The Political Economy of the Maoist Conflict in India: An Empirical Analysis Preliminary Draft March 2011 Joseph Flavian Gomes Department of Economics Universidad Carlos III de Madrid Office: 11.2.32 Phone: 91 624 9320 Email: jgomes@eco.uc3m.es Abstract Papers using cross country aggregate data abound in the literature on civil conflicts. However, such cross country studies have some inherent limitations: data might not be comparable across countries; reasons for conflict might vary from country to country; conflicts are often localized and depend on unequal spatial distribution of resources within the country. Using aggregate data is also problematic, because conflicts might be due to individual-level or group-level characteristics. This paper contributes to a small but burgeoning literature that uses sub-national micro data to identify the causes of civil conflicts. In particular, we study the Maoist/Naxalite conflict in India by constructing a comprehensive district level database using conflict data from four different terrorism databases and combining to it socioeconomic and geography data from myriad sources. In addition to exploiting the within country regional heterogeneity, we use the micro structure of the data to construct grouplevel characteristics. Using data on 362 districts for 3 time periods, we find evidence on how land inequality is extremely important for the Maoist conflict. We also show how historical property rights institutions from colonial times that go back centuries can affect present day conflict outcomes through their impact on economic outcomes, social relations and the political environment in the district. Finally, making use of the micro structure of the data we are able to ask whether exclusion of the low castes and tribal people from the growth story of India is important. At best we get mixed evidence on this. While incomes of lower castes and tribal communities impact the number of Maoist incidents, they do not affect the probability of conflict. 1 1 Introduction In recent years the relation between economic performance and civil conflicts has generated a considerable amount of interest among economists. Not surprisingly within the span of a few years a lot has been written on the subject 1 . This paper contributes to two different strands of the literature. The first strand is the research using sub-national-micro data exploiting the spatial heterogeneity within a country and the micro characteristics of the data to pin down the causes of civil conflict (in contrast to the literature that uses cross country regressions for the same). The second strand falls in a broad class of literature that traces divergences in current economic outcomes to differences in historical institutions in a country 2 . The focus is on one specific country - India and one specific conflict - The Maoist conflict (aka the Naxalite conflict). We use district level conflict data for the period 1979-2009 along with socio-economic and geography data from multiple NSS sample surveys, Censuses etc. to build a district level dataset. Finally using this dataset on 362 districts (for the 16 main states) for three time periods this paper provides evidence on how land inequality is one of the key determinants of the Maoist conflict controlling for all other factors that the literature has found to be important. Moreover, there is evidence on how class antagonism driven by land institutions that have lingered for centuries also has a significant impact on the conflict. The Maoist conflict in India has existed for more than 40 years (since 1967). However, it has seen a terrifying increase in proportions only in the last decade 3 . In the period 2004-2010 there have been more than 5000 lives lost (by official estimates). Including the number of wounded and displaced the figure would be many times higher. In fact, it has been identified as ”the single biggest security challenge to the Indian state” by Dr. Manmohan Singh, the Prime Minister of India. Indeed such a conflict if not tackled on a timely and efficient manner, could have enormous negative socio-economic consequences. Such violence often leads to the destruction of existing infrastructure and discourages investment, apart from the loss in human capital. A good part of the civil conflict literature finds underdevelopment as a primary determinant of civil conflict. If the conflict indeed is mostly located in the more impoverished regions of the country, the existence of such a conflict would give a further adverse shock to the economy of the region. Moreover, if the conflict intensity rises unabated (like it has in the past few years) for too long a period, then it could eventually negatively affect the growth that India is currently experiencing. And this would be a consequence over and above the tremendous direct human suffering that such conflicts inevitably cause. All this makes the Maoist conflict a serious issue and calls for an in-depth analysis identifying its causes and suggesting potential policy interventions. We believe that there is no work (to the best of our knowledge) in the existing literature that does an in-depth empirical analysis of the Maoist conflict in India using a district level panel. 4 . In fact, even some of the studies that look specifically on India have focussed more on the several communal riots between the Hindus and the Muslims that the country has experienced over the 1 See Blattman and Miguel (2010) for a recent survey of the existing literature. 2 A very novel concept in the conflict literature: Jha (2008) for example, associates the Hindu-Muslim conflicts in India to historical institutions. 3 see figure in appendix 4 Barooah (2008) studies the Naxalite conflict, but that study relies on a simple cross section analysis 2 years. Fortunately, such conflicts have seen a general decline in India in the recent years. 5 This makes the analysis of the Maoist conflict even more interesting since one would not be tempted to wrongly conclude that perhaps the law and order situation in the country has deteriorated leading to more violence and conflict. The existing literature has witnessed several different approaches to empirically identify the causes of civil conflicts. There are two clear directions in which this literature needs progress. The first direction is using sub-national micro data in order to overcome the short comings of the cross country analyses. Cross country studies on civil conflicts abound in the literature. Collier and Hoeffler (2004), Fearon and Laitin (2003) for example, do cross-country regressions trying to identify the variables that impact conflict probabilities. Miguel et al. (2004) and Ciccone (2010) on the other hand, look at variation in conflict intensity due to economic shocks instrumented by weather shocks. However, such cross country studies usually suffer from some serious shortcomings. Do and Iyer (2009) point out two caveats that apply to the use of cross country data: (1) Data might not be comparable across countries. (2) Reasons for the conflict might vary from country to country. 6 In fact, cross country studies do not allow us to control for all the factors that are constant within the country viz. the macroeconomic variables and they ignore the within country heterogeneity by treating the country as a unit of observation. This is a serious shortcoming since conflicts are often localized and depend on the unequal spatial distribution of resources within the country. For example, if we look at the Maoist conflict in India, in West Bengal which is one of the severely affected states (located in the east of the country), the conflict is very pronounced in the Midnapore and Puruliya districts while it is completely absent in districts like Howrah, North & South 24 Parganas. 7 This is the kind of heterogeneity that one cannot take into account using even states as units of analysis. Thus, using countries as the units of analysis could be pretty unsatisfactory. In addition, ”the country level of analysis has [other] inherent limitations. Individual and group level conflict factors such as poverty and ethnic hostility are imperfectly tested at the national level” (Blattman and Miguel (2010) from Sambanis (2004)). Indeed, tribal and low caste participation in the Maoist conflict has been much talked about, suggesting that perhaps some sections of society are losing behind in the growth story of India leading to more tension. 8 Moreover, the sudden rise in the conflict levels from 2005 onwards is even more surprising given that the country has been experiencing above 8% growth rates in the same period. The use of micro data could be particularly helpful in this regard in order to identify if there is regional and group level heterogeneity in the growth rates and development that might explain this rise. Thus, as Blattman and Miguel (2010) puts it ”... the most promising avenue for new empirical research is on the sub-national scale, analysing conflict causes, conduct, and consequences at the level of armed groups, communities and individuals”. 5 see Iyer (2009) for a study of all conflicts in South Asia 6 Further, even within a country focussing on one specific conflict might give us more interesting insights than looking at overall violence. 7 Again, if one looks at Maharashtra (which is a state located in the West of the country), almost all the Maoist incidents have been concentrated solely in the Gadchiroli district (formerly part of the Chandrapur district). Again, while the conflict affects virtually all the districts of Bihar, it is almost completely absent in the states of Rajasthan, Punjab and Haryana. 8 Chattisgarh for example, a predominatly tribal state is one of the hotbeds of the conflict. 3 Part of the lack of sub-national level studies has been of course due to the unavailability of reliable sub-national data and/or the tedious task of building such datasets. However, recent times have witnessed a small but burgeoning literature that seeks the causes of civil conflicts using sub national micro data with some very interesting insights 9 . Do and Iyer (2009) for example study the Maoist Conflict in Nepal using a district level dataset comprising economic, social and geography variables and show how the lack of economic opportunities trigger such conflicts while suitable geographic conditions help perpetuate it once the conflict has started. However, ethnic and caste polarization, land inequality and political participation don’t affect violence. Jha (2008) does a town level study of India focussing on the Hindu-Muslim communal conflicts. His primary conclusion is that historical institutions determine peaceful coexistence or conflict between Hindus and Muslims. Bohlken and Sergenti (2009) do a state level study of the same Hindu-Muslim riots and find local economic conditions as a significant determinant of such communal riots in India. Iyer (2009) looks at all terrorist incidents in the Indian subcontinent and infers that lagging regions are more prone to conflicts. For India and Nepal she runs district level regressions. She points out that on the whole terrorist incidents have been on the rise over the years in the Indian subcontinent with the lagging regions more prone to it. Moreover, making use of the district level regressions she shows that it is the lagging districts in India and Nepal that are more prone to conflicts than others. Looking only at the aggregate country level for example would have deprived us of this insight. Thus from the above interesting conclusions it is evident how micro level studies are a clear advance over the cross country studies. The other critical issue in this literature is establishing a causal relation between conflict levels and its determinants. This is due to two main problems 10 (1) There might exist unmeasured factors that affect both conflict intensity and pre conflict characteristics. (2) Districts that are experiencing more violence might also be districts that have experienced high past conflict. Recent studies have tried to address this issue using an Instrumental variable approach when clearly exogenous instruments have been available. Miguel et al. (2004) and Ciccone (2010) have used weather shocks. Dube and Vargas (2008) have used exogenous shocks to agricultural and resource prices. When clear instruments have not been available authors have tried to use data on covariates from the pre conflict levels (Do and Iyer (2009); Mitra and Ray (2010)), in order to prevent endogeneity arising out of reverse causality. Also, all potential covariates are controlled for in order to reduce endogeneity arising out of omitted variables. Following in the same vein in this paper we (i) Use data from the pre conflict period; (ii) Control for all possible variables (that the literature suggests are important) that might play a role subject to the data availability (iii) Always control for the presence of past conflict (iv) also at least try to run some IV regressions where possible with previous period income as IV for present income. Apart from the above mentioned points, this paper has another important contribution. It traces the origins of civil conflict to a new channel over and above the channels like underdevelopment and geography already identified in the literature. We see how historical colonial institutions from centuries ago can impact conflict outcomes in the present times. In this context Jha (2008) has a very interesting insight in his paper. He does a town level study of India focussing on the Hindu-Muslim communal conflicts. His primary conclusion is that historical institutions deter9 10 e.g. Dube and Vargas (2008), Do and Iyer (2009), Jha (2008), Bohlken and Sergenti (2009) from Do and Iyer (2009) 4 mine peaceful coexistence or conflict between Hindus and Muslims. In the presence of a historical complementarily between the two groups the probability of conflict is lower. Besley and Persson (2008) on the other hand highlight the importance of political institutions in explaining conflict outcomes. While their main conclusion is that higher market prices of exported and imported primary commodities have a positively significant effect on the incidence of civil conflict, they find that those effects are heterogeneous depending on the quality of political institutions in the country 11 . There is indeed a huge amount of literature showing how historical Institutions have a persistent effect on current economic performance. Acemoglu et al. (2001, 2002), show how institutions developed centuries ago determine the development or underdevelopment of countries in the present times. La Porta et al. (1998, 1999, 2000) also trace the differences in the economic performance of a country to its colonial origin. Their conclusion is that the legal system of a country is determined by whether the country was colonized by the British or other colonial powers and this difference in legal systems affects the economic performance of the country. Engerman and Sokoloff (1997, 2002) also trace the divergence in the growth rates of Brazil and the USA to the history induced divergence in institutions. Following in the same vein, Banerjee and Iyer (2005) show that the colonial land revenue institutions set up by the British in India, lead to sustained differences in economic outcomes in the post independence period. Areas in which proprietary rights in land were historically given to landlords have significantly lower agricultural investments and productivity in the post-independence period than areas in which these rights were given to the cultivators. These areas also have significantly lower investments in health and education. In fact, these land revenue institutions created some social divisions that continued to undermine economic progress way into the future since, ”... the memory real or imagined, of having been exploited, can create a divide that can continue to hurt the economy many years into the future”. The allocation of land revenue collection responsibility to the landlords (which translates into a de facto property right over the land) gave birth to a reason for perpetual conflict between the peasants and landlords. ”Elsewhere, the colonial state directly collected the land revenue from the cultivator, thereby avoiding this particular source of internecine conflict” (Banerjee and Somanathan (2007)). These historical institutions could affect the conflict both, through their effects on the economic outcomes, or directly through their effects on the social relations among people. Economic underdevelopment has been associated with higher conflict in the literature. As Banerjee and Iyer (2005) have shown, the landlord areas 12 are also the areas with worse economic outcomes and thus they could be experiencing more conflict via the underdevelopment channel. Moreover, landlords areas might still have a more unequal land distribution which might potentially incite social tensions. 13 ”However, districts with worse land distribution historically have also seen more land reforms in the post independence period. This makes it unlikely that the persistence of the landlord effect is mainly through its effect on contemporaneous land distribution.” ”However, as late as 1990, 64% of all landholdings in the landlord areas were classified as ”marginal” (less than 1 hectare) which is about 1 % point higher than the NL [non-landlord] districts. Further 48 % of all holdings are small to midsized (1-10 hectares) in individual based areas, but 11 i.e. whether the country is a parliamentary democracy, or has a system of strong checks and balances 12 from now on we will refer to the areas where historically the revenue collection rights were given to landlords as the landlord areas 13 see figures in appendix for differences in land inequality between Maoist and non Maoist districts. 5 only 35% in landlord areas. However, there is no significant difference in proportion of extremely large holdings, probably due to land ceiling laws passed post independence.” Banerjee and Iyer (2005) The historical institutions could also have a direct impact on the conflict. ”The class based antagonism that [the land revenue institutions] created within the communities in these areas has persisted well into the post independence period” Banerjee and Iyer (2005). Thus, in effect the class antagonism might have survived even after land reforms might have reduced land inequality. ”Areas most associated with Maoist uprisings are WB, Bihar & Srikakulam district of AP- all landlord areas. Paul R. Brass (1994 pg. 326-327) argues explicitly that these peasant movement have their roots in the history of exploitation and oppression of peasants by landlords.” (Banerjee and Iyer (2005)) Thus, there are reasons to believe that the Land institutions have an effect on the conflict over and above the effect through the contemporaneous land inequality and underdevelopment.In this paper we thus test for the direct effect of the Landlord institutions on the Conflict outcomes. If we do not include the direct effect of the Land Institutions variable, we will have problems due to the omitted variable since as we will see later the Land Institutions variable indeed comes out to be significant. Thus, to summarize, this paper makes the following contributions to the existing literature. (1) It adds to a small but burgeoning literature that uses regional level micro data to study civil conflict, which is a clear progress over existing cross country literature. It is also one of the very first attempts to put together district level data from a variety of sources in order to analyze civil conflicts rigorously. Moreover, exploiting the micro characteristics of the data we are able to ask some interesting questions about whether exclusion from growth of certain sections has an impact on the conflict. (2) It is the first to analyze rigorously the Maoist conflict in India which has turned out to be a very serious problem. Moreover, India is a really interesting case since it is a fast growing economy and the success of its economic ambitions determine the fate of one third of the world’s poor that it is home to. (3) It shows that in addition economic underdevelopment, how Land relations and historical institutions within a country could lead to conflicts. In the next section we add a small discussion on the Maoist Conflict in India, in section 3 we list the main hypotheses of the study. Section 4 discusses the data, section 5 the econometric results and section 6 concludes. 2 The Maoist/Naxalite Conflict Overall there are five major sources of conflicts/violence in India 14 : • Maoist/Naxalite/left wing extremism , • Hindu- Muslim communal conflicts, • Separatist movements in the North Eastern states, • Islamic fundamentalist terrorism, 14 see Iyer (2009) for a discussion on the different sources of violence in India and the rest of South Asia 6 • The Kashmir conflict. Only the first three of the above five can be termed as ”Civil” conflict in the true sense of the term. Pure acts of terrorism like the Mumbai terrorist attacks originating from Islamic fundamentalist groups often coming from across the border is now an international problem. The Kashmir problem has been more of a territorial dispute. Thus, both these issues would require a very different analysis from that of conflicts or unrests arising from within the country. The Separatist movements in the North-East are important and interesting but they also require a separate analysis since they are more secessionist in nature (unlike the Maoist conflict). 15 Moreover, over the last decades progress has been made in solving some of the disputes in the North-East and violence has reduced significantly. The Hindu-Muslim communal conflicts have already been studied by various authors in considerable detail and have also been on a declining trend over the years 16 . The Maoist conflict has on the other hand seen a huge increase in intensity over the last decade and is the focus of this paper. The start of the conflict is marked by a peasant uprising in the year 1967 in Naxalbari (whence the term Naxalite), a small village in West Bengal. ”A tribal youth having obtained a judicial order went to plough his land on 2 March 1967. The local landlords attacked him with the help of their goons. Tribal [peasants] of that area retaliated and started forcefully recapturing their land” (Kujur (2008)). The rebellion left nine tribal people and one police personnel dead and the Naxalite movement in India was born. The rebellion itself was contained by government forces within 72 days with the use of force, but had already gathered huge visibility from Communist revolutionaries from across the country. After West Bengal the movement spread to the state of Andhra Pradesh where the formation of the People’s War Group (PWG) in 1980 marks the revival of the movement post the Naxalbari uprising. It has since then spread across various states in India including Bihar, Jharkhand, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Chhattisgarh, Maharashtra and Karnataka across many districts and has existed in varying degrees across the country 17 . However, it was the 2004 merger of the PWG with the Maoist Communist Center (MCC) that lead to the formation of the Communist Party of India-Maoist (CPI-Maoist) that marks the modern revival of the movement and followed a huge rise in insurgency and violence thereafter. While the term ”Naxalite” comes from the place of birth of the movement the term ”Maoist” is used due to the Maoist ideologies that many of these rebel groups adhere too. The CPI-Maoists for example claim to be committed to a ”democratic revolution” through ”a protracted peoples war with the armed seizure of power remaining as its central and principal task” (SATP; Iyer (2009)). While the conflict as a whole has been termed as a Maoist/Naxalite conflict, the movement itself is hardly homogenous. It has in fact, always had a fragmented structure with multiple groups operating without a centralized Movement organization. Different issues like control of common property resources, better wages and housing, protection of land ownership etc, have also been taken up on a timely basis in different places. While in some small pockets of India like the Dantewada district in Chattisgarh the movement has reached a war like situation with constant terror and violence on a daily basis, the entire movement has not always nor everywhere been violent. ”Common forms of nonviolent 15 Also, there is severe lack of good quality data for the North East India. 16 Bohlken and Sergenti (2009), Mitra and Ray (2010), Jha (2008) are some of the more recent studies 17 see map in appendix 7 action include sabha (meeting), bandh (closure), aarthik nakebandi (economic boycott), samajik bahishkar (social boycott), jan adalat (people’s court), dharnas (e.g., the 14-day dharna organised by Liberation in Ara against Ranbeer Sena in 1995), gheraos (e.g., the famous gherao of the state assembly after the Arwal massacre in 1986), rallies (including silent marches, torch processions, and more), chakkajaam (road blocks), putla dahan (effigy burning), and of course strikes. Even hunger strikes have figured in this rainbow of agitations ...... Cultural media (sanskritik madhyam) such as songs and plays have an important role in mobilisation, especially since a large majority of the people in central Bihar are illiterate. Often the songs are made by people themselves and convey their existing reality with great poignancy” (Bhatia (2005)). However, figures suggest that at least in the last five years the violent part of the movement has taken precedence, making the analysis of the conflict ever more crucial. In 2011 alone, by March, 13 already 116 people had been killed due to the conflict (SATP). There are various estimates of the severity of the conflict from a variety of official and unofficial sources. 18 Even according to the official source of the Government of India there have been more than 5000 lives lost (civilians, rebels and security personnel) and more than 12000 incidents of violence in the period of 2004-2010 due to the Naxalite conflict. The number of people displaced in Chhattisgarh alone was more than 43000, end of 2006. Moreover, the geographical spread of the conflict has seen a phenomenal increase from 55 districts in eight states in 2003 to 194 districts spread across 18 states in 2007 (SATP; Iyer (2009)). ”While it is difficult to put an exact figure to the number of rebels, there is an estimated 10000 to 20000 full time fighters with countless thousands of village militias controlling particularly remote jungle areas where the state is hardly present. On April 6th, 2010 several hundred Maoist guerrillas attacked a convoy in a forest in eastern Chhattisgarh state, killing 76 armed policemen. This was reckoned to be the worst loss in the stuttering, four-decade-long conflict” (The Economist). While the death and injured toll looks grim, the other crucial issue is the divergence of development funds to the Maoists. ”Nitish Kumar (the chief minister of Bihar) is among the few who actually put a figure to it; he estimates that the Maoists in his state pull in Rs.150 crore a year-not counting the cost of outright looting of money and snatching of arms and ammunition from security forces..... Raman Singh (the Chief Minister of Chattisgarh) ....estimates Rs.100 crore from Bastar, the Dandakaranya state within his state.” (Chakravarti (2008)) Surprisingly however, there is no in-depth empirical analysis of the Maoist conflict. The conflict is perhaps best understood through the various case studies that exist on the issue. Many of these studies are concentrated on particular states identifying the nature and causes of the conflict in that state through field studies, interviews of local people, and talks with Maoist leaders and cadres etc. Bhatia (2005) for example provides an analysis of the nature, causes and outcomes of the conflict in the context of Central Bihar. While her analysis focuses exclusively on Central Bihar the key insights she brings out could well be true for the rest of the country as well. She identifies three distinct albeit inter-related classes of reasons behind the entire Naxalite movement viz. (1) Economic rights (2) Social rights (3) Political rights. The most important economic issues that have been taken up by the movement as identified by Bhatia are as follows: (1) land rights; (2) minimum wages; (3) common property resources; and (4) housing. The Government of India in its own study recognizes the following socio economic factors behind the discontent of people and support to Naxalism: Land related factors, Displacement & Forced 18 see appendix for some of the estimates. 8 evictions, Livelihood, Social Oppression, (apart from the socio economic reasons the GOI also mentions issues arising out of bad governance and policing)(Government of India (2008). Land rights are indeed one of the most important issues taken up by the Naxalites: Khet par adhikar ke liye ladho, desh mai janwad ke liye badho (Fight for land rights, march towards democracy in the country - Liberation (a Naxalite group) slogan) (Bhatia, 2005). ”[Indeed the] focus of the Naxalite movement is on trying to provide land, whether the land of landlords or government land, to the landless. In fact, as pointed above the ’Naxalite’ term is itself derived from the peasant uprising arising out of land disputes in Naxalbari. However, there are instances of such struggle even later and elsewhere in the country. ”[For example in Bhojpur, Bihar,] Jagdish Mahato, a local teacher who had forged links with Naxalite leaders from West Bengal, led a protracted struggle against exploitative landlords” (Bhatia (2005)). While the inequality in land distribution and the strife between big landowners and landless peasants seems to very important in Bihar and West Bengal, in Chhattisgarh the strife between poor tribal landowners and the state seems to be more important. As Bahree (2010) puts it ”There is a proxy war underway in India’s interior- a bloody conflict raging over that rare and valuable commodity in this too crowded country: land. On one side, powerful rebel groups claim to be fighting for the poor-farmers and small agrarian tribes in particular. On the other side, the government is locking up land and the resources buried beneath it (particularly coal and bauxite) for some of India’s biggest private companies”. Some areas where the conflict is really intense like Bastar while are economically impoverished regions, are very rich in mineral resources” (Bahree (2010)). ”Campaigners say that the reason why the government has opened a new front in this battle lies beneath Chhattisgarh’s fertile soil, which contains some of the country’s richest reserves of iron ore, coal, limestone and bauxite. Above live some of India’s most impoverished people: semi-literate tribes who exist in near destitution. India’s biggest companies have moved stealthily into the forest areas, buying up land and acquiring the rights to extract the buried wealth” (The Guardian 2006). ”People are fighting against land acquisitions and the government is labelling them Naxals and then using that to suppress them. .... If the Naxals were not there, the government would be able to acquire more land for the private sector” (Sundar (2008)). In fact, regardless of the ideologies of the different Maoist factions in practice land redistribution has remained one of the main goals of the movement. This is as evident from the failed peace talks between the Andhra Pradesh government and the PWG in 2004 where this was one of the main issues (Iyer, 2009). Underdevelopment has also been seen as one of the key reasons behind the rebellion. ”Even if there was no truth behind the accusations that poor tribes are being exploited and are being illegally disposed of their lands, it is fairly certain that the Naxalites are feeding on the festering discontent of the impoverished and marginalized tribal communities. According to the 2001 census for example, about three quarters of Dantewada’s 1,220 villages are almost wholly tribal; 1,161 have no medical facilities; 214 have no primary school; the literacy rate is 29% for men and 14% for women” (The Economist, 2006). As far as the participation is concerned, ”...the social base of the movement ...... consists overwhelmingly of the landless, small peasants with marginal landholdings, and to a lesser extent middle peasants. In caste terms, the base of the movement consists of lower and intermediate castes” (Bhatia, 2005). The fight against the social oppression that the dalits [lower castes] and the lower among the OBCs [other backward castes] have been regularly subjected to is perhaps 9 the most significant among the issues used by the Naxalite movement” (GOI, 2008). Given the above discussion on the Naxalite conflict we now come to the main hypotheses of the study. 3 The Main Hypotheses The literature speaks of a variety of different factors that might lead to civil conflicts. ”Civil Wars are more likely to occur in countries that are poor, are subject to negative income shocks, have weak state institutions, have sparsely populated peripheral regions and possess mountainous terrain” (Blattman and Miguel (2010)). Some of the other factors that have been mentioned in the literature are, Ethnic and religious diversity and fragmentation, lack of democracy and civil liberties, linguistic and religious discrimination, inequality, new states and political instability, geographical factors like mountains and non-contiguous territory, population pressure, colonial occupation, weak state institutions etc. 19 In this study we try to identify which factors might be more relevant in the context of the Naxalite conflict in India. Thus, combining the findings from the previous literature and our understanding of the conflict we test for different hypotheses. Hypothesis 1: Land inequality increases conflict. Following up from the discussion in the previous section we think that land issues are crucial. Land inequality and exploitation of the landless/poor farmers by the wealthy landlords has been attributed to be one of the most important causes of the Naxalite movement. In fact, that’s how it started in the first place. ”Land is a very strategic socio-economic asset, particularly in poor societies where wealth and survival are measured by control of, and access to, land” (USAID (2005)). Moreover, land often has valuable natural resources buried beneath it. In a predominantly agrarian economy, the importance of land cannot be overemphasized and survival of the poor often depends on their access to land. There is in fact, empirical evidence on the importance of land on conflicts from elsewhere in the world as well. Andre and Platteau (1996) study a highly densely populated area in the Northwest of Rwanda during the period 1988-93 and find how the land distribution had become increasingly unequal and land dispossession rampant. They further show that pervasive incidence of land disputes and the threat of landlessness had led to rising tensions in social relations. They relate these adverse conditions in land distribution to the civil conflict that broke out in 1994. Verwimp (2003) offers an empirical analysis of the peasant participation in the Rwandan genocide. He uses data from pre-genocide agricultural survey sample and builds a panel dataset. He finds that the genocide perpetrators comprised mostly of poor wage workers and land renters, while the victims were primarily from the landlord class. There are several potential ways in which the land distribution could affect the conflict. A highly skewed land distribution also reflects higher disparities in the social and economic lives of the people and thus a higher potential for grievance. Moreover, if the distribution is too unequal and dominated by a few large landlords while the vast majority being small and landless then there is an additional source of problem. In a growing India the government is trying to acquire land for a variety of purposes including industrialization, mining or building dams. In case of land acquisition by the government while the entire community is adversely affected the compensation 19 See Fearon and Laitin (2003) for a discussion. 10 mostly or fully goes to the big landlords who to start with enjoy a higher socio-economic status, while the vast majority of the affected are left uncompensated. Moreover, it is also common that tribal people in remote places have been living on a certain plot land for generations but do not have any formal title deeds to the land resulting in no compensation whatsoever in case of acquisition by the government. Thus, the Naxalites are fighting for land issues against both big landlords and the state 20 . Indeed, the land distribution is crucial not only for the Maoist conflict but for the overall health of the rural economy. The Land reforms in India in the post independence period thus sought to directly improve the access to land of the poor households. Besley and Burgess (2000), in state level analysis of the Indian land reforms find that indeed the land reforms have been associated with significant poverty reduction. However, implementation was hardly homogeneous across states. These heterogeneities exist even within states which have witnessed widespread implementation. ”The 3 extreme Maoist districts in West Bengal are West Midnapur, Puruliya, Bankura-where land reforms on the scale affected by the CPI (M) in other parts of the state haven’t taken place.” (Chakravarti, (2008))” Thus, we test to see if indeed more land inequality is associated with more conflict. Hypothesis 2: Underdevelopment leads to more conflict. In other words, districts with higher per capita incomes should experience less conflict. The theoretical idea goes back to Becker (1968) where he argues that rise in returns to crime induces more workers to the criminal sector. In fact, the relation between income and conflict is one of the most robust relations in the empirical literature on conflicts. Both Collier and Hoeffler (1998, 2004) and Fearon and Laitin (2003) for example suggest that lower per capita incomes lead to higher probabilities of conflict. Miguel et al. also demonstrate how negative income shocks lead to higher levels of conflict. Collier and Hoeffler (2004) argues that the opportunity cost of fighting is lower when incomes are low and thus making it easier to recruit rebels. Dube and Vargas (2008) identify two distinct channels through which income shocks affect armed conflict. They argue that higher wages reduce conflict (lower international coffee prices lead to a negative shock to certain regions of Colombia leading to higher conflict levels).This is the opportunity cost channel. If on the other hand the price of natural resources viz. oil goes up it increases the contestable income and thus an increase in the conflict levels. This has been termed as the rapacity effect. In the Indian context the rapacity channel seems to be unlikely since the fighting is not (at least not yet) for a share from resource revenues 21 . Fearon and Laitin (2003) on the other hand argues that lower incomes reflect limited state capacity to put the rebellion down. In other words, low per capita income is an indicator of weak and corrupt governments who might be unable to devise effective counter insurgency policies. Moreover, guerrilla warfare is usually concentrated in remote rural areas where the rebels get suitable conditions to pursue such insurgencies. The favourable conditions that such regions provide include superior knowledge of local conditions and territory by rebels than by government forces, rough mountainous territory or forests providing suitable hideouts to insurgents etc. Even for nations with strong military 20 In a recent hostage incident when a government collector was kidnapped, two of the primary demands of the Maoists were as follows: grant of land rights to tribal people in scheduled areas; minimum displacement of tribals while making space for industries and mining (The Hindu, Feb 22, 2011: Orissa accepts eight Maoist demands: http://www.hindu.com/2011/02/22/stories/2011022264251300.htm). 21 However, indeed the government has boosted up spending on development efforts in the Naxalite affected districts and some of this spending is being siphoned off to Naxalites. But that is a consequence rather than a cause of the conflict. 11 capabilities such conditions could turn out to be pretty daunting (e.g. the US in Vietnam, British in the initial days in Northern Ireland) 22 , for poorer nations with weak military capabilities and corrupt bureaucratic set ups it could be hopeless. Thus, we try to test if lower per capita incomes indeed imply higher conflict levels. 23 Hypothesis 3: Historical land institutions directly impact the conflict. As already discussed in section 1, the allocation of the responsibility of collecting the land revenue to the landlords (which translates into a de facto property right over the land) gave birth to a reason for perpetual conflict between the peasants and landlords. ”Elsewhere, the colonial state directly collected the land revenue from the cultivator, thereby avoiding this particular source of internecine conflict” Banerjee and Somanathan (2007). Moreover, land acquisition for mining purposes, building dams or for private industry is an important issue pursued by the Maoists. Such land acquisition often leads to large scale displacement and loss of livelihood of people. Given adequate compensation people might be less discontent with the displacement induced by land acquisition. In this context, Duflo and Pande (2007) show how the landlord districts do worse than the non-landlord districts as far as effects of dams are concerned. They argue that since the social relation in the landlord districts somehow renders collective action difficult it leads to inadequate compensation. Following the same argument if land is taken away in the landlord districts for industrial, mining or the purposes of building dams, historically people in such districts have less potential for collective action leading to inadequate compensation, which in turn leads to more grievances. This makes for easier Maoist recruits. Thus, we try to test whether the historical property rights institutions have any effect over and above its effects through underdevelopment and land distribution. Hypothesis 4: The presence of disadvantaged castes Scheduled Castes (SC) and Scheduled Tribes (ST)) leads to more conflict. As discussed in the previous section ”the main support for the Naxalite movement comes from dalits (SC) and adivasis (ST) (Government of India (2008)).” In fact, the predominantly tribal areas like Chhattisgarh have experienced higher conflict levels. While the SCs and STs have enjoyed affirmative action in the post independence period, they might still not be economically and socially at par with others. ”There are over 2,00,000 pending cases of atrocities against lower castes in India, and the conviction rate is just a little over 2 percent. ”There are an estimated 162 million untouchables in rural India, according to the National federation of Dalit Land rights movement. 70% of them don’t own land” (Chakravarti (2008)). Thus Caste and tribal identities are important issues that could exacerbate the conflict and we directly test to verify if a higher SC & ST percentage indeed lead to higher conflict. Moreover, if the benefits of the high growth that the country is experiencing are not homogeneous across groups, there is further potential of grievances arising out of feelings of exclusion. ”Some case studies [Sambanis 2005, Frances Stewart 2001] suggest that ’horizontal’ inequality-inequality that coincides with ethnic or other politically salient cleavages-is a particular important driver of civil conflict” Blattman and Miguel (2010).” Thus we test to see how the incomes of the different groups impact the conflict. 22 examples from Fearon and Laitin (2003) 23 In the geographical controls we also include proportion of barren and rocky land which also indicates presence/lack of economic opportunity. 12 Apart from the variables mentioned in the above hypotheses we control for several other variables that the literature suggests to be important. For example, Geographical factors have been found to be important in such a context. Geography determines the cost, time and tactics necessary to curtail and check such activity. Fearon and Laitin (2003) for example find that conditions favouring insurgency like rough terrain increases the likelihood of conflict. We thus control for the geographical factors like percentage of forests, sloping land, sandy land, barren rocky land etc. in the district. We also control for income inequality and size variables like population density, area etc. 24 4 Data Districts are the smallest administrative units in India for which coherent reliable data is available. The idea of the study is to exploit micro data and thus all regressions are at the district level. We use data from the 16 main states in India which is about 90% of the Indian population. The data is pooled from diverse sources. In this section we describe the original sources of the data and also try to justify the use of the different variables. Naxalite/Maoist incidents: The data on the Maoist incidents comes from four different sources: • Global Terrorism Database (GTD) I: 1970-1997 & II: 1998-2004: In fact now there is one consolidated GTD which has data till 2007. • Rand-MIPT Terrorism Incident database (1998- present) • Worlwide Incidents tracking system (WITS), National Counter Terrorism Centre (20042007) • South Asia Terrorism Portal (SATP) maintains an excellent web portal tracking all terrorism incidents in South Asia. It has most detailed accounts of the major Naxalite incidents from 2005 onwards. All the above mentioned sources track data on terrorist/violent incidents from different sources like newspapers, official reports etc. 25 . The data is across countries often with the village/city/district name of the place where each particular incident took place specified. We have filtered out all the data pertaining to India and then kept only the incidents that were clearly identifiable as Maoist/Naxalite in nature. To do so we used the name of perpetrator unless it was clearly mentioned as being a Maoist/Naxalite incident. Then except for the cases where the district is clearly mentioned the town or village mentioned was placed in its corresponding district. More often than not we were successful in doing so. However, we had to leave out the cases where it was not possible to do identify the districts. Finally, we have consolidated all the above data sources to construct a comprehensive consolidated district level Maoist 24 A higher total population might by itself indicate more potential recruits. Moreover, when coupled with a higher proportion of barren rocky land it could imply a less per capita availability of usable land and thus a population pressure on land. 25 The first three sources have been used by Iyer (2009) 13 incidents database. Thus, there is information on presence, incidents and the number of deaths and injuries at the district level from 1979-2009. Consumption & Poverty: District-specific indicators of income or expenditure are not available for India. Instead, per capita consumption expenditure is calculated from the National Sample Survey (hereafter NSS) data. The NSS conducts every 5 years the Consumption expenditure survey (among other surveys) whence district specific per capita consumption expenditures are calculated. The last four NSS thick rounds 26 were undertaken in 1987-88 (43rd), 1993-94 (50th), 1999-00 (55th), 2004-05 (61st). Given that district specific data is used, the 50th round is unusable since there are no district identifiers. For the purposes of this paper we use the other three rounds. The per capita consumption expenditure is calculated for all the districts using the Marginal per capita consumption (MPC hereafter), using the 30 day recall period since the 30 day recall period is the only one that is common across rounds. The MPC is used as a proxy for per capita income and the MPC figures are also used to calculate the district specific poverty rates and Gini coefficients of inequality within the districts. Demography: Apart from the Sample surveys by the NSS, India conducts a country wide census every 10 years. The data on demography and public goods are stored in the so called village directory data and is available for each census year since 1961. The 2001 census is used, whence we have data on total population, Schedule tribe and Caste population, population by religious groups. All the above information is available at the village level which have been used to construct the corresponding district level numbers. Geography: We control for geographical terrain by the fraction of the districts uncultivated area that is barren rocky, sandy and steep sloping. We also control for remoteness by the log of the distance from the state capital. Such data is made available in the Wasteland atlas of India, Department of Land Resources (Ministry of Rural development) in collaboration with the National Remote Sensing agency, (Department of Space). These variables by definition do not vary over time. We also have data on forest cover in the different districts. The data comes from the various ”State of forest cover” reports of the Forest Survey of India (FSI) and gives the percentage of forest cover in each district. The 2005 data is used. Land distribution: The data on operational holdings of agricultural land comes from the Agricultural census of India which collects such data every 5 years. The data gives the number of of operated landholdings in the different size classes (viz. Small, semi medium, medium and, large). Both the 1991 and the 2001 censuses are available. The gini coeeficient for land inequality is calculated using this data. The computed Gini coefficient varies from 0.12 to 0.78 and 0.14 to 0.79 in 1991 and 2001 respectively. The average inequality has gone up from 0.47 in 1991 to 0.5 in the year 2001 (data on Bihar not available in 2001). The land inequalities across the 2 years are highly correlated with Correlation coefficient of 0.97. We use the 1991 data since that way we have data prior to the high conflict years and also no major state is missing. Colonial Land Institutions: This data comes from Banerjee and Iyer (2005). However, out of the 362 districts we use in the analysis we have data on Land Institutions for only 233 districts. 27 26 only the thick rounds can be used since the thin rounds have too few observations 27 This data is available for districts which were directly under British control. 14 5 Empirical Analysis We have annual data on the conflict variables for the period 1979-2009. However, since we have only three rounds of NSS data viz. 1987-88 (43rd), 1999-00 (55th), 2004-05 (61st), we club the conflict data to match these three different NSS periods. The district names are first mapped to the districts that existed in 1987. Then all the conflict data from the period 1988- 1999 are collapsed and clubbed together and matched to the 1987-88 NSS data, all the conflict data from the period 1999- 2004 are clubbed together and matched to the 1999-2000 NSS data, all the conflict data from the period 2005- 2009 are clubbed together and matched to the 1987-88 NSS data. Thus we have data on 362 districts for three time periods. There are primarily two variables of interest that we try to explain viz. ’Probability of Conflict’ and ’Intensity of Conflict’. In order to explain the probability of conflict we create a 0-1 binary outcome variable (called Maoist) that takes the value ’1’ if a district has seen any Maoist activity at all in the relevant period while it takes the value ’0’ otherwise. While it is extremely important to understand which factors increase conflict probabilities it is equally important to understand what factors lead to higher intensity of conflict. Intensity is a latent variable that is measured using two variables viz. ”Total number of incidents” in a particular district and ”Total number of deaths + wounded” in the district in the relevant periods. The econometric specification is very simple and is as follows: (Conf lict)j,t = α(Conf lict)j,t−1 + βXj,t−1 + γGj + αs + δt + j,t The (Conf lict)j,t variable gives the conflict (presence or intensity) in district ”j” in round ”t”. The explanatory variables Xj,t include economic variables like MPC and measures of income inequality. ”G” includes all variables that do not change over time: land inequality, demographic variables, presence of marginalized sections like schedule tribes and castes and geographic variables like barren and rocky land , steep sloping land, percentage forests etc. ”s” is the state dummy, while ”t” is the time dummy. For the 0-1 probability of conflict variable we use Probit specifications. The intensity variables are both Count Variables by nature taking integer values from zero upwards. The Poisson model is the standard model used in such cases. However, the Poisson model assumes the mean and variance to be equal. In the presence of many zeros in the data like in our case there is overdispersion and thus the equidispersion assumption of the Poisson model does not hold true. The number of zero counts in my data is more than 70%. The standard parametric model to account for overdispersion is the negative binomial (Cameron and Trivedi (2005)). Thus, we use the Negative Binomial model 28 for explaining intensity. 29 Main Results: In the first set of regressions we try to identify the potential deteminants of the presence and intensity of conflict, primarily focussing on land inequality and MPC . All the specifications control for Time dummies and geography controls. We add controls for income inequality, percentages of Scheduled Castes & Tribes, size variables, and the proportion of the district that was 28 Poisson is a special case of it. 29 All the regressions use cluster robust standard errors, clustered at the state level 15 non landlord. We also control for conflict presence in the previous period in all the specifications. Table 1, 5, 8: Pooled Probit regressions explaining presence of Maoist Conflict in districts. Table 2: IV Probit regressions explaining presence of Maoist Conflict in districts. Table 3, 6, 9: Pooled Negative Binomial regressions explaining no. of Maoist incidents in districts. Table 4, 7, 10: Pooled Negative Binomial regressions explaining no. of dead & wounded in districts. Column 1 includes MPC, land inequality and time and geography controls. Column 2 adds controls for ethnic group sizes, population density and income inequality. Column 3 controls for the initial period income while Column 4 controls also for proportion non-landlord. Column 5 adds state controls (but not the initial period income nor proportion non-landlord). Column 6 adds proportion non-landlord to Column 5. In order to address potential endogeneity concerns, in Table 2 we use lagged consumption as an instrument for previous consumption. 30 Income, Land inequality and Conflict A lower per capita income (as proxied by the mean per capita consumption expenditure) significantly increases the risk of conflict in three of the six specifications in the Pooled Probit regressions (Table 1) explaining presence of Conflict and four and three specifications respectively in the Nbreg regressions (Tables 3 & 4) explaining the number of incidents and the number of people dead and wounded due to the conflict. However, in the IV Probit regressions (Table 2), where we instrument MPC with its lagged values, MPC is a significant and robust predictor of presence of Conflict in all the specifications. Thus, we indeed have evidence that poorer regions experience more conflict. This is pretty much in line with the previous literature and is in fact one of the most robust results in the conflict literature. In terms of Average marginal effects, a 1 SD increase in the log of MPC increases the probability of conflict in the next period by 13 % (highest), and results in 4 more incidents and 28 more dead and wounded people more in the next 5 years. On the other hand, while income inequality does not seem to play any role in the context of the Maoist conflict, Land inequality is a highly significant and robust predictor of conflict in all the specifications. Land inequality also significantly increases the intensity of conflict and this is robust to all sorts of controls. This gives support to the the greivance arising out of land inequities being a key reason behind the conflict. In terms of Average marginal effects, a 1 SD increase in land inequality increases the probability of conflict in the next period by at least 9 % , and results in 5 more incidents and 35 more dead and wounded people more in the next 5 years. While a higher SC population does not indicate higher presence of conflict, tribal areas do tend to experience more conflict, at least in some of the specifications. However, this is not robust in all the specifications. In the next set of regressions we will use the incomes of two groups separately (Tables 5 to 7). The land Institutions variable, p nland i.e. the proportion of districts that was not under land30 Thus we use data from the last two available rounds. In any case, conflict occurrence is highly concentrated during this period). 16 lord control is highly significant and negative in the specifications where it has been included. We will analyse its robustness in the tables 8 to 10. As far as the geography variables are concerned, barren & rocky areas experince more conflict. This is in agreement to our expectations. In a primarily agrarian economy, a higher proportion of barren & rocky land indicates lack of economic opportunity. This supports the opportunity cost story. Percentage steep sloping land is significant in almost all the specifications and always has a negative coefficient. This could sound a bit counter intuitive since most of the previous literature mentions mountainous land as being more suitable for conflict. However, given that the Naxalite conflict is almost exclusively concentrated in the plains of India this result makes absolute sense. If we could have used even finer dummies for regions than what we have used, perhaps the results would have been different. More interestingly, the percentage of forest cover comes out to be highly significantly increasing the probability of conflict in almost all the specifications (in fact of all the specifications in Tables 2, 3 & 4). There could be several plausible explanations for this. For one thing, large patches of forest cover provides the perfect hiding and fighting conditions for rebels and makes it quite difficult for security forces to keep up with them. While such an explanation is perfectly plausible there could be a deeper meaning to the forest cover variable turning out to be positively significant even when we account for income, inequality and regional dummies. What this might be showing is the confrontation of modernization and development with previously isolated communities who are mostly concentrated in remote areas with higher forest cover. As discussed in section 2, there seems to be some relation between the land acquisitions from tribal peasants in previously untapped resource rich areas by the state with the conflict. Accounting for differences in income of Lower castes/tribes and others: Exclusion : In the tables 5 to 7, we check specifically for the exclusion story. We run the same set of regressions as above but instead of the overall income we use the incomes clubbed in two groups: Scheduled Castes & tribes vs General Castes. The better thing to do would have been to put the incomes of all the three groups separately but we are unfortunately unable to do so since the number of Scheduled tribal people surveyed is just too low in many instances and thus we would lose a lot of observations. Instead we club the the Scheduled Castes and Tribes together. Overall, the incomes of both the groups i.e the General Castes & the SCSTs matter and they both reduce the probabilty of conflict (at least when they matter significantly). Interestingly in the specifications where both the variables are significant, the SCST consumption has a higher magnitude. But the relationship is not robust in all the specifications when we are trying to explain the presence of conflict. However, we find that SC/ST income has a negatively significant and robust impact on the number of incidents in a particular district, ceteris paribus. In other words, districts where the SCs & STs have a lower income experience significantly more Maoist incidents than other districts. The same result does not hold for the incomes of the general castes. If we look at the number of people dead and wounded the results are pretty much similar. Moreover, in almost all the specifications we have percentage of Scheduled Castes and Tribes in the district, significantly increases the conflict presence and intensity. While this is not conclusive but it does give some confirmation of the participation from the lower castes and tribes. In terms of AME, we have a 1 SD increase in the log(MPC) of the SC/STs resulting in around 4-6 more Maoist incidents while the similar increase in the incomes of the General Castes result in around 1-3 more incidents. 17 Institutions and Conflict: Finally, we directly test for how far the colonial institutions matter (Tables 8 to 10). While, following the earlier discussion we know that the land institutions could matter either indirectly through its effect on underdevelopment and/or land inequality or directly through the environment of class antagonism it has created. But we finally test for the direct effect. We do this since if indeed the land institutions have a direct effect on the conflict we cannot use it as an instrument for income or land inequality. However, using the proportion non-landlord variable directly, we can get the remaining effect that the institutions have on the conflict outcome, once we control for income and land inequality. We note that the proportion of the district i.e. not landlord is robust to the various specifications and has significant negative effect on the presence and intensity of conflict. We also note that land inequality and the geography variables still continue to be significant in explaining presence of conflict. In terms of Average marginal effect, an increase of 1 SD in the proportion of the district that was not controlled by the landlords reduces the probability of Maoist conflict in this district by around 8%, results in 2 less incidents and around 10-12 less dead & wounded people. Growth and Conflict: In the next set of tables we try to identify what impacts growth might have on the conflict (Table 11). The evidence in favour of low growth leading to higher conflict is not too strong. While indeed in 3 of the 5 specifications in Table 11, growth significantly reduces conflict levels, the result is not robust once we account for historical land institutions. Land inequality on the other hand continues to be significant. Moreover, the Average Marginal effects are too small in magnitude. We also try to identify if the growth of income of the different subgroups i.e. SCs & STs versus the general castes have any significantly different impact on the conflict (Tables 12-14). The incomes of both the groups come out to be significant in some of the cases. However, this result is also not robust in all specifications. However, we find that the magnitudes of the growth rates of incomes of the disadvantaged castes/tribes are always higher than that of the general castes. Moreover, we find that the SCST income growth rate has a significant effect in many cases at least as far as the intensity of conflict is concerned. Even in this case the average marginal effects are too small. 6 Conclusion This paper is the very first attempt to study the political economy of the Maoist conflict in India in-depth using a district level panel. It contributes to the civil conflict literature by adding to a small but growing literature that uses sub-national micro data to study civil conflicts. Making use of a newly constructed district level conflict database the paper provides some very interesting insights on the causes of the Maoist conflict. The evidence on how lower income leads to more conflict is pretty much in line with the existing literature and in addition the significance of the proportion of non agricultural land that is barren rocky in turn gives support to the grievance and opportunity cost story. Land inequality on the other hand comes out to be very robust in explaining the Maoist conflict and thus has immediate policy implications in terms of land reforms. The other important contribution of this paper is to the Institutions literature. This paper shows how centuries old historical institutions could have a significant impact on present day conflict outcomes. The significance of the Historical Land institutions 18 variable is also interesting since it shows that while the landlord districts might have indeed experienced more land reforms, the land reforms per se haven’t been able to address the class based antagonism and embittered social relations that these districts continue to experience. The Government of India has indeed recognized that apart from an appropriate police strategy to handle the conflict there is need for a non-military approach involving development of the relevant regions and solving disputes arising out of land. 31 Also there is evidence that while the income of the general castes are not that important the lower incomes of the SC/ST lead to higher conflict incidents (once we control for incomes of the general castes). This could be evidence in favour of the exclusion story, i.e. the income rise in India is not homogeneous and some groups are falling behind. While this evidence is not conclusive we still have been able to ask this interesting question due to the Micro nature of the data. Future research would be in the direction of controlling for land reforms at the district level and verifying its effects on the conflict outcomes 32 . The other direction for future research would be to find adequate instruments for the income variables that would allow us to further ensure that our results are not affected by endogeneity. Moreover, a lot of work remains to be done in terms of data collection from the households of the perpetrators and victims in order to further pin down both the causes and consequences of the Maoist conflict at the household/individual level. 31 The Ministery of Home Affairs, Government of India(http://mha.nic.in/uniquepage.asp?Id Pk=540) points out over and above the policing issues the other aspects related to Naxalism are: • fair and firm revenue (land) administration, with attention on elements like proper maintenance of land records, expeditious recording of mutations and fair disposal of land disputes, without undue delay. • appropriate mechanisms for grievance redressal, public contact and public awareness, for creating an overall positive environment and confidence of the people in the State administrative machinery. 32 See Besley and Burgess (2000) for a state level study of the land reforms. 19 References Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91 (5):1369–1401, 2001. Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (4):1231–94, 2002. Catherine Andre and Jean-Philippe Platteau. Land tenure under unendurable stress: Rwanda caught in the malthusian trap. Cahiers de la Faculte des Sciences Econommiques et Sociales de Namur, Serie Recherche, 164 - 1996/7, 1996. Megha Bahree. The forever war: Inside india’s maoist conflict. World Policy Journal, Summer, 27.2:83–89, 2010. Abhijit Banerjee and Laxmi Iyer. History, institutions and economic performance: The legacy of colonial land tenure systmes in india. American Economic Review, 2005. Abhijit Banerjee and Rohini Somanathan. The political economy of public goods: Some evidence from india. Journal of Development Economics, Elsevier, 82(2):287–314, 2007. Vani K. Barooah. Deprivation, violence and conflict: An analysis of naxalite activity in the districts of india. International Journal of Conflict and Violence, 2 (2):317–333, 2008. Gary S Becker. Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2):169–217, 1968. Timothy Besley and Robin Burgess. Land reform, poverty reduction, and growth: Evidence from india. Quaterly Journal of Economics, 115 (2):389–430, 2000. Timothy J. Besley and Torsten Persson. The incidence of civil war: Theory and evidence. NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper 14585, 2008. Bela Bhatia. The naxalite movement in central bihar. Economic and Political Weekly, 40 (15) Apr 9-15, 2005. 20 C. Blattman and E. Miguel. Civil war. The Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1):3–57(55), 2010. Anjali Thomas Bohlken and Ernest Sergenti. Economic growth and ethnic violence: An empirical investigation of the hindu-muslim riots in india. 2009. A. Colin Cameron and Pravin K. Trivedi. Microeconometrics:methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, 2005. Sudeep Chakravarti. Red sun-travels in naxalite country. Penguin Global, 2008. Antonio Ciccone. Transitory economic shocks and civil conflict. unpublished, 82(2):287–314, 2010. P. Collier and A. Hoeffler. Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4):563–596, 2004. Quy-Toan Do and Lakshmi Iyer. Geography, poverty and conflict in nepal. HBS Working Paper, 07-065, 2009. Oeindrila Dube and Juan F. Vargas. Commodity price shocks and civil confict:evidence from colombia. CID Graduate Student and Postdoctoral Fellow Working Paper No. 14, 2008. Esther Duflo and Rohini Pande. Dams. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2):601–646, 05, 2007. Stanley L. Engerman and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economies: A view from economic historians of the united states. in Steven Haber, ed., How Latin America fell behind: Essays on the economic histories of Brazil and Mexico, 18001914. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1997. Stanley L. Engerman and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among new world economies. Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association, 3 (1):41–88, 2002. 21 J. Fearon and D. Laitin. Ethnicity, insurgency and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97 (1):75–90, 2003. Lakshmi Iyer. The bloody millennium: Internal conflict in south asia. Harvard Business School, Working Paper, 09-086, 2009. Saumitra Jha. Complementarities and religious tolerance: evidence from india. Stanford GSB Working Paper No. 2004, 2008. Rajat Kujur. Naxal movement in india: A profile. Institute of Peace and Conflict Studies, New Delhi, 2008. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106 (6):113–55, 1998. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. The quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 15 (1):222–79, 1999. Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez de Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 58 (1-2):3–27, 2000. E. Miguel, S. Satyanath, and E. Sergenti. Economic shocks and civil conflict: An instrumental variables approach. Journal of Political Economy, 112 (41):725–753, 2004. Anirban Mitra and Debraj Ray. Implications of an economic theory of conflict:hindu-muslim violence in india. unpublished, 2010. Government of India. Development challenges in extremist affected areas. Report of an Expert Group to the Planning Commission, 2008. Nandini Sundar. Subalterns and sovereigns, an anthropological history of bastar (1854-2006). Oxford University Press, 2008. USAID. Land and conflict: A toolkit for intervention. US Agency for International Development (USAID) Office of Conflict Management and Mitigation, 2005. 22 Philip Verwimp. Micro-level evidence from rwanda. HiCN Working Papers 08, Households in Conflict Network, 2003. 23 7 Appendix 24 maoist 1 Table 1: Dep Var: Maoist; Probit regressions (1) (2) (3) (4) probit1 probit2 probit3 probit4 1.912*** 1.875*** 2.111*** 1.453*** (5) probit5 0.928*** (6) probit6 0.626*** prop sandy -2.497 1.074 5.001 23.67*** 24.40** 31.53** log stcapdistance -0.0847 -0.0841 0.0488 0.247 -0.0181 0.192 prop barrenrocky 7.877*** 12.37*** 17.32*** 34.39*** 19.24*** 33.93*** prop steepsloping -68.93*** -59.95*** -81.18** -61.78** -132.7*** -106.9*** proportion forest cover 1.145** 1.100 1.863** 1.572** 1.961*** 2.040*** log area 0.558** 0.671*** 0.724*** 0.902*** 0.732*** 0.759*** consumption pc -1.621*** -1.413*** -1.805*** -0.828 -1.097 -0.588 land inequality 3.337*** 3.434*** 3.441*** 2.992*** 4.374*** 5.324*** %Scheduled Castes -0.531 0.116 -0.953 2.282 3.958** %Scheduled Tribes 0.849* 1.106* 0.269 1.457*** 1.256** population density -59.74 -150.6** -113.9*** 19.63 2.098 income inequality -0.178 -3.348* -5.958*** 1.166 -1.320 -0.263 0.387 initial consumption pc Prop. Non landlord -1.392*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes 996 Yes 996 Yes 656 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 25 Yes 431 -1.256** Yes Yes Yes 767 Yes 548 consumption pc Table 2: Dep Var: Maoist; IVProbit regressions (1) (2) (3) (4) ivprobit1 ivprobit2 ivprobit3 ivprobit4 -3.078*** -2.808*** -3.427*** -3.215** maoist 1 (5) ivprobit5 -3.551*** (6) ivprobit6 -3.536* 1.954*** 2.007*** 1.919*** 1.308*** 0.954*** 0.639** prop sandy -0.907 5.844 5.729 26.31*** 35.48 43.08* log stcapdistance -0.0245 0.00487 0.0325 0.192 0.0776 0.226 prop barrenrocky 10.43*** 17.33*** 18.22*** 32.26*** 25.49*** 34.56*** prop steepsloping -56.51** -45.69* -75.42** -56.67* -82.55** -49.45 proportion forest cover 1.278* 1.866** 1.818** 1.529* 2.758*** 3.018*** log area 0.338 0.575** 0.553** 0.661** 0.708*** 0.723*** 3.610*** 3.215*** 3.039** 2.363** 3.530*** 3.884*** %Scheduled Castes -0.118 -0.353 -1.095 2.030 3.950** %Scheduled Tribes 0.657 0.548 -0.841 0.955* -0.505 population density -132.3** -135.1** -90.23*** -72.44 -79.00 income inequality -1.333 -0.190 -0.763 3.478 1.564 0.716 1.338 land inequality initial consumption pc Prop. Non landlord -0.953** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes 640 Yes 640 Yes 638 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 26 Yes 420 -1.314*** Yes Yes Yes 520 Yes 359 maoist 1 Table 3: Dep Var: No. of Incidents (1) (2) (3) (4) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 nbreg4 2.891*** 2.731*** 2.935*** 2.165*** (5) nbreg5 1.201*** (6) nbreg6 0.888** prop sandy -17.30 -12.67 -13.25 1.164 8.291 18.12 log stcapdistance -0.287* -0.302 -0.0125 0.159 -0.104 0.0306 prop barrenrocky 19.24** 30.17*** 36.71*** 39.24*** 21.59*** 27.99*** prop steepsloping -112.9*** -101.3** -135.1*** -152.3** -136.2** -124.1* proportion forest cover 2.385** 2.200* 2.767** 2.991** 2.960*** 3.762*** log area 1.570*** 1.865*** 1.891*** 2.434*** 1.536*** 1.955*** consumption pc -2.887*** -2.004** -1.744* -1.376 -1.718** -1.637 land inequality 7.590*** 8.066*** 7.977*** 6.160*** 6.499*** 6.511*** %Scheduled Castes -0.867 -0.0752 -1.311 2.821 5.415* %Scheduled Tribes 2.198*** 2.302*** -0.579 2.358*** 1.188 population density -107.7*** -137.6*** -132.0** 85.04 50.03 income inequality -3.240 -9.450** -14.12*** 0.246 -1.734 -0.931 0.0657 initial consumption pc Prop. Non landlord -1.279*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes 996 Yes 996 Yes 656 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 27 Yes 431 -1.183** Yes Yes Yes 996 Yes 655 maoist 1 Table 4: Dep Var: No. of dead wounded (1) (2) (3) (4) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 nbreg4 2.925*** 2.755*** 2.941*** 2.298*** prop sandy -50.69*** -39.58** -48.38*** -40.40*** 11.45 36.52 log stcapdistance -0.497*** -0.636*** -0.151 -0.127 -0.251 -0.189 prop barrenrocky 21.44*** 30.25*** 40.17*** 40.48*** 34.47*** 42.84*** prop steepsloping -191.3*** -187.0*** -234.0*** -255.9*** -306.5*** -323.7*** proportion forest cover 4.119*** 3.691** 4.248** 5.890*** 4.949*** 6.060*** log area 1.940*** 2.409*** 2.317*** 3.038*** 2.144*** 2.691*** consumption pc -4.398*** -2.845** -1.674 -1.499 -3.329* -2.612 land inequality 11.44*** 12.34*** 11.14*** 8.581*** 13.13*** 14.11*** %Scheduled Castes -3.005 -3.845 -5.684 5.467 9.513*** %Scheduled Tribes 2.819** 1.972* -3.349*** 2.764 1.037 population density -88.03** -119.2*** -128.2 149.5 124.7 income inequality -5.387 -14.42*** -21.21*** -1.728 -5.001 -2.611** -1.829 initial consumption pc Prop. Non landlord (6) nbreg6 0.639 -1.186*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations (5) nbreg5 0.943** Yes 996 Yes 996 Yes 656 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 28 Yes 431 -1.335* Yes Yes Yes 996 Yes 655 maoist 1 Table 5: Dep Var: Maoist (1) (2) (3) probit1 probit2 probit3 1.916*** 1.901*** 2.174*** (4) probit4 1.468*** (5) probit5 0.926*** (6) probit6 0.632*** prop sandy -2.343 1.654 4.163 24.90*** 24.08*** 28.40** log stcapdistance -0.0853 -0.0573 0.0525 0.270 -0.0195 0.134 prop barrenrocky 8.558*** 12.59*** 16.43*** 34.48*** 18.93*** 33.41*** prop steepsloping -74.89*** -60.84*** -83.24** -63.82** -134.0*** -108.2*** proportion forest cover 1.188** 1.295* 1.740** 1.601* 1.770*** 1.600** log area 0.572** 0.643*** 0.703** 0.896*** 0.753*** 0.773*** log gen mpc -0.570 -0.513* -0.635*** -0.236 -0.340*** -0.122 log scst mpc -1.154*** -1.042*** -1.070** -1.009 -0.614 -0.578 land inequality 3.277*** 3.196*** 3.350*** 2.765*** 4.436*** 5.535*** %Scheduled Castes & Tribes 1.077* 1.804** -0.000150 1.760*** 1.861*** population density -63.02 -136.8** -108.9*** 21.24 4.844 income inequality -0.731 -4.405** -6.291*** 0.802 -1.346 -0.976* 0.345 0.515 0.174 General MPC SCST MPC Prop. Non landlord -1.396*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes 993 Yes 993 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 29 Yes 651 Yes 426 -1.278** Yes Yes Yes 765 Yes 546 maoist 1 Table 6: Dep Var: No. of Incidents (1) (2) (3) 2.869*** 2.777*** 3.034*** (4) 2.301*** (5) 1.228*** prop sandy -16.40 -11.72 -12.20 4.016 8.007 log stcapdistance -0.305* -0.244 0.0183 0.141 -0.104 prop barrenrocky 20.33*** 31.37*** 36.70*** 34.73*** 21.40*** prop steepsloping -119.1*** -97.48*** -129.9*** -147.1*** -133.1** proportion forest cover 2.594** 2.511** 2.743** 2.559* 2.847*** log area 1.589*** 1.778*** 1.841*** 2.486*** 1.558*** log gen mpc -1.201*** -0.932 -0.683 -0.306 -0.700*** log scst mpc -2.079*** -1.710*** -1.669*** -2.161*** -1.161* land inequality 7.425*** 7.703*** 7.502*** 5.505** 6.465*** %Scheduled Castes & Tribes 2.611*** 3.297*** -0.852 2.614*** population density -107.2*** -142.2*** -132.2** 75.03 income inequality -3.356 -9.596*** -13.84*** -0.549 -1.733*** -1.312 0.956 1.725 General MPC SCST MPC Prop. Non landlord -1.140*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 993 Yes 993 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 30 Yes 651 Yes 426 Yes 993 maoist 1 Table 7: Dep Var: No. of dead wounded (1) (2) (3) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 2.880*** 2.771*** 3.072*** (4) nbreg4 2.562*** (5) nbreg5 1.076* prop sandy -46.41** -39.40* -39.59* -37.42** 8.840 log stcapdistance -0.521*** -0.486*** -0.0354 -0.176 -0.273 prop barrenrocky 22.31*** 31.30*** 39.94*** 34.49*** 32.08*** prop steepsloping -191.8*** -174.3*** -207.9*** -253.5*** -278.3*** proportion forest cover 4.461*** 3.712** 3.910** 5.464*** 4.613*** log area 2.116*** 2.315*** 2.168*** 3.131*** 2.271*** log gen mpc -2.113*** -1.844*** -1.106 -0.0971 -1.374** log scst mpc -2.848*** -2.169*** -1.994* -2.717** -2.063 land inequality 11.39*** 12.06*** 10.58*** 6.911** 12.74*** %Scheduled Castes & Tribes 3.841*** 4.145*** -3.230* 3.332** population density -88.55** -128.7*** -147.3* 118.8 income inequality -4.222 -12.39*** -21.41*** -2.793 -2.876*** -3.084** 0.835 1.522 General MPC SCST MPC Prop. Non landlord -1.161** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 993 Yes 993 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 31 Yes 651 Yes 426 Yes 993 maoist 1 Table 8: Dep Var: Maoist (1) (2) (3) (4) 1.904*** 1.707*** 1.504*** 1.503*** (5) 1.357*** (6) 1.364*** (7) 0.611*** Prop. Non landlord -1.047*** -1.266*** -1.526*** -1.268*** -1.436*** -1.234*** -1.230** 16.62*** 18.69*** 19.84*** 20.33*** 20.42*** 31.42** log stcapdistance 0.0838 0.151 0.164 0.188 0.192 0.193 prop barrenrocky 9.442** 25.87*** 24.55*** 28.18*** 27.63*** 33.81*** prop steepsloping -57.69* -27.05 -22.45 -39.45 -33.89 -107.7*** proportion forest cover 0.784 1.559** 1.674** 1.260** 1.296* 2.091*** log area 0.336 0.587*** 0.579*** 0.761*** 0.725*** 0.734*** population density -120.6*** -125.4*** -85.26*** -78.17*** 4.929 %Scheduled Castes -1.269 -1.069 -1.498 -1.394 3.966** %Scheduled Tribes -0.302 -0.901 0.765 0.211 1.229** -0.948** -0.724 2.973*** 5.391*** prop sandy consumption pc -1.087*** land inequality 3.014*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 698 Yes 668 Yes 668 32 Yes 655 Yes 668 Yes 655 Yes 548 maoist 1 Prop. Non landlord Table 9: Dep Var: No. of incidents (1) (2) (3) (4) 3.378*** 2.307*** 1.991*** 2.150*** -1.089* (5) 1.805*** (6) 1.904*** (7) 0.864** -1.986*** -2.186*** -1.589*** -1.883*** -1.381*** -1.145** prop sandy -0.110 2.987 7.379 6.717 8.738 18.12 log stcapdistance -0.251 -0.104 -0.0130 -0.0156 0.0753 0.0388 prop barrenrocky 13.46 32.29*** 24.36*** 45.14*** 39.17*** 28.30*** prop steepsloping -77.67* -51.75 -45.80 -69.91 -62.04 -126.9* 0.507 2.533** 2.759** 2.277* 2.257* 3.788*** 1.487*** 1.831*** 1.817*** 2.171*** 2.073*** 1.906*** population density -186.3*** -192.7*** -143.1*** -113.3*** 52.93 %Scheduled Castes -0.868 -1.097 -0.906 -1.061 5.609* %Scheduled Tribes -0.646 -2.461*** 1.200 -0.489 1.175 -2.218*** -1.842 6.632*** 6.681*** proportion forest cover log area consumption pc -2.365*** land inequality 6.593*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 698 Yes 668 Yes 668 33 Yes 655 Yes 668 Yes 655 Yes 655 maoist 1 Table 10: Dep Var: No. of dead wounded (1) (2) (3) (4) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 nbreg4 3.026*** 2.104*** 1.875*** 2.012*** (5) nbreg5 1.782*** (6) nbreg6 1.813*** (7) nbreg7 0.549 Prop. Non landlord -1.911*** -2.595*** -2.732*** -2.135*** -2.534*** -2.053*** -1.207 prop sandy -24.70 -3.391 -1.021 -0.578 -2.990 38.57 log stcapdistance -0.585 -0.566 -0.309 -0.343 -0.172 -0.126 prop barrenrocky 17.62 43.17*** 37.41** 59.70*** 54.96*** 46.07*** prop steepsloping -133.4*** -114.6* -106.4* -148.4** -143.4** -337.2*** 1.735 4.455*** 4.649*** 4.797*** 4.857*** 6.277*** 1.728*** 2.482*** 2.285*** 2.951*** 2.722*** 2.483*** population density -281.5*** -279.4*** -181.7*** -148.0*** 130.5 %Scheduled Castes -4.150 -4.325 -3.072 -3.013 10.10*** %Scheduled Tribes -1.441 -3.643*** 1.312 -0.489 1.336 -2.431* -3.207 10.87*** 14.79*** proportion forest cover log area consumption pc -2.852** land inequality 10.86*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 698 Yes 668 Yes 668 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 34 Yes 655 Yes 668 Yes 655 Yes 655 maoist 1 Table 11: Dep Var: Maoist (Growth) (1) (2) (3) 2.375*** 2.109*** 2.161*** (4) 1.468*** (5) 1.069*** prop sandy -1.552 3.260 3.244 25.81*** 43.60 log stcapdistance -0.0501 0.000879 0.00972 0.200 0.150 prop barrenrocky 3.563 15.00*** 17.17*** 34.31*** 27.98*** prop steepsloping -54.89*** -71.01*** -89.14*** -69.43* -110.3*** proportion forest cover 0.958 0.779 1.483* 1.687** 2.119** log area 0.0728 0.581* 0.542* 0.745** 0.942*** -0.0361*** -0.0509*** -0.0582*** -0.0344 -0.00706 %Scheduled Castes 0.399 0.350 -1.227 2.205 %Scheduled Tribes 2.355*** 1.599** 0.975 2.174*** population density -82.71 -83.13 -103.0*** -6.836 gini growth -0.00143 -0.00375 -0.0159 -0.0226* land inequality 3.984*** 3.776*** 3.207*** 4.158*** -1.612** -0.172 mpc growth initial consumption pc Prop. Non landlord -1.539*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes Yes 640 Yes 639 35 Yes 637 Yes 419 Yes 500 maoist 1 Table 12: Dep Var: Maoist (Growth by subgroups) (1) (2) (3) (4) 2.441*** 2.187*** 2.319*** 1.584*** (5) 1.110*** (6) 0.732*** prop sandy -1.552 2.655 4.493 24.91*** 43.48** 47.46** log stcapdistance -0.0524 0.0323 0.0445 0.262 0.149 0.242 prop barrenrocky 3.282 13.64** 15.28*** 32.78*** 27.69*** 37.51*** prop steepsloping -58.38*** -68.27*** -84.31** -61.28* -112.0*** -84.32* proportion forest cover 1.098* 1.014 1.710** 1.949** 2.173*** 2.368*** log area 0.0821 0.517 0.521 0.691** 0.935*** 0.827*** General MPC growth -0.00709** -0.00884* -0.0168* -0.0128 -0.00247 -0.00749 SCST MPC growth -0.0275** -0.0314** -0.0294** -0.0229 -0.00616 -0.00923 2.208*** 2.089*** 0.250 2.129*** 2.347*** population density -67.85 -110.7 -95.94*** -4.027 -15.14 gini growth -0.0123 -0.0276*** -0.0305*** -0.0233* -0.0185 3.653*** 3.086** 2.668*** 4.240*** 5.059*** General MPC -1.935*** -0.176 SCST MPC -0.00814 -0.309 %Scheduled Castes & Tribes land inequality Prop. Non landlord -1.574*** State Dummies Time Dummies Observations Yes 636 Yes 636 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 36 Yes 633 Yes 415 -1.504*** Yes Yes Yes 497 Yes 355 maoist 1 Table 13: Dep Var: No. of incidents (1) (2) (3) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 3.512*** 3.066*** 3.180*** (4) nbreg4 2.264*** prop sandy -13.70 -7.699 -13.36 -2.861 log stcapdistance -0.289 -0.114 -0.00654 0.0991 prop barrenrocky 2.695 32.27*** 37.39*** 40.74*** prop steepsloping -82.08** -78.88*** -126.5*** -157.3* proportion forest cover 2.242 2.099 2.322* 2.010 log area 0.674 1.458*** 1.578*** 2.134*** General MPC growth -0.00500 -0.0186 -0.0244 -0.0255 SCST MPC growth -0.0537** -0.0436** -0.0298 -0.0443** %Scheduled Castes & Tribes 4.307*** 3.755*** 0.358 population density -123.2*** -137.6*** -122.2*** -0.0209 -0.0402** -0.0588** 7.808*** 7.227*** 6.118*** -2.887*** -1.946* 0.130 0.505 gini growth land inequality General MPC SCST MPC Prop. Non landlord Time Dummy Observations -1.410*** Yes 636 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 37 Yes 636 Yes 633 Yes 415 maoist 1 Table 14: Dep Var: no of dead + wounded (1) (2) (3) nbreg1 nbreg2 nbreg3 3.518*** 3.257*** 3.299*** prop sandy (4) nbreg4 2.337*** -33.48 -29.17 -36.71 -47.97** log stcapdistance -0.532** -0.246 -0.0300 -0.0571 prop barrenrocky -1.995 27.94*** 39.11*** 43.96*** prop steepsloping -122.2*** -127.0*** -180.8*** -255.5** proportion forest cover 3.174 2.405 3.108* 3.952** log area 0.616 1.599*** 1.867*** 2.627*** -0.0114 -0.0401** -0.0445** -0.0354 -0.0765** -0.0492* -0.0319 -0.0537* 5.593*** 4.784*** -0.918 population density -102.0* -130.2*** -118.8* gini growth -0.0438 -0.0628** -0.115*** 11.05*** 10.31*** 8.629*** -4.507*** -3.808*** -0.486 -0.231 General MPC growth SCST MPC growth %Scheduled Castes & Tribes land inequality General MPC SCST MPC Prop. Non landlord Time Dummy Observations -1.643*** Yes 636 * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 38 Yes 636 Yes 633 Yes 415 39 Table 15: Districts affected Round 1 Conflict t-1 Conflict t+1 Not Affected 358 338 Affected 3 23 Round 2 Not Affected 339 293 Affected 23 69 Round 3 Not Affected 293 269 Affected 69 93 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 Variable maoist deadwounded nincidents maoist 1 gini mpc 87 General MPC 87 SCST MPC 87 landineq91 p forest pop density log mpc log gen mpc log scst mpc log area prop sandy prop barrenrocky prop steepaloping log stcapdistance SCST percent log mpc lag log gen mpc lag log scst mpc lag p nland Table 16: Summary: All 3 rounds Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min 1085 0.170507 0.376251 0 1085 6.322581 59.3128 0 1085 2.41106 15.79039 0 1085 0.087558 0.282781 0 1046 0.266298 0.060809 0.103525 1030 5.052897 0.244983 4.410083 1030 5.132978 0.249794 4.498148 1028 4.870675 0.250028 4.180412 1055 0.47359 0.178855 0.120449 1082 0.167094 0.18037 0.000699 1082 0.006383 0.022805 0.000692 1046 5.849775 0.628196 4.410083 1043 6.002583 0.696857 4.498148 1045 5.674889 0.628981 4.180412 1082 8.721257 0.696394 6.475433 1040 0.006336 0.040049 0 1040 0.00799 0.020191 0 1040 0.002556 0.010052 0 1031 5.485296 0.811263 0 1082 0.292082 0.15533 0.016113 686 5.608404 0.620172 4.410083 685 5.727645 0.666179 4.498148 685 5.440889 0.634257 4.180412 698 0.522766 0.429809 0 51 Max 1 1837 428 1 0.525915 5.777959 6.014436 5.941787 0.788384 0.832942 0.416596 7.352093 8.501844 7.374076 10.7288 0.688315 0.265584 0.129534 6.899219 0.946497 6.848523 7.336274 7.374076 1 Variable maoist deadwounded nincidents maoist 1 gini mpc 87 General MPC 87 SCST MPC 87 landineq91 p forest pop density log mpc log gen mpc log scst mpc log area prop sandy prop barrenrocky prop steepaloping log stcapdistance SCST percent p nland Table Obs 361 361 361 361 350 350 350 350 351 360 360 350 350 350 360 346 346 346 343 360 232 17: Summary: Round Mean Std. Dev. 0.063712 0.244578 1.227147 7.815471 0.171745 0.874566 0.00831 0.090907 0.268654 0.049943 5.053116 0.24615 5.134089 0.252915 4.871676 0.250661 0.473529 0.17919 0.166137 0.179325 0.00637 0.022845 5.053116 0.24615 5.134089 0.252915 4.871676 0.250661 8.72076 0.69759 0.006344 0.040126 0.007996 0.020229 0.002559 0.010071 5.485555 0.812822 0.291302 0.154554 0.52343 0.430869 52 1 Min 0 0 0 0 0.14319 4.410083 4.498148 4.180412 0.120449 0.000699 0.000692 4.410083 4.498148 4.180412 6.475433 0 0 0 0 0.016113 0 Max 1 114 9 1 0.517323 5.777959 6.014436 5.941787 0.788384 0.832942 0.416596 5.777959 6.014436 5.941787 10.7288 0.688315 0.265584 0.129534 6.899219 0.946497 1 Variable maoist deadwounded nincidents maoist 1 gini mpc 87 General MPC 87 SCST MPC 87 landineq91 p forest pop density log mpc log gen mpc log scst mpc log area prop sandy prop barrenrocky prop steepaloping log stcapdistance SCST percent log mpc lag log gen mpc lag log scst mpc lag p nland Table Obs 362 362 362 362 335 330 330 329 352 361 361 335 334 334 361 347 347 347 344 361 351 351 351 233 18: Summary: Round Mean Std. Dev. 0.190608 0.393324 3.743094 15.56642 1.743094 6.166011 0.063536 0.244262 0.222355 0.044069 5.050845 0.242649 5.129295 0.243505 4.867642 0.249575 0.47362 0.178942 0.167571 0.181136 0.006389 0.022816 6.18721 0.256414 6.347735 0.295582 6.03601 0.253107 8.721505 0.696764 0.006332 0.040069 0.007987 0.020201 0.002554 0.010057 5.485167 0.811668 0.292471 0.155929 5.055982 0.251596 5.137588 0.260924 4.874592 0.256194 0.522436 0.430207 53 2 Min 0 0 0 0 0.103525 4.410083 4.498148 4.180412 0.120449 0.000699 0.000692 5.413915 5.419044 5.395524 6.475433 0 0 0 0 0.016113 4.410083 4.498148 4.180412 0 Max 1 122 61 1 0.409687 5.777959 5.831726 5.941787 0.788384 0.832942 0.416596 6.848523 7.336274 7.374076 10.7288 0.688315 0.265584 0.129534 6.899219 0.946497 6.059236 6.362353 5.941787 1 Variable maoist deadwounded nincidents maoist 1 gini mpc 87 General M 87 SCST MPC 87 landineq91 p forest pop density log mpc log gen mpc log scst mpc log area prop sandy prop barre y prop steep g log stcapd e SCST percent log mpc lag log gen mpc lag log scst mpc lag p nland Table 19: Summary: Round Obs Mean Std. Dev. 362 0.256906 0.437532 362 13.98343 100.8417 362 5.312155 26.38211 362 0.190608 0.393324 361 0.304792 0.056793 350 5.054611 0.246686 350 5.13534 0.253162 349 4.872531 0.25051 352 0.47362 0.178942 361 0.167571 0.181136 361 0.006389 0.022816 361 6.309026 0.302151 359 6.528189 0.379725 361 6.119516 0.284002 361 8.721505 0.696764 347 0.006332 0.040069 347 0.007987 0.020201 347 0.002554 0.010057 344 5.485167 0.811668 361 0.292471 0.155929 335 6.18721 0.256414 334 6.347735 0.295582 334 6.03601 0.253107 233 0.522436 0.430207 54 3 Min 0 0 0 0 0.158474 4.410083 4.498148 4.180412 0.120449 0.000699 0.000692 5.641609 5.802069 5.494266 6.475433 0 0 0 0 0.016113 5.413915 5.419044 5.395524 0 Max 1 1837 428 1 0.525915 5.777959 6.014436 5.941787 0.788384 0.832942 0.416596 7.352093 8.501844 7.244851 10.7288 0.688315 0.265584 0.129534 6.899219 0.946497 6.848523 7.336274 7.374076 1