods may be characterized by internal development and growth, while others demand restructuring and reorganization (Tushman and Romanelli, 1985). Moreover, organizations may expand in different ways, for instance by acquiring other companies or through the internal development of greenfield ventures. Firms are not restricted to one of these modes, but may combine or alternate them over time (Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001). These different strategic actions reflect in the activities that top managers perform. Acquisitions, for instance, require top managers to spend a lot of time on screening take-over candidates, price negotiation, etc. Internal firm development requires close engagement in, for example, management programs (Rodgers, Hunter, and Rogers, 1993). We distinguish between two broad sets of activities that managers undertake. On the one hand, management actions that are 7 geared to grow and develop a firm organically. We label this organizational ‘cultivation’. In order to do this, top executives must play an active role managing the internal organization of the firm. On the other hand another important task of top management is to manage the composition of the company’s portfolio of businesses. We label this organizational ‘compilation’. Activities that a top manager employs for this task center around the buying and selling of businesses. The specific way in which a firm is developing will influence how much time and effort top managers spend on activities of cultivation and compilation, and with it how their organizational commitment evolves. Some periods may be characterized by organizational cultivation, during which a top manager will spend a lot of time inside the firm, building relationships and designing work processes and structures (Hambrick, Nadler, and Tushman, 1998; Nahavandi and Malekzadeh, 1993). Activities of compilation will imply that the networks and social capital that the top managers develop, in interaction with the selling or acquiring corporations, investment banks, etc., largely take place outside the firm. These external activities lead to external networks and knowledge, and are much less, or not at all firm-specific. Hypotheses Cultivation and the likelihood of top managers’ exit. Firms change and develop over time. Periods of stability often alternate with periods of reorganization and restructuring (Miller and Friesen, 1980; Tushman and Romanelli, 1985). These periods of reorganization are often difficult and painful for the people involved since they usually require fundamental adaptations of work processes, responsibilities, structures, and mental models. Effective reorganizations require the close involvement and commitment of top management (e.g. Kotter, 1995; Rodgers, 8 Hunter, and Rogers, 1993; Wetlaufer, 1999). Engaging in internal reorganizations can be expected to increase a manager’s commitment to an organization, in all its dimensions. By reshaping a firm through programs of organizational transformation top managers build ties with employees (Ibarra, 1993) and firm-specific knowledge about products, work processes, internal power coalitions, etc. (Garguilo, 1993). These ties imply costs of leaving and switching organizations. Moreover, top managers may lose general credibility if they leave shortly after a fundamental organizational re-design. Furthermore, reorganizations ask for a manager’s close, emotional engagement, which will heighten identification with the goals of the firm and its new course, increasing affective commitment. Likewise for normative commitment. Top management will need to convince the people in the organization of the purpose and necessity of the change, propagating the benefits of the renewed organization. This will build a sense of obligation, and commitment to the future of the firm. It will also bring about a forward-looking perspective in the manager’s relation with the organization (McGrath, 1988). Reorganizations are experienced as a starting point in time, rather than an endpoint (Ancona, Okhuysen, and Perlow, 2001). The increased commitment, brought about by engagement in internal reorganizations, makes it more likely that top managers will continue their tenure at the firm. Hypothesis 1: Internal reorganizations are negatively related to the probability of a top manager’s exit. Likewise, setting up greenfield ventures is expected to decrease the likelihood that individual top managers will leave a firm. Start-ups are often the initiative of top management. As such they are associated with both affective and normative commitment. New ventures offer a signal of what top management wants to achieve 9 with the firm, and the direction they want to take. They will usually be closely involved in the decision making around the set up of the new subsidiaries. Although distinct points in time, greenfields may bring about a more continuous and forward-looking perception of time, in a manager’s relationship with his organization. The greenfields are the beginning of a new venture, which will need to be nourished and grown into a profitable operation. This will give managers a focus on the future (McGrath, 1988; Zaheer, Albert, and Zaheer, 1999). Moreover, the management of a newly formed subsidiary will often be carefully selected and hand-picked by the company’s top management. This will lead to social relationships and effective network ties, all of which strengthens a top manager’s bond with the firm, both emotionally and in terms of continuance commitment, i.e. the costs associated with leaving and having to rebuild such valuable relationships in a new company. Therefore, we expect that setting up greenfields will make managers inclined to continue their tenure at a firm. Hypothesis 2: Greenfield ventures are negatively related to the probability of a top manager’s exit. Compilation and the likelihood of top managers’ exit. Another important managerial task, which top managers of large corporations undertake, is managing the composition of the company’s portfolio of businesses. It represents activities that treat a company as a compilation of businesses. This implies buying and selling of businesses, to alter, extend, or eliminate involvement in certain lines of activities, in order to expand or change strategic direction. The reasons behind buying or selling certain businesses may be multiple. They may mirror a firm’s particular development stage (Greiner, 1972), need for revitalization (Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001), or the individual preferences of top managers (Kets de Vries and Miller, 1984; Miller and 10 Shamsie, 2001). For instance, firms have been shown to refocus through divestitures for reasons of poor performance, ineffective strategy, overdiversification, and institutional pressures (Johnson, 1996; Markides, 1992). Deal-making, whether it involves take-overs or sell-offs, however, is timeconsuming and requires much managerial effort and investment (Hitt, Hoskisson, and Ireland, 1990, Hitt, Hoskisson, Ireland, and Harrison, 1991). The compilation activities will affect the organizational commitment that a top manager develops. Divesting companies, for example, will not lead to many useful social ties with people within those divisions. More likely, spinning off or terminating businesses eliminates existing network ties, making it less costly for a manager to terminate his or her tenure at the company, and switch to a different firm. Hence, divestitures can be expected to decrease continuance commitment. Likewise, affective commitment will likely not be stimulated through divestment activity, since the top manager does not build up social relationships. On the contrary, abstaining from strong affective and normative commitment may actually facilitate divestment activity, since a strong emotional attachment to the ventures could lead to escalation (Ross and Staw, 1986; Whyte, 1986). Furthermore, divestitures may give a manager a sense of completion, marking an end point in time (Ancona, Okhuysen, and Perlow, 2001; Zaheer, Albert, and Zaheer, 1999). The “mandate” of a manager (Hambrick and Fukutomi, 1991) may be to “clean up the company’s portfolio”, making it easier for managers to terminate their affiliation “after a job completed”. Hence, divestments may decrease top managers emotional and social involvement with the organization and, hence, make it more likely that they will discontinue their tenure. Thus: Hypothesis 3: Divestment activity is positively related to the probability of a top manager’s exit. 11 Likewise, engaging in acquisitions may decrease a top manager’s stay at the firm. Managers engaged in acquisitions spend much time on making the deal happen; screening and selecting candidates, engaging in negotiations, due diligence, etc. All this time is spent outside the firm, i.e., not on building relationships within the company (Hitt, Hoskisson, and Ireland, 1990, Hitt, Hoskisson, Ireland, and Harrison, 1991). The networks and knowledge acquired through these activities are not firmspecific. They can largely be transfered when a manager accepts a position at a different firm. Hence, there are fewer costs associated with leaving a firm. Actually, external networks are known to facilitate moving on to a new position (Granovetter, 1974; Lin and Dumin, 1986; Montgomery, 1992; Wegener, 1991). Furthermore, the acquired parts of the company have existing social relationships in place, and existing management and employees, not selected by top management. They do not share a common history, that would create bonding and identification with one another (Schein, 1985). This lowers both affective and continuance commitment. Additionally, similar to divestment activity, after deals have been completed top managers often have a sense of achievement and the notion of the completion of a task. This makes it justifiable to themselves and to the outside world to leave their position, i.e., normative commitment is relatively low after a period of intense acquisition activity. Moreover, it leads people to have a discrete, backward looking notion of time (Ancona, Okhuysen, and Perlow, 2001; McGrath, 1988), making it a natural point to terminate an affiliation. Therefore, we predict that: Hypothesis 4: Acquisition activity is positively related to the probability of a top manager’s exit. 12 METHODOLOGY Data The hypotheses were tested on a database regarding a sample of 437 top managers. We wanted to collect a longitudinal database tracking top managers throughout their tenure, collecting data on all the reorganizations, greenfields, divestitures, and acquisitions that occurred during their membership of the top management team. In order to achieve this, we selected a sample of 25 Dutch nonfinancial, multinational companies listed on the Amsterdam Stock Exchange in the year 1999. We selected firms that had been in existence for a considerable period of time because this should enable us to build up a complete picture of the tenure of a large number of top managers. Subsequently we traced back in time the complete membership of their top team to the year 1966 – before which data sources became scarce or non-existent – including all their reorganizations, greenfields, divestitures, and acquisitions. This led to a total sample size of 3300 manager/year observations, which is the models’ unit of analysis. We are aware that this procedure creates a bias towards surviving firms, but it enabled us to have observations of both the entry and the exit dates of a large number of managers. Indeed we managed to obtain uncensored data on 342 of the 437 top managers. Moreover, this procedure minimizes distortion in the data on management turnover due to bankruptcies etc. The selection of surviving firms does not create a bias towards any of our hypotheses, although obviously care should be applied when discussing generalizability of our results. The companies in the database were active in a large variety of businesses: in the manufacture of office equipment, precision machinery, paper and packaging, food 13 products, and pharmaceutical and chemical products and brewing, publishing and printing, retailing, trading, tank storage, and many other industries. The companies are large, but not so large that management of individual divisions are the main driving force behind strategy and development routes, rather than the top management team of the whole company. For instance, the average number of employees over the period 1966-1999 was 11,449. The 25 firms undertook a total of 108 major reorganizations, initiated 401 greenfields, desinvested 724 businesses, and engaged in 1491 acquisitions. An advantage of using Dutch firms is that companies in the Netherlands are all headed by a clearly defined “Raad van Bestuur”, which is considered the firm’s top management team. The average top team consisted of 4.3 members. Average number of years that people stayed on as members of the top management team (excluding censored observations) was 9.3 years, with a standard deviation of 6.2 years. For each of the 25 firms, and all of their managers, a historical overview was made in terms of membership and turnover in the top team, all internal reorganizations, greenfield ventures, divestments of subsidiaries, acquisitions, and a number of control variables, spanning the period 1966-1999. We used a variety of archival sources, such as annual reports, management lexicons, who-is-who in the Netherlands, and sometimes archival records provided for by the firms. In addition, all companies were contacted by telephone and fax to verify information. This led to fully time-variant data regarding all the variables in the study. Dependent variable and analysis The hypotheses were tested using survival analysis, or event history analysis. We used Cox’s semiparametric proportional hazard model (Kiefer, 1988) because we 14 had no apriori knowledge of how the baseline hazard is distributed across tenure, i.e. how the probability that a manager will exit depends on tenure duration. Cox’s semiparametric hazard model does not require assumptions about this distribution, instead it only uses the time order in which the manager is observed, i.e. t 0 < t1 < t2 < … < tk , and not the length between observations (which is why it is called a semiparametric model). Hence, the dependent variable is the instantaneous rate that a manager will exit, building on the information whether or not a manager exited and how many intervals had passed. Note that this model is equivalent to a piecewise exponential survival model, with the number of time intervals equal to the number of distinct times that a manager is observed (Vermunt, 1996). Thus, the dependent variable can be interpreted as the probability that a manager will leave the team. All models were estimated using White, heteroscedasticity robust standard errors. Alternatively, to avoid heteroscedasticity, we also estimated models stratified by company, which allows the baseline hazard function to differ per company. This led to results identical to the ones reported below with all coefficients significant in the same direction. Furthermore, we estimated models controlling for time using a free time polynoom, that is, a variable indicating calendar time and several of its powers, which also produced results which were virtually identical. Because we measure time in a discrete way – that is, we have yearly observations while time in reality is continuous – we also re-estimated the models shown below through discrete-time analysis using a logistic regression model (Vermunt, 1996). All the results, as shown below, were clearly replicated, with all the variable signs in the same direction, at at least similar levels of statistical significance. Independent variables 15 Reorganizations. Internal reorganizations are initially coded as a dummy variable in a certain year if the company in their annual report makes notice of a formal reorganization and transformation program within (part of) the company. This can be a company wide program or a reorganization within a division. Reorganizations in service departments were excluded in the models shown below but their inclusion did not change the results. From this variable we subsequently constructed a moving average of the three years preceding the observation, to take into account possible clustering of reorganizations within a certain time period and because experiences that raise the chance of turnover to some extent accumulate over time (Hackett, Bycio, and Hausdorf, 1994). This variable was lagged one year to ensure causality. We also estimated models adding reorganizations over a number of years, with the older years discounted through various rates (cf. Ingram and Baum, 1997), which produced highly similar results. Greenfield ventures. Similarly, we measured greenfield ventures as the moving average of the number of greenfield expansions over three years, lagged one year, preceding the year of observation. Greenfields were newly established companies, reported as separate entities in the company’s annual report. Divestitures. Likewise for divestitures. We counted the number of divestitures over three years, and lagged this measurement with one year. A divestiture could be the outright dissolution or the sell-off of a previously reported subsidiary. In our theory, concerning the effect on managerial organizational commitment, it does not matter whether the subsidiary gets sold to a different company or whether it is dissolved altogether. In both cases the venture ceases to exist as part of the manager’s organization. 16 Acquisitions. Acquisitions were measured in a similar way; a moving average over three years, lagged one year. Acquisitions concerned the take-over of a different existing company or part of a company. Control variables. We included several control variables on the level of the manager: a dummy variable measuring whether the executive is the CEO of the company, a dummy whether the manager had a technical background, since engineers may be more focused on internal growth, and a dummy for legal background since lawyers may be more focused on deal-making (Barker and Mueller, 2002). On the firm level we controlled for profitability, through return on assets, for instance because managers may be inclined to use financial slack to engage takeovers (Jensen, 1986). We controlled for profitability growth/decline through the percentage change in return on assets. Unfortunately, we had no direct information whether an exit was voluntary or forced, for instance for reasons of bad performance. However, forced exit can be expected to be quite rare in our sample, since it is notoriously difficult for top managers in the Netherlands to be fired for reasons of poor financial performance. However, together these two variables, return on assets and change in return on assets, should control for the effects of (involuntary) turnover due to performance. Any other reasons, causing forced exit, will simply form part of our error term. RESULTS Table 1 displays summary statistics and the correlation matrix of the independent variables. There are no exceptionally large correlations between the variables, but it is noteworthy, however, that the correlations between our predictors 17 are not negative. This is an indication that managers do not necessarily focus on either cultivation (i.e. internal reorganizations and greenfield expansions) or compilation activities (i.e. divestments and acquisitions); apparently these activities do not need to be mutually exclusive. Note that our theory does not suggest that managers engage in either cultivation or compilation, but that cultivation activities increase organizational commitment, while compilation reduces the inclination of top managers to remain at the firm, independent of the correlation between the two. ----- Please insert Table 1 about here ----- Table 2 displays the results of the event history analyses. Recall that, since we had no apriori knowledge of the shape of the baseline function between tenure duration and the hazard, i.e. the probability of exit, we estimated our models using Cox’s partial likelihood approach, to avoid making assumptions about this relationship. Therefore, we first examined the estimated cumulative baseline hazard (using model 2), which is displayed in Figure 1a, and its logical converse the estimated baseline survival function, which indicates the proportion of managers remaining, displayed in Figure 1b. These graphs show that the hazard is monotonically increasing; the longer the manager is in function, the higher the chance becomes that he or she will leave. This relationship is stronger at higher levels of tenure, which makes sense; the chance of departure increases more between, for example, year 15 and 16 than between year 2 and 3. This suggests that if future research would like to estimate parametric hazard models, and hence make assumptions about the form of the baseline hazard, it would be better to opt for, for 18 instance, a Weibull distribution, rather than a loglogistic or lognormal distribution (Allison, 1984; Kiefer, 1988). ----- Please insert Figures 1a and 1b about here --------- Please insert Table 2 about here ----- Test of the hypotheses Model 1 in Table 2 concerns the model with estimates of the effect of the control variables only. The first column depicts the coefficients, while the second column displays the size of the so-called multiplier, or the hazard ratio of the variable’s effect. The size of coefficients in an event history model cannot be interpreted directly, since it is a multiplicative rather than an additive model, but they can be transformed into the multiplier (which is simply e β). The multiplier shows the influence that one (additional) unit of the variable has on the probability of a manager’s exit. For instance, the model shows that CEO’s have a lower probability of exit; hence the negative coefficient in first column of model 1. The multiplier in the second column shows that the probability that a CEO will exit at a certain point in time is 69% of the probability that a regular member will leave the top team. Furthermore, the model indicates that Dutch top managers are more likely to leave in times of high profitability, rather than when return on assets is low. Previous research has shown managers to leave both in times of poor performance and in times of high performance, supposedly due to favorable labor market effects (Salancik and Pfeffer, 1980; Wagner, Pfeffer, and O'Reilly, 1984). Adding a square term to our variable to capture non-linear effects did not alter the results; the estimate was wholly insignificant. Hence, the probability of turnover of Dutch top managers seems to be influenced by 19 high performance, rather than low performance. The estimates on the variable change in profitability, however, show that managers are more likely to leave when performance in declining. Taken together, these results indicate that Dutch top managers are most likely to leave their company when its performance trend is just ‘over the hill’. Hypothesis 1 predicted that internal reorganizations decrease the probability that top managers will exit. The results in model 2 show that the effect of reorganizations is indeed negative and significant. The size of the multiplier indicates that each reorganization decreases the probability that a manager will leave with 39%. Likewise for the effect of greenfield ventures; this variable too is negative and highly significant, which corroborates hypothesis 2. The size of the effect is comparable; each greenfield decreases the probability of managers’ exit with 41%. Note, however, that greenfield ventures are less rare than internal reorganizations; an average of .53 per year, versus an average of .14. Therefore, in total the influence of greenfields on managers seems more prominent. Together, these results support the notion that activities of organizational cultivation increase managers’ commitment to their organization. Hypothesis 3 and 4 addressed the influence of compilation activities; buying and selling businesses. The coefficient on desinvestments is indeed positive and highly significant. In fact, a desinvestment of a subsidiary during a top manager’s tenure increases the chance that he or she will leave the firm with 27%. Take-overs also significantly increase the probability of top management exit; each acquisition increases the chance of a manager’s departure with 9%. Together, the estimates corroborate the idea that deal-making, or compilation activities, increases the likelihood that managers will subsequently leave their position. On average, desinvestments take place about once a year (i.e. .99), while the average number of 20 acquisitions that the managers in our database experienced was 1.7. Hence, the effect of divestments on the probability of managers terminating their tenure is the strongest influence in our model, taking into account how often the different events take place. We also estimated models with interactions between our four predictors and the control variables indicating performance, return on assets and change in return on assets. One could suspect that the relationship between managerial actions (i.e. reorganizations, divestments, etc.) is moderated by performance; for instance, reorganizations might only lead to sustained management tenure if they result in improved performance, or acquisitions lead to higher turnover if they do not work out, i.e. if firm performance suffers as a result, etc. None of these interactions, however, were significant. Apparently, in support of our theory regarding the effect of the predictors on managerial commitment, the results displayed in Table 1 are not conditional on their influence on firm performance. DISCUSSION The findings in this study help to further complete the picture of the relationship between top managers and their firms. Over the last decade, a stream of research has emerged that has shown, in various ways, how managers shape firms; the strategic development of organizations is influenced by the particular individual characteristics and preferences of their top managers. Our study adds a new perspective to this literature: how firms shape managers. Our longitudinal study shows that the particular strategic developments firms are undergoing have repercussions for the top managers at the helm of these organizations. In particular, 21 we examined the effect on managers’ organizational commitment, or their inclination to remain at, or leave a firm. We argued that development targeted at the internal development of organizations, such as reorganizations and greenfield ventures – something we labeled cultivation activities – lead to increased managerial commitment, and thus lengthen management tenure. Firm development building on largely external activities, such as buying and selling businesses – which we labeled compilation – was thought to decrease commitment and therefore shorten management tenure. These views were strongly corroborated through our event history analysis on the probability of individual managers’ turnover. Alternative explanations and study limitations An alternative explanation for our study’s findings would be that the managers in our sample did not change due to the particular experiences that they go through with their firms but that the managers who are committed to their organizations have a preference for cultivation and the managers who are less committed to begin with emphasize organizational compilation. That is, for example, the people who do a lot of acquisitions were prone to leave early anyway. Although we think this scenario is relatively unlikely anyway, since we examined top managers in general, rather CEO’s alone, and hence the strategic development of these firms is not influenced by these individual managers only, plus we know that firms go through certain periods of growth and decline independent of managers’ preferences (Greiner, 1972; Vermeulen and Barkema, 2001), we performed a series of analyses to restrict this possibility. Firstly, we ran a number of OLS regression analyses whether firms indeed emphasize either cultivation or compilation activities. Hence, we for instance defined number of reorganizations as the dependent variable and regressed it on greenfields, 22 divestments, and acquisitions, controlling for, among others, firm size and firm specific effects (using firm dummies). Likewise, for the other three predictors, which we set as dependent variables. If the above alternative explanation were to hold true, we should see a negative partial correlation between cultivation activities and compilation activities. As already suggested by the correlation matrix (Table 1) this was not the case; firms and their managers do not do one or the other thing. Cultivation and compilation activities often take place at the same time. A management team may be performing both types of activities concurrently, it is just that one increases commitment while the other one has negative influence on commitment. A direct test of the above alternative explanation would be to control for manager-specific effects in our models, for instance adding 436 (= n-1) manager dummies or, the equivalent, running fixed-effects models on our database. Unfortunately, fixed effects are not possible in log-linear analysis such as event history analysis or logit models. However, to explore within group estimates, we ran fixed-effects, linear probability models (Amemiya, 1981) on our panel data with as a dependent variable a dummy whether or not a manager left in a certain year. In effect, these models only compare the observed manager with him or herself; for example, they model whether the probability of an average manager’s exit increases due to an acquisition, beyond his or her specific probability of exit before the acquisition. Note that these linear probability models will create unbiased estimates of the coefficients but will produce biased standard deviations, hence the reported significance levels should be interpreted with care. We first ran the models displayed in Table 2 using linear probability estimates, without the fixed effects condition, which led to highly identical results as the ones displayed. Adding the fixed effects produced 23 the same results for all predictors but the coefficient on reorganizations, which was insignificant. The statistical significance for the other three variables was at least p<.001. Again, this is likely to be a very conservative test of our hypotheses and the results should therefore be interpreted with care, but it does lead to further support that at least our findings on the influence of greenfield ventures, divestments, and acquisitions are not due to unobserved manager specific influences, in conformity with our theory. Thus, it leads to further confidence that our models indicate that firm experiences are changing managers, rather than that different managers experience different things. Conclusion Previous research has shown that managers shape firms. Different managers do different things (Chaganti and Sambharya, 1987; Hambrick and Mason, 1984). But part of these preferences are shaped by the experiences that they have gone through. Some of these experiences are formed by the actions that they have undertaken at the helm of their companies. Our study emphasizes how their experiences shape the commitment that they feel towards their organizations. Managers that employ many external activities such as acquiring and selling businesses were found to leave their firms more quickly than managers who invest a lot of time cultivating the internal organization of their firms through reorganizations and setting up and fostering internal ventures. A conclusion of these findings is that the life cycle of top executives is not fixed (Miller and Shamsie, 2001), but dependent on what they do during this cycle. In that sense, we do not reject the view that managers shape their firms, but argue that this is a reciprocal relationship; different managers do different things, brought about by 24 different institutional circumstances, different periods in time, different development stages, or because they find themselves in a different phase during their career and tenure. Thus, managers emphasize different actions during their tenure (Miller and Shamsie, 2001), but how long this tenure prolongs is in turn affected by these actions. Previous research has emphasized that organizational change is provoked by management turnover (Furtado and Karan,1990; Weisbach, 1995). Our study shows that this turnover is not exogenous, but that there is a dynamic interplay between firms and the people that govern them. 25 Table 2. Event history analysis on the probability of manager exit Model 1 Model 2 Variable coefficients multiplier coefficients multiplier Control variables Ceo Technical background Legal background Return on assets Change in ROA -.374** -.029 .146 2.49*** -1.96*** .69 .97 1.2 12.2 .14 Predictors Internal reorganizations Greenfield ventures Desinvestments Acquisitions Log likelihood *** p<.001, ** p<.01, * p<.05 -1583 -.359** .018 .094 2.11** -1.98*** .69 1.02 1.10 8.24 .14 -.502* -.534*** .239*** .090*** .61 .59 1.27 1.09 -1503 26 Table 1. Summary statistics and correlation matrix Variable Mean SD Min Max 1 1. chairman 0.23 0.42 0.00 1.00 1.00 2. technical 0.20 0.40 0.00 1.00 0.06 3. legal 0.12 0.32 0.00 1.00 0.01 4. roa 0.54 0.71 -0.32 1.10 -0.01 5. change in roa 0.00 0.07 -1.05 1.00 -0.00 6. reorganizations 0.14 0.24 0.00 1.00 -0.01 7. greenfiels 0.53 0.76 0.00 5.67 -0.03 8. desinvestment 0.99 0.96 0.00 4.67 -0.00 9. acquisitions 1.70 1.68 0.00 9.67 -0.02 * correlations exceeding .035 are significant at the .05 level 2 3 4 5 1.00 -0.18 -0.04 0.00 0.04 -0.06 -0.06 -0.08 1.00 0.01 0.01 0.03 -0.06 -0.01 0.04 1.00 0.56 0.10 -0.14 -0.14 0.15 1.00 0.06 -0.03 -0.06 -0.03 6 1.00 -0.01 0.07 0.02 7 1.00 0.31 0.13 8 1.00 0.17 9 1.00 Figure 1a: Estimated cumulative baseline hazard 7 6 hazard 5 4 3 2 1 0 0 10 20 30 years Figure 1b: Estimated baseline survival function proportion surviving 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 10 20 years 30 References Allen, NJ. And Meyer, JP. 1990. The measurement and antecedents of affective, continuance, and normative commitment ot the organization. Journal of occupational psychology: 63: 1-18. Allen, NJ. And Meyer, JP. 1996. Affective, continuance, and normative commitment ot the organization: An examination of construct validity. Journal of vocational behavior. 49: 252-276. Allison, P.D. 1984. Event history analysis: Regression for longitudinal data. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Amemiya, T. 1981. Qualitative response models: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 19: 1483-1536. Ancona, Deborah G., Okhuysen, Gerardo A. and Perlow, Leslie A. 2001. Taking time to integrate temporal research. Academy of Management Review, 26: 512-529. Bantel, K.A. and S.E. Jackson. 1989. Top management and innovations in banking: Does the composition of the team make a difference? Strategic Management Journal, 10(special issue): 107-124. Barker, VL and Mueller, GC. 2002. CEO characteristics and firm R&D spending. Management Science, 6: 782-801. Boeker W. 1997a. Strategic change: The influence of managerial characteristics and organizational growth. Academy of Management Journal, 40: 152-170. Boeker W. 1997b. Executive Migration and strategic change: the effect of top manager movement on product-market entry. Administrative Science Quarterly 42: 213-236. Chaganti, R. and R. Sambharya. 1987. Strategic orientation and characteristics of upper management. Strategic Management Journal, 8: 393-401. Daily, CM, Trevis Certo, S, and Dalton, DR. 2000. International experiences in the executive suite: The path to prosperity? Strategic Management Journal, 21: 515-523. Dickter, David N., Roznowski, Mary, and Harrison, David A. 1996. Temporal tempering: An event history analysis of the process of voluntary turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology. 81: 705-716. Finkelstein, S. and D.C. Hambrick. 1990. Top-management-team tenure and organizational outcomes: The moderating role of managerial discretion. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 484-503. Furtado E, and Karan V. 1990. Causes consequences, and shareholder wealth effects of management turnover: A review of the empirical evidence, Financial Management 19: 60-75. 29 Gargiulo M. 1993. Two-step leverage: Managing constraint in organizational politics. Administrative Science Quarterly 38: 1Granovetter, Mark S. 1974. Getting a job. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. Greiner, Larry E. 1972. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, July-August: 37-46. Hackett RD, Bycio P, Hausdorf PA. 1994. Further assessments of Meyer and Allen’s (1991) three-component model of organizational commitment. Journal of Applied Psychology 1: 15-23. Hambrick DC, and Fukutomi GDS. 1991. The seasons of a CEO's tenure. Academy of Management Review, 16: 719-742. Hambrick, D.C. and P.A. Mason. 1984. Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its top managers. Academy of Management Review, 9: 193-206. Hambrick, DC, D.A. Nadler, and M.L. Tushman, How CEOs, Top Teams, and Boards Steer Transformation, Harvard Business School Press, 1998. Hannan, M.T. & Freeman, J. 1977. The population ecology of organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929-964. Herscovitch, Lynne, and John P. Meyer. 2002. Commitment to organizational change: Extension of a three-component model. Journal of Applied Psychology, 87: 474-487. Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE, and Ireland RD. 1990. Mergers and acquisitions and managerial commitment to innovation in M-form firms. Strategic Management Journal 11: 29-47 Hitt MA, Hoskisson RE, Ireland RD, and Harrison JS. 1991. Effects of acquisitions on R&D inputs and outputs. Academy of Management Journal 34: 693-706. Ibarra H. 1993. Network centrality, power, and innovation involvement: Determinants of technical and administrative roles. Academy of Management Journal 36: 471-502 Ingram, Paul, and Joel A.C. Baum. 1997. Chain affiliation and the failure of Manhattan hotels, 1896-1980. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 68-102. Jensen, M.C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review, 76: 323-329. Johnson, Richard, A. 1996. Antecedents and outcomes of corporate refocusing. Journal of Management, 22(3): 439-483. Kets de Vries MFR, Miller D. 1984. The neurotic organization: Diagnosing and changing counterproductive styles and management. San Fransisco: Jossey-Bass. 30 Kiefer, N.M. 1988. Economic duration data and hazard functions. Journal of Economic Literature, 26: 646-679. Kotter JP. 1995. Leading change: Why transformation efforts fail. Harvard Business Review 73(2): 59-67 Lewin AY and Stephens CU. 1994. CEO attitudes as determinants of organization design: An integrated model. Organization Studies 15: 183-212. Lin, Nan, and Mary Dumin. 1986. Access to occupations through social ties. Social Networks. 8: 365-385. Markides, C.C. 1992. Consequences of corporate refocusing: Ex-ante evidence. Academy of Management Journal, 35: 398-412. Mathieu, JE, and Zajac, DM. 1990. A review and meta-analysis of the antecedents, correlates, and consequences of organizational commitment. Psychological Bulletin. 108: 171-194. McFarlane Shore, Lynn, and Sandy J. Wayne. 1993. Commitment and employee behavior: Comparison of affective commitment and continuance commitment with perceived organizational support. Journal of Applied Psychology, 78: 774-780. McGrath, JE. 1988. The social psychology of time. Newbury Park, CA: Sage. Meyer JP, Allen NJ. 1984. Testing the “side-bet theory” of organizational commitment: Some methodological considerations. Journal of Applied Psychology. 69: 372-378. Meyer JP, Allen NJ. 1991. A three-component conceptualization of organizational commitment. Human Resource Management Review 1: 61-89. Miller D. 1993. Some organizational consequences of CEO succession. Academy of Management Journal 36: 644-659. Miller, Danny, Cornelia Droge. 1986. Psychological and traditional determinants of structure. Administrative Science Quarterly, 31: 539-560. Miller, D., and P.H. Friesen. 1980. Momentum and revolution in organizational adaptation. Academy of Management Journal, 23: 591-614. Miller, D., & Shamsie, J. 2001. Learning across the life cycle: Experimentation and performance among Hollywood studio heads. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 725-746. Montgomery, James D. 1992. Job search and network composition: Implications of the strength-of-weak-ties hypothesis. American Sociological Review 57: 586-596. Nahavandi A, and Malekzadeh AR. 1993. Leader style in strategy and organizational performance: An integrative framework. Journal of Management Studies, 30: 405-425. 31 Noda, Tomo, and Collis, David J. 2001. The evolution of intraindustry firm heterogeneity: Insights from a process study. Academy of Management Journal, 44: 897- 925. Norburn, D. and S. Birley. 1988. The top management team and corporate performance. Strategic Management Journal, 9: 225-237. Quinn, Robert E., & Kim Cameron. 1983. Organizational life cycles and shifting criteria for effectiveness: Some preliminary evidence. Management Science, 29: 33-51. Rodgers R, Hunter JE, Rogers DL. 1993. Influence of top management commitment on management program success. Journal of Applied Psychology 78: 151-155. Ross J, Staw BM. 1986. An escalation prototype. Administrative Science Quarterly 31: 274-297. Salancik, Jeffrey, & Gerald R. Pfeffer. 1980. Effects of ownership and performance on executive tenure in U.S. corporations. Academy of Management Journal, 23: 653-664. Schein EH. 1985. Organizational culture and leadership. San Fransisco: Jossey-Bass. Sutcliffe, K.M. 1994. What executives notice: Accurate perceptions in top management teams. Academy of Management Journal, 37(5): 1360-1378. Thomas, A.B. 1988. Does leadership make a difference to organizational performance? Administrative Science Quarterly, 33: 388-400. Tsai, Wenpin, and Sumantra Ghoshal. 1998. Social capital and value creation: The role of intrafirm networks. Academy of Management Journal, 41: 464-478. Tushman ML, Romanelli E. 1985. Organizational evolution: A metamorphosis model of convergence and reorientation. In L.L. Cummings & B.M. Staw (Eds.), Research in organizational behavior, vol. 7: 171-222. Greenwich, CT: JAI Tyler, BB, and Steensma, HK. 1998. The effects of executives’ experiences and perception on their assesment of potential technological alliances. Strategic Management Journal. 19: 909-1006. Vermeulen, Freek, and Harry Barkema. 2001. Learning through acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal: 44: 457-476. Vermunt JK. 1996. Log-linear event history analysis: A general approach with missing data, latent variables, and unobserved heterogeneity. Tilburg University Press, the Netherlands. Wagner, W.G., J. Pfeffer en C.A. O'Reilly. 1984. Organizational demography and turnover in top management groups. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29: 74-92. 32 Wegener, Bernd. 1991. Job mobility and social ties: Social resources, prior job, and status attainment. American Sociological Review, 56: 60-71. Weisbach MS. 1995. CEO turnover and the firm's investment decisions, Journal of Financial Economics 37: 159-188. Wetlaufer S. 1999. Driving Change. Harvard Business Review 77(2): 76-88. Whyte G. 1986. Escalating commitment to a course of action: A reinterpretation. Academy of Management Review, 11: 311-321. Wiersema, M.F. en K.A. Bantel. 1992. Top management team demography and corporate strategic change. Academy of Management Journal, 35(1): 91-121. Young, GJ, Charns, MP, and Shortell, SM. 2001. Top manager and network effects on the adoption of innovative management practices: A study of TQM in a public hospital system. Strategic Management Journal, 22: 935-952. Zaheer, Srilata, Albert, Stuart, and Zaheer, Akbar. 1999. Time scales and organizational theory. Academy of Management Review, 24: 725-741. 33