Work place wage growth and worker retention by Paul Bingley,CLS, University of Aarhus, Steve Bronars,University of Texas at Austin) & Niels Westergaard-Nielsen, CLS, Aarhus School of Business. Abstract: There is a substantial volume of indirect evidence which suggests that firms/workplaces are willing to pay employees more to encourage long-term employment relationships. Although most new jobs end early, long term employment relationships are common, and the probability of job separation declines with tenure. However, there is dispute over the magnitude of the effect of higher tenure on wages, because of self-selection and the simultaneity of job changes and potential wage growth. This paper provides direct measures of the effect of wage growth at firm level on employee turnover. We obtain consistent estimates of wage growth due to tenure and experience for the population of (19538) Danish private sector plants during 1986-95 employing 10 or more white collar men. Further, we estimate wage profiles for (405) "competing" employers operating in the same 2-digit product market (of 27) and located in the same county (of 15) as defined over the population of (140000) private sector plants employing any white collar men. Given own and competing wage profiles, agents are assumed to solve an inter-temporal optimization problem by comparing the discounted present value of the wage costs of job turnover at all future dates until retirement, assuming turnover is to a competing employer. Our empirical results are consistent with the hypothesis that firms influence worker turnover through their wage policies: job separations are a decreasing function of value of a job with the present employer and an increasing function of the value of a job with a competing firm. For the first time, we are able to quantify the wage costs of retaining workers. 1 1. Introduction In his recent survey, Farber (1999) summarizes a substantial volume of indirect evidence that suggests that firms are willing to pay workers more to encourage long-term employment relationships. The empirical evidence surveyed by Farber shows that although most new jobs end early, long-term employment relationships are common, and the probability of job separations declines with tenure. It is difficult to obtain consistent estimates of the impact of higher job tenure on wages, holding constant experience, because job tenure and turnover are endogenous. Wages increase with job tenure, but there is some dispute over the magnitude of this effect due to self-selection and endogeneity biases. A plausible explanation of the evidence on wages and inter-firm mobility is that firms have made investments in specific human capital, and therefore benefit from wage policies that discourage turnover and promote job stability. Thus despite the limitations in the empirical literature, Farber concludes that specific capital models are useful for understanding worker mobility and wage dynamics. The purpose of this paper is to directly examine the relationship between wage growth at an employer and the job separation rate at the employer. We obtain consistent (establishment) firm-specific estimates of the wage growth on the job, due to both tenure and experience, for male white collar workers in a sample of medium to large employers in Denmark. We also estimate wage profiles for “competing” employers in the same 2-digit industry and geographic area of each firm in the sample. Given these estimated wage profiles, we can compute the expected discounted present value of the wage costs of job turnover (assuming that workers turnover to a “competing” employer). We then use these estimated wage costs of turnover to explain differences in job separation rates across employers. Our empirical results are consistent with the hypothesis that firms influence workers’ job turnover behavior through their wage policies. The job separation rate is a decreasing function of the expected discounted present value of future wages in the firm and increases with the expected discounted present value of expected wages offered by competing employers. 2. Data The data used in this study originates from the Statistics Denmark IDA Register (The Integrated Database for Labour Market Research). IDA contains information on labour market conditions for persons and workplaces in Denmark over the years 1980-1995. The 2 important feature of IDA is that it is possible to associate workplaces with the identity of all employees at a specific day in November (see Leth-Sørensen, 1998). The information on employees is quite comprehensive and contains data on wage rates, number of hours worked, experience, unemployment, demographic variables, education, region, occupation, unemployment insurance funds, etc. The information on work-places consists of 5-digit industry codes, (ISIC), plant size, and location (municipality). Education is measured in years. Individual labour earnings data come from tax records and incorporate all labour income received in the year by an individual. Firm size is measured as the number of primary workers in November. A primary worker means a worker that Statistics Denmark has determined has her/his main job at the workplace. We are able to identify which workers are hired at a plant and which leave, all measured on a November to November basis. The limitation is that we are not able to identify those who have been employed say from December to January the following year. These limitations are no different from the US LRD data used by Davis and Haltiwanger (1999) for example. The main difference is, however, that the IDA data allows us to identify the flows of persons between work places because we also know the identity of persons. We do not observe causes for mobility, neither do we exploit any information on job changes. In this study we are of different reasons only using white collar male workers and have consequently omitted all blue collar workers. One reason is that wage competition is believed to be strongest for white collar workers since wages here are to a lesser degree determined by union agreements. Another reason is that temporary lay offs will play no role for white collar workers. Furthermore, the replacement ratio from unemployment benefit is relatively low because all recipients among white collar-workers will be in a wage class where unemployment benefit is capped, not unlike the rules in the US. While blue-collar workers in Denmark have little employment protection, white collar-workers have some mandatory legal rights through a law covering all salaried employees. However, the most important rule is that the period of notice in case of dismissal increases with tenure and reaches its maximum at 6 months. There are no legal requirement of general redundancy payments etc known from other countries unless special agreements have been made. Though the data have no information in this direction, such agreements are reserved a small fraction of top salaried 3 employees. Finally, we have chosen to look at men only, because that diminishes problems with part time work. A white collar worker is in this context an employee who is salaried on a monthly basis in contrast to blue-collar workers, who are in principle paid on an hourly basis. We can follow each worker throughout her/his employment at the sampled workplace. We have drawn a 10% sample of all male white collar workers. Table 1 shows summary statistics. There are altogether 118117 observations on 36941 individuals working in 19538 workplaces. For each worker we have information on age1, education, tenure at the present employer. The Table shows that tenure is quite short, since people stay on in their jobs for only 3.9 years but with a relatively high standard deviation. Table 1. Summary statistics Summary Statistics Coeff Std.dev. Age 39.57 10.38 Tenure 3.90 3.40 Educy 12.82 2.38 No of plants 19538 Persons 36941 For each plant we identify “competing plants”. A competing workplace is identified as a different workplace, which is within the same 2-digit industry code, within the same county and employing more than 10 white-collar workers. As there are 15 counties and 27 different industries within the 2 digit industry code that produces 405 different groups of competing work places. 3. Wage Profiles of Plants Methodology 1 Used as an indicator of experience. Though we could have used a variable based on the pension point allocation, it is not considered to be important in this context, since we are interested in the annual increment. 4 There is a substantial empirical literature that attempts to estimate the return to tenure and experience in wage regressions. Consider the simple wage regression (In our empirical work we include quadratic terms in ED, EXP and TEN, which provides a better fit of the data, but does not alter the arguments below): lnWit = β0 + β1ED1 + β2EXPit + β3TENit + εit where Wit is the wage of worker i in year t, ED measures a worker’s completed schooling, and EXP and TEN measure a worker’s labor market experience and job tenure, respectively, and ε is an error term. Because tenure and job turnover are endogenous, it is unclear that β3 yields a consistent estimate of the marginal return to an additional year of tenure, holding constant experience. Even if panel data are utilized, the parameters β2 and β3 can only be individually estimated by relying on between job-match variation in EXP and TENURE. If we consider only within job-match wage changes, so that ∆EXPit=∆TENit=1, the return to an additional year of both tenure and experience is β2 + β3. Following Topel (1991, pages 152-153), least squares estimates of wage changes within jobs will yield a consistent estimate of within-job wage growth (the sum of β2 and β3). The controversy between Abraham and Farber, Altonji and Shakotko, and Topel centers around the decomposition of β2 + β3 into the partial derivatives ∂Wit/∂EXPit and ∂Wit/∂TENit. For our purposes, however, the decomposition of this total effect into components due to EXP and TEN is unimportant. We consider M wage regressions, one for each of the employers in our sample, of the form: lnWijt = β0j + βljEDi + β2jEXPijt+ β3jTENijt + εijt, for j = 1,2,3,...M where i indexes workers, j indexes employers and t indexes time periods. We measure withinjob wage growth at employer j as the sum of β2j and β3j.We are particularly concerned with the extent of variation in rates of within-job wage growth (β2j + β3j) between employers. We do not attempt to explain whether employer j has high within-job wage growth because ∂Wijt/∂EXPijt or ∂Wijt/∂TENijt is particularly high at this employer. Theory (for example Lazear) predicts that firms which have made greater investments in specific capital, or that face higher costs of job turnover for any other reason, will choose 5 wage policies which have particularly high values of (β2j + β3j). The wage cost of job turnover in these firms will be particularly large and, if the theory is correct, we should see lower rates of job separation at these employers. For each of the M plants in our sample, we estimate lnWaijt = βa0j + βaljEDi + βa2jEXPijt+ βa3jTENijt + εijt where the superscript a denotes the alternative wage offered by competing employers in the same 2-digit industry and geographic area as employer j. Note that there are 405 different sets of competing employers corresponding to the 15 combinations of geographic areas and 27 2digit industry codes in our data. For each set we calculate the mean coefficients representing the alternative wages. Results Table 2 shows the results of estimating plant specific coefficients. The reported figures are actually mean values of the plant specific βs weighted with the number of employees. The similar figures are also reported for the competing plants. Table 2. Plant coefficients to the wage function. Means across plants weighted by number of employees Plant Coeff const age age2 tenure tenure2 educy educy2 N Competing plant Std.dev. Coeff Std.dev. 9.3945 9.2918 0.0433 0.0024 0.1080 0.1206 0.0008 0.0001 -0.1178 0.0000 -0.0013 0.0000 0.1331 0.1076 0.0014 0.0001 -0.0108 0.0002 -0.0073 0.0000 0.0054 0.0068 -0.0166 0.0000 0.0018 0.0027 0.0003 0.0002 118117 118117 Table 3 shows the return to an additional year of tenure and experience (for a worker with the mean characteristics in the sample) at the median employer, and employers at different percentiles of the distribution of plants with respect to their earnings per worker. 6 Table 3. The return to an additional year of tenure and experience for a worker with plant level mean tenure and age at employers at different levels of earnings per worker. (In order to smooth the results plant estimates are averaged over 7 plants around the percentile point.) Wage distribution 5% 10% 20% 25% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 75% 80% 90% 95% Wage growth -0.0271 -0.0024 0.0143 0.0183 0.0224 0.0302 0.0444 0.0532 0.0643 0.0756 0.0834 0.1384 0.1581 The entire wage curves for firms at different levels of earnings are depicted in Figure 1. Figure 1. The earnings profile of typical plants at different levels of the earnings scale 500000 400000 10% 25% 50% 75% 90% 300000 200000 100000 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 4. Wage Costs of Turnover Given the estimated wage profiles for each employer j, and its competitors, we can construct estimated values of the wage costs of turnover for each individual in our sample. Figure 2 shows the relation between the present values of the wage in the current job and the wage in a job in a competing plant. The Graph shows that there a substantial interval where the present value of the wage of the competing plant over the next 5 years is slightly above the wage of the present plan. In another part of the distribution, PV’s of the present plant wage is clearly above the competing level. The latter reflects those work places where a good match between 7 employer and employee allows a higher pay. The first part of the distribution reflects cases where there is only small differences and where there is no great benefit by leaving or staying. Figure 2. Distribution of Present value of future earnings based on 5 periods log pv 100000000 10000000 1000000 100000 0 20 40 60 80 100 percentiles plant competing plant However, the expected future wage benefits do also depend on the probability of remaining with the employer. Similarly, when calculating the expected future wage after having turned over. Thus, the expected future wage benefits conditional on turning over to a competing employer depend on the worker’s characteristics (ED, EXP, and TEN), the competing firm’s wage policy (the β3’s), and the probability of remaining with the competing employer, conditional on turnover. To construct the expected future wage benefits of remaining with employer j, we must compute the probability that a worker, with ‘r years of tenure at employer j, remains on the job for another year (the survivor rate from τ to τ+l years of tenure at j). We proxy for this expected future job separation rate by calculating the lagged separation rate for workers with τ years of tenure in the previous X years. To construct the expected future wage benefits of separating from employer j, we must compute the probability that a worker who separates from j and begins working for another employer and remains with that employer for another year. We proxy for this expected future job separation rate in competing firms by calculating lagged survivor rates averaged across all employers in the same 2-digit industry and geographic area over the previous X years. We do 8 it in a similar manner, when we are looking 2 periods ahead. For each period, we take account of the lagged survivor rates. We calculate the discounted sum of wage payments in the current and competing employers over several alternative time horizons using a discount rate of 3%. 5. Individual Worker Mobility In the final state we have for each person a net present value of staying and similar for moving. We have this information for all 140169 observations together with information on education, tenure, size of plant and ID of individual workers. We estimate the following logit model: Prob(Worker i moves from employer j) = F(γ0 + γ1EDit + γ2EXPit + γ3TENijt + γ4PVWAGEijt + γ5PVWAGEaijt) PVWAGE and PVWAGEa are the present value of the wage stream if the worker stays at employer j, and if the worker leaves j for a competing employer, respectively. These present values are functions of only the worker’s individual characteristics and the firm’s wage policy parameters including the lagged probabilities of retention in the firm. Because we condition on all of the worker characteristics in the wage regression in this logit, the only source of variation in the terms PVWAGE and PVWAGEa is due across-employer differences in the wage policy parameters. Theory predicts that γ4 should be significantly negative and γ5 should be significantly positive if employers with high turnover costs seek to lower their job separation rate through their wage policies. We have estimated this equation using 3 different methods: LOGITS, OLS and OLS with fixed effects using the fact that we are observing the same individuals multiple times. Though OLS is of course not ideal when estimating probability functions, it has clear computational advantages when we are doing fixed effects estimations. All three methods presents the same signs, so we have chosen to present only the OLS with fixed effects because this takes account of unobserved individual effects as well. Furthermore, we have estimated these three 9 functions for different horizons. First for 2 years, then 3 years, 4 years, 5 years and finally 6 years. In principle, we should estimate it for the full horizon until pension. Table 4. Probability functions of moving from the presents employer. 2 periods 3 periods 4 periods 5 periods 6 periods ahead ahead ahead ahead ahead Coeff. Std.dev Coeff. Std.dev Coeff. Std.dev. Coeff. Std.dev. Coeff. Std.dev. Const 32.165 0.169 32.177 0.170 32.192 0.172 32.194 0.173 32.198 0.175 -0.021 0.002 -0.026 0.002 -0.031 0.003 -0.035 0.003 lnpvwage -0.016 0.001 lnpvwageC 0.013 0.005 0.017 0.005 0.020 0.005 0.025 0.005 0.028 0.005 -0.062 0.002 -0.062 0.002 -0.062 0.002 -0.062 0.002 tenu -0.062 0.002 tenu2 0.003 0.000 0.003 0.000 0.003 0.002 0.003 0.000 0.003 0.000 exp -0.721 0.005 exp2 -0.001 0.000 educy -0.031 0.019 educy2 0.002 0.001 lsize 0.007 0.004 y90 -2.974 0.020 y91 -2.217 0.019 y92 -1.532 0.018 y93 -0.732 0.020 nobs adj R-sq 140169 0.5442 140169 0.5442 140169 0.05443 140169 0.5443 140169 0.5443 Note: The coefficients to EXP, EXP2 etc do only change slightly for further horizons, so they have been omitted from Table 4. a The main variables of interest are LNPWAGE and LNPWAGE . The negative sign to the expected wage with the current employer means that a higher wage at the current employer makes it less likely that the person leaves his job. Similarly, we have found that a higher wage at the competing employer increases the probability of mobility. If we are only allowing the person to look 2 periods ahead, we find that a 1% increase in salary reduces the probability that this person leaves for another job with 1.6%. Increasing the horizon to 6 periods increases the elasticity, so that a one percent salary increase reduces the probability of changing job in the first period with 3.5%. Visual inspection indicates that these elasticities are asymptotic to a finite value. Similarly, the coefficient to the competing wage can be interpreted as quantifying how much extra should be offered to a person to get him to move to a competing work place. 10 The other coefficients are almost constant for all horizons. The tenure variable shows that the likelihood of moving decreases over the first 11.7 years of tenure. After that, it increases. This fits very well with the literature. The coefficients to Exp show that the likelihood of moving is reduced over the entire working life. Education has also a U-shaped impact. We find that employees at larger plants - all other things equal – are more willing to leave their jobs. Finally, we find that the likelihood of moving has been increasing since 1990. 6. Conclusion The conclusions are the following: - separations are a decreasing function of the value of the job at the present employer - Job separations are a an increasing function of the competing wage - We have quantified the cost of retaining workers. We have found that the probability of retaining a worker increases with 2-4% for every time we increase his present value of earnings. 11