MEASURING THE EFFECTS OF NON-TARIFF BARRIERS (NTBs) ON SERVICES TRADE IN ECOWAS COUNTRIES This study analyses the determinants of trade in services, measures the effects of non-tariff barriers on services trade for selected ECOWAS Countries and their main services trading partners, the focus was on total services trade between years 2001 to 2010. These were achieved using a gravity model approach, which relates the level of trade between countries to their physical and economic characteristics. Introducing a variable measuring the level of a country’s barriers to services trade into the gravity equation allows for a tariff equivalent of the barriers to be estimated, but the NTBs variable is statistically insignificant. Key words: Trade in Services, ECOWAS, Gravity model, Non Tariff Barriers (NTBs) JEL Classification: F1, L7, L8, L9 1 1 Introduction International trade in services has become more important in recent years as advances in technology have permitted new means of providing services across borders. While there is little doubt that services trade is an essential ingredient to economic growth and sustainable development, it is widely accepted that it can only make such positive contribution if appropriately liberalised and implemented across countries (Copeland and Mattoo, 2008). The performance of the services sector is vital for growth and poverty reduction in developing countries. Directly because services are already a large if not the largest part of their economy. Indirectly because services like finance, communication, and transport, as well as education and health, affect other sectors of the economy and the productive potential of the people. Today, in many countries around the world, inadequate access to services hurts people, not just in their role as consumers; it also perpetuates poverty by undermining the productivity of firms and farms as well as their ability to engage in trade. The growing role of services and their increasing importance to trade flows led to the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) in 1995. This agreement governs the rights and obligations of World Trade Organisation (WTO) member countries in the area of services trade. To facilitate the negotiations to liberalize services trade in the context of the round of multilateral negotiations agreed at Doha, Qatar, in November 2001, it is important to have measures of the various possible barriers to international trade in services. Unlike most developed countries where studies that use different methods of measuring the Barriers to trade in services are common, see for instance: Hoekman (1995), Brown and Stern (2001), Findlay and Warren (2000), Ec (2002), Grunfeld and Moxnes (2003), Lejour and de Paiva Verheijden (2004), Lennon (2006), Walsh (2006), Mcguire (2008) and among others. However, to our knowledge research into this area in developing countries especially Africa is not well documented in the literature, which necessitates this study. There are convincing reasons justifying the need for this study in Africa: (1) Most African countries are part of negotiations to liberalize services trade and this call for measures of the various possible barriers to international trade in services. (2) With the share of services in world trade increasing 1, it becomes important to be able to model services trade and measure the impact of changes in 1 See Escaith, 2008; Francois, Christen, Francois, and Hoekman, 2011; 2 restrictions on trade flow.(3) Our results can be used as a representative of other sub regions in Africa. 2 Trade in services: An overview 2.1 Defining services There exists no unique classification list of services. Different studies and organizations classify services differently. According to the International Monetary Fund (IMF), services include distributive services (e.g. transportation), producer services (e.g. banking and finance), social services (e.g. education) and personal services (e.g. catering) (Lehmann, et al, 2003). The WTO, on the other hand, classifies services on the basis of the UN Central Product Classification: business services; communication services; construction and related engineering services; distribution services; educational services; environmental services; financial services; health related and social services; tourism and travel related services; recreational, cultural and sporting services; transport services; and other services not included elsewhere (WTO, 2001). 2.2 Classification of Trade in Services The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), which provides the framework for the liberalization of international trade in services, classifies trade in services into 155 service types and four modes of supply: Mode one: cross-border supply This mode of delivery is the most similar to trade in goods in that the service is supplied from abroad. Examples of cross-border trade would include distance education. In this case, production takes place somewhere other than where the consumer is located. This also means that the factors of production do not have to move to meet the consumer. Mode two: consumption abroad The second mode of service provision is called consumption abroad. In this instance, consumers move to the service providers. This has important implications for the production of the service and the location of the factors of production. Examples of this mode of service provision include the education of students in countries other than their home country, or tourism. 3 Mode three: commercial presence The most important method of service provision is commercial presence. In this case, Foreign Service providers establish a local branch and supply to the local market from within the country’s borders. Once again this means that the factors of production come into contact with the consumers, which does not have to occur in the market for goods. Examples of commercial presence include banking, catering and accommodation, transport and insurance, amongst others. Mode four: movement of natural persons The last mode of service provision is related to the input of foreign workers, rather than the production itself. It is referred to as the movement of natural persons. In this mode the service is provided through workers moving between countries and using their skills in foreign countries. In this case, countries can usually only determine the level of such service imports through regulations restricting the entry of foreigners. 2.3 Brief descriptions of Trade flows between 1980 to 2010 Table 1a below shows that, the World Export of Goods and Services in 1980 was about 2373.43 Billion US Dollars, out of which about 395.66 Billion US Dollars was Services Exports, while 1977.77 Billion US Dollars accounted for World Goods Export. In year 2000 the World Export of Goods and Services increased to 7930.13 Billion US Dollars, Services Export was 1521.68 Billion US Dollars, while Goods export was 6408.45 Billion US Dollars. In year 2010 World Export of Goods and Services was 18946.76 Billion US Dollars, out of which 3834.99 Billion US Dollars was Services Export, while, Goods Export accounted for about 15111.77 Billion US Dollars. This shows there was relative increase in the Export of Goods and Services. The Export of Goods and Services from ECOWAS Countries in the year 1980 was about 35.76 Billion US Dollars, Services Export was about 17.22 Billion US Dollars, while Goods Export was about 18.54 Billion US Dollars. In the year 2000, ECOWAS Countries exported about 32.64 Billion US Dollars, worth of Goods and Services, about 15.02 Billion US Dollars services Export, while, Goods Export was about 17.62 Billion US Dollars. In the year 2008, there was a shift in the flow of ECOWAS Countries Goods and Services Export, as total Export increased to about 123.00 Billion US Dollars, ECOWAS Countries services Export was about 76.04 Billion US Dollars, while, ECOWAS Countries Goods Export was about 46.96 Billion US Dollars. Finally, in year 2010, ECOWAS Countries Goods and Services Export, increased to about 119.08 Billion US Dollars, out of which services Export was about 71.73 Billion US Dollars, while, 4 Goods Export was about 47.36 Billion US Dollars. The ECOWAS Countries Services Export later displaced the Goods Export. Table 1b shows that, 16.67% of the world Export was services Export, while, 83.33% of the world Export was Goods Export, in 1980. This later rise to 20.24% for world services Export and 79.76% for World Goods Export. The percentage share of ECOWAS Countries in the World Export of Goods and Services is about 1.51%, 0.41%, 0.57%, 0.62% and 0.63% in 1980, 2000, 2006, 2008 and 2010 respectively. The percentage share of ECOWAS Countries Goods Exports is Greater than Services Export in 1980 with 48.16% for Services, and 51.84% for Goods. But, the reverse was the case since year 2006 with 55.06% for Services Export, and 44.96% for Goods Export, which increased to 60.23% for Services Export and 39.77% for Goods Export in Year 2010; this could be as a result of Technological advancement that encourages Trade in services in recent times. 5 Table 1a: Exports of goods and services, (in Billions US Dollars) 1980-2010 YEAR 1980 1990 2000 2007 2008 2009 ECONOMY 2373.43 4274.14 7930.13 17368.45 19867.66 15889.98 World (Goods and Services Exports) 395.66 830.24 1521.68 3488.21 3914.74 3486.62 World Services Exports 1977.77 3443.90 6408.45 13880.25 15952.92 12403.36 World Goods Exports Developing economies 671.77 988.58 2438.84 6255.58 7367.57 5969.08 (Goods and Services Exports) Developing economies 73.39 150.39 351.00 896.71 1036.59 940.48 Services Exports Developing economies 598.39 838.19 2087.84 5358.87 6330.98 5028.59 goods Exports Transition economies 63.35 112.27 180.39 642.72 850.01 578.83 (Goods and Services Exports) Transition economies 9.81 16.69 24.26 90.37 113.28 94.62 Services Exports Transition economies 53.53 95.58 156.13 552.35 736.74 484.21 Goods Exports Developed economies 1638.31 3173.29 5310.90 10470.14 11650.08 9342.08 (Goods and Services Exports) Developed economies 312.46 663.16 1146.42 2501.12 2764.88 2451.52 Services Exports Developed economies 1325.85 2510.12 4164.48 7969.02 8885.20 6890.56 Goods Exports Developing economies: 136.35 127.43 183.07 531.21 663.22 481.11 Africa (Goods and Services Exports) Developing economies: 13.44 21.71 33.12 78.84 90.36 81.58 Africa Services Exports Developing economies: 122.92 105.72 149.95 452.36 572.86 399.53 Africa Goods Exports Sub-Saharan Africa 87.40 81.16 112.38 328.93 405.28 304.59 (Goods and Services Exports) Sub-Saharan Africa 8.55 11.43 16.43 38.87 42.32 38.86 Services Exports Sub-Saharan Africa 78.85 69.73 95.94 290.05 362.95 265.73 Goods Exports ECOWAS Countries 35.76 24.58 32.64 96.24 123.00 92.82 (Goods and Services Export) ECOWAS Countries 17.22 12.70 15.02 59.43 76.04 64.73 Services Export ECOWAS Countries 18.54 11.89 17.62 36.82 46.96 28.09 Goods Export Source: UNCTAD, UNCTAD stat, 2011 6 2010 18946.76 3834.99 15111.77 7568.24 1137.77 6430.48 732.79 103.09 629.70 10645.73 2594.13 8051.59 595.73 90.54 505.19 384.53 44.41 340.12 119.08 71.73 47.36 Table 1b: Exports of goods and services, (in Percentage) 1980-2010 Year 1980 1990 2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ Individual economies 16.67 19.42 19.19 19.81 19.51 20.08 19.70 21.94 20.24 World Services Exports (in %) 83.33 80.58 80.81 80.19 80.49 79.92 80.30 78.06 79.76 World Goods Exports (in %) Developing economies 28.30 23.13 30.75 34.58 35.71 36.02 37.08 37.57 39.94 (% of World Exports) Developing economies 10.92 15.21 14.39 14.07 13.79 14.33 14.07 15.76 15.03 Services Exports (in %) Developing economies 89.08 84.79 85.61 85.93 86.21 85.67 85.93 84.24 84.97 Goods Exports (in %) Transition economies 2.67 2.63 2.27 3.25 3.46 3.70 4.28 3.64 3.87 (% of World Exports) Transition economies 15.49 14.86 13.45 13.69 13.49 14.06 13.33 16.35 14.07 Services Exports (in %) Transition economies 84.51 85.14 86.55 86.31 86.51 85.94 86.67 83.65 85.93 Goods Exports (in %) Developed economies 69.03 74.24 66.97 62.18 60.84 60.28 58.64 58.79 56.19 (% of World Exports) Developed economies 19.07 20.90 21.59 23.33 23.21 23.89 23.73 26.24 24.37 Services Exports (in %) Developed economies 80.93 79.10 78.41 76.67 76.79 76.11 76.27 73.76 75.63 Goods Exports (in %) Developing economies: 5.74 2.98 2.31 2.95 2.99 3.06 3.34 3.03 3.14 Africa (% of World Exports) Developing economies: 9.86 17.04 18.09 15.61 15.00 14.84 13.62 16.96 15.20 Africa Services Exports (in %) Developing economies: 90.14 82.96 81.91 84.39 85.00 85.16 86.38 83.04 84.80 Africa Goods Exports (in %) Sub-Saharan Africa 3.68 1.90 1.42 1.85 1.85 1.89 2.04 1.92 2.03 (% of World Exports) Sub-Saharan Africa 9.79 14.08 14.63 12.45 12.17 11.82 10.44 12.76 11.55 Services Exports (in %) Sub-Saharan Africa 90.21 85.92 85.37 87.55 87.83 88.18 89.56 87.24 88.45 Goods Exports (in %) ECOWAS Countries 1.51 0.58 0.41 0.61 0.57 0.55 0.62 0.58 0.63 (% of world Export) ECOWAS Countries 48.16 51.65 46.02 38.17 55.04 61.75 61.82 69.74 60.23 services Exports(in %) ECOWAS Countries 51.84 48.35 53.98 61.83 44.96 38.25 38.18 30.26 39.77 Goods Exports(in %) Source: UNCTAD, UNCTAD stat, 2011 Table 2a below shows that, the World Import of Goods and Services in 1980 was about 2388.59 Billion US Dollars, out of which about 447.77 Billion US Dollars was Services Import, while 1940.82 Billion US Dollars accounted for World Goods Import. In year 2005 the World Import 7 of Goods and Services increased to 12780.62 Billion US Dollars, Services Import was 2467.44 Billion US Dollars, while Goods export was 10313.18 Billion US Dollars. In year 2010 World Import of Goods and Services was 18531.18 Billion US Dollars, out of which 3685.11 Billion US Dollars was Services Import, while, Goods Import accounted for about 14846.07 Billion US Dollars. This shows there was relative increase in the Import of Goods and Services. The Import of Goods and Services from ECOWAS Countries in the year 1980 was about 31.46 Billion US Dollars, Services Import was about 8.61 Billion US Dollars, while Goods Import was about 22.85 Billion US Dollars. In the year 2007, ECOWAS Countries Imported about 87.29 Billion US Dollars, worth of Goods and Services, about 29.71 Billion US Dollars services Export, while, Goods Import was about 57.58 Billion US Dollars. Finally, in year 2010, ECOWAS Countries Goods and Services Import, increased to about 119.42 Billion US Dollars, out of which services Import was about 35.86 Billion US Dollars, while, Goods Import was about 83.56 Billion US Dollars. Table 2b shows that, 18.75% of the world Import was services Import, while, 81.25% of the world Import was Goods Import, in 1980. This later rise to 19.89% for world services Import and 80.11% for World Goods Import, in the year 2010. The percentage share of ECOWAS Countries in the World Import of Goods and Services is about 1.32%, 0.33%, 0.47%, 0.59% and 0.64% in 1980, 2000, 2006, 2008 and 2010 respectively. The percentage share of ECOWAS Countries Services Import in 1980 was 27.37% for Services, and 72.63% for Goods. But, increased to 33.74% for services Import, and 66.26% for goods Import in the year 2007. Finally, in the year 2010, the percentage share of Services Import by ECOWAS Countries was 30.03%, while, Goods Export was 69.97%. 8 Table 2a: Imports of goods and services, (in Billions US Dollars) 1980-2010 YEAR 1980 1990 2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 ECONOMY World (Goods and Services Imports) 2388.59 4275.92 7933.48 12780.62 14618.47 16952.78 19539.96 15529.08 18531.18 447.77 877.74 1515.96 2467.44 2766.11 3287.40 3759.27 3366.54 3685.11 1940.82 3398.18 6417.52 10313.18 11852.37 13665.38 15780.69 12162.54 14846.07 617.70 951.42 2283.33 3978.79 4654.37 5530.17 6673.59 5566.33 7116.05 139.58 193.76 415.18 700.43 822.45 998.09 1186.86 1087.22 1298.74 478.12 757.66 1868.15 3278.36 3831.91 4532.08 5486.73 4479.12 5817.30 65.03 117.77 131.70 326.24 392.11 544.97 701.75 493.47 593.08 12.41 30.58 28.39 68.47 79.96 105.14 131.31 107.27 123.71 52.62 87.19 103.31 257.77 312.15 439.83 570.44 386.19 469.37 1705.86 3206.73 5518.45 8475.59 9571.99 10877.64 12164.62 9469.28 10822.05 295.78 653.40 1072.39 1698.55 1863.69 2184.17 2441.10 2172.05 2262.66 1410.08 2553.33 4446.06 6777.05 7708.30 8693.47 9723.52 7297.23 8559.40 124.75 122.51 164.66 330.23 380.50 480.83 610.09 524.71 606.06 29.41 30.31 41.27 77.12 94.00 118.82 152.43 135.57 151.27 95.34 92.19 123.40 253.11 286.49 362.01 457.66 389.14 454.79 81.64 75.53 103.18 220.21 255.99 318.02 394.63 336.32 400.29 20.03 21.53 27.39 53.44 68.15 86.82 109.32 95.02 107.74 61.61 54.00 75.79 166.77 187.84 231.20 285.31 241.30 292.55 31.46 19.44 26.24 62.43 69.40 87.29 114.75 94.28 119.42 8.61 6.35 7.51 15.03 23.41 29.71 38.02 32.37 35.86 22.85 13.09 18.73 47.40 45.99 57.58 76.73 61.91 83.56 World Services Imports World Goods Imports Developing economies (Goods and Services Imports) Developing economies Services Imports Developing economies Goods Imports Transition economies (Goods and Services Imports) Transition economies Services Imports Transition economies Goods Imports Developed economies (Goods and Services Imports) Developed economies Services Imports Developed economies Goods Imports Developing economies: Africa (Goods and Services Imports) Developing economies: Africa Services Imports Developing economies: Africa Goods Imports Sub-Saharan Africa (Goods and Services Imports) Sub-Saharan Africa Services imports Sub-Saharan Africa Goods imports ECOWAS Countries (Goods and Services Import) ECOWAS Countries Services Import ECOWAS Countries Goods Import Source: UNCTAD, UNCTAD stat, 2011 9 Table 2b: Imports of goods and services, (in Percentage) 1980-2010 MEASURE YEAR ECONOMY World Services Imports ( in %) World Goods Imports (in %) Developing economies (% of World Imports) Developing economies Services Imports (in %) Developing economies Goods Imports (in %) Transition economies (% of World Imports) Transition economies Services Imports (in %) Transition economies Goods imports (in %) Developed economies (% of World Imports) Developed economies Services Imports (in %) Developed economies Goods Imports (in %) Developing economies: Africa (% of World imports) Developing economies: Africa Services Imports (in %) Developing economies: Africa Goods Imports (in %) Sub-Saharan Africa (% of World Imports) Sub-Saharan Africa Services imports (in %) Sub-Saharan Africa Goods imports (in %) ECOWAS Countries (% of world Import) ECOWAS Countries services Imports(in %) ECOWAS Countries Goods Imports(in %) Source: UNCTAD, UNCTAD stat, 2011 US Dollars at current prices and current exchange rates in millions 1980 1990 2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 18.75 20.53 19.11 19.31 18.92 19.39 19.24 21.68 19.89 81.25 79.47 80.89 80.69 81.08 80.61 80.76 78.32 80.11 25.86 22.25 28.78 31.13 31.84 32.62 34.15 35.84 38.40 22.60 20.37 18.18 17.60 17.67 18.05 17.78 19.53 18.25 77.40 79.63 81.82 82.40 82.33 81.95 82.22 80.47 81.75 2.72 2.75 1.66 2.55 2.68 3.21 3.59 3.18 3.20 19.09 25.97 21.55 20.99 20.39 19.29 18.71 21.74 20.86 80.91 74.03 78.45 79.01 79.61 80.71 81.29 78.26 79.14 71.42 75.00 69.56 66.32 65.48 64.16 62.26 60.98 58.40 17.34 20.38 19.43 20.04 19.47 20.08 20.07 22.94 20.91 82.66 79.62 80.57 79.96 80.53 79.92 79.93 77.06 79.09 5.22 2.87 2.08 2.58 2.60 2.84 3.12 3.38 3.27 23.57 24.75 25.06 23.35 24.71 24.71 24.98 25.84 24.96 76.43 75.25 74.94 76.65 75.29 75.29 75.02 74.16 75.04 3.42 1.77 1.30 1.72 1.75 1.88 2.02 2.17 2.16 24.53 28.51 26.54 24.27 26.62 27.30 27.70 28.25 26.92 75.47 71.49 73.46 75.73 73.38 72.70 72.30 71.75 73.08 1.32 0.45 0.33 0.49 0.47 0.51 0.59 0.61 0.64 27.37 32.66 28.62 24.07 33.74 34.04 33.13 34.33 30.03 72.63 67.34 71.38 75.93 66.26 65.96 66.87 65.67 69.97 10 3 Review of relevant literature Prior to the formal recognition of services as an item of international exchange, several trade-growth theories had existed in the literature for goods trade, of which some have been tested for its applicability to services trade. The first relates to the theory of comparative advantage whereby, Ricardo (1817) developed the idea that both parties can benefit from trade if each party specializes in the good in which it relatively produces cheaply, thus creating static gains from trade which contributes to overall growth and welfare of the nations. Studies which have shown the applicability of the theory of comparative advantage to services trade include Hindley and Smith (1984) and Deardorff (1985). Secondly, the factor endowment theory by Ohlin (1933) stipulates that the main reason why countries trade is due to the differences in factor endowments or the supply of land, labour and capital in the various countries. This trade pattern encourages specialisation which in turn leads to welfare gains and economic growth analogous to that of the Ricardian model. Studies by Bhagwati (1984) and Melvin (1989) have shown that the factor endowment theory is compatible with services trade. The third trade-growth theory challenged the classical models through authors such as Myint 1958, 1969; Balough 1973; Smith and Toye 1979; Myrdal 1970; Riedel 1983; and Toye 1987. This led to the North-South (i.e. developed and developing countries) trade proposition that associate trade with uneven development. The North-South trade represents the trade relations between rich (North) and poor (South) countries and argues that there is unequal exchange between the North and the South due to historical forces, differences in factor endowments and income elasticities of demand of the North’s capital goods and the South’s consumption goods. Generally speaking, measures of barriers to trade in services parallel those that were previously developed to measure NTBs to merchandise trade, and thus can be classified into: frequency measures, quantity-based measures and price-based measures. The most widely used frequency measures are those developed by Hoekman (1995) using the GATS commitment schedules of member countries. Hoekman classifies these commitments into three categories, and assigns a numerical score to each category: 11 If no restrictions are applied for a given mode of supply in a given sector, a value of 1 is assigned. If no policies are bound for a given mode of supply in a given sector, a value of 0 is assigned. If restrictions are listed for a given mode of supply in a given sector, a value of 0.5 is assigned. Hoekman calls these scores the openness/binding factors. Since, there are 155 non-overlapping service sectors in the GATS classification list, and for each sector there are four possible modes of supply, a total of 620 such openness/binding factors exist for each member country. Using these factors, Hoekman calculates three sectoral coverage indicators (hereafter the "Hoekman indices"). The first is calculated as the number of commitments made by a country in its GATS schedules divided by the 620 maximum possible. The second, which Hoekman calls "average coverage," is equal to the sectors/modes listed as a share of maximum possible, weighted by the openness/binding factors. The third is also a frequency ratio. It is the share of "no restriction" commitments in either (a) a member's total commitments, or (b) relative to the 155 possible sectors. While the original purpose of these coverage indicators was to quantify GATS commitments, Hoekman argues that they provide information on the relative restrictiveness of policy regimes pertaining to service industries because the coverage in each country's schedule is an indicator of its policy stance--the higher the coverage, the more open the regime. There are two ways in which these coverage ratios can be used for this purpose. First, the restrictiveness of a country's policy in a sector can be measured by the ratio equalling (1- the Hoekman indices). For example, if a country has made commitments in 10 percent of the 620 possible sector/modes, then using the first Hoekman index it would get a restrictiveness score of .9, meaning that 90 percent of its sector/modes are closed. Alternatively, "tariff equivalents" can be constructed using a country's coverage ratio, as Hoekman (1995) has done. He does so by first constructing a list of benchmark guess estimates of what tariff equivalents of the most protectionist nation might be. Then the "tariff equivalent" of a given country is obtained by multiplying this guesstimate by (1 minus the Hoekman indices). Thus, if the most restrictive 12 country worldwide had restrictions equivalent to a 50 percent tariff, then a country with a 0.9 restrictiveness index as in the preceding example, would have a tariff equivalent of 45 percent (i.e. 0.9 times 50). A more elaborate set of frequency measures, called the trade restrictiveness indices, has been constructed by a team of researchers from Australia's Productivity Commission, the University of Adelaide, and the Australian National University for six service industries: telecommunications (Warren 2001), banking (McGuire and Schuele 2001), maritime transport (McGuire et al 2001), education (Kemp 2001), distribution (Kalirajan 2000) and professional services (Nguyen-Hong 2000). In addition, Hardin and Holmes (1997) have developed frequency indices to measure the size of barriers to FDI across service industries. Quantity-based measures of trade restrictiveness are typically derived using econometric models based on the standard models of trade determination: the Heckscher-Ohlin model where trade is motivated by comparative advantage; the Helpman-Krugman model where trade is motivated by product differentiation, and the gravity model, where an important part of trade is determined by the relative size and proximity of trading partners (in terms of both distance but also other factors such as language, culture, etc.). The sizes of NTBs are measured either by the residuals from the estimated regression (i.e. the difference between the level of actual trade and the level predicted by the model), or by using various dummy variables (Deardorff and Stern 1998, p. 24). Kimura, and Lee (2004) selected the data on trade in services and goods of 10 OECD member countries and 47 trading nations in the 1999-2000 to test the effect of standard gravity model. The conclusion was that it is complementary between goods export and services imports, and trade in services can be better forecasted by gravity equation. Walsh (2006) estimated gravity model for the total services trade of 1999-2001 in a sample of 27 OECD member countries and 55 non-OECD countries. The paper found that the Hausman-Taylor gravity model was most suitable and the gravity variables of economic size, a common language were significant factors in services trade, while the distance was not significant. Janer Ceglowski (2006) estimated a standard gravity equation for bilateral services trade in 28 countries; the results indicated that economic scale and geographic proximity were significant in services trade. The research 13 implied that efforts to enhance goods trade –bilateral or multilateral – should lead to more services trade as well. Price-based measures derive estimates of barriers to trade from differences in domestic and foreign prices ("price wedges"). If there are sufficient data on prices, then, following Deardorff and Stern (1998), such measures can be constructed directly by comparing the domestic price of the imported good (P) with a reference foreign price (P*).9 In this approach, the percentage difference between the domestic and foreign price is comparable to a tariff (T), provided the price differences are not due to factors such as sunk costs and entry deterrence strategies by incumbent firms, rather than government-imposed barriers (see Ross (1999) for a detailed discussion on various types of barriers to entry). Price wedges can also be quantified using econometric methods or derived from quantity-based measures with the help of elasticities of demand and supply. Most price-based measures for services have been obtained by the Australian team using econometric methods. These studies are Trewin (2001) for telecommunications, Kalirajan et al. (2001) for banking, Kang (2001) for maritime transport, Kalirajan (2000) for food distribution, and Nguyen-Hong (2000) for engineering services. All five studies use the following procedure: one, a proxy of the domestic price is identified for the industry in question; two, a model is constructed to identify a list of variables that affect the price, one of which is the barriers to trade measured by the trade restrictiveness indices developed by the Australian team; three, a regression model is specified and estimated; and four, the estimated coefficients and trade restrictiveness index are used to calculate the sizes of price wedges for individual economies. This last step is done only in three of the five studies, but it could have been done without difficulty in all studies. 14 4 Methodology 4.1 Model Specification and Estimation Techniques The concept of the gravity model is based on Newton’s Law of Universal Gravitation relating the force of attraction between two objects to their combined mass and the distance between them. The application of gravity to the social sciences was first proposed by James Stewart in the 1940s (Fitzsimons et al., 1999). Originally applied to international trade by Tinbergen (1962), the gravity model predicts bilateral trade flows between any two countries as a function of their size and the distance between them. As the empirical applications of the gravity model have grown, the theoretical foundations of the model have also been developed. Beginning with Anderson (1979), who showed that the gravity framework is consistent with a model of world trade in which products are differentiated by the country of origin (the Armington assumption), a series of papers have shown the gravity model framework to be consistent with a number of standard trade theories such as Heckscher-Ohlin and monopolistic competition2. The initial gravity model estimated in this paper is (1), in which all continuous variables are expressed in logarithms, as applied by Walsh, 2006. The dependent variable is imports of services from country into country at time . The data used covers imports between Five ECOWAS Countries3 and their major Services trading partners4 over a ten year period (2001-2010). The gravity model is estimated with total services as dependent variables. As explanatory variables, in the literature on gravity models, three variables are used as measures of the size of a country: Gross Domestic Product (GDP), GDP per capita and population. In order to avoid multicollinearity, the latter two are included in this paper. As countries tend to consume 2 See Anderson (1979), Bergstand (1985, 1989), Helpman and Krugman (1985) and Deardorff (1995). 3 Côte d'Ivoire, Ghana, Liberia, Nigeria, and Senegal 4 Belgium, Czeck Rep., Denmark, Italy, Luxemburg, Netherland, Poland, Sweden, Ukraine, and united Kindom. 15 more service commodities as they become richer, GDP per capita is of more relevant than GDP itself. The first two continuous variables are real GDP per capita of the exporting and importing countries at time t ( and respectively). The coefficients and are expected to be positive. A higher level of income in the importing country should indicate a higher level of demand for services (produced domestically or imported), whilst a higher income level in the exporting country should be positively related to that country’s ability to produce more services for export. Mirza and Nicoletti (2006) show that the supply of services to foreign markets is strongly linked to the availability of inputs in both domestic and foreign markets. The coefficients on and , the population in the importing and exporting countries at time t, may be expected to take either a negative or positive sign. As MartinezZarzosa and Nowak-Lehmann (2002) show, population size may have a negative effect on exports if countries export less as they become larger (as they rely more on internal trade) or a positive effect if they export more as they become larger as they are able to achieve economies of scale. Population size will have a similar effect on imports. Although distance between the importer and exporter ( ) is typically expected to have a negative impact on trade in goods, it is not clear from the review of the existing literature that this is necessarily the case for services. Service products do not have to be physically transported from location to location. Depending on the nature of the service, in some cases it will require movement of physical persons, but in others it may be communicated electronically. Consequently, the importance of distance in services trade may be low or even insignificant. The standard measure of distance, also employed in this paper, is to measure the distance between the countries’ capitals. The final regressor is dummy variable indicating whether the importing country and exporting share a common language ( level of trade. Finally, ). This is expected to be positively related to the are year dummies to control for any time trends in the data. Language has been found to be significant in gravity model assessments of goods trade flows and this effect could be expected to be particularly strong in services, as common language should greatly facilitate many transactions. There is evidence to suggest that a common language 16 variable may also capture other effects such as cultural or institutional similarities between countries. This should be borne in mind when interpreting the results of the model. A key objective of this paper is to estimate tariff equivalents of the barriers to services trade using the gravity framework. This is accomplished by adding a new variable ( ) that measures the total level of non-tariff barriers (NTBs) of the importing country j to the gravity equation. A higher level of protection in the importer should reduce the level of services trade between countries. The model estimated for total services imports becomes (2). The variable used in equation (2) is primarily based on a Service trade restrictiveness index produced by the World Bank (iresearch.worldbank.org). 4.2 Data Issues and Data Sources Data used for the empirical analyses were obtained from the following sources: (1) Services trade by partner, 2001-2010. Find data at: htpp://www.trademap.org. (2) GDP per capita, and Population: WDI (2011): World Bank. (3) Bilateral distances, Common (official) language: CEPII distance database (http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm). (4) Service trade restrictiveness index: World bank (htpp://www.iresearch,worlbank.org) 5 Result Interpretation Using panel data techniques captures the relationships between variables over the period of the sample and can control for the possibility that the unobserved effects may be correlated with the regressors5. The two most commonly employed panel models are the fixed effects model (FEM) and the random effects model (REM). In the FEM, the intercept terms are allowed to vary over the individual units (in this case the importing and exporting country pairs) but are held constant over time. REM assumes that the intercepts of individual units are randomly distributed and independent of the explanatory variables. A priori, the FEM would be expected to be a better fit in the gravity model context as the panel tracks pairs of countries over time and it is not realistic 5 See Baier and Bergstrand (2005) for discussion of the potential sources of bias in gravity model estimation and the techniques that may be used to overcome this problem 17 to consider them to be randomly drawn. If this is the case and the unobserved effects are correlated with regressors, the REM estimates will be biased6. A shortcoming of the FEM is that variables that do not vary over time (distance or common language for example) cannot be estimated as they are dropped in the fixed effects transformation. Both FEM and REM are estimated and their efficiency compared. First, the Breusch-Pagan test is applied to the REM and compared to the pooled OLS estimator. The null hypothesis is rejected, indicating that REM is a better estimator than OLS- A test statistic of 195.58, 196.53, 86.63, 46.71 and 40.06 are greater than the critical chi-squared value at one degree of freedom at 1% significance level (6.63). The Hausman test is applied to REM and FEM. The test statistic of 13.88, 16.63, 24.85, 16.67, and 34.51 is greater than the chi-squared critical value at six degrees of freedom at the 5 percent significance level (12.59), therefore the null hypothesis that the REM is consistent is rejected, the REM is shown to suffer from correlation and generate biased estimates. As an alternative to both the fixed effects and random effects models, Egger (2002, 2005) proposes using the Hausman and Taylor model (HTM) (See Hausman and Taylor, 1981). The HTM employs an instrumental variable approach that uses information solely from within the dataset to eliminate the correlation between the explanatory variables and the unobserved individual effects that undermines the appropriateness of the REM in the gravity model context. The HTM is increasingly applied in gravity models of trade in goods; likewise Egger and Pfaffermayr (2004) apply a HTM to FDI flows. To test the appropriateness of the HTM, the Hausman-Taylor over-identification test is applied to the FEM and HTM specifications. The test statistic of 1.53, 4.88, 6.73, 5.18, and 2.67 are less than the critical chi-squared value with six degrees of freedom at 1 percent significance, so the null hypothesis that the unobserved effects are correlated with other regressors is not rejected: HTM is more efficient. Testing of the different specifications appears to confirm the findings of Egger (2002, 2005), that the HTM is the most appropriate estimator for the gravity equation of trade in goods, also holds for trade in services. 6 In the gravity model relationship it is more likely than not that the REM will be biased. Egger (2005, p883) cites the example of an observed variable such as GDP being correlated with unobservable determinants of trade such as human capital stock or trade barriers in the importing and exporting countries. The explanatory variables are considered to be endogenous as they are correlated with the error term. See Cheng and Wall (2005) for a more detailed discussion. 18 As shown in table 3, In the HTM estimation there is mixed results in the selected ECOWAS Countries. First, GDP per capita determines the supply of services in the selected countries except Liberia, where GDP per capita is statistically insignificant. A 1 percent increase in GDP per head increases supply of services by 4.2%, 10.5%, 8.1%, and 10,7% in Côte d'Ivoire, Ghana, Nigeria, and Senegal respectively. Intuitively, in the exporting country: a richer country (rather than a larger country) will be able to produce more service commodities and will export more services. GDP per capita also determines the importer’s demand for service commodities of three out of the selected ECOWAS Countries. Intuitively, this would be expected as individuals and countries tend to consume more services as they become richer. But, GDP per capita of the importers of services trade from Ghana and Liberia is statistically insignificant. Population of the Exporting countries has negative significant impact on the supply of services in three out of the selected countries, but in Ghana and Liberia, Population of the Exporting countries is statistically insignificant. This could account for the fact that population-size of a country is not a major determinant of services trade export; this is in line with Walsh, 2006 findings. Population of the importers of services trade from Senegal, Ghana, and Nigeria determines the importer’s demand for service commodities. Intuitively, this would be expected as individuals and countries tend to consume more services as they become larger in size. But, the importers’ population is statistically insignificant for Côte d'Ivoire, and Senegal. A common language has no significant influence on trade flows using the HTM. This may be because; the selected ECOWAS Countries did not share common language with most of their service trade partners. Distance has no significant influence on trade flows using the HTM. This may reflect the fact that physical distances have little or no relevance for the movement of service commodities. The lack of a statistically significant coefficient on the distance variable is particularly interesting because it confirms an earlier finding of Egger (2002) in relation to the application of the HTM gravity model to goods trade, likewise, McPherson and Trumbell (2003) also find evidence in support of this argument. The variable that accounts for non-tariff barriers in the importing countries is statistically insignificant but the coefficient has the expected sign. This shows the non-tariff barriers did not 19 has significant impact on the services trade flows between the selected ECOWAS Countries and their services trade partners. This seems contradicting the established view those barriers to services trade are important. The outcome of this study may be as a result of the following among others: The problem of collecting accurate data on barriers to services trade. Data on services flows are recent but limited. Barriers to services trade are wide ranging and reflect the heterogeneous nature of services products. Compiling and categorising restrictions is difficult but progress needs to be made in this area for the effects of restrictions to be understood properly. 6. Conclusions This paper employs a gravity model approach to analyse the determinants of services trade and to measure the importance of non-tariff barriers on trade in services for selected ECOWAS Countries. Using data from Trade Map (www.trademap.org) providing total services imports a variety of panel data estimators are applied and tested. The Hausman-Taylor model is used to estimate the gravity equation for services. It is found to be superior to the random effects model, which typically suffers from heterogeneity bias in the gravity model, and avoids the problems associated with dealing with time-invariant variables using a fixed-effects model. A variable measuring the non-tariff barriers (NTB) to trade in each importing country, primarily based on trade restrictiveness indexes of the World Bank (htpp://www.iresearch,worlbank.org), is added to the gravity equation to calculate a set of tariff equivalents of the restrictions to services trade. The NTB variable is only found to be insignificant. 20 References Anderson, J. 1979. A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Model. American Economic Review, Vol. 69(1), pp. 106-116. Baier, S. and Bergstrand, J. 2005a. Bonus Vetus OLS: A Simple OLS Approach for Addressing the “Border Puzzle” and other Gravity Equation Issues. Balough, T. (1973). “Fact and fancy in international economic relations, part 1.” World Development, 1(1-2), 76-92. Bergstrand, J. 1989. The Generalised Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71(1), pp. 143-153. Bhagwati, J. (1984). “Why are services cheaper in the poor countries?” Economic Journal, 94(374), 279-286. Bhagwati, J.N. 1985. ‘Trade in Services and Developing Countries’. London: Tenth Annual Geneva Lecture at the London School of Economics. Chen, Z. & Schembri, L. (2002). Measuring the Barriers to Trade in Services: Literature and Methodologies. http://www.dfait-maeci.gc.ca/eet/pdf/17-en.pdf. Cheng, I.-H. and Wall, H. 2005. Controlling for Heterogeneity in Gravity Models of Trade and Integration. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 87(1), pp. 49-63. Chichilnisky, G. (1986). “A General Equilibrium Theory of North-South Trade.” In W. eller (Ed.), Essays in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow. New York: Cambridge University Press. Christen, E., Francois, J., and Hoekman, B. 2011 ‘CGE Modeling Of Market Access In Services; Bernard Working Paper No. 1208. Deardorff, A. 1995. Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neo-Classical World? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, No. 5377. Deardorff, A. and Stern, R. 1997. Measurement of Non-Tariff Barriers. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development Economics Department Working Paper, No. 179. Egger, P. 2005. Alternative Techniques for Estimation of Cross-Section Gravity Models. Review of International Economics, Vol. 13(5), pp. 881-891. Egger, P. 2002. An Econometric View on the Estimation of Gravity Models and the Calculation of Trade Potentials. The World Economy, Vol. 29(2), pp. 297-312. Egger, P. and Pfaffermayr, M. 2004. Distance, Trade and FDI: A Hausman-Taylor SUR Approach. Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 19, pp. 227-246. Escaith, H. (2008), "Measuring trade in value added in the new industrial economy: statistical implications", WTO, mimeo. Findlay, C. and Warren, F. 2000. Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and Policy Implications. London: Routledge. Fitzsimons, E., Hogan, V. and Neary, P. 1999. Explaining the Volume of North-South Trade in Ireland: A Gravity Model Approach. The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 30(4), pp. 381-401. Francois, J. 2001. The Next WTO Round: North-South Stakes in New Market Access Negotiations. Adelaide: Centre for International Economic Studies. Greenaway, D. and Milner, C. (1990). “South-South trade.” The World Bank Research Observer, 5(1), 47-68. 21 Grunfeld, L. and Moxnes, A. 2003. The Intangible Globalisation: Explaining Patterns of International Trade in Services. Norwegian Institute of International Affairs Paper, No. 657. Hausman, J. and Taylor, W. 1981. Panel Data and Unobservable Effects. Econometric, Vol. 49 (6), pp. 1377-1398. Helpman, E. and Krugman, P. 1985. Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the International Economy. Brighton: Wheatsheaf Books. Hill,-T-P (1977), ‘On Goods and Services’, Review-of-Income-and-Wealth. Dec.; 23(4): 315-38 Hindley,-Brian; Smith,-Alasdair (1984), ‘Comparative Advantage and Trade in Services’, World-Economy. December; 7(4): 369-89. Hoekman, B. & Mattoo, A. (1999). Services, Economic Development and the Next Round of Negotiations on Services. http://mmikic.efzg.hr/uploads/ hoekman%20and%20mattoo_services_ldc.pdf. Hoekman, B. and Stern, R. M. (1988). “The Service Sector in Economic Structure and in International Transactions.” In L. V. Castle (Ed.), Pacific Trade in Services. Sydney, Australia: Allen and Unwin. Hoekman, B. 1995. Tentative First Steps: An Assessment of the Uruguay Round Agreement on Services. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 1455. Hoekman, B. and Mattoo, A. (2008). “Services trade and growth.” Policy Research Working Paper No. 4461, Development Research Group, World Bank. Ohlin, B. (1933). Inter-Regional and International Trade. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press. Kalirajan, K (2000), ‘Restrictions on Trade in Distribution Services’, Productivity Commission Staff Research Paper, Ausinfo, Canberra. Krugman, P. (1981). “Trade accumulation and uneven development.” Journal of Development Economics, 8(2), 149-161. Lejour, A. and de Paiva Verheijden, J.-W. 2004. Services Trade Within Canada and the European Union: What do They Have in Common? CPB Discussion Paper, No. 42. Marko, M (1998), ‘An Evaluation of the Basic Telecommunications Services Agreement’, CIES Policy Discussion Paper 98/09, Centre for International Economic Studies, University of Adelaide. McGuire, G. (2002). Trade In Services – Market Access Opportunities And The Benefits Of Liberalization For Developing Economies. http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/ itcdtab20_en.pdf. McPherson, M. and Trumbull, W. 2003. Using the Gravity Model to Estimate Trade Potential: Evidence in Support of the Hausman-Taylor Estimation Model. Melvin, J. R. (1989), ‘Trade in Producer Services: A Heckscher-Ohlin Approach’, Journal of Political Economy 97:5,October, 1180-1196. Myint, H. (1958). “The classical theory of international trade and the underdeveloped countries” Economic Journal, 68(270), 317-337. Myrdal, G. (1970). The Challenge of World Poverty. New York: Pantheon. Nguyen-Hong, Duc (2000) "Restrictions on Trade in Professional Services," Productivity Commission Staff Research Paper, Ausinfo, Canberra. Ross, T. W. (1999) "Barriers to Entry," in R. Shyam Khemani (ed.) A Framework for the Design and Implementation of Competition Law and Policy, Paris: OECD. 22 Sampson, G.P. and R.H. Snape (1985). Identifying the Issues in Trade in Services. The World Economy, 8, pp.171-81. Smith, S. and Toye, J. (1979). “Special issue on trade and poor countries” Journal of Development Studies, 15(3), 1-18. Toye, J. (1987). Dilemmas of Development: Reflections on the Counter-Revolution in Development Theory and Policy. Oxford: London. Trewin, R. (2001), ‘A Price-Impact Measure of Impediments to Trade in Telecommunications Services’, Impediments to Trade in Services: Measurement and Policy Implications, London, Routledge, pp. 101-118. Walsh, K., 2006 ‘Trade in Services: Does Gravity Hold? A Gravity Model Approach to Estimating Barriers to Services Trade’ Institute for International Integration Studies; Discussion Paper No. 183. World Trade Organization. (2005). A Handbook on the GATS Agreement. United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press. 23 APPENDIX Table: 3a Regression Results Pooled OLS FEM Dependent Variable Total Services Import Côte d'Ivoire LNGDPPC_Exporter LNGDPPC_Importer LNPOP_ Exporter LNPOP_ Importer Liberia Nigeria Senegal Ghana Liberia Nigeria Senegal 4.45 10.79 .98 5.74 1.66 4.15*** 9.72*** .56 7.98** 10.55** (4.28) (12.54) (1.49) (5.24) (6.14) (2.35) (6.24) (.99) (3.89) (4.39) 4.08 3.55* 3.12* 3.80* 4.08* 1.79** .05 .52 1.87** -1.37 (.28) (.40) -26.65*** -30.44 .39 (.21) (.30) (.80) (.96) (1.07) (.79) (.96) -3.92** -19.93 -9.80 -18.25*** -22.88 -3.67*** -24.36** -13.46** (17.39) (32.20) 1.86 (14.32) (9.17) (10.08) (16.08) (2.29) (10.50) (6.29) .90* .78* .99* 1.24* 1.09* 2.50 16.76* 30.64* 15.38* 8.69 (.12) (.21) .19 (.12) (.12) (4.44) (6.13) (7.31) (4.96) (5.75) .52*** -.72** .84* - - - - - - (.33) .31 (.18) - - - - - - 2.49*** .41 .92 5.41* 1.46 - - - - - (1.54) (2.10) (2.13) 1.04 (1.46) - - - - - .42 1.08*** 2.74* 2.63* 2.31* - - - - - (.46) (.66) (.62) (.36) (.42) - - - - - 0.73 0.57 .48 0.86 0.75 3.88 16.63 24.85 16.67 34.51 Common Language Distance LNNTBsTotal R2 Côte d'Ivoire Ghana Hausman Test Source: Authors’ Computation. Note: The Standard errors for the coefficients are in italics and bracket below them. *, **, *** represent 1%, 5% and 10% levels of statistical significance. 24 Table: 3b Regression Results REM HTM Dependent Variable Total Services Import Côte d'Ivoire LNGDPPC_Exporter LNGDPPC_Importer LNPOP_ Exporter LNPOP_ Importer Common Language Distance LNNTBsTotal_Partner Côte d'Ivoire Ghana Liberia Nigeria Senegal Ghana Liberia Nigeria Senegal 4.26*** 11.04*** .458 6.69*** 5.29 4.18*** 10.49**** .39 8.06** 10.72* (2.37) (6.59) (1.07) (4.13) (4.80) (2.30) (6.18) (.99) (3.86) (4.28) 2.65* .46 1.03 (.63) (.86) (.92) 2.82* 1.79* 2.03* -.30 .21 1.59** -1.62*** (.53) (.68) (.72) .94 (1.07) (.77) (.90) -21.11** -24.24 -.77 -20.40*** -10.60 -18.73** -22.46 -1.91 -22.70** -12.15** (9.91) (17.01) (1.87) (11.20) (7.01) (9.69) (15.95) (2.18) (10.94) (6.07) .58 .02 .55 .97* .61*** .49 7.40*** 19.88* 7.75** 1.69 (.41) (.75) (.64) (.34) (.33) (.79) (4.12) (5.90) (3.45) (2.57) - 1.27 -.40 1.14** - - -5.17 -18.27 -4.64 - - (1.32) (1.13) (.54) - - (9.75) (17.21) (8.32) - -1.54 -6.77 -5.22 3.67 -5.78 -3.28 -12.93 -42.46 3.61 -17.65 (5.12) (8.26) (7.24) (3.26) (3.90) (9.96) (63.46) (113.61) (50.90) (31.75) -.34 -.28 1.80 2.24** 1.41 -.74 -16.10 -38.51 -12.48 -3.05 (1.60) (2.73) (2.26) (1.15) (1.22) (3.19) (20.16) (34.25) (17.45) (11.38) 0.50 0.91 0.75 86.16 46.71 40.06 1.53 4.88 6.73 5.18 2.67 R2 Breusch-Pagan test: 195.58 196.63 Over-identification Test Source: Authors’ Computation. Note: The Standard errors for the coefficients are in italics and bracket below them. *, **, *** represent 1%, 5% and 10% levels of statistical significance. 25 26