The Role of Technology in Transition Economies of Europe Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Abstract Fifteen years ago, the world witnessed the breakup of the Soviet Union and its influence on the countries of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE). Relatively “simple” technologies proved to be key factors in overcoming government propaganda by rapidly publishing free and open information. In the succeeding years CEE countries began political, economic, and social reforms to transition from centrally planned socialist economies to free market capitalist economies. The improved business climate from these reforms resulted in increased Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in various forms, primarily capital, knowledge and technology transfer. These resources and technologies facilitated economic growth in CEE countries by improving their infrastructures, communication, efficiency, productivity, competitive advantage, and job creation. As a result, these countries have ultimately seen increases in their Gross Domestic Product, decreased unemployment, and accelerated growth and learning. Thesis Modern technology in various forms has played the most critical role in Central and Eastern Europe’s transition from socialist to capitalist economies by liberating information and facilitating economic growth. 1 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Introduction Fifteen years ago, the world witnessed the fall of the Berlin wall, the break up of the Soviet Union and its influence on the Soviet Bloc countries of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE). In the succeeding years, these countries began their transition from centrally planned socialist economies to free market capitalist economies. Despite the varying degrees of socialism in CEE, from command socialism to market socialism, all transition economies have similar objectives and elements. Privatization, liberalization, and stabilization can be considered the primary objectives of a country in transition (Meier). Transitions also “entail the creation or reform of institutions – economic, social and political – and organizational change” (Meier, 338). These expansive reforms created a favorable business climate which allowed FDI to flow in, and with it came an abundance of technology from the west – not just information and communication technologies, but up-to-date knowledge, management practices, and industry expertise. In this paper, the role of technology in CEE is examined as a tool for political, social, and economic reform as well as a vehicle for economic growth. It is clear that the Soviet empire could not have existed without strict information control. However, the enormous task of controlling information became increasingly difficult with the development of increasingly sophisticated information technology. Technology allows the free flow of information, improves transparency, communication, transfers knowledge, ideas and expertise. Furthermore, technology improves a country’s infrastructure and can strengthen comparative advantage. Modern technology in various forms has played the most critical role in Central and Eastern Europe’s transition from socialist to capitalist economies by liberating information and facilitating economic growth. 2 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Technology as a tool for reform Socialist economies of the former Soviet Bloc were marked by inefficiency, poor economic growth, high unemployment, and experienced a shortage of goods. To maintain social order, governments needed to control information though an extensive propaganda campaign. […] for reasons compellingly articulated by Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich A. Hayek during the 1920s and 1930s, socialism doesn’t work; it doesn’t produce goods and services for the vast majority of people who live under it to nearly the same extent that free markets do. So, to keep people from being discontented and wanting a different system, what is a socialist government to do? […] the government must lie. It must tell its people how good they have it (Henderson, 519). Henderson goes on to say that “In the Soviet Union, the government used a massive censorship apparatus to suppress other sources of information, virtually from the beginning of communism in 1917 until the Gorbachev era starting in the mid-1980s […] but the communications technology employed for spreading the lies can backfire. Lying in print is easy; lying with video footage is much harder” (519). In the late 80’s, Gorbachev’s glasnost campaign to push his perestroika reforms removed the lynchpin of fear and allowed information to flow more freely in the Soviet Union. Existing mass media technology rapidly spread more accurate information about the dismal state of the Soviet Union as well as everyday “luxuries” average westerners enjoyed. This information “appeared in the pages of official newspapers, resounded from millions of radios and televisions, began to bounce around the country on photocopied leaflets and telefax news services” (Shane, 73). Gorbachev himself did not expect such a revolutionary outcome. Since information had to be suppressed for socialism to work, the communist party and the Soviet Union could not survive when these technologies freed up information. A good case can be made that information technology helped bring down the Soviet Union. I am not referring to the Internet, which was not in widespread use until the mid1990s. I have in mind instead information technology that had been around a long time, including television and print media (Henderson, 518). 3 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Scott Shane provides additional evidence of the role that “simple” technologies, such as fax and photocopy machines, played in the collapse of the Soviet Union. Shane was a correspondent from the Baltimore Sun living in Moscow in the late 80’s. After installing a fax machine in his office, he reported “it operated around the clock, spewing out political communiqués from nationalist groups and infant political parties, advertisements, and news from the new information services Interfax and Baltfax” (Shane, 205). Once information began flowing freely in this more transparent environment, there was no stopping the inevitable effect it would have. Along with the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989, a wave of reform swept through the former Soviet Bloc countries and the Soviet Union was officially dissolved in 1991. With political and economic reforms taking place, the stage was being set for increased foreign direct investment and economic growth. Technology plays an important role in this arena as well. Today, information and communication technologies such as the Internet, satellite TV, and cell phones play an important political and business role in CEE. These technologies help to organize grassroots political parties, promote democracy and reform, as well as facilitate business and economic growth. Technology as a vehicle for growth Technology is an important tool for improving business practices and serves as a vehicle for economic growth. The positive results are best seen after the necessary reforms have taken place. Once the social foundations are in place, all economic growth depends upon improvements in technology. Successful countries go through 3 stages in acquiring technology. In stage 1 they mobilize human and capital resources to fully exploit existing technologies. In stage 2 they copy existing technologies from more advanced countries to catch up. And in Stage 3 they build new industries based upon the advance in knowledge that flow from their own research and development (Thurow, 191). 4 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 CEE countries started in stage 1 in the early 90’s and have been moving toward stage 2. So far, investment in the region has been to take advantage of local resources. The majority of new technology has been transferred from the west, such as computers, management skills, and product knowledge. Computerized information systems improve managerial control, facilitate accounting, and financial reporting, which results in increased efficiency and productivity. From a government’s perspective, improved financial reporting also facilitates taxation of revenue. Latecomers such as Serbia have recently begun introducing computerized cash registers in order to track sales, thereby allowing better “financial policing” (Biberović). The effect of economic reforms and technology became evident early on in Central and Eastern Europe. Privatization and modernization of the banking industry increased electronic transactions and international capital flows. In 1989, securities exchanges began opening across CEE, allowing greater investment in the region. By 1995, 13 countries had stock markets. Figure 1: Stock Exchange Openings in CEE, 1989 – 1995 (www.business2.com) Number of New Stock Exchanges in CEE 4 3 2 1 0 1 1989 2 1990 3 1991 4 1992 Year 5 1993 5 6 1994 7 1995 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Additionally, investments from multinational corporations and joint ventures have been the primary vehicle for technology transfer in the region. As will be discussed further, foreign direct investment is considered to be pure technology transfer. The following examples show the effect that FDI and technology transfer has had: Case in Point: Škoda Škoda started as a private Czech car company in 1925 but was nationalized after WWII in socialist Czechoslovakia. The company fell victim to central planning and lagged behind the rest of the world in R&D and production. During privatization efforts in 1991, a 70% stake in the company was sold to Volkswagen/Audi. This was the FDI that transferred the technology and expertise Škoda needed to catch up with the rest of the world. In 4 years, sales increased 21% and productivity increased 30%. (www.skodaauto.com and C.I.P.E) Technology transfer doesn’t have to be high-tech, but can come in the form of knowledge and expertise, as seen in the East European wine industry. Case in Point: Wine Industry “Now, little by little, whole wine industries – wineries, vineyards, state cellars – are being dismantled and handed over to private owners who need to sell to the west because Eastern export markets have dried up. Much needed European and Australian investment has begun to move in, bringing with it essential expertise to show local winemakers how wine has to be made if it is to sell to Western palates.” (Simon, 150). Similarly, modern information and communication technologies (ICTs) have helped transfer knowledge and learning in transition economies. “The Internet facilitates education, a fundamental underpinning of economic development.” (Cateora, 249). This points to the sustainability of technology, social and political reform and economic progress. Cateora describes additional benefits of ICTs: The cellular phone, the Internet, and other advances in IT open opportunities for emerging economies to catch up with richer ones. […] The Internet accelerates the process of economic growth by speeding up the diffusion of new technologies to emerging economies. […] IT can jump-start national economies and allow them to leapfrog from high levels of illiteracy to computer literacy (249). 6 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Realizing the advantages of a modern IT infrastructure, the Czech Republic approved a comprehensive State Information Policy in 1999 with eight priority areas: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. Information Literacy Information Democracy Development of the Public Administration Information Systems Communications Infrastructure Reliability and Security of Information Systems and Personal Data Protection Electronic Commerce Transparent Economic Environment The Information Society, ‘Stable and Safe’ (Czech Republic, 1) Comparing Progress During the first decade of transition (1990-2000), the efforts of CEE countries resulted in winners and laggards. Poland, Slovenia, Slovakia, Hungary, and the Baltics fared well with an average real GDP growth of 4.5%. On the other hand Ukraine, Romania, Bulgaria and other Balkan countries lagged behind with growth rates between -2.3% and 0.2%. Russia’s growth varied widely from -13% in 1991 to 10% in 2000 (Sources of data: Meier and IMF). Since 2000, however, all CEE countries have experienced respectable growth. 2004 was a particularly good year with all GDP growth rates falling between 2.3 and 12.1% (IMF, 209). As Rosser and Meier both discuss, numerous other metrics are used to compare the progress and performance of transition economies: Per capita income, PPP, inflation rate, unemployment, debt and debt ratio Private sector share of GDP; score for privatization, restructuring, prices/competition, trade/foreign exchange, and banks Indicators for transparency, democratic rights, and regulatory burden; Human Development Index, and Gini coefficient Level of Foreign Direct Investment The last metric is of interest here because FDI directly translates to the level of technology use in a transition economy. It is not a coincidence that the countries with the most 7 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 FDI have fared the best economically. A study of 25 CEE countries by Campos and Kinoshita found that “FDI has a positive and significant impact on economic growth” (398). Further, they assert that “FDI directly raises the level of technology in the host economy. […] FDI diffuses knowledge about production methods, product design, and new organizational and managerial techniques.” (401). Perhaps the most important benefit to host-country recipients is the direct and indirect creation of jobs that would otherwise not be created there (Hill, 246). Data on FDI distribution to individual industries in CEE countries is limited. Poland, however, had some relevant data revealing that FDI flows to its ICT industry accounted for 25% and 35% of Poland’s total FDI in 1999 and 2000, which was more than any other industry (Source: UNTCAD). Conglomerate sectoral data on FDI distribution is more prevalent. The Center for European Integration Studies indicates that between 1989 and 2002 the largest percentage of FDI to CEE was directed to sectors classified as “high tech” and “mediumhigh tech”. The FDI flows to these sectors accounted for 44% to 55% of total FDI in the region (Resmini, 8). These sectors included industries such as aerospace, pharmaceuticals, information & communication technologies, automotive, chemicals and heavy machinery. During that same period, average annual GDP growth in CEE as a whole improved from 0.9% to 4.4% (IMF, 209). Although a detailed analysis would need to be done to be conclusive, this evidence lends weight to the idea that FDI in high-tech industries in particular contributed to growth in Central and Eastern Europe. Another correlation can be seen in FDI flows to individual CEE countries. The countries that received more FDI tended to fare better than others during the first decade of transition. 8 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Figure 2: Foreign Direct Investment in Eastern Europe, US$ millions (Meier, 365) Country Hungary Slovakia Poland Czech Republic Russia Other CIS Baltics Romania Ukraine Slovenia Bulgaria Other Balkans Albania 1990-1995 11,200 7,555 7,148 5,666 4,400 2,300 1,280 933 574 501 412 300 205 1996-2000 12,968 2,150 21,969 15,466 26,960 5,085 1,890 4,017 1,400 3,052 1,428 2,210 583 It is important to note that the reasons some countries receive more foreign investment than others can vary substantially. Determinants of FDI A higher level of Foreign Direct Investment generally means reforms have been implemented, business climate is improving, and investor confidence is rising. Tihanyi and Roath concluded “…the adoption of essential market institutions and the specific norms of regional integration with the European Union [are the] most important determinants.” (188). On the other hand, Campos and Kinoshita maintain “…the determinants of FDI are rather different across transition economies.” (414). They agree that economic policies worked well in Hungary and Poland, but it was the initial favorable conditions in the Czech Republic and the abundance of natural resources in Russia that determined FDI flows (Campos, 414). Regardless of the reason, their study found that: …in the context of the transition economies FDI has a positive impact on the annual rates of economic growth. This finding is robust after we instrument FDI in order to account for the variety of determinants in different transition economies. Irrespective of whether FDI is attracted by good policies or favorable initial conditions, the positive effect on growth rates seems to hold. (Campos, 414) 9 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Furthermore, Campos and Kinoshita tested for “reverse causality” or the possibility that fast growing countries attract more FDI. They found that this was not the case in CEE transition economies (411). But FDI alone does not guarantee a successful transition. The amount of investment by itself does not explain the success of Slovenia with modest FDI and the mixed results in Russia with heavy FDI, especially in the last decade. This is likely due to the fact that there are many other factors that affect economic growth and transition status. The relative success of transitions has also been influenced by the following: State of the economy before the transition. o Type of socialist economy – command, worker-managed, market, etc. Stability o Internal politics, legal system, corruption, mafia, security/law enforcement. o Pace and effectiveness of political, social, and economic reforms – Poland (“shock therapy”), Hungary (gradual). o Business and investment climate, level of IP protection o War and/or economic sanctions Geography, history and culture (proximity to Western Europe). Regional Alliances o Visegrád Group “V4”: Poland, Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Hungary. 1991 cooperation to move toward free market reforms. o OMX Group: Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania joined Denmark, Sweden and Finland in Baltic Sea regional securities exchange. o Free trade agreements among various CEE countries. Factor Endowments/Comparative advantage. State of the Western European and world economies due to interdependence and availability of cash for investment in CEE. Given the difficulty and complexity of transforming a country’s economic system, it is not surprising that transitions have taken well over a decade and will continue for years. However, it begs the question, “When is a transition complete?” Different economists have had varying responses to this question. János Kornai “declared it completed if a country is no longer a one-party state, most of its enterprises are privately owned, and the market is the dominant force in decision-making” (Rosser, 76). Marie Lavigne believes it is complete when a country 10 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 joins the EU while others believe this is an unanswerable question and transitions will never be completed (Rosser, 76). Depending on the point of view, the transitions of some CEE countries can be considered over, especially the ones that were admitted to the EU on May 1, 2004 – the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia, and Slovenia. Obstacles to reform Several things have hindered CEE countries in their efforts to transition to market economies. Remnants of the Communist party still exist throughout CEE and work to subvert reform efforts. This may have been more true in countries that implemented gradual transitions. Governments “that took the slow road permitted the bureaucrats from communist days to organize effectively to delay and even derail the transition to a market economy” (Cateora, 263). (Although the slow road didn’t seemed to slow down Hungary’s success). However, in lagging transition economies lingering socialist institutions have been a problem. “…the socialist past, especially the separation of research and development from production, is an important obstacle to technological progress […] In order to integrate research and production, socialist institutions need to be transformed or abolished while new ones have to be created.” (Lankhuizen, 9) In addition, crime and corruption increased in some CEE countries during their transition due to the power vacuum that was created when the government collapsed. This environment inherently encouraged growth in the “informal sector.” Black market “informal economies” existed before the transition period to circumvent a non-functional economic system, but likely increased later out of desperation. “The informal sector has grown fast in transition economies to the point that it accounts for more than half of national output in the most extreme cases.” (Campos, 406). This represents a significant loss of tax revenue for governments – money that could have been used for development. 11 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Another problem has been the lack of intellectual property (IP) protection in some CEE countries, which has had a negative impact on FDI: “…weak [IP] protection deters foreign investors in technology-intensive sectors that rely heavily on intellectual property rights” (Javorcik, 39). It is safe to say that the countries that do more to protect IP should receive more FDI. All of these obstacles create unfavorable conditions for business and economic growth, but some countries worry that FDI itself may have a negative impact on their economies. As Hill points out, FDI may have adverse effects on the host country. “Three costs of FDI concern host countries. They arise from possible adverse effects on competition within the host nation, adverse effects on the balance of payments, and the perceived loss of national sovereignty and autonomy” (Hill, 251). These concerns could eventually be alleviated if investment and technology begins to come from the home country instead of the west. In the future: Technology as a revenue source Even though the former Eastern Bloc countries were industrialized before the transition, they are not at the top rung of the “Ladder of Comparative Advantage” (Meier, 49). They have what Meier refers to as a “natural comparative advantage [which] is related to Ricardian and HO-type of goods that have a cost-based type of advantage.” (Meier, 49). Multinational Corporations have been investing in CEE to capitalize on the region’s resources and endowments. The factor endowments of CEE countries include natural resources, low-cost but educated/skilled workforce, and an existing industrial/supplier base. Much of the industrial equipment and infrastructure in CEE countries was outdated by the early 90’s. “Technological progress has been extremely limited, and much of the productive technology is internationally noncompetitive” (Meier, 339). FDI to upgrade infrastructure and typical capital equipment with modern computer-controlled mills and lathes would improve the 12 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 quality and efficiency in manufacturing. In addition to low labor costs, this makes the prospect of sourcing manufacturing work in CEE countries more attractive to western companies. In this way, technology transfer can strengthen existing comparative advantage. Furthermore, as FDI and subsequent technology transfer increases, so will learning and domestic research and development. This “home-grown” indigenous technology will eventually help CEE countries move up the ladder to “the higher rungs of ‘acquired’ comparative advantage related to Porter- and Krugman-type of goods that have a product-based type of advantage. A good example of this is the up-and-coming Romanian software industry. Conclusion Technology in various forms has played a critical role in the Central and Eastern Europe’s transition from socialist to capitalist economies. “Simple” technologies helped bring down the Soviet Union by increasing government transparency and spreading information rapidly. Once political, economic, and social reforms began to take place across CEE, foreign direct investment and the transfer of modern technologies facilitated economic growth in the region. Initial transition efforts resulted in winners and laggards throughout CEE, but today all countries seem to be progressing. Thus far, technology transferred from the west has diffused knowledge and expertise, increased efficiency and productivity, and strengthened comparative advantage. In time however, CEE countries will begin to develop their own technology, which can lead to a sustainable and prosperous future. 13 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 References Biberović, Radisav. Comptroller for the City of Niš, Serbia and Montenegro. Personal interview: January 1, 2005. Business 2.0. “Stock Exchanges in Eastern Europe and Central Asia.” <http://www.business2.com/b2/webguide/0,17811,9399,00.html> Campos, Nauro and Kinoshita, Yuko. “Foreign Direct Investment as Technology Transferred: some panel evidence from the transition economies.” The Manchester School. Manchester: Jun 2002, Vol. 70, Iss. 3, pg. 398, 22 pp. Cateora, Philip and Graham, John. International Marketing. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, New York: 2005. Center for International Private Enterprise. “Skoda’s Recipe for Success.” Economic Reform Today. Number 4, 1995. Czech Republic. “State Information Policy.” Government Resolution No. 525, May 31, 1999. Resmini, Laura. Agglomeration and FDI in Central and Eastern European Countries: Facts and Figures. Center for European Integration Studies, Work package No. 4, 10 Jan 2005. < http://www.zei.de/eurec/WP4_Summary.pdf> Henderson, David. “Information Technology as a Universal Solvent for Removing State Stains.” The Independent Review. Vol. 4, Number 4, Spring 2000. Hill, Charles. International Business. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, New York: 2005. International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook. April 2005. <http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2005/01/index.htm> Javorick, Beata Smarzynska. “The composition of foreign direct investment and protection of intellectual property rights: evidence from transition economies.” European Economic Review. Amsterdam: Feb 2004, Vol. 48, Iss. 1, pg. 39. Lankhuizen, Maureen. “Shifts in foreign trade, competitiveness and growth potential: From Baltics to ‘Bal-techs’?” Research Policy. Amsterdam: Jan 2000, Vol.29, Iss. 1, pg. 9. Shane, Scott. Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union. Ivan R. Dee, Inc. Chicago: 1994. Simon, Joanna. Discovering Wine. Fireside/Simon & Schuster, New York: 1994. 14 Jon Campbell MGMT 6730 April 18, 2005 Thurow, Lester. Fortune Favors the Bold. HarperCollins, New York: 2003. Tihanyi, Laszlo and Roath, Anthony. “Technology Transfer and Institutional Development in Central and Eastern Europe.” Journal of World Business. Greenwich: Autumn, 2002. Vol. 37, Iss. 3, pp 188 – 198. Yergin, Daniel and Stanislaw, Joseph. The Commanding Heights: The Battle for the World Economy. Touchstone, New York: 2002. Škoda Auto. “History of the Company.” <http://www.skoda-auto.com/global/history/company/> United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNTCAD). FDI Country Profiles: Poland. <http://www.unctad.org/Templates/Page.asp?intItemID=3198&lang=1> The World Bank. <http://www.worldbank.org> 15