Do Depositors Discipline Banks and Did Government Actions During the Recent Crisis Reduce this Discipline? An International Perspective Allen N. Berger University of South Carolina Wharton Financial Institutions Center CentER – Tilburg University aberger@moore.sc.edu Rima Turk-Ariss Lebanese American University rima.turk@lau.edu.lb May 2014 The recent financial crisis highlights the importance of both regulatory and market discipline. Government reactions to the crisis included expanding deposit insurance coverage and rescuing troubled institutions, including some institutions that might not otherwise be considered too important to fail. These actions may have the unintended consequence of a reduction in market discipline that might otherwise penalize banks for risk-taking behavior. Alternatively, market discipline may have increased during the crisis due to heightened awareness of the risks of bank failures. To address these issues, we first test for the presence of depositor discipline effects in the period leading up to the financial crisis in both the US and the EU. Second, we test whether depositor discipline decreased or increased during the crisis. We find significant depositor discipline prior to the crisis in both the US and EU, but this varies between the US and the EU as well as with banking organization size and with listed versus unlisted status. We also find that depositor discipline mostly decreased during the crisis, except for the case of small US banks. JEL Classification Numbers: G21, G28 Keywords: Market Discipline, Depositor Discipline, Banks The authors thank an anonymous referee, Rob Bliss, Arnoud Boot, Bob Collender, Bob DeYoung, Astrid Dick, Stefano Giglio, John Goodell, Ed Kane, Mark Flannery, Phil Molyneux, Herman Saheruddin, Klaus Schaeck, Greg Udell, Larry Wall, Maxim Zagonov, participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago conference on Bank Structure and Competition, seminar participants at the Money and Capital Markets department of the International Monetary Fund, and participants at the Financial Management Association meeting for helpful comments and suggestions, and Raluca Roman for outstanding research assistance. Please address correspondence to Allen N. Berger, Moore School of Business, University of South Carolina, 1705 College Street, Columbia, SC 29208. Phone: 803-576-8440, Fax: 803-7776876, email aberger@moore.sc.edu. I - INTRODUCTION The recent financial crisis highlights the importance of both regulatory and market discipline of financial institutions, which seem to have been lacking in some cases. The government rescue actions for troubled financial institutions included increased deposit insurance coverage (e.g., FDIC, Dodd-Frank),1 capital injections (e.g., TARP), government takeovers of financial institutions (e.g., AIG, Northern Rock), increased central bank lending (e.g., Term Auction Facility (TAF)), expanded discount window lending authority under Federal Reserve 13(3)), more explicit too-important-to-fail protection of large financial institutions (e.g., Supervisory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP)),2 and the explicit or implicit guarantees in many countries to all deposits. The goals included reducing panic and the potential for runs and other short-term disruptions, but a potential unintended consequence may be a reduction in market discipline that might otherwise penalize financial institutions for excessive risk-taking behavior. However, potentially offsetting or even overwhelming this effect may be an increase in market discipline due to heighted public awareness of bank risks because of the dramatic increase in the numbers of failures and near-failures and the media coverage of them. We examine an potentially important source of market discipline in this study – depositor discipline. We address two issues. First, we test for the presence of depositor discipline effects in the period leading up to the financial crisis in both the US and the EU (plus Switzerland). Second, we test whether this discipline decreased or increased during the crisis. Specifically, for 1 In the US, the deposit insurance cap on the dollar amount of funds insured was temporarily raised from $100,000 to $250,000, and this was made permanent by Dodd-Frank. In the EU, moves were made to eliminate co-insurance and raise the deposit insurance coverage caps. See Carbo-Valverde, Kane, and Rodriguez-Fernandez (2008) for more general discussion of deposit insurance and the government safety net in the EU prior to the recent crisis. 2 Under the 2009 US bank stress tests, the Supervisory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP), the government may have effectively announced that the 19 largest banking organizations were too important to fail by stating that these institutions would need sufficient capital to survive another downturn or would be provided with such capital. 1 the pre-crisis period, we examine the effects of measures of bank risk on deposit growth for over 2000 commercial banks and bank holding companies over the period 1997-2007. expositional convenience, we refer to both organizational types as “banks.” For We include institutions from the US and 21 EU nations plus Switzerland. We refer to banks in the EU, but this should be taken to include Swiss banks as well. We include Swiss banks in order to have coverage of virtually all of the large banking organizations in Europe. To test whether depositor discipline decreased or increased during the recent crisis, we repeat the analysis for the period 2008-2009, and test whether depositor discipline changed from the pre-crisis period to the crisis period. The change should reflect net effect of any decrease in depositor discipline due to government actions and any increase due to the public’s heightened awareness of risk during the crisis. For our main results, we include insured and uninsured deposits together because of the difficulty of separating them. For the US, we include an extra analysis of uninsured deposits. We conduct tests separately on institutions above and below the top 10th percentile of total banking assets in each country, on banks in the US and EU, and on listed versus unlisted banking organizations.3 We regress measures of deposit growth rates on measures of bank risk, controls for bank and country characteristics, and the lagged deposit rate premium (the difference between deposit rate and the short-term Treasury rate). The inclusion of the lagged deposit rate premium takes into account that deposit growth rates may be jointly determined with rate premia. We acknowledge the fact that we have not been able to completely rule out causality issues because both deposit growth and risk may be reflections of a broader strategy. 4 In the robustness section, 3 Reasons for these separate treatments are given in the text below. We also assume that the supply function of deposits does not significantly vary with other factors such as monetary policy changes. 4 2 we additionally try dropping the deposit rate premium, and also run a dynamic model. In both cases, the main results are robust. In the literature, there are a number of tests for depositor discipline in the US, but there is much less information available about the effects in the EU, and very few international comparisons. As well, there are no tests to our knowledge about the effects of bank size, listed versus unlisted status, or comparisons of different indicators of financial condition. Most important, we are unaware of studies that test whether market discipline decreased or increased during the recent crisis. By way of preview, we find significant depositor discipline in both the US and EU prior to the crisis, but generally that the effects were stronger at large banks in the US than in the EU, consistent with the conjecture that government bailouts of large organizations were considered more likely in the EU. Depositor discipline was more economically significant for large US institutions than for small US institutions, presumably due to either the greater preponderance of uninsured deposits or more sophisticated depositors in large institutions. We also find less measured discipline for large, listed institutions, which may be because depositor discipline is based on variables other than equity ratios and loan performance that are not highly correlated with these measures. Depositor discipline effects were in most cases reduced during the crisis, consistent with the hypothesis that government actions taken at the beginning of the crisis reduce such discipline. An exception is small US banks, where depositor discipline held or was increased, consistent with a heightened awareness of bank risk due to the numbers of small US banks that failed, although other explanations are also possible. 3 The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews the prior literature on market discipline of different types of debt – subordinated debt and deposits. Section III introduces the data and methodology. Section IV discusses the main empirical findings. Section V conducts robustness tests, and Section VI presents the results of tests on uninsured deposits in the US. Section VII concludes. II - LITERATURE REVIEW ON MARKET DISCIPLINE The literature on market discipline of banking organizations primarily focuses on subordinated debt and depositor discipline.5 We review these in order. A. SUBORDINATED DEBT LITERATURE In an investigation of the market disciplining effect at US bank holding companies, Bliss and Flannery (2002) note that effective market discipline involves two distinct components: the ability of investors to evaluate a firm’s financial position, and to produce or trigger change at the bank management level. The authors investigate the market disciplining effect of shareholders and subordinated bondholders by examining their monitoring and influencing power at US bank holding companies. While they find evidence about substantial monitoring effects, market signals are not sufficient to influence managerial actions. Flannery and Sorescu (1996) investigate the market’s ability to recognize default risk in subordinated debentures and reject the null hypothesis that investors cannot differentiate among the risks of US banking institutions. Flannery (1998) argues that while government regulation is 5 Some studies have also examined interbank market discipline. Furfine (2001) investigates the disciplining effects of the overnight federal funds market and finds that interest rates are dependent on the credit risk of the borrowers. King (2008) uses 20 years of panel data to provide evidence on interbank money market discipline, whereby banks with high credit risk have consistently paid higher rates on interbank loans compared to low risk banks. Similar discipline may be affected by counterparties to off-balance sheet activities. One study finds evidence of market discipline in the standby letter of credit market (Koppenhaver and Stover, 1994), 4 likely to displace private efforts to evaluate banks, market investors and analysts may improve banks’ corporate governance mechanisms.6 Jagtiani, Kaufman, and Lemieux (2000) also find evidence of credit risk pricing in bank and bank holding company debt, and argue that requiring banks to issue subordinated debt is likely to reveal additional information about the financial condition of the issuer and to supplement prudential regulatory discipline. DeYoung, Flannery, Lang, and Sorescu (2001) use supervisory CAMEL ratings and find that examiners have private information that is not captured in contemporaneous bond yields, but is reflected in bond yields one or two quarters later, suggesting a positive market reaction to supervisory recognition of developing problems. Kwast, Covitz, Hancock, Houpt, Adkins, Barger, Bouchard, Connolly, Bradly, English, Evanoff, and Wall (1999) and Evanoff and Wall (2000) summarize arguments in favor of mandatory subordinated debt, including the sending of important signals for supervisory discipline, and address some potential criticisms by presenting a proposal for the use of subordinated debt in bank capital regulation. Evanoff and Wall (2001, 2002) attempt to predict supervisor ratings of CAMELS by considering subordinated debt yields; however, results show that subordinated debt signals can be noisy, leading to many misclassifications. Litan (2000) suggests linking subordinated debt with prompt corrective action. Evanoff and Wall (2002) conclude that a mandatory subordinated debt requirement would be a useful source of indirect discipline, but they do not favor subordinated debt signals as prompt corrective action triggers. Flannery (2005) argues that the inclination of supervisors to help large distressed banks mitigates investors’ incentives to discipline these firms, and proposes “Reverse convertible debentures” as a transparent un-levering mechanism. 6 Blum (2002), however, argues that Similarly, Cole and Gunther (1998) find that off-site monitoring is more accurate in predicting bank survivability than two-quarter old supervisory CAMEL ratings. Berger, Davies, and Flannery (2000) also report that, except for recent bank examinations and inspections, bond and equity markets are more accurate in predicting bank performance than supervisory assessments. 5 subordinated debt results in greater market discipline only if banks can credibly commit to a certain level of risk. Since banks have an incentive to increase risk taking after contracting the interest rate on the debt, the author demonstrates that subordinated debt may have an ambiguous impact on risk-taking incentives. Balasubramnian and Cyree (2011) argue that the reduction in the risk sensitivity of yield spreads on bank subordinated debt can be explained by the market’s increased perception that large issuers will be bailed out by the government and because banks started selling a new class of trust-preferred securities that is junior to subordinate debt. Evanoff, Jagtiani, and Nakata (2011) state that failure of some researchers to find a significant relation between yield and risk is due to lack of secondary market liquidity and they use the yields on bank subordinated debt at time of issue when the bonds are most liquid and show that subordinated debt yields do reflect bank risk. Acharya, Anginer, and Warburton (2013) suggest that market discipline effectiveness may vary across different institution sizes. They find that while credit spreads are risk sensitive for most financial institutions, credit spreads lack risk sensitivity for the largest financial institutions because bondholders of large financial institutions have an expectation that the government will shield them from losses. Other papers investigate the market disciplining effects of subordinated debt in Europe. Sironi (2003) examines whether private investors can differentiate among the risks taken by banks by examining the variability of spreads of subordinated debt. His results indicate that investors do impose market discipline on European banks and that the sensitiveness of bond spreads to bank risk taking has increased as too-big-to-fail guarantees had lessened as of that time. Pop (2006) confirms this result for European, North American, and Japanese banks. Gropp, Vesala, and Vulpes (2006) find that combining the subordinated debt yield spreads, the distance-to-default (DD) measure developed by the KMV Corporation, and a third measure 6 based on accounting information can increase the accuracy of predicting “serious weakening” of a bank’s financial condition by 85 percent. Iannotta (2006) tests for the opaqueness of the European banking industry and reports that ratings agencies are likely to disagree on the riskiness of subordinated debt. He also finds that bank opaqueness increases (decreases) with a larger fraction of financial (physical) assets.7 B. DEPOSIT LITERATURE Deposits represent the bulk of funding for most banks. It is argued that relying on deposits can have costly consequences in terms of asset-liability mismatches and bank runs, causing banks to hold unproductive reserves (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). In contrast, Calomiris and Kahn (1991) view demandable deposits as a means for monitoring bankers’ behavior and debt is considered as an incentive arrangement to promote good behavior by bankers. Similarly, Diamond and Rajan (2001) also emphasize the governance advantages of demandable debt. Flannery (1994) also argues that bank deposits produce a disciplining effect on bank managers to prevent them from undertaking risky investment strategies and expropriating creditors’ wealth. It is commonly believed that deposit insurance distorts depositors’ incentives to monitor banks. A few studies have investigated the market discipline of insured deposits, arguing that insured depositors may not perceive their deposits as being perfectly safe and that they may also be concerned about the solvency of banks. Flannery (1998) contends that depositors are not only concerned about the solvency of banks, but also about the solvency of the insurer and the willingness of the government to support it. Cook and Spellman (1994) report that rates on small 7 Bank opaqueness in the context of the US is also noted by Morgan (2002), who examines the pattern of disagreement between rating agencies when rating banks. 7 Certificates of Deposits (CDs) generally vary with banks’ financial conditions. Park and Peristiani (1998) also find evidence for market discipline by insured depositors, notwithstanding their lower effect compared to uninsured depositors. In a cross-country survey, Demirgüç-Kunt, Karacaovali, and Laeven (2005) show that while less than 49 percent of the 181 surveyed countries have enacted an explicit deposit insurance covering deposits up to some level, only 38 percent of the total are permanently funded, indicating that deposit insurance funds are limited. Except for Norway where the deposit coverage is close to $300,000 and a few other economies where deposits are explicitly fully insured,8 all other countries with explicit deposit insurance have a coverage limit well below that of the US, which was increased from $100,000 to $250,000 in 2008 and this increase was made permanent by Dodd-Frank in 2010. However, the study also points out that several countries without explicit coverage have taken steps in the past to compensate uninsured depositors. So it is not just deposit insurance that matters, but the entire government safety net that helps protect bank creditors, especially for banks considered to be too important to fail. Barrell, Davis, Fic, and Karim (2011) find a direct relationship between bank size and risk taking, which is consistent with the existence of implicit too-big-to-fail insurance that increases moral hazard incentives. In line with this, Jacewitz and Pogach (2013) find that largest banks pay significantly less on comparable deposits than their smaller bank counterparts. Demirguc-Kunt and Huizinga (2004) use cross-country information on deposit insurance systems to investigate the impact of explicit deposit insurance on bank interest rates and market discipline. They find that explicit deposit insurance lowers banks’ interest expenses and makes interest payments less sensitive to bank risk, thus undermining depositor discipline. 8 EU countries with unlimited deposit insurance include Ireland as of September 2008 and Slovenia as of November 2008 until December 2010. 8 Most of the previous research, as well as the main analysis in our study, includes both insured and uninsured deposits because they are often difficult to separate, although we also include an additional analysis of uninsured deposits in the US. Hannan and Hanweck (1988) report a significant relationship between the rates on large and partially insured CDs and bank risk as measured by leverage, variability of earnings, and risk assets. Goldberg and Hudgins (2002) report that depositors adjusted their holdings at thrifts from 1984 to 1994 in response to impending institutional failure. The authors argue that deposits are governed by market discipline, and they recommend decreasing insurance limits on deposits to reduce the “perverse incentive features of deposit insurance” and increase market discipline. Ellis and Flannery (1992) find evidence to suggest that CD rates paid by large money center banks include significant default risk premia. Other studies examining the market discipline effect of deposits include Billet, Garfinkel, and O’Neal (1998), who show that banks tend to rely more on insured funds as they get into trouble, and Park and Peristiani (1998) and Goldberg and Hudgins (1996), who find evidence of depositors’ discipline in US thrifts and S&Ls, respectively. Maechler and McDill (2006) also focus on deposits at US banks to show that, by raising the cost of choosing a higher level of risk, depositor discipline may effectively constrain managers’ behavior. A few studies, however, conclude that deposits have no market disciplining effect on bank managers. Gilbert and Vaughan (2001) do not find unusual deposit withdrawals or spread increases following the announcements of formal enforcement actions. Jordan, Peek, and Rosengren (1999) examine deposit level changes following formal action announcements and improved disclosure for problem banks during a banking crisis and find only a moderate decline 9 in deposit levels. Jagtiani and Lemieux (2001) find no evidence of market discipline in the CD market.9 Research on depositor discipline in the context of European countries is scant. Mondschean and Opiela (1999) report that there is little depositor discipline in Poland, likely because full deposit insurance and government ownership of Polish banks reduce the monitoring incentives of depositors. Birchler and Maechler (2001) find considerable evidence of depositor discipline in Switzerland – depositors are sensitive to bank specific fundamentals, to institutional differences across bank groups, and to institutional changes to the Swiss bank depositor protection system. Using a sample of Central and Eastern European banks, Distinguin, Kouassi, and Tarazi (2013) find that banks with a higher proportion of interbank deposits have lower levels of risk. Depositor discipline has recently been investigated in Russia, where Ungan, Caner, and Özyildirim (2008) show that well-capitalized and more liquid banks significantly increase their deposits. Semenova (2007) also analyzes depositor discipline in Russia by different groups of banks (state, private, and foreign). The author finds that depositors of foreign banks exert virtually no discipline, while depositors of state banks use a quantity-based discipline mechanism, but the only significant characteristic is bank size (depositors are sensitive to bank total assets even after introduction of the deposit insurance system), and depositors of private domestic banks discipline their banks by quantity, price, and by switching from on-call to longterm deposits. Karas, Pyle, and Schoors (2013) use the introduction of deposit insurance for 9 In a contemporaneous working paper that is closest to ours, Lambert, Noth, and Schüwer (2013) find an increase in risk taking by some banks in the U.S. after the deposit insurance cap was raised from $100,000 to $250,000 in 2008. However, they do not look at depositor discipline directly. 10 households in Russia as an event study to test for its effect on market discipline, and find that deposit inflows and outflows are less sensitive for insured than for uninsured depositors. Much of the empirical research on depositor discipline in countries other than the US or Europe is for Latin American countries. Martinez Peria and Schmukler (2001) find that depositors disciplined banks by withdrawing deposits and by requiring higher interest rates in Argentina, Chile, and Mexico during the 1980s and 1990s. Calomiris and Powell (2001) find that in Argentina, both large deposit withdrawals and high interest rates are associated with great asset risk and leverage. Barajas and Steiner (2000) report that depositors in Colombia prefer better capitalized, highly liquid, and profitable banks with low non-performing loans. In Japan, the depositor discipline study of small financial institutions by Murata and Hori (2006) supports the effective role of market discipline. Hori, Murata, and Ito (2009) also investigate depositor discipline for institutions in Japan. They find that depositors appreciate the difference between healthy banks and risky banks, and that depositors of larger institutions are more sensitive to bank risk than those of smaller institutions. Other related research includes Ghosh and Das (2006), who find that depositors in India ‘punish’ banks for risky behavior, judged in terms of either the quantity or the price variable. However, Omet and Fayyoumi (2004) document that depositor discipline is largely non-existent in Jordan. III - DATA AND METHODOLOGY A. DATA We retrieve the financial statements for 2,038 banking organizations in the US and 21 EU countries plus Switzerland from the Bankscope database provided by Bureau van Dijk and Fitch 11 Ratings, including bank holding companies (BHCs) and commercial banks. We divide our sample into two periods: the pre-crisis period 1997-2007 (with a total of 13,494 bank-year observations) and the crisis period 2008-2009 (with a total of 3,995 bank-year observations).10 We also extract data from Bankscope on shareholder ownership to identify the majority shareholder to account for foreign-controlled institutions. Next, we match the banking sample with data from the Zephyr database (Bureau van Dijk Electronic Publishing), which provides historical information on merger and acquisition deals since the year 1997. We incorporate information on bank mergers and acquisitions (M&As). We specifically exclude from our sample bank-year observations in which a merger deal is concluded to avoid counting the consequent increase in bank size as a reduction in depositor discipline and to avoid problems in measuring lagged variables. In a follow-up analysis, we collect data from the bank Call Reports in the US, which separate uninsured deposits from insured deposits and focus on the uninsured, which should be more sensitive to risk. We describe the data and results for this analysis in detail in Section V – Robustness. Table 1 lists the distribution of banking organizations across countries for the pre-crisis period 1997-2007 and the crisis period 2008-2009.11 In our sample, almost 46% of all banks are from the US. The majority of banks in all countries are commercial banks, with the lone exception of the US where bank holding companies have a dominant presence relative to other countries. We also categorize our banks as listed and non-listed financial institutions. Publiclylisted financial institutions represent less than 20% of all banks, with more than 64% of them located in the US. Also, the number of listed institutions varies from one in some EU countries 10 During the sample period, EU publicly traded firms were required to switch from their national accounting procedures to IFRS no later than January 1, 2005. We account for the change in accounting practices by including time dummies in our analysis, and we do not believe that the adoption of IFRS standards affects our dependent variables. 11 We winsorize the data at the top and bottom 1st percentile of the distribution. 12 to over one-fourth of all banks in the US. Note that the number of banks has slightly decreased following the recent financial crisis, especially for listed banks. We compute the deposit growth rate on an annual basis for all banks in our sample. 12 Table 2 provides a description of all of the variables and Table 3 presents descriptive statistics for our key variables across the US and the EU for the pre-crisis period 1997-2007 (Panel A) and the crisis period 2008-2009 (Panel B). In both Panels A and B, the average bank size is larger for European banks compared to the US, and there is also greater variability in bank total assets in Europe. However, the average equity-to-assets ratio is higher for the US than for the EU (9.4% vs. 7.7%, respectively, in the pre-crisis period and 10.3% vs. 9.1%, respectively, for the crisis period), and US banks carry, on average, a better loan portfolio quality relative to EU banks. In the pre-crisis period, the average ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) stood at 0.66 percent for the US, while the corresponding figure for the European banks was 4.14 percent. During the crisis period, however, the average gap in the ratio of NPL/Loans between the US and the EU closed considerably, with the mean for the US spiking to 3.61% compared to 4.19% for the EU. Deposit growth was higher in the EU than in the US in the pre-crisis period (11.02% vs. 9.10%, respectively), but this finding is reversed with the advent of the crisis (4.22% vs. 10.08%, respectively, for the EU and the US).13 B. METHODOLOGY We investigate depositor discipline proxied by the deposit growth rate in face of greater bank risk taking. We proxy for bank risk taking using the ratio of equity to assets and an 12 Quantities of deposits may be subject to window dressing, but we do not believe that it is very often the case. The evidence suggests that banks window dress their assets, rather than deposits (see Allen and Saunders 1992). 13 Some of these differences may be attributable to changes in exchange rates, but we do not believe this to be a significant factor because most depositors just deal with their home currency. 13 indicator of loan portfolio performance – the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans.14,15 In robustness checks, we try other measures of loan performance. We regress deposit growth on indicators of bank risk taking, while controlling for bank characteristics and country differences:16 DGRij ,t f ( BankRiskij ,t 1 , DRPij ,t 1 ,Wij ,t , Z j ,t ) it (1) where DGRij,t denotes the deposit growth rate17 for bank i in country j at time t.18 BankRiskij,t-1 proxies the bank’s risk taking in the previous period using the equity-to-assets ratio and the nonperforming-loans-to-total-loans ratio mentioned previously. DRPij,t-1 represents the lagged deposit rate premium.19 Wij,t represents bank controls, including growth in assets20 and market share of assets, institution type in the form of a BHC, and whether the majority shareholder is foreign. The foreign dummy is included because foreign parent organizations may be viewed as sources of strength, or alternatively, foreign owned banks might be more or less opaque than domestic institutions.21 Zj,t controls for country differences for country j at time t, including the presence of explicit deposit insurance, Financial Freedom, the three-month money market rate, the percentage change in real GDP, and the natural logarithm of GDP per capita. Other country 14 Our analysis rests on accounting ratios because market values are unavailable for most banks. Any measurement error introduces a bias against finding statistically significant depositor discipline, which we do find. 15 Kalemli-Ozcan, Sorensen, and Yesiltas (2012) argue that excessive risk taking is not easily detectable at banks because it involves the quality rather than the quantity of assets. 16 We also tried changes in risk and allowed them to have asymmetric effects and found the main results to hold, but more weakly, with no consistent greater effect of either increases or decreases in risk (not shown). 17 Deposit growth rate is calculated as 100 multiplied by the natural logarithm of the ratio of total deposits to total deposits lagged by 1 year. 18 We acknowledge that there could be some inertia in the deposit quantities because some banks significantly rely on term funding, which would bias the results against finding depositor discipline. 19 Deposit rate premium is calculated as 100 multiplied by the difference between deposit rate and the short-term Treasury rate for the country in question measured at year end, where deposit rate equals the ratio of interest expenses to total deposits. 20 Asset growth is included to control for any increase in deposits caused by the bank wanting to keep pace with asset growth. 21 We do not have information on whether banks are government owned, but this should not be a significant issue for most of these developed nations and is not the focus of our study. 14 controls are dummy variables for banks in the UK and in the US because of the different levels of capital market development in these countries. Exceptions are that the US dummy is excluded from the US and EU regressions and the UK dummy is excluded from the US regressions because there is no variation in these variables in these regressions. All variables are expressed in 2007 real U.S. dollars. We estimate equation (1) using random effects.22 The inclusion of the lagged deposit rate premium is to deal with a potential endogeneity problem. High deposit rate premiums may result in an increase in deposit growth in the following year, as depositors may be attracted by the higher rates. We account for this by including a lag of the deposit rate premium in the determination of the deposit growth rate. That is, we examine how sensitive deposit growth is to an increase in bank risk, controlling for lagged deposit rate premium, while controlling for bank and country characteristics. By controlling for DRP, we can also be relatively certain that the DGR reactions to BankRisk reflect actions by the depositors because a change on the part of the banks themselves would generally require a change in the deposit rate premium. As discussed in the robustness section, our results are robust to dropping the lagged deposit rate premium, and to the use of a dynamic model. IV - MAIN EMPIRICAL FINDINGS A. PRE-CRISIS PERIOD 1997-2007 We present the regression results over the pre-crisis period for large banks (above the top 10th percentile of total banking assets in their nation in real 1997 US dollars) in Table 4, with corresponding results for small banks (below the top 10th percentile) in Table 5. We run 22 We also try fixed effects and our main findings are maintained, but doing so results in dropping some of our important control variables (Foreign, BHC, Deposit Insurance, and UK and US dummy variables), so we prefer the random effects model as our main approach. 15 estimations separately for US banks, EU banks, listed banks, and unlisted banks. In all estimations, we include two types of indicators of bank risk taking, capitalization (ratio of equity to assets) and loan portfolio performance (ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans). We first discuss the statistical significance of the main coefficients of interest, and then discuss their economic significance. The DGR pre-crisis regression results for large banks in Table 4 show that the coefficient on equity to assets is positive and significant for large US banks and large unlisted banks, but insignificant for large banks in the EU and large listed banks. A worsening in the ratio of equity to assets – or an increase in bank risk – is positively associated with a reduction in the deposit growth rate at large US banks and large unlisted banks, but has no significant effect on large banks in the EU or large listed banks. Prior to the crisis, depositors at large US banks seemed to react in face of greater bank risk taking (lower equity to assets ratios) by curtailing the rate of growth in their supply of funds. Depositor discipline is also found using the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans. The coefficient estimate on NPL/Loans is negative and significant for large US and EU banks and for large unlisted banks, implying that an increase in NPL/Loans – or an increase in bank risk – reduces deposit growth rates at those banks, but has no significant effect on large listed banks.23 Thus, we find that depositor discipline is more often significant at large US banks. In the EU, there may be a greater ex ante perception on the part of depositors that large banks are likely 23 We acknowledge the possibility that bank supervisors may affect deposit growth rates in response to bank riskiness. To the extent that this occurs, our findings reflect supervisory discipline as well as depositor discipline. However, evidence from Germany suggests that supervisors only seldomly intervene on the liability side of banks’ balance sheets (Berger, Bouwman, Kick, and Schaeck (2014)). 16 to enjoy too-important-to-fail protection compared to the US and/or depositors in the EU may have been less aware of banks’ risks.24 Further, we find that there is less measured depositor discipline for large, listed institutions. As argued above, the measured effect of depositor discipline may be greater at unlisted institutions because depositors have less information available, so that the reaction to any one ratio may be stronger.25 In Table 5, we find a significant and positive relationship between the ratio of equity to assets and DGR for small banks pre-crisis. Lower bank capitalization is associated with reduced deposit growth rates. The quantity response of depositors at small banks to greater risk taking in the form of lower equity to assets is significant across all models except for small unlisted banks. In addition, the coefficient on NPL/Loans is of the expected sign in Table 5 across all specifications. It is negative and highly significant, suggesting that poorer loan portfolio performance and consequently high levels of bank risk are associated with lower deposit growth rates at small banks, whether in the US or EU and across listed and unlisted institutions. We next examine the economic significance of the pre-crisis results using the ratio of equity to assets measure of bank risk taking. We first assess the economic significance of a 1 percentage point increase in the ratio of equity to assets on DGR for large and small banks. In Table 4, the coefficient on equity to assets for large US banks is 85.344. Given an average deposit growth rate for large US banks of 9.10%, a 1 percentage point increase in equity to assets increases the DGR by more than 85 basis points to become 9.95%. An analysis for small US banks shows that the effect of a 1 percentage point increase in bank capitalization is less 24 We acknowledge the possibility that some of the stronger results for the US may be due to more supervisory focus on the leverage ratio compared to the EU. 25 We conduct tests of differences in means for the coefficients on bank risk for large US and EU banks and for large listed and unlisted banks. We find that differences are generally statistically significant across most specifications. 17 economically significant than for large US banks. In Table 5, the coefficient on equity to assets for small banks is 13.796 and is around 16% of the corresponding estimate reported for large US banks.26 The greater economic significance for large banks may reflect that more of the depositors at large banks are uninsured and therefore more sensitive to bank risk or greater knowledge of risk on the part of depositors at large banks than depositors at small banks. For large EU banks, the effect the ratio of equity to assets is not statistically significant. For small EU banks, a 1 percentage point increase in equity to assets raises the deposit growth rates marginally by 21 basis points. Before proceeding to the crisis results, we briefly investigate the extent to which listed/unlisted split may be picking up something besides the information from being on an exchange. We first note that foreign banks make up only a minority of observations of the large listed, large unlisted, small listed, and small unlisted subsamples, with the largest proportional foreign representation in large listed banks (158 of 511 are foreign). Next, we observe that the listed banks are mostly from the US, both for large listed banks (221 of 353 are from the US) and small listed banks (1986 of 2575). No other country has as much as 10% of the listed observations. We also try separating by US and UK versus other countries for listed and unlisted banks in the regressions as an additional way to account for the greater capital market development of these nations. We find that the effect of the ratio of equity to assets is significant for both listed samples (US/UK and other countries) and insignificant for both unlisted samples (US/UK and other countries). The NPL/Loans variable is significant in all four regressions.27 B. CRISIS PERIOD 2008-2009 26 We conduct tests of differences in means for the significance of coefficients on bank risk and similarly find that there are statistical differences in depositor discipline across large and small US banks. 27 These statistics and results are all available upon request from the authors. 18 We next consider the crisis period 2008-2009, and investigate whether discipline is decreased by the government interventions taken at the beginning of the crisis or alternatively, is increased by the public’s heightened awareness of bank risk. We present the results for large and small banks in Tables 6 and 7, respectively. In Table 6, the coefficients on equity to assets and the NPL/Loans ratio lose statistical significance for large banks and are at times of the opposite sign as predicted. These results are consistent with the hypothesis that government interventions during the crisis resulted in weaker depositor discipline for large banks. It is just as likely that these findings are due to reduced test power because of the significantly fewer observations during the crisis period, an alternative we test in Table 8 below, where we look at whether the changes in the coefficients between the crisis period and pre-crisis period are statistically significant. In contrast, as shown in Table 7, the coefficients on our two measures of bank risk remain significant and sometimes increase in magnitude for small US banks, whereas they sometimes are significant and of the opposite sign for small EU banks as compared to the pre-crisis period. Preliminarily, it appears that for small banks, depositor discipline continued for US banks and was weakened or disappeared for EU banks. Again, we will test the changes in the coefficients in Table 8. Table 8 shows our formal tests of the changes in depositor discipline. Specifically, we show t tests of the difference between the coefficients of the key depositor discipline coefficients in Tables 6-7 versus Tables 4-5. Negative signs on Equity/Assets and positive signs on NPL/Loans point to reduced depositor discipline. For clarity, we shade all of the t tests that are significant. We find that, for large banks, the signs generally point in the direction of reduced 19 depositor discipline, and are significant in some cases for NPL/Loans. For small banks, the signs are somewhat mixed, but the significant t tests point to increased depositor discipline US small banks and reduced discipline for small EU banks. Overall, these results are consistent with depositors at large banks in the US and EU and small banks in the EU reducing their discipline due to government actions taken near the beginning of the crisis, but depositors at small US banks maintaining or increasing their discipline due to heightened awareness of bank risk because of the numbers of failures of such banks. To analyze the economic significance of the changes in depositor discipline, we again focus on Equity/Assets ratios using the reduced form results. For the pre-crisis period, we found above that a 1 percentage point increase in equity to assets would increase the expected deposit growth rate for large US banks by an estimated 85.32 basis points. For the crisis period, this is entirely eliminated – it changes to a 40.56 basis point decrease. For large EU banks, listed banks, and unlisted banks, depositor discipline completely vanishes in the crisis period. For small banks, depositor discipline at US banks actually increases in economic significance in the crisis period relative to the pre-crisis period (the coefficient on the ratio of equity to assets increasing from 13.93 to 55.59), but it disappears for EU banks. V - ROBUSTNESS We run a number of robustness checks of our main results. The results are consistent with our main results and are not shown in tables to conserve space. We first test the sensitivity of our results to including other indicators of loan portfolio quality. We consider two alternative measures of loan portfolio performance – the ratios of loan loss reserves to total loans (LLR/Loans) and net charge-offs to total loans (NCO/Loans). When 20 these variables are used in place of NPL/Loans, the Equity/Assets results and the loan performance results are similar to our main results. Specifically, depositor discipline is stronger at large US banks compared to EU banks as well as at large unlisted institutions. We also follow the methodology of Berger, DeYoung, Flannery, Lee, and Oztekin (2008) to test the robustness of our results using a dynamic model that allows for partial adjustment to desired deposit growth rates slowly over time and find our results to be maintained.28 Since we are presenting in this paper a US versus EU perspective on depositor discipline, we run all of our specifications excluding banks in Switzerland and find robust results. We also examine whether our results are fairly consistent across countries in Europe or whether there were any country-specific effects. We find different degrees of depositor discipline in Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, France, Italy, Malta, Norway, Slovenia, Switzerland, and the UK, but no evidence of depositor discipline in Germany, Luxembourg, Netherlands, and Spain.29 The signs of the key coefficients are generally consistent across countries. We also try a cutoff of $50 billion for large banks – motivated by the Dodd-Frank Act provision that designates banking organizations above this level as systemically important to receive additional regulation by the Federal Reserve – and we exclude bank control variables from all specifications because they could be considered as measures of risk. All of our previous findings are preserved. We also consider changes instead of levels of risk, and find that the key coefficients are generally statistically significant for the same variables as for the regressions with levels. We 28 Berger, DeYoung, Flannery, Lee, and Oztekin (2008) use Generalized Method of Moments estimation (Blundell and Bond, 1998) that allows a target variable (the deposit growth rate in our case) to adjust to a long-run desired level slowly over time within a partial adjustment framework. 29 Not all countries are represented in these lists because some nations had too few observations to measure depositor discipline separately. 21 also allow for asymmetric effects of increases and decreases in risk and find the results to generally hold, with no consistent greater effect of either increases or decreases in risk. Additionally, late in 2007, the announcement by the Federal Reserve to start the Term Auction Facility on December 17 and by the European Central Bank (ECB) and the Swiss National Bank (SNB) to hold dollar auctions might have affected the deposit growth rate at the end of 2007. To allow for this, we try ending our pre-crisis period in 2006 and adding 2007 to the crisis period. Our results are qualitatively unchanged. VI – TESTS USING UNINSURED DEPOSITS IN THE US We also acknowledge that the Bankscope data have some limitations. While they have the advantage of allowing a comparison across countries, they also have the disadvantage that the data are not very disaggregated. Thus, we are not able to distinguish between insured versus uninsured deposits. To mitigate these concerns, we use data for the US banks to conduct a supplementary analysis which allows us to focus on uninsured deposits and more directly test depositor discipline. For this analysis, we acquire annual bank data over 1997 – 2009 from the Call Reports, which contain financial information on all commercial banks in the US. We adjust the data to be in real 1997 terms using the GDP price deflator. Our initial dataset comprises 113,807 bank-year observations. We omit observations that do not refer to commercial banks according to the Call Reports Indicator, which leaves us with 102,587 observations. We next remove any observations that have missing or incomplete financial data on basic accounting variables such as total assets and equity, as well as observations that have missing or negative data for income statement variables such as interest expenses, personnel expenses, and non-interest expenses, resulting in 22 102,584 bank-year observations. Following the procedure in Berger and Bouwman (2009), we further refine our sample by excluding observations with no outstanding loans or deposits (i.e., entities not engaged in deposit-taking and loan-making, which are required for banks to be considered commercial banks). In addition, as in our cross-country analysis, we specifically exclude from our sample bank-year observations in which a merger deal is concluded. These screens leave us with a final sample of 94,196 bank-year observations for 10,490 banks over the entire sample period. We do not include the deposit rate premium in this analysis because we do not have sufficient data to calculate this premium for uninsured deposits. Finally, to avoid distortions in ratios that contain equity, for all observations with total equity less than 1% of total assets, we replace equity with 1% of total assets, consistent with the treatment in Berger and Bouwman (2013). We keep observations of the impaired banks because this is where we expect the strongest depositor discipline if there is any. To calculate uninsured deposits, we take all the funds in accounts that are partially insured and subtract off the amount that is insured. This requires separate treatment for several time periods because of the changes in the insured deposit limits over time.30 30 For the period 1997:Q1-2006:Q1, we calculate the uninsured deposits as the amount of bank deposit accounts (demand, savings, and time) with a balance on the report date of more than $100,000 minus the number of such deposit accounts multiplied by $100,000. For the period 2006:Q2-2009:Q2, we take into account the different treatment of deposit retirement accounts versus the rest. Thus, we calculate the uninsured deposits as the amount of bank deposit accounts (demand, savings, and time, excluding retirement accounts) with a balance on the report date of more than $100,000 minus the number of such deposit accounts multiplied by $100,000 plus the amount of bank deposit retirement accounts with a balance on the report date of more than $250,000 minus the number of such deposit accounts multiplied by $250,000. For the period 2009:Q3 onwards, we account for the deposit insurance limit increase from $100,000 to $250,000 for all deposits except foreign ones. Thus, we calculate the uninsured deposits as the amount of bank deposit accounts (demand, savings, and time, including retirement accounts) with a balance on the report date of more than $250,000 minus the number of such deposit accounts multiplied by $250,000. While the last change in deposit insurance took place in October 2008, the call report did not change to reflect it until 2009:Q3. For all time periods, we also add the foreign deposits to the uninsured deposits because foreign deposits are not covered by the FDIC deposit insurance. 23 Our regression results are reported in Table 9 and present the estimated models for both small (below the top 10th percentile of national total assets in real 1997 US dollars) and large banks (above the top 10th percentile of national total assets in real 1997 US dollars). We run estimations separately for the pre-crisis time period 1997-2007 and the crisis period 2008-2009. In all estimations, we include two types of indicators of bank risk taking, capitalization (ratio of capital to assets) and loan portfolio performance (ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans). The regression results in Table 9 columns (1) and (2) show that over the pre-crisis period, the coefficient on equity to assets is positive and significant for both large and small US banks, while the coefficient estimate on NPL/Loans is negative and significant for both size classes in the US. Using both risk indicators results suggest that prior to the crisis, depositors exerted market discipline at US banks and reacted in face of greater bank risk taking by curtailing the rate of growth in their supply of uninsured deposits, consistent with our main results for US when using the Bankscope data, which is a much smaller data set that comingles insured and uninsured deposits. When looking at the crisis period results in columns (3) and (4), we find that the coefficient on equity to assets flips sign and loses significance for large US banks, but it is still positive and significant and slightly higher for the small banks. However, the coefficient estimate on NPL/Loans is no longer significant for either large or small banks in the US. Consistent with our prior findings, these results suggest that depositor discipline declined during the financial crisis for large US banks potentially due to government interventions. In contrast, depositor discipline is maintained during the crisis for small US banks, at least for the equity to assets ratio, potentially due to heightened awareness of the uninsured depositors in these banks because of the numbers of small banks that failed during the crisis, although other explanations are possible. 24 Table 10 shows t tests of the difference between the coefficients of the key depositor discipline coefficients between the crisis and pre-crisis periods in Table 9. Negative signs on Equity/Assets and positive signs on NPL/Loans point to reduced depositor discipline. For clarity, we shade all of the t tests that are significant. By looking at the difference between the crisis and pre-crisis periods, we find that discipline was significantly reduced for Equity/Assets for the large banks and also reduced for the small banks when looking at NPL/Loans. The other results did not significantly change, which could reflect the lack of test power because of the small number of observations for the crisis period. VII - CONCLUSIONS This paper examines depositor discipline of bank risk taking in the US and EU (plus Switzerland) in the 11-year period prior to the recent financial crisis, and in 2 years of crisis. We also analyze how the effects of such discipline may differ between large and small institutions, and between listed and unlisted banking organizations. We look at the effects on deposit growth, and examine whether depositors react more to bank equity-to-asset ratios or measures of loan portfolio performance. Finally, and most importantly, we test the hypothesis that the measures that governments took at the beginning of the crisis reduced depositor discipline versus the hypothesis that depositor discipline may have increased due to heightened depositor attention to bank risk. Our results suggest that there was significant depositor discipline in both the US and EU prior to the crisis, but generally that the effects were stronger in the US for large institutions, consistent with the conjecture that government bailouts were considered to be more likely in the EU and/or that depositors in the EU may have been less aware of banks’ risk. We also find more 25 economically significant depositor discipline for large US institutions (larger than the top 10th percentile of national assets) than for small US institutions (smaller than the top 10th percentile of national assets), possibly reflecting the greater preponderance of uninsured deposits in the large institutions or greater sophistication of large bank depositors. However, we find less measured discipline for large, listed institutions compared to other institutions, perhaps because depositors at unlisted institutions have less information available, so that the reaction to the measured ratios may be stronger. Finally, we find evidence consistent with the hypothesis that depositor discipline generally declined after implementation of the government actions, except for the case of small US banks, where depositors, particularly those that were uninsured, may have become more sensitive to bank risk taking through capital ratios, due to heightened awareness of the numbers of small banks that failed during the crisis. In terms of policy conclusions, our findings suggest that significant depositor discipline existed prior to the recent financial crisis, and that actions such as raising deposit insurance coverage limits, reducing co-insurance, and rescuing troubled institutions may have eroded an important source of discipline on the risk taking of banking organizations in both the US and EU. However, Basel III may be complementary to depositor discipline: To the extent that it is effective in getting banks to raise their equity capital, the affected banks will be rewarded with additional deposits. In addition, under the Dodd-Frank Act, US banks with over $50 billion in assets are considered systemically important, and may be required by the Federal Reserve to hold additional capital, with implications for deposit growth. Finally, making the public aware of the risks to depositors may have a beneficial effect in terms of disciplining risky banks. Future research beyond the scope of this paper might consider ex-post failures as alternative measures of ex-post risk taking instead of our lagged variables of equity to assets or 26 nonperforming loans to total loans. It is also possible to consider executive compensation schemes (e.g., Cheng, Hong, and Scheinkman, 2011) or employee ownership structures (e.g., Berger, Imbierowicz, and Rauch, 2014) as alternatives to depositor discipline in controlling bank risk. 27 REFERENCES Acharya, V.V., Anginer, D., and A.J., Warburton, 2013, “The End of Market Discipline? Investor Expectations of Implicit State Guarantees”, Working Paper, New York University Stern School of Business. Allen, L. and A. Saunders, 1992, “Bank window dressing: Theory and evidence,” Journal of Banking and Finance 16: 585-623. Balasubramnian, B. and K.B., Cyree, 2011, “Market Discipline of Banks: Why Are Yield Spreads on Bank-Issued Subordinated Notes and Debentures Not Sensitive to Bank Risks?,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 35, 21-35. Barajas, A. and R. Steiner, 2000, “Depositor Behavior and Market Discipline in Colombia,” International Monetary Fund Seminar Series 51:1–39. Barrell, R., E.P. Davis, T. Fic, and D. Karim, 2011, “Is there a Link from Bank Size to Risk Taking? Working Paper. Brunel University. Barth, J.R., G. Caprio, Jr., and R. Levine, 2013, "Bank Regulation and Supervision in 180 Countries from 1999 to 2011." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 18733. Berger, A.N., and C.H.S. Bouwman, 2009, “Bank Liquidity Creation,” Review of Financial Studies 22: 3779-3837. Berger, A.N., and C.H.S. Bouwman, 2013, “How Does Capital Affect Bank Performance During Financial Crises, Journal of Financial Economics 109: 146-176. Berger, A.N., C.H.S. Bouwman, T. K. Kick, and K. Schaeck, 2014, “Bank risk taking and liquidity creation following regulatory interventions and capital support,” Working Paper, University of South Carolina. Berger, A.N., S.M. Davies, and M. J. Flannery, 2000, “Comparing market and regulatory assessments of bank performance: Who knows what when?” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 24: 641-667. Berger, A.N., R. DeYoung, M.J. Flannery, D. Lee., and O. Oztekin, 2008, “How do large banking organizations manage their capital ratios?” Journal of Financial Services Research 34: 123-149. Berger, A.N., B. Imbierowicz, and C. Rauch, 2014, “The Roles of Corporate Governance in Bank Failures During the Recent Financial Crisis,” Working Paper, University of South Carolina. Bertay, A.C. A. Demirguc-Kunt, and H. Huizinga, forthcoming, "Do We Need Big Banks? Evidence on Performance, Strategy and Market Discipline," Journal of Financial Intermediation. Billet, M.T., J.A. Garfinkel, and E.S. O’Neal, 1998, “The cost of market versus regulatory discipline in banking,” Journal of Financial Economics 48: 333-358. Birchler, U.W. and A.M. Maechler, 2001, “Do depositors discipline Swiss banks?” Swiss National Bank, Working Paper No. 01.06. 28 Bliss, R.R. and M.J. Flannery, 2002, “Market discipline in the governance of U.S. bank holding companies: Monitoring vs. influencing,” European Finance Review 6: 361-395. Blum, J.M., 2002, “Subordinated debt, market discipline, and banks' risk taking,” Journal of Banking & Finance 26: 1427-1441. Carbo-Valverde, S., E. J. Kane, and F. Rodriguez-Fernandez, 2008, “Evidence of differences in the effectiveness of safety-net management in European Union countries,” Journal of Financial Services Research 34: 151-176. Calomiris, C.W. and C.M. Kahn, 1991, “The role of demandable debt in structuring optimal banking arrangements,” American Economic Review 81: 497-513. Calomiris C.W. and A. Powell, 2001, “Can emerging market bank regulators establish credible discipline? The case of Argentina, 1992–1999,” in Frederic S. Mishkin (ed) Prudential supervision: what works and what doesn’t? University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Cheng, I-H, H. Hong, and J.A. Scheinkman, 2011, “Yesterday's Heroes: Compensation and Creative Risk-Taking,” Working Paper Series, No. 16176, National Bureau of Economic Research. Cole, R.A. and J.W. Gunther, 1998, “Predicting Bank Failures: A Comparison of On- and OffSite Monitoring Systems.” Journal of Financial Services Research 13, 103-17. Cook, D.O. and L.J. Spellman, 1994, “Repudiation risk and restitution costs: Toward understanding premiums on insured deposits,” Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, 26 (3) Part 1: 439-459. Demirgüç-Kunt, A., and H. Huizinga, (2004), “Market Discipline and Deposit Insurance,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51, 375-399. Demirgüç-Kunt, A., B. Karacaovali, and L. Laeven, 2005, “Deposit insurance around the world: A comprehensive database,” Policy Research Working Paper #3628, Washington, DC: World Bank. DeYoung, R., Flannery, M. J., Lang, W. W., and S. M., Sorescu, 2001, “The Information Content of Bank Exam Ratings and Subordinated Debt Prices,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 33, 900-925. Diamond, D.W. and P.H. Dybvig, 1983, “Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy 91: 401-419. Diamond, D.W. and R.G. Rajan, 2001, “Banks, short term debt and financial crises: Theory, policy implications and applications,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 54: 37-71. Distinguin, I., T. Kouassi, T., and A. Tarazi, 2013, “Interbank Deposits and Market Discipline: Evidence from Central and Eastern Europe,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 41, 544-560. Ellis, D.M. and M.J. Flannery, 1992, “Does the Debt Market Assess Large Banks, Risk?,” Journal of Monetary Economics 30: 481-502. Evanoff, D.D. and L.D. Wall, 2000, “Subordinated debt as bank capital: A proposal for regulatory reform," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago: Economic Perspectives: 40-53. 29 Evanoff, D.D. and L.D. Wall, 2001, “Sub-Debt Yield Spreads as Bank Risk Measures,” Journal of Financial Services Research, 20, 121-145. Evanoff, D.D. and L.D. Wall, 2002, “Measures of the Riskiness of Banking Organizations: Subordinated Debt Yields, Risk-Based Capital, and Examination Ratings,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 26, 989-1009. Evanoff, D. D., J. A., Jagtiani, and T., Nakata, 2011. “Enhancing Market Discipline in Banking: The Role of Subordinated Debt in Financial Regulatory Reform,” Journal of Economics and Business, 63, 1-22. Flannery, M.J., 1994, “Debt maturity and the deadweight cost of leverage: Optimally financing banking firms,” American Economic Review 84: 320-331. Flannery M.J., 1998, “Using market information in prudential bank supervision: A Review of the U.S. empirical evidence,” Journal of Money Credit and Banking 30: 273–305. Flannery, M.J., 2005, “No pain, No gain? Effecting market discipline via ‘reverse convertible debentures,’” in Hal S. Scott (ed.), Capital Adequacy beyond Basel: Banking, Securities, and Insurance (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Flannery, M.J. and S.M. Sorescu, 1996, “Evidence of bank market discipline in subordinated debenture yields: 1983-1991,” Journal of Finance 51: 1347-1377. Furfine, C.H., 2001, “Banks as monitors of other banks: Evidence from the overnight federal funds market,” Journal of Business 74: 33–57. Ghosh, S. and A. Das, 2006, “Depositor discipline in Indian banking: Separating facts from folklore”, Reserve Bank of India, MPRA Paper No. 17427, http://mpra.ub.unimuenchen.de/17427/ Gilbert, R.A., and M.D. Vaughan, 2001, “Do depositors care about enforcement actions?” Journal of Economics and Business 53: 283-311. Goldberg, L.G. and S.C. Hudgins, 2002, “Depositor discipline and changing strategies for regulating thrift institutions,” Journal of Financial Economics 63 (1): 263-274. Goldberg, L.G. and S.C. Hudgins, 1996, “Response of uninsured depositors to impending S&L failures: Evidence of depositor discipline,” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 36: 311-325. Gropp, R., Vesala, J. and G. Vulpes, 2006, “Equity and Bond Market Signals as Leading Indicators of Bank Fragility,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 38, 399-428. Hannan, T.H. and G.A. Hanweck, 1988, “Bank insolvency risk and the market for large certificates of deposit,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20: 203-211. Hori, M., Y. Ito, and K. Murata, 2009, “Do depositors respond rationally to bank risks? Evidence from Japanese banks during crises,” Pacific Economic Review, 14:5 Iannotta, G., 2006, “Testing for opaqueness in the European banking industry: Evidence from bond credit ratings,” Journal of Financial Services Research 30(3), 287-309. Jacewitz, S., Pogach, J., 2013, “Deposit Rate Advantages at the Largest Banks,” Working Paper, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 30 Jagtiani, J., G.G. Kaufman, and C. Lemieux, 2000, “Do markets discipline banks and bank holding companies? Evidence from debt pricing,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper. Jagtiani, J. and C. Lemieux, 2001, “Markets discipline prior to failure,” Journal of Economics and Business 53: 313–324. Jordan, J.S., J. Peek, and E.S. Rosengren, 1999, “The impact of greater bank disclosure amidst banking crises,” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Working Paper, No. 99-1. Kalemli-Ozcan, S., B. Sorensen, and S. Yesiltas, 2012, "Leverage Across Firms, Banks, and Countries," Journal of International Economics 88(2), 284-298. Karas, A., W. Pyle, and K. Schoors, 2013, “Deposit Insurance, Banking Crises, and Market Discipline: Evidence from a Natural Experiment on Deposit Flows and Rates,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45: 179–200. King, T.B., 2008, “Discipline and liquidity in the interbank market,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 40 (2/3): 295-317. Koppenhaver, G.D. and R.D. Stover, 1994, “Standby letters of credit and bank capital: Evidence of market discipline." Journal of Banking and Finance 18 (3): 553-73. Kwast, M. L., D. M. Covitz, D. Hancock, J. V. Houpt, D. P. Adkins, N. Barger, B. Bouchard, J. F. Connolly, T. F. Brady, W. B. English, D. D. Evanoff, and L. D. Wall, 1999, “Using Subordinated Debt as an Instrument of Market Discipline,” Federal Reserve Board of Governors. Lambert, C., F. Noth, and U. Schüwer, 2013, “How do insured deposits affect bank stability? Evidence from the 2008 Emergency Economic Stabilization Act,” 8th Annual Conference, Financial Intermediation Research Society, Dubrovnik. Litan, R.E., 2000, “International bank capital standards: Next steps,” in Global Financial Crises: Lessons From Recent Events, Joseph R. Bisignano, William C. Hunter, and George C. Kaufman (eds.), Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishing: 221-231. Maechler, A.M. and K.M. McDill, 2006, “Dynamic depositor discipline in US banks,” Journal of Banking and Finance 30 (7): 1871-1898. Martinez Peria, M.S. and S.L. Schmukler, 2001, “Do depositors punish banks for bad behavior? Market discipline, deposit insurance, and banking crises,” The Journal of Finance 56 (3): 10291052. Mondschean, T.S. and T.P. Opiela, 1999, “Bank time deposit rates and market discipline in Poland: the impact of state ownership and deposit insurance reform,” Journal of Financial Services Research 15:179–196. Morgan, D.P., 2002, “Rating banks: Risk and uncertainty in an opaque industry,” American Economic Review 92: 874-888. Murata, K. and M. Hori, 2006, “Do small depositors exit from bad banks? Evidence from small financial institutions in Japan,” The Japanese Economic Review, Vol. 57, No 2, June 2006. Omet, G. and N. Fayyoumi, 2004, “Do depositors discipline for risk and reward for cash prizes: The case of the Jordanian banking sector,” ERF 11th Annual Conference: Post Conflict Reconstruction, Lebanon. 31 Park, S. and S. Peristiani, 1998, “Market discipline by thrift depositors,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30 (3): 347-365. Pop, A., 2006, 'Market Discipline in International Banking Regulation: Keeping the Playing Field Level'. Journal of Financial Stability, 2, 286-310. Semenova, M., 2007, “How depositors discipline banks: The case of Russia,” Economics Education and Research Consortium, Working Paper Series, ISSN 1561-2422, No 07/02. Sironi, A., 2003, “Testing for market discipline in the European banking industry: Evidence from subordinated debt issues,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 35, 443-472. Ungan, E., S. Caner, and S. Özyildirim, 2008, “Depositors’ assessment of bank riskiness in the Russian Federation,” Journal of Financial Services Research 33: 77-101. 32 Table 1 Distribution of Banks across Countries for the Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 and Crisis Period 2008-2009 COUNTRY Austria Belgium Cyprus Denmark Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 Num. of Banks Listed BHC 42 5 7 34 2 8 8 3 1 38 23 3 Crisis Period 2008-2009 Num. of Banks Listed BHC 39 34 8 38 3 4 3 18 5 8 1 3 Finland France Germany Greece Iceland Ireland 10 143 132 24 5 36 2 8 12 12 1 4 1 4 12 1 0 0 10 143 123 24 5 36 3 7 8 10 0 2 1 6 10 1 0 0 Italy Liechtenstein Luxembourg Malta Monaco Netherlands 143 5 92 6 8 57 15 1 1 2 1 3 11 1 6 0 0 15 143 5 92 4 8 57 13 1 1 1 1 5 11 1 6 0 0 13 16 31 12 65 16 65 1 5 2 14 4 11 2 8 0 1 4 9 16 31 11 65 16 64 1 4 3 8 4 8 2 8 0 1 4 9 120 930 2038 8 250 390 25 475 594 119 929 2020 6 230 344 23 472 585 Norway Portugal Slovenia Spain Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom US Total 33 Table 2 Variable Descriptions Variable Name Description Deposit Growth 100 multiplied by the natural logarithm of the ratio total deposits to total deposits lagged by 1 year. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope. Equity/Assets The ratio of equity to total assets. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope NPL/Loans Bank Size A measure of loan portfolio performance, calculated as the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans. Bankscope defines nonperforming loans as all impaired loans falling in two types of retail lending, residential mortgages and other consumer loans, as well as corporate and commercial loans. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope. 100 multiplied by the difference between deposit rate and the short-term Treasury rate in that country measured at the end of the year; where deposit rate equals the ratio of interest expense to deposits and money market funding. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope. The natural logarithm of total assets. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope. Market Share The bank’s market share in assets. Source: Authors’ Calculations from Bankscope. Money Market Rate The three-month money market rate. Source: Thomson Datastream Advance 4.0 Foreign A dummy variable set to 1 if the majority shareholder of the bank is a foreigner. BHC A dummy variable for Bank Holding Companies. Source: Bankscope. Deposit Insurance A dummy variable set to 1 if there is an explicit deposit insurance scheme in a country and depositors were fully compensated the last time a bank failed. Source: Barth, Caprio and Levine (2013) The freedom for banks to engage in nontraditional banking activities. Source: Heritage Foundation. Deposit Rate premium Financial Freedom GDP Growth GDP pc Uninsured Deposit Growth (US) Rate of growth in real GDP calculated as 100 multiplied by the natural logarithm of the ratio of real GDP to real GDP lagged by 1 year. Source: Authors’ Calculations from the International Financial Statistics. The natural logarithm of GDP per capita. Authors’ Calculations from the International Financial Statistics. 100 multiplied by the natural logarithm of the ratio of uninsured deposits to uninsured deposits lagged by 1 year. Uninsured deposits are calculated as discussed in footnote 24 in the text. Source: Authors’ Calculations from US Call Report. 34 Table 3 Descriptive Statistics Total Assets are in million of real U.S. 1997 dollars, DGR is deposit growth rate (in %), Equity/Assets is the ratio of equity to total assets, and NPL/Loans is the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (in %). Total Assets Panel A: Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 Mean 25,900 Std Dev 108,000 US Banks Min 8.2 Max 2,190,000 Mean 38,800 Std Dev 172,000 EU Banks Min 21.5 Max 2,970,000 Panel B: Crisis Period 2008-2009 Mean 48,000 Std Dev 202,000 US Banks Min 391 Max 2,220,000 Mean 74,500 Std Dev 288,000 EU Banks Min 6 Max 3,500,000 DGR Equity/ Assets NPL/ Loans 9.104 14.037 -10.226 46.515 11.023 22.145 -30.133 59.829 0.094 0.029 0.048 0.175 0.077 0.051 0.019 0.217 0.658 0.718 0.000 4.194 4.144 4.268 0.000 15.565 10.082 21.152 -89.209 113.871 4.220 34.762 -191.213 152.858 0.103 0.051 0.014 0.381 0.091 0.116 0.000 0.820 3.611 3.849 0.000 20.432 4.197 4.105 0.000 22.110 35 Table 4 Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007: Large Banks, Deposit Growth Rate Models The dependent variable is deposit growth rate (DGR); bank risk variables include the lagged values of the ratio of equity to assets (Equity/Asset) and of the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) as a measure of loan portfolio performance. Lagged DRP is the lagged deposit rate premium. Market Share is the bank’s national share in assets and Assets Growth is the lagged value of the growth in bank assets; Foreign identifies the largest shareholder as a foreign entity; BHC is a dummy variable for bank holding companies; DI is a dummy variable for explicit deposit insurance; Fin. Freedom is the financial freedom of banks to engage in nontraditional activities; MM Rate is the three-month money market rate; GDP growth is the real growth in GDP; GDP pc is per capita gross domestic product; and US and UK are dummies for banks in the US and UK, respectively. All variables are expressed in 1000s of 1997 real U.S. dollars. The constant term is not reported. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p<.1, ** p<.05, *** p<.01 US Banks Equity/Assets NPL/Loans EU Banks Listed Unlisted 85.344 68.12 66.665 66.436 (26.845)*** (65.088) (48.570) (29.016)** -3.417 -1.256 -0.151 -2.213 (0.810)*** (0.576)** (0.822) (0.638)*** Lagged DRP -0.012 -0.292 0.524 -0.243 (0.187) (0.317) (0.383) (0.190) Market Share 185.197 0.418 -0.663 -10.07 (54.658)*** (9.021) (9.005) (20.382) 0.000 -0.057 -0.017 -0.02 (0.014) (0.014)*** (0.013) (0.014) -1.949 -4.908 -1.508 -4.21 (2.010) (2.823)* (1.847) (3.175) -1.513 2.307 7.111 -1.1 (1.583) (3.516) (4.243)* (2.029) 6.529 -10.645 9.913 (5.258) (6.692) (7.025) 0.036 -0.018 0.126 (0.154) (0.151) (0.210) -0.363 2.143 0.644 0.275 (0.537) (1.408) (0.852) (0.911) 0.827 -0.097 1.614 1.354 Assets Growth Foreign BHC DI Fin. Freedom MM Rate GDP Growth GDP pc (0.857) (1.098) (0.802)** (0.848) -25.856 5.192 -3.38 -0.49 (24.131) (5.341) (7.013) (8.881) -9.375 -6.754 -6.287 (7.225) (7.466) (9.440) -11.915 -15.499 (4.990)** (6.514)** 245 378 UK US No. of Obs. 457 166 36 Table 5 Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007: Small Banks, Deposit Growth Rate Models The dependent variable is deposit growth rate (DGR); bank risk variables include the lagged values of the ratio of equity to assets (Equity/Asset) and of the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) as a measure of loan portfolio performance. Lagged DRP is the lagged deposit rate premium. Market Share is the bank’s national share in assets and Assets Growth is the lagged value of the growth in bank assets; Foreign identifies the largest shareholder as a foreign entity; BHC is a dummy variable for bank holding companies; DI is a dummy variable for explicit deposit insurance; Fin. Freedom is the financial freedom of banks to engage in nontraditional activities; MM Rate is the three-month money market rate; GDP growth is the real growth in GDP; GDP pc is per capita gross domestic product; and US and UK are dummies for banks in the US and UK, respectively. All variables are expressed in 1000s of 1997 real U.S. dollars. The constant term is not reported. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p<.1, ** p<.05, *** p<.01 US Banks Equity/Assets 13.796 Lagged DRP Assets Growth Foreign BHC 9.88 (9.013)** (11.404)*** (6.383) -1.664 -0.731 -0.788 -0.996 (0.290)*** (0.165)*** (0.270)*** (0.161)*** 0.014 -0.223 -0.154 -0.034 (0.158) (0.218) (0.101) 801.56 16.919 11.963 3.688 (603.100) (7.755)** (10.441) (12.347) 0.01 -0.007 0.01 0.004 (0.004)*** (0.007) -0.639 0.632 0.814 -1.706 (0.950) (1.294) (1.100) (1.272) 0.439 3.669 0.87 0.612 (0.604) (2.195)* GDP pc (1.225) 1.49 3.964 (2.130) (2.493) (2.931) -0.027 0.003 -0.067 (0.056) (0.056) (0.049) 0.089 2.505 -0.377 0.369 (0.163) (0.524)*** (0.271) (0.251) 0.34 -1.345 1.112 0.296 (0.253) (0.468)*** (0.299)*** (0.274) -29.754 5.489 -0.716 2.65 (6.602)*** (1.962)*** (3.277) (1.938) -9.548 5.519 -3.803 (2.694)*** (6.961) (2.509) -9.252 -8.251 (2.509)*** (1.643)*** 1954 2643 UK US No. of Obs. (0.005) (2.147) Fin. Freedom GDP Growth (0.005)** 2.618 DI MM Rate Unlisted 50.48 (0.099) Market Share Listed 20.501 (6.197)** NPL/Loans EU Banks 3509 1088 37 Table 6 Crisis Period 2008-2009: Large Banks, Deposit Growth Rate Models The dependent variable is deposit growth rate (DGR); bank risk variables include the lagged values of the ratio of equity to assets (Equity/Asset) and of the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) as a measure of loan portfolio performance. Lagged DRP is the lagged deposit rate premium. Market Share is the bank’s national share in assets and Assets Growth is the lagged value of the growth in bank assets; Foreign identifies the largest shareholder as a foreign entity; BHC is a dummy variable for bank holding companies; DI is a dummy variable for explicit deposit insurance; Fin. Freedom is the financial freedom of banks to engage in nontraditional activities; MM Rate is the three-month money market rate; GDP growth is the real growth in GDP; GDP pc is per capita gross domestic product; and US and UK are dummies for banks in the US and UK, respectively.31 All variables are expressed in 1000s of 1997 real U.S. dollars. The constant term is not reported. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p<.1, ** p<.05, *** p<.01 US Banks Equity/Assets NPL/Loans Lagged DRP Market Share Assets Growth Foreign BHC EU Banks 4.549 105.191 -62.761 (97.537) (147.617) (97.960) (107.782) -1.627 1.48 1.385 2.754 (2.959) (1.418) (1.830) (2.356) -1.104 -1.226 -0.461 -4.421 (1.591) (0.869) (0.606) (1.993)** -83.08 -5.207 5.272 -142.354 (171.485) (26.432) (21.796) (122.789) 0.093 -0.278 -0.033 0.098 (0.124) (0.173) (0.091) (0.147) -1.42 -3.691 -5.633 -1.115 (8.358) (6.532) (7.487) (9.484) -5.985 7.136 7.09 2.787 (7.105) (8.537) (10.810) (11.344) -6.176 -9.323 7.859 (23.385) (19.528) (48.077) -0.056 -0.412 1.297 (0.447) (0.495) (1.011) -2.79 -0.135 -3.845 (6.295) (9.005) (12.964) Fin. Freedom MM Rate GDP Growth GDP pc UK 0.214 1.463 -3.5 (2.979) (2.405) (8.987) -15.299 -6.771 -19.585 (16.384) (23.056) (27.744) 1.643 -9.271 (22.930) (44.247) US 31 Unlisted -30.897 DI No. of Obs. Listed 41 40 -5.517 -4.673 (12.859) (16.384) 32 49 The UK dummy variable is dropped from the regressions on listed banks as all of the large UK banks were listed during the crisis sample. 38 Table 7 Crisis Period 2008-2009: Small Banks, Deposit Growth Rate Models The dependent variable is deposit growth rate (DGR); bank risk variables include the lagged values of the ratio of equity to assets (Equity/Assets) and the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) as a measure of loan portfolio performance. Lagged DRP is the lagged deposit rate premium. Market Share is the bank’s national share in assets and Assets Growth is the lagged value of the growth in bank assets. Foreign identifies the largest shareholder as a foreign entity, BHC is a dummy variable for bank holding companies, MM Rate is the three-month money market rate, Fin. Freedom is the financial freedom of banks to engage in nontraditional activities, GDP growth is the real growth in GDP, and GDP pc is per capita gross domestic product. All variables are expressed in 1000s of 1997 real U.S. dollars. The constant term is not reported. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p<.1, ** p<.05, *** p<.01 US Banks Equity/Assets NPL/Loans Lagged DRP Market Share Assets Growth Foreign BHC EU Banks Unlisted 54.47 -55.488 34.71 -21.927 (21.647)** (31.502)* (43.800) (21.996) -1.444 -0.691 -1.31 -0.875 (0.321)*** (0.498) (0.579)** (0.345)** -0.688 -2.504 -0.281 -2.706 (0.749) (0.459)*** (0.810) (0.380)*** -1337.084 30.687 23.857 41.225 (1,398.031) (24.029) (25.646) (27.879) -0.05 -0.11 0.116 -0.117 (0.046) (0.078) (0.118) (0.050)** -13.047 -6.101 -15.868 -7.885 (2.651)*** (3.652)* (4.826)*** (2.653)*** 1.745 -9.24 -3.436 -1.075 (1.606) (7.572) (5.773) (3.578) DI 21.92 22.167 (14.440) (12.418)* Fin. Freedom -0.126 -0.763 -0.009 (0.223) (0.307)** (0.209) -6.972 7.546 -8.3 (3.494)** (5.732) (3.075)*** MM Rate GDP Growth 0.428 -0.903 0.862 (1.350) (1.853) (1.320) 2.245 -9.699 4.642 (7.777) (12.390) (7.010) 3.526 28.137 0.863 (14.103) (21.740) (11.707) 13.796 -11.762 (6.921)** (3.415)*** 239 480 GDP pc UK US No. of Obs. Listed 406 313 39 Table 8 Tests of Differences in Depositor Discipline Coefficients, Deposit Growth Rate Models Between the Crisis Period 2008-2009 and the Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 US Banks EU Banks Listed Unlisted Large Banks Equity/Assets -1.15 -0.39 0.35 -1.16 NPL/Loans 0.58 1.79 0.77 2.03 Small Banks The table shows the t statistics for tests of the difference between the Crisis Period 2008-2009 and the Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 for the key depositor discipline exogenous variables Equity/Assets and NPL/Loans in the DGR regression equations. The shaded t statistics indicate significant differences in depositor discipline between the crisis and pre-crisis periods. Negative signs on Equity/Assets and positive signs on NPL/Loans point to reduced depositor discipline. Equity/Assets 1.81 -2.32 -0.35 -1.39 NPL/Loans 0.51 0.08 -0.82 0.32 40 Table 9 US Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 and Crisis Period 2008-2009: Uninsured Deposit Growth Rate Models The dependent variable is the uninsured deposit growth rate; bank risk variables include the lagged values of the ratio of equity to assets (Equity/Asset) and of the ratio of nonperforming loans to total loans (NPL/Loans) as a measure of loan portfolio performance. Market Share is the bank’s national share in assets and Assets Growth is the lagged value of the growth in bank assets; Foreign identifies the largest shareholder as a foreign entity; BHC is a dummy variable for bank holding companies; MM Rate is the three-month money market rate; GDP growth is the real growth in GDP; GDP pc is per capita gross domestic product;. All variables are expressed in 1000s of 1997 real U.S. dollars. The constant term is not reported. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. * p<.1, ** p<.05, *** p<.01. Equity/Assets NPL/Loans Market Share Assets Growth Foreign BHC MM Rate GDP Growth No. Observations Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 Large Small 195.412*** 359.626*** (24.423) (11.195) -126.621*** -155.160*** (44.930) (18.179) -162.508*** 5,721.125*** (23.963) (610.385) 0.138*** -0.053*** (0.039) (0.016) -3.681 0.063 (7.414) (7.657) 8.745 0.360 (6.420) (1.405) 0.469 0.710** (0.962) (0.296) 1.194 -0.752** (0.961) (0.292) 3,948 55,764 41 Crisis Period 2008-2009 Large Small -236.872 401.821*** (181.532) (49.283) -236.434 -29.034 (162.240) (56.057) 512.023* 79,079.231*** (260.557) (5,932.106) -1.044*** -0.754*** (0.317) (0.076) -44.141 (62.688) 24.510 3.512 (71.281) (13.552) 3.045*** (0.447) 854 5.786*** (0.118) 11,122 Table 10 Tests of Differences in Depositor Discipline Coefficients, Uninsured Deposit Growth Rate Models Between the Crisis Period 2008-2009 and the Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 The table shows the t statistics for tests of the difference between the Crisis Period 2008-2009 and the Pre-Crisis Period 1997-2007 for the key depositor discipline exogenous variables Equity/Assets and NPL/Loans in the uninsured deposit growth rate regression equations. The shaded t statistics indicate significant differences in depositor discipline between the crisis and pre-crisis periods. Negative signs on Equity/Assets and positive signs on NPL/Loans point to reduced depositor discipline. Large Banks Equity/Assets -2.36 NPL/Loans -0.65 Small Banks US Banks Equity/Assets 0.83 NPL/Loans 2.14 42