Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Chapter 14 Rent, Interest, and Profit QUESTIONS 1. How does the economist’s use of the term “rent” differ from everyday usage? Explain: “Though rent need not be paid by society to make land available, rental payments are very useful in guiding land into the most productive uses.” LO1 Answer: In everyday usage, “rent” is the term used to describe the payment that must be paid for the legal borrowing of some good or service. One pays rent for the use of a house or apartment; or one rents a tool from the equipment rental company. When paying this rent one is paying for part of the capital cost of the commodity, plus its maintenance, plus a share of the taxes on it, plus profit to the owner. An economist defines rent much more restrictively: Economic rent is the price paid for the use of land and other natural resources which are completely fixed in total supply. Land is completely fixed in total supply. No matter how high the rent, no more can be brought into use. Thus rent serves no incentive function; the same amount of land will be available no matter how high the rent. But the resulting argument that rent is a surplus that could be eliminated without reducing the supply is to look at it from the viewpoint of society only. 2. Explain why economic rent is a surplus payment when viewed by the economy as a whole but a cost of production from the standpoint of individual firms and industries. Explain: “Land rent performs no ‘incentive function’ for the overall economy.” LO1 Answer: Land is completely fixed in total supply. As population expands and the demand for land increases, rent first appears and then grows. From society’s perspective this rent is a surplus payment unnecessary for ensuring that the land is available to the economy as a whole. If rent declined or disappeared, the same amount of land would be available. If it increased, no more land would be forthcoming. Thus, rent does not function as an incentive for adding land to the economy. But land does have alternative uses. To get it to its most productive use, individuals and firms compete and the winners are those who pay the highest rent. To the high bidders, rent is a cost of production that must be covered by the revenue gained through the sale of the commodities produced on that land. 3. In the 1980s land prices in Japan surged upward in a “speculative bubble.” Land prices then fell for 11 straight years between 1990 and 2001. What can we safely assume happened to land rent in Japan over those 11 years? Use graphical analysis to illustrate your answer. LO1 Answer: Given that the supply of land is perfectly inelastic, the drop in prices must have resulted from decreased demand for land. The demand for land would fall if there were less of a return on the land (i.e. rent), so we can safely assume that land rent fell in Japan between 1990 and 2001. The shifts from D1 to D2 to D3 in Figure 14.1 demonstrate graphically what happened in Japan. 14-1 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit 4. How does Henry George’s proposal for a single tax on land relate to the elasticity of the supply of land? Why are there so few remaining advocates of George’s proposal? LO3 Answer: The supply of land is perfectly inelastic. Therefore, taxing returns on land (thus changing its price) will not affect how much is available. Taxing other inputs would discourage their use, so George reasoned that the government could earn sufficient revenue without diminishing the productive potential of the economy by taxing land only. There are a number of reasons why few support George’s proposal today. They include: 1) Taxing land only would not provide sufficient revenue for the government; 2) It is difficult to separate the rent from other resource payments for many income payments; 3) There are many forms of unearned income, such as those inheriting large sums and living off the interest; and 4) It would unfairly burden current land owners who paid the increased land values to former owners. 5. If money is not an economic resource, why is interest paid and received for its use? What considerations account for the fact that interest rates differ greatly on various types of loans? Use those considerations to explain the relative sizes of the interest rates on the following: LO2 a. A 10‐year $1000 government bond. b. A $20 pawnshop loan. c. A 30‐year mortgage loan on a $175,000 house. d. A 24‐month $12,000 commercial bank loan to finance the purchase of an automobile. e. A 60‐day $100 loan from a personal finance company. Answer: Though money is not in itself productive, it is useful for acquiring resources that are productive. In borrowing money, businesses get the use of it to buy factories, machines, and equipment that are productive and with which the businesses hope to make a profit. Thus, it makes economic sense to pay for the use of money. It would make no economic sense to lend money without charging interest, for the lender has the alternative of buying productive real capital or consumer goods with it. There are many considerations involved in the fact that interest rates differ greatly on various types of loans. (1) Risk: The greater the chance the borrower will not repay, the higher the interest rate. (2) Maturity: The longer the term of the loan, the higher the interest rate to compensate the lender for the risk of being without the use of the money for an extended period of time. (3) Loan size: The smaller the loan, the higher the interest rate because the administrative costs of large and small loans are about the same absolute amounts. (4) Taxability: The interest payments on certain state and municipal bonds being nontaxable, the interest that lenders require as payment is lower. (a) A 10-year $1000 government bond will have a relatively low rate of interest because it is risk-free: The Federal government cannot default (since its promise to repay is in currency that the government can have printed). However, the term to maturity normally would lead to a higher interest rate than a shorter-term government bond. The loan size is irrelevant here because the government pays the same interest regardless of the bond’s denomination. 14-2 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit (b) A $20 pawnshop loan will have a high rate of interest. There’s good chance the good pawned will not be redeemed but, in this case, the pawnbroker is not really at risk. The pawned article undoubtedly has a resale value greater than $20. The high interest rate in fact helps ensure that the good will not be redeemed—to the pawnbroker’s benefit. The high interest rate also compensates for the small size of the loan. (c) Mortgages are generally large loans at a relatively low interest rate. The loan is for a very long term and the house is pledged as collateral. Under certain circumstances, the loan may qualify for a government-subsidized mortgage insurance program, which insures the lender against default. Additionally, the borrower may deduct the interest from his/her taxable income. These contrasting considerations result in a lower interest rate than most types of long-term loans. (d) A 24-month $12,000 commercial bank loan to finance the purchase of an automobile will certainly have a higher interest rate than a government bond, but its risk is reduced by the fact that the automobile serves as collateral for the loan. However, the bank would rather get its money back than a used car, so the bank certainly does not consider the loan risk-free. The loan is of a relatively large size; this will tend to lower the interest rate. The outcome of these conflicting considerations is an interest rate lower than for a straight, unsecured, consumer loan but higher than for a loan to a well-established business. (e) A 60-day $100 loan from a personal finance company will have the highest rate of all, except possibly for the pawnshop loan. Though it is very short term, it is considered relatively high risk, because otherwise the borrower would have gotten the loan from a bank; and the loan size is very small, making the administrative costs high in relation to the loan size. Also, the fact that it is a personal loan implies there is no collateral like a car or home to back it up. 6. Why is the supply of loanable funds upsloping? Why is the demand for loanable funds downsloping? Explain the equilibrium interest rate. List some factors that might cause it to change. LO2 Answer: (a) The supply of loanable funds is upsloping because savers will make more funds available at higher interest rates than lower interest. (b) The demand for loanable funds is downsloping because there are few investment and R&D projects that yield a high rate of return and many more that will yield a lower rate of return. 14-3 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit (c) The equilibrium interest rate is determined where the interest rate (cost of borrowing the funds) is equal to the expected rate of return (the expected benefit from borrowing the funds and engaging in the investment or R&D project). The supply of loanable funds may change because of a change in households’ attitudes about saving (tax policies, macroeconomic conditions) or changes in Federal Reserve policies relative to the money supply. The demand for loanable funds could change as a result a change in technology or a change in the demand for the final product. If there is either a change in supply of or demand for loanable funds, the interest rate will change. 7. Here is the deal: You can pay your college tuition at the beginning of the academic year or the same amount at the end of the academic year. You either already have the money in an interest‐bearing account or will have to borrow it. Deal, or no deal? Explain your financial reasoning. Relate your answer to the time-value of money, present value, and future value. LO4 Answer: The answer is you pay at the end of the academic year in both cases. For demonstrative purposes consider the following values: Tuition is $10,000 and the interest rate over the academic year is 10% (not an annual rate). If you already have the $10000 and you put it in an interest bearing account you will have $11000 (=1.10*$10000) at the end of the academic year. You pay the $10000 in tuition and pocket $1000. If you paid at the $10000 tuition at the beginning of the year you would lose this $1000 (The future value of the $10000 is $11000). On the other hand, if you had to borrow the $10000 to pay your tuition you would still pay at the end of the academic year. Using the values as above, you borrow the $10000 today and put in an interest bearing account, which give you $11000 at the end of the academic year. You pay your tuition of $10000, which leaves you $1000 additional dollars. If you paid at the beginning of the academic year you would once again lose this $1000. This implies you could reduce your remaining debt burden to $9000 (assuming a government financed interest free student loan) by using the $1000 in interest to pay down the principal on the original loan. 8. What are the major economic functions of the interest rate? How might the fact that many businesses finance their investment activities internally affect the efficiency with which the interest rate performs its functions? LO3 Answer: There are two major economic functions of the interest rate. (1) Interest rates affect the level of domestic output as the monetary authorities deliberately vary them by changing the money supply. Low interest rates encourage investment, and this tends to expand the economy. High interest rates discourage investment and this tends to restrain inflation or contract the economy. (2) Interest rates allocate capital to its most productive uses. When interest rates are, say, at 10 percent, a project that expects to earn 8 percent after the payment of all costs will not be undertaken, because the cost of the borrowed money is greater than the return expected on it. This is true even if the firm is using its own money. Why make 8 percent on the project with the firm’s money when lending it will earn 10 percent? On the other hand, all projects that are expected to return more than the interest rate will be undertaken. The interest rate thus allocates money capital to those investments that are most productive, that is, which have the highest rate of return. 14-4 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit To the extent that firms truly are profit maximizers, the internal financing of investment should make no difference to the investment decision. One invests if the expected rate of return is greater than the rate of interest; one does not if the rate of interest is greater. However, firms are probably somewhat less anxious about what happens to money that they do not have to pay back. In other words, the efficiency with which the interest rate performs its functions is probably lessened the more firms finance their investments internally. 9. Distinguish between nominal and real interest rates. Which is more relevant in making investment and R&D decisions? If the nominal interest rate is 12 percent and the inflation rate is 8 percent, what is the real rate of interest? LO3 Answer: The nominal interest rate is the interest rate stated in dollars of current value (unadjusted for inflation). The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate adjusted for inflation (or deflation). The real interest rate is more relevant for making investment decisions—it reflects the true cost of borrowing money. It is compared to the expected return on the investment in the decision process. Real interest rate = 4 percent (= 12 percent - 8 percent). 10. Historically, usury laws that put below‐equilibrium ceilings on interest rates have been used by some states to make credit available to poor people who could not otherwise afford to borrow. Critics contend that poor people are those most likely to be hurt by such laws. Which view is correct? LO3 Answer: The critics are probably closer to the truth than the legislators. The relatively high interest rates charged in a free market to those with little or no collateral to put up as security on a loan is demanded by banks and other legitimate lending institutions because of the additional risk of nonrepayment involved. No doubt, banks are sometimes a little more hardhearted with the poor than is necessary to keep the banks viable; they may well charge a little more than the risks really require. However, when laws are passed preventing banks and other legitimate lending institutions from charging the rate they think is justified, these institutions simply stop lending to the poor entirely. So, the poor, who were supposed to be helped, end up going to loan sharks and others outside the law, who charge truly usurious interest rates running into the hundreds of percent a year and who demand an arm and a leg as security. Sometimes literally! 11. How do the concepts of accounting profit and economic profit differ? Why is economic profit smaller than accounting profit? What are the three basic sources of economic profit? Classify each of the following according to those sources: LO4 a. A firm’s profit from developing and patenting a new medication that greatly reduces cholesterol and thus diminishes the likelihood of heart disease and stroke. b. A restaurant’s profit that results from the completion of a new highway past its door. c. The profit received by a firm due to an unanticipated change in consumer tastes. 14-5 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Answer: Accounting profit is what remains of a firm’s total revenues after it has paid for all the factors of production employed by the firm (its explicit costs) but not for the use of the resources owned by the business itself. Economists also take into consideration implicit costs—the payment the owners could have received by using the resources they own in some other way. The economist adds these implicit costs to the accountant’s explicit costs to arrive at total cost. Subtracting the total cost from total revenue results in a smaller profit (the economic profit) than the accountant’s profit. Sources of economic profit: (1) creating popular new products; (2) reduce production costs below rivals' costs; and (3) create and maintain a profitable monopoly. (a) Profit from creating a popular new product, as well as monopoly profit from the patent. (b) Creating and maintaining a monopoly as a result of its locational advantage. (c) Profit from creating a popular 'new' product. Note here that the change in consumer preferences has made the good 'popular'. The term 'new' is relative, it may have been around for awhile but people just did not want to buy it in the quantities they now do. 12. Why is the distinction between insurable and uninsurable risks significant for the theory of profit? Carefully evaluate: “All economic profit can be traced to either uncertainty or the desire to avoid it.” What are the major functions of economic profit? LO4 Answer: An insurable risk does not fatally affect the profit and loss of a firm. The firm insures against fire and theft and so on and then goes about its business, secure in the knowledge that it cannot suffer an irreparable loss if one of the insured-against events occurs. Economic profit (and serious loss) occurs when the firm takes uninsurable risks. Such risks relate to uncontrollable and unpredictable changes in demand and supply conditions. An insurance company is most unlikely to insure against a serious recession occurring in the next year or so or against the price of oil skyrocketing—or, if one did, the premium the insurance company would demand would be greater than the profit a firm could expect to make by forecasting these events correctly. Thus, firms must risk that the demand for their products in the future will give them adequate revenue to cover their future costs that, too, they must take the risk of estimating. If the firms are successful, they have earned their economic profits. “All economic profits can be traced to either uncertainty or the desire to avoid it.” A considerable amount of economic profits can be traced to either uncertainty or the desire to avoid it, but not all. There is clearly uncertainty in trying to estimate future demand and supply conditions. A firm cannot be sure what it will get for its output, what the input will cost, and the consequent economic profit or loss. There is also much uncertainty with regard to innovation. Will it fly, literally, or figuratively in the sense of being able to convince people to buy the new or redesigned product? Or will all of the revenue needed to pay back the development costs be gained before freeloading copiers come on the market with their versions? However, though monopoly economic profits may be the product of the same types of uncertainty just discussed, they are by no means entirely so. It is De Beers’ tight control of the supply of diamonds that has ensured its continuing economic profits, not favorable changes in the public’s demand for diamonds. 14-6 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit The major functions of profits include providing an incentive for entrepreneurial initiative in combining resources to produce a good or service; for innovation in the form of new products or production processes; and for taking the risks which the entrepreneur bears by operating in a dynamic and uncertain environment. Profits also allocate resources among alternative lines of production. Entrepreneurs seek profits and shun losses, which means industries will expand as long as they experience economic profits and contract when they experience losses. 13. What is the combined rent, interest, and profit share of the income earned by Americans in a typical year if proprietors’ income is included within the labor (wage) share? LO5 Answer: If proprietors’ income is included within the labor share of income, wages would be almost 80 percent of national income. That leaves about 20 percent of the national income in the form of rent, interest and profit—a relatively small share and a share that has been remarkably stable in the United States since 1900. 14. LAST WORD Assume that you borrow $5000, and you pay back the $5000 plus $250 in interest at the end of the year. Assuming no inflation, what is the real interest rate? What would the interest rate be if the $250 of interest had been discounted at the time the loan was made? What would the interest rate be if you were required to repay the loan in 12 equal monthly installments? Answer: Simple interest in the first case is 5 percent. $250 / $5000 100 In the second case the amount received at the time of borrowing would be $4750, so the interest rate is slightly higher at 5.26%. $250 / $4750 100 If you repaid the loan in twelve monthly installments and the interest payments still were equal to $250, then you have repaid $5250 total, but you have repaid part of the principal each month. Therefore, you did not borrow the entire $5000 for the whole year. Without having the exact equation to solve this problem, you could estimate that you borrowed on average $2500 for the whole year, since you would have paid back about half by the sixth month and reduced the principal by about 1/12 for every month thereafter. This means that the $250 is about 10 percent of the average amount borrowed. PROBLEMS 1. Suppose that you own a 10‐acre plot of land that you would like to rent out to wheat farmers. For them, bringing in a harvest involves $30 per acre for seed, $80 per acre for fertilizer, and $70 per acre for equipment rentals and labor. With these inputs, the land will yield 40 bushels of wheat per acre. If the price at which wheat can be sold is $5 per bushel and if farmers want to earn a normal profit of $10 per acre, what is the most that any farmer would pay to rent your 10 acres? What if the price of wheat rose to $6 per bushel? LO1 14-7 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Answers: At a wheat price of $5 per acre, the revenue from the land would be $200 per acre (= 40 bushels per acre times $5 per bushel) or $2000 for all 10 acres. The cost including a normal profit would be $190 per acre (= $30 + $80 + $70 + $10) or $1,900 for all 10 acres. Thus the most anyone would pay to rent the land would be $10 per acre (= $200 per acre $190 per acre) or $100 for all 10 acres. At a wheat price of $6 per acre, the revenue from the land would be $240 per acre (= 40 bushels per acre times $6 per bushel) or $2400 for all 10 acres. Since the costs will remain unchanged at $190 per acre, the most anyone would pay to rent the land would be $50 per acre (= $240 per acre - $190 per acre) or $500 for all 10 acres. Feedback: Consider the following example. You own a 10‐acre plot of land that you would like to rent out to wheat farmers. For them, bringing in a harvest involves $30 per acre for seed, $80 per acre for fertilizer, and $70 per acre for equipment rentals and labor. With these inputs, the land will yield 40 bushels of wheat per acre. If the price at which wheat can be sold is $5 per bushel and if farmers want to earn a normal profit of $10 per acre, what is the most that any farmer would pay to rent your 10 acres? To answer this question we begin by calculating the revenue generated per acre. A bushel of wheat sells for $5 and each acre produces 40 bushels of wheat. Thus, revenue per acre equals $200 (=$5 x 40). Since there are 10 acres of land on the farm total revenue equals $2000 (=10 x $200). The total cost per acre equals $190 (=$30+$80+$70+$10), which is the sum of the seed cost, fertilizer cost, equipment rental, and normal profit respectively. Thus, the total cost for 10 acre farm is $1900 (=10 x $190). To find the most any farmer would pay to rent the 10 acre farm (land) we subtract the total cost from total revenue. This equals $100 (=$2000 (revenue) - $1900 (cost)). So, the most the farmer would be willing to pay to rent the land is $100 since anything more would result in a loss (negative economic profit). Finally, since there are 10 acres of land, the most the farmer would be willing to pay per acre in rent is $10 (=$100/100). If the price of wheat increased to $6 a bushel then total revenue per acre would equal $240 (=$6 x 40). Total revenue for the farm would equal $2400 (=10 x $240). The total cost remains the same, $1900. This implies $500 remains for potential land payment (=$2400-$1900), which is the most any farmer would be willing to pay to rent the land. Again, since there are 10 acres of land the most any farmer would pay per acre is $50 (=$500/10). 2. Suppose that the demand for loanable funds for car loans in the Milwaukee area is $10 million per month at an interest rate of 10 percent per year, $11 million at an interest rate of 9 percent per year, $12 million at an interest rate of 8 percent per year, and so on. If the supply of loanable funds is fixed at $15 million, what will be the equilibrium interest rate? If the government imposes a usury law and says that car loans cannot exceed 3 percent per year, how big will the monthly shortage (or excess demand) for car loans be? What if the usury limit is raised to 7 percent per year? LO2 14-8 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Answers: The equilibrium interest rate is 5 percent per year. Under the usury law’s 3 percent per year cap on interest, the excess demand will be $2 million dollars worth of car loans per month. When the usury law is changed to raise the maximum interest rate to 7 percent per year, it is no longer a binding constraint since the equilibrium interest rate is 5 percent per year; thus, there is $0 of excess demand at that usury limit. Feedback: Consider the following example. Suppose that the demand for loanable funds for car loans in the Milwaukee area is $10 million per month at an interest rate of 10 percent per year, $11 million at an interest rate of 9 percent per year, $12 million at an interest rate of 8 percent per year, and so on. Also assume the supply of loanable funds is fixed at $15 million. Interest rate on Loan 10% 9% 8% 7% 6% 5% 4% 3% 2% 1% Demand for Loanable Funds $10 million $11 million $12 million $13 million $14 million $15 million $16 million $17 million $18 million $19 million Supply of Loanable Funds $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million $15 million The table above demonstrates that the demand for loanable funds increases by $1 million for every 1% reduction in the interest rate. The equilibrium interest rate occurs where the demand for loanable funds equals the supply of loanable funds. This occurs at the interest rate of 5%. Now, if the government imposes a usury law and says that car loans cannot exceed 3 percent per year, how big will the monthly shortage (or excess demand) for car loans be? What if the usury limit is raised to 7 percent per year? Under a usury law’s 3 percent per year cap on interest, the excess demand will be $2 million dollars worth of car loans per month. When the usury law is changed to raise the maximum interest rate to 7 percent per year, it is no longer a binding constraint since the equilibrium interest rate is 5 percent per year; thus, there is $0 of excess demand at that usury limit. 3. To fund its wars against Napoleon, the British government sold consol bonds. They were referred to as “perpetuities” because they would pay £3 every year in perpetuity (forever). If a citizen could purchase a consol for £25, what would its annual interest rate be? What if the price were £50? £100? Bonds are known as “fixed income” securities because the future payments that they will make to investors are fixed by the bond agreement in advance. Do the interest rates of bonds and other investments that offer fixed future payments vary positively or inversely with their current prices? LO3 14-9 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Answers: 12 percent; 6 percent; 3 percent; inversely. Feedback: To calculate the price of a perpetuity we use the formula, price = (payment/interest rate), or to calculate the interest rate we use the formula, interest rate = (payment/price). Given the following payments (example): If a citizen could purchase a consol for £25, what would its annual interest rate be? What if the price were £50? £100? Assume a payment of £3 every year in perpetuity (forever). Consol for £25: interest rate = (£3/£25) = 0.12 (12%) consol for £50: interest rate = (£3/£50) = 0.06 (6%) consol for £100: interest rate = (£3/£100) = 0.03 (3%) The interest rates vary inversely with current prices (see formulas above). 4. Suppose that the interest rate is 4 percent. What is the future value of $100 four years from now? How much of the future value is total interest? By how much would total interest be greater at a 6 percent interest rate than at a 4 percent interest rate? LO3 Answers: $116.99; $16.99; $9.26 Feedback: Consider the following example. Assume that the interest rate is 4 percent. What is the future value of $100 four years from now? How much of the future value is total interest? By how much would total interest be greater at a 6 percent interest rate than at a 4 percent interest rate? To calculate the future value of $100 four years from we compound the interest for the four years. The future value for each successive year is: Year 1: $100 x (1.04) = $104 (carry this amount forward to year two) Year 2: $104 x (1.04) = $108.16 (carry this amount forward to year three) Year 3: $108.16 x (1.04) = $112.49 (carry this amount forward to year four) Year 4: $112.49 x (1.04) = $116.99 (future value in four years) Note that this answer could also be found via substitution back to Year 1, which gives us the formula: Future value = initial amount x (1+interest rate)T, where T is the number of years of compounding. For the values above we have Future value = $100 x (1.04)4 = $100 x 1.1699 = $116.99. To calculate the future value of total interest, subtract the principal (the initial amount) from total future value. This is $16.99 (=$116.99 - $100). 14-10 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit To find out how much greater total interest would be at a 6 percent interest rate than at a 4 percent interest rate, first find the future value at the 6% interest rate. Using the formula above, future value = $100 x (1.06)4 = $100 x 1.2635 = $126.25. Second, find the future value of total interest. This is $26.25 (=$126.25 - $100). Finally, subtract the total interest at the 4% rate from the total interest at the 6% rate. This equals $9.26 (= $26.25 - $16.99). 5. You are currently a worker earning $60,000 per year but are considering becoming an entrepreneur. You will not switch unless you earn an accounting profit that is on average at least as great as your current salary. You look into opening a small grocery store. Suppose that the store has annual costs of $150,000 for labor, $40,000 for rent, and $30,000 for equipment. There is a one‐half probability that revenues will be $200,000 and a one‐half probability that revenues will be $400,000. LO4 a. In the low‐revenue situation, what will your accounting profit or loss be? In the high‐revenue situation? b. On average, how much do you expect your revenue to be? Your accounting profit? Your economic profit? Will you quit your job and try your hand at being an entrepreneur? c. Suppose the government imposes a 25‐percent tax on accounting profits. This tax is only levied if a firm is earning positive accounting profits. What will your after-tax accounting profit be in the low‐revenue case? In the high‐revenue case? What will your average after‐tax accounting profit be? What about your average after‐tax economic profit? Will you now want to quit your job and try your hand at being an entrepreneur? d. Other things equal, does the imposition of the 25‐percent profit tax increase or decrease the supply of entrepreneurship in the economy? Answers: (a) Explicit costs are $220,000 (= $150,000 + $40,000 + $30,000). Thus accounting profits in the lower-revenue case are -$20,000 (= $200,000 - $220,000) while accounting profits in the higher-revenue case are $180,000 (= $300,000 - $220,000). (b) On average, revenues will be $300,000 per year (= 0.5*$400,000 + 0.5*$200,000). Thus, on average, accounting profits will be $80,000 per year (= $300,000 in average revenue $220,000 in explicit costs). This means that on average economic profits will be $20,000 per year (= $80,000 of average accounting profits - $60,000 opportunity costs of foregone wages). You WILL want to quit your job to become an entrepreneur. (c) In the low-revenue case, the after-tax accounting profit will be the same since the firm is making a loss of - $20,000 and the tax is only applied if the firm is making a profit. In the high-revenue case, the after-tax accounting profit will be $135,000 (= 0.75* $180,000). Given those numbers, the average after-tax accounting profit will be $57,500 (= 0.5*[$20,000] + 0.5*$135,000). The average after-tax economic profit will be - $2,500 (= $57,500 in average after-tax accounting profit - $60,000 in foregone wages). You will NOT want to quit your job and become an entrepreneur. (d) The profit tax decreases the supply of entrepreneurship in the economy. 14-11 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Feedback: Consider the following example: You are currently a worker earning $60,000 per year but are considering becoming an entrepreneur. You will not switch unless you can expect to earn a profit that is on average at least as great as your current salary. You look into opening a small grocery store. Suppose that the store has annual costs of $150,000 for labor, $40,000 for rent, and $30,000 for equipment. There is a one‐half probability that revenues will be $200,000 and a one‐half probability that revenues will be $400,000. Part a: The accounting profit in each scenario equals revenue minus explicit costs. The explicit costs in both cases (independent of state) equal $220,000 (= $150,000 (labor) + $40,000 (rent) + $30,000 (equipment)). Scenario 1 (low revenue case, Revenue equals $200,000): Here the accounting profit is $20,000 (= $200,000 - $220,000). Scenario 2 (high revenue case, Revenue equals $400,000): Here the accounting profit is $180,000 (= $400,000 - $220,000). Part b: The average revenue will be a weighted average of the two cases above, where the weights are the probabilities of each case. Here we assume that each case, or scenario, is equally likely (probability of 0.5 for each). Average revenue equals $300,000 (= 0.5x$200,000 + 0.5x$400,000). Average profit will equals $80,000 (= $300,000 (average revenue) - $220,000 (explicit cost)). Note that the explicit cost is the same in both scenarios. You will quit your job because the average profit of $80,000 exceeds your current income of $60,000. (NOTE, we ignore risk here.) Part c: If the government were to impose a 25% tax on all accounting profits this would only affect scenario 2. The government does not subsidize losses. Scenario 1 (low revenue case, Revenue equals $200,000): Here the accounting profit is $20,000 (= $200,000 - $220,000). 14-12 Chapter 14 - Rent, Interest, and Profit Scenario 2 (high revenue case, Revenue equals $400,000): Here the accounting profit is $180,000 (= $400,000 - $220,000). With the 25% tax the net revenue equals $135,000 (= 0.75x$180,000). This is the percentage of the accounting profit the firm receives after paying taxes. Here, we calculate the firm's average profit by taking a weighted average of the 'after-tax' profits for the two scenarios. average after-tax profits equal $57,500 (= 0.5x(-$20,000) + 0.5x$135,000). You will not quit your job because the average profit of $57,500 is less than your current income of $60,000. (NOTE, we ignore risk here.) Part d: Yes, the reduction in after-tax profits induces some individuals not to undertake investments or decisions that are pre-tax profitable. 14-13