Convergence in tax revenues across ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries: Evidence from club convergence Nicholas Apergis Department of Banking and Financial Management University of Piraeus Piraeus, Greece napergis@unipi.gr and Arusha Cooray (corresponding author) School of Economics University of Wollongong NSW 2552, Australia arusha@uow.edu.au March 2013 Abstract The goal of the present paper is to investigate the degree of convergence in tax revenues for a panel of 16 ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries spanning the period 1990-2012. We apply the methodology of Phillips and Sul (2007) to various categories of tax revenues to assess the presence of convergence clubs. We consider five alternative categories of tax revenues. Overall, the results do not support the hypothesis that all countries converge to a single equilibrium state in such tax revenues. Keywords: convergence; tax revenues; ASEAN countries; club convergence approach JEL Classification Codes: H20; C33 1 1. Introduction The ASEAN encompasses ten Southeast Asian nations – Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Lao, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Vietnam. The ASEAN is currently in the process of launching a single common market by 2015 through increased economic integration. In order to achieve this objective, the ASEAN member nations have established mechanisms through which to strengthen the operation of its prevailing economic initiatives including the ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), the ASEAN Framework Agreement on Services (AFAS) and the ASEAN Investment Area (AIA) (Jogarajan, 2001). The ASEAN countries planned to complete a network of bilateral tax treaties across all member nations by 2010. Although significant progress has been made towards achieving this objective, the process is still not complete. Some argue that an ASEAN multilateral tax treaty may be better for promoting intra-regional investments (Rogarajan 2001; ADBI 2009). Against this backdrop, the goal of this study is to investigate, for the first time, tax policy convergence among ASEAN countries, as greater integration between the tax policies of these countries would accelerate the process of achieving a single common market. We examine tax policy convergence for income-profits-capital gains, social security contributions, property and general taxes on goods and services. The ASEAN group is also exploring the means through which economic integration can be increased amongst its members and the Asia Pacific and Oceania including economies, such as, Japan, South Korea, China, Australia and New Zealand. Therefore, tax policy convergence between the ASEAN and these countries is also examined. An additional novelty of this paper stems from the implementation of the new methodology of panel convergence testing, recommended by Phillips and Sul (2007). The philosophy of the methodological approach is based on the club convergence hypothesis, which considers that certain countries, states, sectors or regions that belong to a club move from disequilibrium positions to their club-specific steady-state positions. This methodology has several appealing characteristics. To begin with, no specific assumptions concerning the stationarity of the variable of interest and/or the existence of common factors are necessary. Nevertheless, this convergence test could be interpreted as an asymptotic cointegration test without suffering from the small sample problems of unit root and cointegration testing. In addition, the methodology is based on a quite general form of a nonlinear time varying factor model. 2 Our results suggest evidence of club divergence in tax revenues with three to four clubs depending on the type of tax investigated. This study will allow policy makers to determine the countries in which tax systems have converged and help implement measures to promote greater integration between tax systems of countries which have not converged. Tax convergence permits increasing the efficiency of public policies and prevents member states from being exploited due to excessive taxes (Fuest and Huber, 1999), member states are able to compete strategically for mobile factors (Winner, 2005), and member states are able to prevent a race to the bottom due to tax harmonization (Winner, 2005). The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the recent empirical literature on tax revenues convergence. Section 3 presents the new methodology employed. Section 4 reports and discusses the results of the empirical analysis, while Section 5 summarizes the paper and offers some policy implications. 2. The Literature The focus of much of the literature on tax convergence has been on the European Union (EU) and OECD nations. Empirical studies on tax convergence employing cross sectional data have examined beta and sigma convergence (Esteve et al., 2000; SosvillaRivera et al., 2001). Studies using time series data have used unit root tests (Delgado and Presno 2011) and studies based on panel data have used random effects estimation (Bretschger and Hettich, 2002). Delgado and Presno (2011) investigate tax policy convergence (for income and profits, social security contributions, property, general taxes on goods and services, taxes on specific goods and services) in the EU over the period 19652005 taking as reference Germany, the United Kingdom and the European average. Using time series methodology, they find little evidence of tax convergence across the countries in the sample under investigation. Bretschger and Hettich (2002) investigating the impact of globalisation on corporate taxes for a panel of 14 OECD countries over the period 1967-1996 and a random effects model, similarly find evidence of a negative and significant impact of globalisation on corporate taxes. They additionally find evidence of an increase in labour taxes and social expenditures due to globalisation. In a different strand of the literature, that exemplifies the β-and σ-convergence approaches, Sosvilla-Rivera et al. (2001) investigate the degree of beta and sigma convergence in the tax burden for 14 EU countries over the period 1965-1995. They show that there is some evidence in favour of convergence in the sub-period 1967-1974, but 3 evidence of divergence from 1974-1984 and evidence of convergence again beyond 1974. Similar conclusions are reached by Esteve et al. (2000) for fiscal policy convergence in the EU over the period 1967-1994. Both beta and sigma convergence in tax policy show evidence of divergence over the period 1967-1979 and convergence over the period 19791994. Examining if international tax competition leads to a shift of tax burden from mobile to immobile tax bases in 23 OECD economies, in particular, for small open economies over the period 1965–2000, Winner (2005) finds that capital mobility has a negative effect on capital tax burden and a positive impact on labour tax burden. Country size is found to have a positive effect with small open economies imposing lower capital and labour taxes compared to larger ones. He finds evidence of an increase in tax competition rather than convergence between the countries since the mid 1980s. However, critics on β-convergence question the adequacy of -convergence regressions. Binder and Pesaran (1999) show that -convergence, even when used to study the growth path of a given economy towards its own steady state, can collapse in the case of a stochastic technological progress, while Durlauf et al. (2005) note that a negative coefficient (β) on initial income in a cross-section framework could simply imply that economies converge to their own different steady states. At the same time, critics of σ-convergence argue that it provides a necessary, but not sufficient, ingredient for observing reductions in any variable dispersion (Quah 1993). If countries converge to a common equilibrium with shared global technologies and identical internal structures, then the dispersion of income should disappear in the long-run as all countries converge to the same real per capita income. If, however, countries converge to convergence clubs or to their own unique equilibrium, the dispersion of real per capita income will not approach zero (Miller and Upadhyah, 2002). Devereux et al. (2002) and Devereux et al. (2008) similarly find evidence of tax competition rather than convergence across the EU and OECD countries. Devereux et al. (2002) examine the effect of taxes on corporate income in the EU and G7 nations over a period of two decades. They conclude that effective tax rates on marginal investment have remained relatively unchanged but that those on more profitable investments have fallen due to tax-cutting and base-broadening restructuring. They argue that this could be due to government reaction to a fall in the cost of income shifting by placing downward pressure on the statutory tax rate and the competition for more profitable projects. Devereux et al. (2008) in a study of whether OECD countries compete with each other over corporate taxes to attract investment, find evidence of countries competing for the statutory tax rate, the effective 4 average tax rate and the effective marginal tax rate, but in particular, over the statutory tax rate and effective average tax rate. They state that this is due to locational choices by multinational firms. Sorensen (2000; 2001; 2004) examines fiscal competition for mobile capital and its effect on resource allocation, income distribution and social welfare within a general equilibrium framework. He argues in favour of a fully harmonised corporate tax within the EU, observing the differences between global and regional tax coordination. Fuest and Huber (1999) similarly argue that a coordination of regional policies can help internalizing positive externalities of domestic policies. Theoretical models of international taxation have also been put forward by Edwards and Keen (1996), Keen and Marchand (1997), Fuest and Huber (1999), Becker and Fuest (2010), Marchand et al. (2003), Kanbur and Keen (1993), Razin and Sadka (1991), among others. Razin and Sadka (1991), in a model of tax coordination between a small country and the rest of the world, show that that if competing countries are well coordinated with the rest of the world, then tax competition leads each country to apply the residence principle of taxation and there will be no gains from tax harmonization. If, however, there is no proper coordination, then tax competition can lead to low capital income taxes and the tax burden falls on internationally immobile factors. The study of Becker and Fuest (2010), for instance, shows that coordination of investment in transport cost cutting infrastructures within union countries, increases welfare and reduces tax competition. Marchand et al. (2003) argue that partial coordination of withholding taxes on interest income can be welfare reducing as opposed to no coordination at all. Keen and Marchand (1997) show that welfare can be increased through a coordinated decrease in the provision of local public inputs and an increase in the public provision of local public goods, and Kanbur and Keen (1993) find that smaller countries lose from coordination of tax rates between those set in the non-cooperative equilibrium, but both small and large countries gain from the enforcement of a minimum tax. To the best of our knowledge, there are no studies which have empirically examined tax convergence across the ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania nations. Additionally, studies have also not employed the Phillips and Sul (2007) convergence formulation to investigate tax policy convergence. Therefore, we extend upon the literature by empirically investigating tax policy convergence across the ASEAN and the Asia Pacific and Oceania nations using this particular convergence methodological approach. 5 3. Econometric methodology In this section, we outline the methodology proposed by Phillips and Sul (2007) (henceforth PS) to test for convergence in a panel of countries. Let us have panel data for a variable X it , where i = 1,...N and t = 1,...T , with N , T the number of countries and the sample size, respectively. Often X it is decomposed into two components, one systematic, g it , and one transitory ait (1) X it = g it + ait PS transforms (1) in a way that common and idiosyncratic components in the panel are separated. Specifically, g ait X it it t t it t , for all i, t (2) In this way, the variable of interest, Xit, is decomposed in two components, one common, μt, and one idiosyncratic, δit, both of which are time varying. This formulation enables testing for convergence by testing whether the factor loadings δit converge. To do so, PS define the relative transition parameter, hit, as: X δ hit = 1 it = 1 it ∑X it ∑δit N N (3) which measures the loading coefficient δit in relation to the panel and, as such, the transition path for the economy i relative to the panel average. The relative transition curves depict the relative transition coefficients hit, calculated from Equation (3). In the context of macroeconomic data, and since our interest is on the long-run behaviour, we first remove the business cycle component of Xit by employing the HodrickPrescott (1997) filter. The only input required is a smoothing parameter determined mainly by the frequency of the data.1 Having extracted the trend component from the series denoted 1 In our application with quarterly data, the smoothing parameter λ, is set equal to 1600. 6 Xˆ it as X̂ it , we calculate the estimated transition paths as hˆit = 1 . Next we construct the ∑Xˆ it N cross-sectional variation ratio H 1 Ht = Ht where: 1 N ˆ ∑(h - 1) 2 N i =1 it PS show that the transition distance Ht has a limiting form of Ht ∼ A L(t ) 2 t 2α as t → ∞ where A is a positive constant, L(t) is a slowly varying function, such as log( t 1) and α denotes the speed of convergence. To test for the null hypothesis of convergence, H0 : δi = δ and α ≥0 against the alternative H A : δi ≠δ for all i, or α 0 PS run the following log t regression: log H 1 2 log L(t ) cˆ bˆ log t ut Ht (4) where L(t) = log(t + 1). The standard errors of the estimates are calculated using a heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent (HAC) estimator for the long-run variance of the residuals. In this study, we employ the quadratic spectral kernel and determine the bandwidth by means of the Andrews (1991) data-dependent procedure. By employing the conventional t-statistic tb the null hypothesis of convergence is rejected if t b 1.65 . In practice, this regression is run after a fraction of the sample is removed. PS recommend starting the regression at some point t = [rT ] , where [rT ] is the integer part of rT , and r = 0.3. 2 This null hypothesis implies relative convergence (conditional convergence) rather than absolute convergence (convergence in level). If we change the null hypothesis to α ≥1, 2 Extensive Monte Carlo simulations conducted by Phillips and Sul (2007) show that terms of both size and power. r = 0.3 is satisfactory in 7 which is equivalent to b̂ ≥2 , we can test for absolute convergence. Given that rejection of the null for the panel as a whole does not imply the absence of club convergence, PS go one step beyond and develop an algorithm for club convergence. We next briefly outline the basic steps of the respective algorithm. 4. Empirical analysis and results 4.1 Data Quarterly data on a number of tax revenues classifications as a percentage share of GDP, such as total, income-profits-capital gains, social security contributions, property, and general taxes on goods and services -all measured as percentages of their corresponding GDP- are obtained from the Datastream database for a number of ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries, they are in local currency and spanning the period 1990-2012. All tax revenues and the GDP are measured at 2000 constant prices. The countries included in the sample are: Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore and Thailand. Taxes on income-profits-capital gains are levied on the actual or presumptive net income of individuals, on the profits of corporations and enterprises, and on capital gains, whether realized or not, on land, securities, and other assets. Social contributions include social security contributions by employees, employers, and self-employed individuals plus actual or imputed contributions to social insurance schemes operated by governments. Taxes on goods and services include general sales and turnover or value added taxes, selective excises on goods, selective taxes on services, taxes on the use of goods or property, taxes on extraction and production of minerals, and profits of fiscal monopolies. 4.2 Empirical results Table 1 reports the results for total tax revenues. We reject the null hypothesis of full convergence for this variable at the 5-percent significance level. The results of the club convergence algorithm indicate the presence of two clubs plus a non-converging group. Three countries (Australia, New Zealand, Singapore) form the first club, whereas the second club includes six countries (Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, the Republic of Korea and Thailand). China and Japan do not converge at all. 8 Table 2 reports the results for tax revenues on income, profits and capital gains. We reject the null hypothesis of full convergence for this variable at the 5-percent significance level. The results of the club convergence algorithm indicate the presence of three clubs with 3 countries, Australia, New Zealand, Singapore, in the first, Indonesia, Malaysia and Myanmar in the second club, and 5 countries (China, Japan, Philippines, the Republic of Korea and Thailand) in the third. The strongest speed of convergence is between countries in the second group, Indonesia, Malaysia and Myanmar with b̂ 3.328. Compared to the total tax revenues variable, we see more dispersion of countries with more in the third group. Table 3 reports the results for tax revenues on social security contributions. We reject again the null hypothesis of full convergence at the 5-percent significance level. The results of the club convergence algorithm indicate the presence of three clubs with 4 countries (Australia, New Zealand, Singapore and the Republic of Korea) in the first club, 2 countries (Indonesia and Malaysia) in the second, and 3 countries (Japan, Philippines and Thailand) in the third. China and Myanmar form a non-converging group. The speed of convergence for tax revenues on social security contributions is highest between member countries in the second group, Indonesia and Malaysia with b̂ 3.874. The last two tables (Tables 4 and 5) report the convergence findings for tax revenues on property and tax revenues on general taxes on goods and services, respectively. In particular, Table 4 displays the presence of four converging clubs plus a non-converging group in terms of tax revenues on property. Australia and New Zealand form the first club, Indonesia, Malaysia and Myanmar the second, the Republic of Korea and the Philippines the third, and Japan, Singapore and Thailand the fourth. China falls into the non-converging group. These results document high dispersion across the countries included in the sample under investigation. The highest speed of convergence is recorded between Australia and New Zealand ( b̂ 3.782). Finally, similar results are obtained in Table 5 that shows divergence in terms of tax revenues on general taxes on goods and services. Table 5 indicates the presence of four clubs with Australia and New Zealand in the first, Indonesia and Malaysia in the second, Japan, the Republic of Korea and Singapore in the third and the Philippines and Thailand in the fourth. This time the non-convergence group, in addition to China, contains the country of Myanmar. The highest speed of convergence for general taxes on goods and services is between Australia and New Zealand ( b̂ 3.672). 9 The results for all tax revenue groups are summarized in Table 6. There is strong evidence of convergence in all tax revenues between Australia and New Zealand. This is not surprising given their geographical proximity and similar economic conditions. Singapore forms part of this club with regard to tax revenues on income-profits-capital gains and social security contributions. There is also evidence of tax convergence between Indonesia and Malaysia. These two countries are also geographically closely located and have similar cultural and economic backgrounds. Additionally, the taxable income (chargeable income/employment income less exemptions and deductions) of Indonesia, Myanmar and Malaysia are similar (National Tax Research Journal (NTRC, 2007). The tax revenues of Thailand and the Philippines also appear to move together. This perhaps is because the tax base of employment income, that is, the annual gross income less deductions of the Philippines is similar to the assessable income (gross employment income less personal reliefs and standard/itemized deductions) tax base of Thailand (NTRC, 2007). There is little evidence to suggest that China’s tax revenues will converge with those of the ASEAN in the near future. Japan and the Republic of Korea show only weak evidence of convergence. Japan’s tax revenues appear to be most closely aligned with those of Thailand and the Republic of Korea’s with that of the Philippines. Overall, although we observe evidence that supports club divergence across the ASEAN and the Asia Pacific and Oceania countries and in terms of disaggregated tax revenues, this divergence does not seem substantial when it comes to the total tax revenues, denoting that a specific mechanism in tax collection can generate tendencies for convergence. 4.3 Robustness tests Figure 1 depicts the relative transition curves for total tax revenues of each convergence club. Visual inspection of these curves enables us to gain some insight on the outcomes of the testing methodology and monitor the convergence of total tax revenues for each club, relatively to the sample average. In particular, the transition curves report a graphical picture about the tendency of the cluster participants to converge or diverge from above or below 1, which is the convergence path reference point during the period under study. Both transition curves show that at 2012 (the end point of our sample) the tendency is towards convergence, though curves 1 seems to approach convergence from above and curve 2 seems to approach convergence from below. 10 Finally, Phillips and Sul (2009) argue that their convergence club methodology tends to overestimate the number of clubs than their true number. To avoid this overdetermination, they run the algorithm across the sub-clubs to assess whether any evidence exists in support of merging clubs into larger clubs. The results of the new converging tests are reported in Table 7. The empirical findings display that for the two sub-clubs there is no evidence to support mergers of the original clubs. 5. Conclusions This paper investigated the issue of tax convergence across a sample of 16 ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries spanning the period 1990-2012. To serve this objective, the novel methodology of Phillips and Sul (2007) was used. This methodology used a non-linear factor model with a common and an idiosyncratic component – both time-varying, which allowed for technical progress heterogeneity across these countries. In terms of total tax revenues, the empirical findings suggested that the 16 ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries under study did not form a homogeneous convergence club. In addition to the total tax revenues variables, we also used four different disaggregated tax revenues variables. We found no evidence supporting full convergence across all countries in our sample. Rather, we discovered club divergence with a number of different clubs, depending on the definition of the variable measured. Club divergence could suggest that differences in tax revenues between clubs could exist over a period of time. The potential adverse effects of a non-harmonised tax system include tax competition and harmful bidding wars between nations leading to a race to the bottom. The ASEAN and Asia Pacific and Oceania countries could follow the example of other regions which have been successful in tax policy cooperation. For example, Nordic tax cooperation is strongly aligned with the region’s overall cooperation objectives. The treaty on administrative assistance among these countries specifies the requirements for countries with respect to the exchange of information and tax collections (Jogarajan, 2011). These countries could follow a similar practice to increase transparency and accelerate the process of tax cooperation. Similarly, ensuring that tax policies are tightly aligned with the objectives of these countries would permit maximizing the welfare gains from tax coordination. 11 References ADBI (2009). Second ADBI Regional Tax Forum Intensive Course on International Tax Treaties for Selected Asian Countries, Executive Summary of Tax Forum Proceedings, Tokyo 2009. Becker, J. and Fuest, C. (2010). EU Regional Policy and Tax Competition, European Economic Review, 54, 150-161. Binder, M. and Pesaran, M.H. (1999). Stochastic growth models and their econometric implications, Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 173-183. Bretschger, L. and Hettich, F. (2002). Globalisation, Capital Mobility and Tax Competition: Theory and Evidence for OECD Countries. European Journal of Political Economy 18, 695-716. Delgado, F. and Presno. M.J. (2011). Convergence of Fiscal Pressure in the EU: A Time Series Approach. Applied Economics, 43, 4257-4267. Devereux, M.P., Lockwood, B., Redoano, M. (2008). Do countries compete over corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1210–1235. Devereux, M.P., Griffith, R. and Klemm, A. (2002). Corporate Income Tax Reforms and International Tax Competition. Economic Policy, 35, 450–495. Durlauf, S.N., Johnson, P.A. and Temple, R.W. (2005). Growth econometrics, in: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1. North Holland: Amsterdam. Edwards, J. and Keen, M. (1996). Tax Competition and Leviathan. European Economic Review, 40, 113-134. Esteve, V., Sosvilla-Rivero, S. and Tamarit, C. (2000). Convergence in fiscal pressure across EU countries. Applied Economics Letters, 7, 117-123. Fuest, C. and Huber, B. (1999). Can Tax Coordination Work? FinanzArchiv / Public Finance Analysis, 56, 443-458. Jogarajan, S. (2011). A multilateral tax treaty for ASEAN: lessons for the Andean, Caribbean, Nordic and South Asian nations. Asian Journal of Comparative Law, 6, 145-166. Kanbur, R. and Keen, M. (1993). Jeux Sans Frontier: Tax Competition and Tax Coordination when Countries Differ in Size. American Economic Review, 83, 877–892. Keen, M. and Marchand, M. (1997). Fiscal competition and the pattern of public spending. Journal of Public Economics, 66, 33–53. Marchand, M., Pestieau, P. and Sato, M. (2003). Can Partial Fiscal Coordination be Welfare Worsening? A Model of Tax Competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 451-458. 12 Miller, S.M. and Upadhyay, M.P. (2002). Total factor productivity and the convergence hypothesis, Journal of Macroeconomics, 24, 267-286. National Tax Research Journal (NRTC 2007) Summary Significant Features of the Income Tax Structure Among ASEAN Member Countries, July-August 2007, Volume XIX.4, pp. 1-44 Phillips P.C.B. and Sul D. (2009). Economic transition and growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 24, 1153-1185. Phillips, P.C.B. and Sul, D. (2007). Transition modeling and econometric convergence tests. Econometrica, 75, 1771-1855. Quah, D. (1993). Galton's fallacy and tests of the convergence hypothesis, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 95, 427-443. Sorensen, P.B. (2004). International tax coordination: regionalism versus globalism. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1187-1214. Sorensen, P.B. (2001). Tax coordination in the European Union: What are the issues? Swedish Economic Policy Review, 8, 143-195. Sorensen, P.B. (2000). The Case for International Tax Co-ordination Reconsidered. Economic Policy, 15, 429-472. Sosvilla-Rivero, S., Galindo, M.A. and Meseguer, A. J. (2001). Tax Burden Convergence in Europe. Estudios de Economia Aplicada, 17, 183-191. Winner, H. (2005). Has tax competition emerged in OECD countries? Evidence from panel data. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 667–687. 13 Table 1. Total tax revenues Full sample Countries t-stat b coefficient Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand -0.537 -9.342 Australia, New Zealand, Singapore -0.155 -1.375 Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Thailand 2.327 2.482 1st club 2nd club China, Japan Non - converging 14 Table 2. Tax revenues on income, profits and capital gains Countries t-stat b coefficient Full sample Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand -0.792 -9.672 1st club Australia, New Zealand, Singapore 0.136 0.573 2nd club Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar 0.371 3.328 3rd club China, Japan, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Thailand 0.564 1.893 15 Table 3. Taxes revenues on social security contributions Full sample Countries t-stat b coefficient Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand -2.782 -6.548 1st club Australia, New Zealand, Republic of Korea, Singapore 2.518 3.509 2nd club Indonesia, Malaysia 1.472 3.874 3rd club Japan, Philippines, Thailand 1.815 2.326 Non - converging China, Myanmar 16 Table 4. Tax revenues on property Countries t-stat b coefficient Full sample Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand -0.584 -21.328 1st club Australia, New Zealand 0.471 3.782 2nd club Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar 0.152 2.673 3rd club Philippines, Republic of Korea 0.094 0.793 4th club Japan, Singapore, Thailand 1.683 3.861 Non - converging China 17 Table 5. Tax revenues on general taxes on goods and services Countries t-stat b coefficient Full sample Australia, China, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Myanmar, New Zealand, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand -1.384 -23.906 1st club Australia, New Zealand 0.086 3.672 2nd club Indonesia, Malaysia -0.037 -0.1941 3rd club Japan, Republic of Korea, Singapore 0.493 1.785 4th club Philippines, Thailand 0.381 0.852 Non - converging Myanmar, China 18 Table 6: Summary of Results Tax Revenues Clubs Income, Profits 1st club Social Property Goods and Security Services Capital Gains Contributions Australia, Australia, New New Zealand, Zealand, Singapore, Singapore Republic and Total Australia Australia, Australia, New Zealand New New Zealand Zealand, of Singapore Korea 2nd club Indonesia, Indonesia, Indonesia, Indonesia, Indonesia, Malaysia, Malaysia Malaysia, Malaysia Malaysia, Myanmar Myanmar Myanmar, Philippines, Republic of Korea, Thailand 3rd club China, Japan, Japan, Philippines, Philippines, Republic Republic Philippines, of Thailand Korea Korea, Japan, of Republic of Korea, Singapore Thailand 4th club - - Japan, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand - Thailand Nonconverging - China, Myanmar China China, China, Myanmar Japan 19 Figure 1. Total tax revenues: relative transition curves of convergence clubs Table 7. Convergence club classification (total tax revenues) ___________________________________________________________________________ Club Tests of club merging ___________________________________________________________________________ 1 Club 1+2 = -0.083* (-6.71) 2 ___________________________________________________________________________ Notes: * denotes statistical significant at the 5% level, while it rejects the null hypothesis of convergence. The figures in parenthesis denotes t-statistics. 20