Measuring Bank Cost Efficiency: Don’t Count on Accounting Ratios Robert DeYoung This article explores the challenges and misconceptions of measuring cost efficiency at financial institutions. We illustrate situations in which accounting-based expense ratios are misleading and show that statisticsbased “efficient cost frontier” approaches often measure cost efficiency more accurately. We also demonstrate a less complicated “fix-up” technique that combines the best qualities of both approaches. Finally, we summarize the existing literature on cost inefficiencies, scale economies, scope economies, and technological change at commercial banks, and conclude that any thorough treatment of bank efficiency must analyze revenues as well as expenses. n The deregulation of financial markets in the 1980s led to a massive restructuring of the commercial banking industry. Barriers to geographic expansion and ceilings on interest rates were eliminated, and commercial banks experienced dramatic increases in actual and potential competition from in-state banks, out-of-state banks, and non-bank rivals. Over 1,000 banks became insolvent after 1980, succumbing to the combination of unfamiliar competitive conditions and unfavorable macroeconomic events. Thousands more were acquired by rival institutions, leaving the US banking system with about 25% fewer banks today than at the start of the 1980s. These trends are likely to continue, and perhaps accelerate, when the final provisions of the RiegleNeal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act become law in 1997. What kind of banks are likely to flourish, fail, or be acquired as the industry continues to consolidate? If the past is prelude to the future, the banks that disappear will be those that are inefficiently run. Inefficient banks have relatively high costs and earn relatively low revenues, and as a result generate smaller capital cushions to protect Robert DeYoung is a Senior Financial Economist at the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Washington, DC, 20219. The opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency or the Department of the Treasury. The author thanks Tara Rice for excellent research assistance and Kevin Jacques, Larry Mote, and two anonymous referees for invaluable comments on earlier drafts. themselves during bad times. Inefficient banks also tend to make attractive merger targets, because they can often be purchased for low price-to-book ratios and then be made to run more efficiently. Bank analysts generally measure “efficiency” in terms of spending on overhead, such as physical plant and bank personnel, relative to the amount of financial services produced by the bank. Based on this notion of efficiency, one would expect the banking industry to be turning in some impressive efficiency gains, because reducing overhead is a stated goal in many bank mergers and bank holding company reorganizations. However, a close look at the data suggests otherwise. For example, the commercial banking system currently spends more on labor than it did a decade ago. Although total employment at commercial banks has fallen by about 5% over the past decade (and by about 13% per dollar of real assets), this has been more than offset by a 19% increase in real salaries and benefits per employee.1 Commercial banks also operate more branch locations now than they did a decade ago. The number of banks has declined dramatically, but the number of branch offices 1 In 1985, the 14,373 commercial banks with insured deposits held $3.646 billion of assets (in 1994 dollars), employed the equivalent of 1,561,339 full-time employees, and paid them an average of $34,200 in salaries and benefits (in 1994 dollars). In 1994, the comparable figures were 10,444 banks, $4.012 billion of assets, 1,488,583 full-time employees, and $40,710 in salaries and benefits. Source: Reports of Condition and Income, 1985, 1994. 20 DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY per dollar of real assets has increased by about 4%, and the number of automated teller machines (ATMs) operated by banks has almost doubled. 2 Humphrey (1994) reports that the number of bank locations (main offices, branches, and ATMs) per person in the US tripled between 1973 and 1992. How can industry-wide expenditures on labor and physical overhead be increasing at a time when the most inefficient banks are exiting the industry? Because efficiency and cost cutting are not always one and the same. This article addresses some of the misconceptions inherent in measuring the cost efficiency of financial institutions. We illustrate situations in which accounting-based cost ratios can be misleading, and show that statistics-based efficient cost frontier approaches, although far from flawless, often provide more accurate estimates of cost efficiency. Because these techniques require advanced statistics training, we also demonstrate a simpler fixup procedure that allows the analyst to establish more accurate benchmarks for accounting cost ratio analysis. To put our empirical results in perspective, we briefly review the bank cost literature, which suggests that moving closer to the efficient cost frontier yields larger potential cost savings for the typical commercial bank than do scale economies, scope economies, or technological change. Finally, we recognize that neither statistics-based or accountingbased measures of cost efficiency are complete gauges of bank performance, and conclude that any investigation of bank efficiency must consider revenues as well as costs. I. Accounting-Based Cost Ratios Accounting-based cost ratios are a traditional tool used by bank analysts to measure cost efficiency. These easy-to-use bellwethers express a bank’s annual noninterest expenditures (e.g., salaries, benefits, materials, physical capital, outsourced services) as a percentage of its assets or its annual revenue. All of the information needed to construct these ratios can be read directly from a bank’s basic financial statements. Although cost ratios are easy to construct and use, they can be difficult to interpret. Myopic analysis of expenditures can be misleading—reduced spending on labor, materials, or physical plant is no guarantee that a bank is being run efficiently, and high levels of 21 spending on these items does not necessarily signal inefficiency. Excessive cost cutting can damage service quality, portfolio quality, and earnings. For example, high expenditures on branches and/or ATMs might provide greater convenience for customers, high wages might result in the production of more financial services per worker, and large employee rolls might make a bank healthier if the additional workers are put to work monitoring loans. Expense levels can also vary significantly according to business strategy or economic conditions. For instance, banks that produce large amounts of fee-based services will incur large amounts of labor expenses, banks located in fastgrowing markets will incur expansion-related expenses, and banks in economically depressed regions will incur large expenses related to administering problem loans. An example of how cost ratio analysis can be misleading is shown in Exhibit 1, which charts the aggregate ratio of noninterest expenses to assets for the US commercial banking system from 1985 through 1994.3 The trend is unmistakably upward. The exhibit suggests that the banking industry has become grossly inefficient over time, spending over 20% more on labor, materials, and physical plant now than a decade ago. The data are misleading, however, because this cost ratio does not control for increases in fee-based activities, which have significantly altered the relationship between noninterest expenses and assets at banks. Fee-based activities (e.g., mutual fund sales, data processing, letters of credit, financial advice, mortgage servicing) only generate noninterest expense and add next to nothing to a bank’s asset base. The bias is confirmed in Exhibit 1 by adding the aggregate ratio of noninterest income to assets, which increases in sympathy with the cost ratio. Thus, expense ratios can be misleading in trend analysis if product mix changes over time and in cross-sectional analysis if the banks being compared have dissimilar product mixes. A more frequently used cost ratio expresses noninterest expense as a percentage of net revenue— bank analysts often refer to this ratio as the efficiency ratio, and we will simply call it EFFRAT.4 Because it uses revenues rather than assets as a base, EFFRAT relates overhead spending to the entire range of bank activities, both on and off the balance sheet. Exhibit 2 displays aggregate EFFRAT for the commercial banking system from 1985 through 1994. Note that the upward expense trend from Exhibit 1 has disappeared. 3 2 In 1985, commercial banks held $3.646 billion of assets (in 1994 dollars) and operated 49,478 banking offices and 48,118 ATMs. In 1994, the comparative figures were $4.012 billion of assets, 56,397 bank offices, and 109,080 ATMs. Sources: Rhoades (1995), Reports of Condition and Income, 1985, 1994. Unless otherwise indicated, all data used in this article are taken from the Reports of Condition and Income (a.k.a., the call reports) between 1985 and 1994. 4 Net revenue equals net interest income (interest income minus interest expense) plus noninterest income. Some analysts use variants of EFFRAT, but the form defined here is the most common. See Toevs and Sitka (1994). 22 FINANCIAL PRACTICE AND EDUCATION — SPRING / SUMMER 1997 Exhibit 1. Overhead Costs-to-Assets—Annual Aggregate Data for US Commercial Banks from 1985 to 1994 EFFRAT bounces up and down across time, but if the bad bank performance years of 1990 and 1991 are ignored the trend in EFFRAT is consistent with the expected post-deregulation improvements in industrywide cost efficiency.5 But EFFRAT is not a flawless measure of bank cost efficiency, either. Because it has net revenue in its denominator, EFFRAT is sensitive to changes in the term structure of interest rates. For example, for liabilitysensitive banks (banks that lend long and borrow short), a steepening of the yield curve enhances interest margins and drives up net revenue. Evidence of this phenomenon can be seen in Exhibit 2. Aggregate EFFRAT tends to move in the opposite direction of the aggregate ratio of interest margin to assets, which implies that changes in the yield curve can create misleading movements in EFFRAT over time. Unless the analyst is careful, EFFRAT can also be misleading when used to compare the performance of an individual bank to the performance of a group of peer institutions having similar characteristics. Asset size is the characteristic used most often to identify a peer group of banks. However, EFFRAT can vary even among equally efficient banks of similar size. Exhibit 3 plots EFFRAT values for 330 commercial banks in 1994, each of which held between $90 and $100 million in assets. The banks are divided into four groups 5 Nonperforming loans comprised about 3.7% of total loans for commercial banks in both 1990 and 1991, substantially above the normal levels of between 2 and 3%. Deteriorating loan quality causes reductions in interest income (reducing t h e d e n o m i n a t o r o f E F F R AT ) a n d i n c r e a s e s i n l a b o r intensive activities such as monitoring loans, renegotiating terms, and working out defaulted loans (increasing the numerator of EFFRAT). according to the percentage of net revenue derived from noninterest income. Note that average EFFRAT increases markedly across the four groups, climbing from 0.57 in the first group (for which noninterest income averaged just 7% of net revenue) to 0.72 in the fourth group (for which noninterest income averaged 26% of net revenue).6 II. Cost Frontier Analysis Cost frontier analysis provides an alternative to accounting-based efficiency ratios. In cost frontier analysis, the analyst attempts to estimate the maximum amount that a bank could reduce its costs while still producing the same amount and combination of financial services. We refer to these potential cost savings simply as cost inefficiencies, or sometimes as X-inefficiencies. Note that eliminating cost inefficiencies is separate and distinct from achieving scale economies, which requires a bank to increase the amount of output it produces. Similarly, shedding cost inefficiencies differs from capturing increased scope economies, which requires a bank to alter the combination of outputs it produces. Perhaps the biggest advantage of cost frontier analysis is the luxury of not having to construct peer groups of banks with similar characteristics. Instead, cost frontier analysis uses statistical techniques to simulate a hypothetical best practice bank similar to the real bank that is under evaluation. The hypothetical 6 In Exhibit 3, all of the inter-group comparisons of EFFRAT are significantly different from zero at the 0.05 level. DeYoung (1994) finds a pattern similar to that shown in Exhibit 3 for banks of all sizes in 1992. DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY 23 Exhibit 2. Overhead Costs-to-Net Revenues (EFFRAT)—Annual Aggregate Data for All US Commercial Banks from 1985 to 1994 Exhibit 3. Overhead Costs-to-Net Revenue (EFFRAT) for 330 US Commercial Banks with Assets Between $90 and $100 million in 1994 bank produces the same level and combination of financial services, under the same market conditions, as does the real bank, but does so at the lowest cost possible. Cost inefficiency is estimated by comparing the expenses actually incurred by the real bank to the simulated expenses for the best practice bank, i.e., the expenses that the bank in question would have incurred had it been operating on the efficient cost frontier. Exhibit 4 shows a simplified picture of an efficient total cost frontier. The points suspended in the center of the graph represent the annual total expenses incurred by banks of different asset sizes. The efficient cost frontier curves through the lower portion of this expense cloud, representing the total expenses incurred by best practice banks. For each bank, cost inefficiency is measured by the vertical distance between its actual expenses and its potential low cost position on the frontier. This vertical gap is the total cost savings a bank could potentially capture by achieving best practice cost levels. Although no bank can consistently incur less than best practice costs, notice that some of the banks in Exhibit 4 are located slightly below the efficient cost frontier. These deviations reflect random, one-time fluctuations in 24 FINANCIAL PRACTICE AND EDUCATION — SPRING / SUMMER 1997 Exhibit 4. An Example of an Efficient Cost Frontier reported expenses due to measurement error or luck. As described below, the chief goal of cost frontier techniques is to disentangle these random vertical cost fluctuations from the vertical cost inefficiency gaps. Cost inefficiency will be overstated if positive random errors are mistaken for excess costs and understated if negative random errors are allowed to cancel out some or all of a bank’s excess expenditures. Note that Exhibit 4 is only a stylized representation of an actual cost frontier. For one thing, Exhibit 4 has only one attribute (asset size) over which to compare the expense levels of banks. An actual cost frontier contains multiple attributes that drive bank expenses, such as portfolio mix, input prices, state branching laws, and regional economic conditions. Including multiple cost drivers allows the analyst to simulate the expense levels for hypothetical best practice banks that have attributes more closely resembling those of the banks under investigation. Hence, by estimating a single cost frontier, the analyst can evaluate the cost efficiency of dozens, hundreds, or even thousands of banks with very different attributes, largely eliminating the need to construct peer groups. Regardless of it simplicity, Exhibit 4 illustrates two of the fundamental cost inefficiency patterns found in the banking industry. First, the very smallest banks tend to exhibit the highest levels of cost inefficiency.7 Some of these banks operate in rural markets where a lack of competitive rivalry creates less pressure to operate efficiently, while others are newly chartered 7 Berger and Humphrey (1991) showed that, although accounting costs vary widely for banks of all sizes, cost dispersion is markedly larger for banks with less than $50 million in assets (1984 dollars). banks still traveling down a learning curve. Second, with the exception of the very small banks, cost inefficiency is not necessarily related to asset size. Large and moderate-sized banks are equally likely to operate near the cost frontier or far above it. Although large banks should be able to attract more highly skilled managers who are better able to control costs, the complexity of large banks makes them more difficult to operate efficiently, and these two phenomena may tend to cancel each other out.8 Depending on the methodology used, the time period examined, and the set of banks being evaluated, cost frontier studies generally conclude that the typical bank could reduce its total expenses by 15 to 25% by operating on the efficient cost frontier. Berger, Hunter, and Timme (1993) provide a review of this literature. However, the application of cost frontier analysis to commercial banks is constantly being refined, and several more recent studies have found substantially smaller levels of cost inefficiency. Berger and DeYoung (1995) estimated that operating cost inefficiencies averaged between 5 and 10% across the entire US banking industry, Mester (1996) concluded that total accounting cost inefficiencies averaged about 8% for banks in three east coast states, and Clark (1996) found total economic cost inefficiencies of less than 5% for large US banks. 9 Still, since even these smaller 8 There is no definitive evidence on the relationship between bank size and cost efficiency. Some studies have found a positive relationship, while others have found a negative o r n o r e l a t i o n s h i p . D e Yo u n g ( 1 9 9 7 ) i n c l u d e s a b r i e f discussion of this literature. 9 Operating cost includes only noninterest expenses, total accounting cost adds interest expenses to this, and total economic cost adds the opportunity cost of capital to this. DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY 25 estimates of cost inefficiencies are found for banks of all sizes, they represent the potential for cost reductions more widespread than those available from scale economies. Banking economists have used three different statistics-based methods to disentangle cost inefficiencies from random cost fluctuations. The thick cost frontier approach, introduced by Berger and Humphrey (1991), uses accounting cost ratios to separate banks into high cost and low cost groups, isolates random error by estimating a separate cost function for each group, and measures cost inefficiency as the vertical distance between the two cost functions. This approach is impractical for our purposes because it estimates cost inefficiency for the banking industry in general but not for individual banks. The distribution-free approach, developed by Berger (1993) based on earlier work by Schmidt and Sickles (1984), estimates a cost function using a time series-cross section data set, then measures cost inefficiency by averaging together the annual residuals for each bank. The annual random errors tend to cancel each other out in the averaging process, leaving only cost inefficiency—which is assumed to be constant over time—in the averaged residuals. This technique is also inappropriate for our purposes because it generates long-run average estimates of cost inefficiency that are not directly comparable to annual accountingbased cost ratios. The stochastic cost frontier approach, which was made tractable by Jondrow, Lovell, Materov, and Schmidt (1982), estimates a cost function with a two-part error structure in which random error and cost inefficiencies are separate, independent elements. Cost inefficiency is assumed to follow a one-sided positive (usually half-normal) distribution. Although this approach has been criticized for imposing a specific distribution on the unknown patterns of cost inefficiencies, we use it here because it generates annual estimates of cost inefficiency for individual banks. A more in-depth discussion of these three approaches is beyond the scope of this article—the interested reader can refer to the above citations for technical details. Including a wide variety of expense drivers (output levels, input prices, and other conditions) in the cost equation ensures that the resulting efficient cost frontier can be used to simulate a best practice bank that closely matches the characteristics of the banks that the analyst wishes to evaluate. The composite error structure U+V separates the two vertical components of costs that are unrelated to the expense drivers. When Equation (1) is estimated properly, V isolates and absorbs any random disturbances and prevents them from affecting the estimate of cost inefficiency U. 10 In this study, we include only noninterest expenses on the left-hand side of Equation (1). This makes the resulting estimates of cost frontier inefficiency more comparable to accounting-based cost ratios like EFFRAT, which include only noninterest expenses.11 On the right-hand-side of Equation (1) we include five types of output (C&I loans, real estate loans, consumer loans, noninterest income, and transactions services), two input prices (the wage rate and the price of physical capital), and dummy variables that control for state-level branching laws. We assume a Fourierflexible functional form for Equation (1) and impose a truncated normal distribution on the inefficiency term U. 12 The resulting efficient cost frontier was estimated using 1994 data for 9,622 commercial banks. Exhibit 5 compares estimated cost inefficiency from our SCF model to the accounting cost ratio EFFRAT, using the same 330 banks shown in Exhibit 3. Recall that EFFRAT overstated inefficiency for banks that generated large portions of their income from fee-based activities. In contrast, the SCF estimates of frontier cost inefficiency (expressed as the percentage by which a bank could reduce its noninterest costs by moving to the efficient frontier) do not contain this bias. Frontier cost inefficiency averages between 5 and 6%, and none of the differences between the four groups of banks are significantly different from zero. Hence, because the SCF cost equation controls for the effects of noninterest income on operating costs, our estimates of frontier cost inefficiency do not suffer from the bias found in EFFRAT. A. Example: A Stochastic Cost Frontier B. Example: A Middle Ground The stochastic cost frontier (SCF) approach is based on a cost equation that relates a bank’s expenses to the conditions that drive those expenses, such as output levels, input prices, and regional economic or regulatory conditions. As described above, the SCF cost equation also contains a two-part, or composite, error structure that distinguishes random cost fluctuations from cost inefficiencies. The following equation is a simplified example: Although the SCF method—or either of the other frontier efficiency approaches discussed above—can Costs = f (output, input, other ) + U + V (1) 10 In application, cost inefficiency is estimated as the expected value of U conditional on the residual U+V. 11 Most studies conclude that inefficiencies due to excess interest expenses are small relative to inefficiencies due to excess noninterest expenses. See Berger, Hunter, and Timme (1993). 12 This specification is more general than the usual translog, half normal specification most often found in the literature. See Berger and DeYoung (1995) for further details of this cost model. 26 FINANCIAL PRACTICE AND EDUCATION — SPRING / SUMMER 1997 Exhibit 5. Overhead Costs-to-Net Revenue (EFFRAT) and Estimated Frontier Cost Inefficiency for 330 US Commercial Banks with Assets Between $90 and $100 Million in 1994 be used to correct for such biases, implementing these methods require a great deal of time and statistical expertise. Instead, the analyst might use a more rudimentary statistical procedure to fix-up the simple EFFRAT ratio. One possible approach is to regress EFFRAT on a set of variables including the variable thought to be causing the bias. In the following equation, A represents assets, NI = noninterest income, and NR = net revenue. The equation is a simple ordinary least squares regression example for the 330 banks shown in Exhibit 5: EFFRAT = 0.1834 + (0.0038)A + 0.6033 (NI/NR) (0.2056) (0.0022) (0.0636) (2) where assets are in millions of dollars, adjusted R2 equals 0.1978, and the coefficient standard errors appear in parentheses. Once estimated, Equation (2) becomes a formula for determining a corrected-EFFRAT benchmark to which any of the 330 banks can be compared. For example, for a bank with assets of $95 million and noninterest income-to-net revenue of 15%, we generate the appropriate benchmark by substituting these values into the right-hand-side of the formula. This yields a corrected-EFFRAT benchmark of 63.5%— if the actual EFFRAT of this bank is above (below) 63.5%, then the bank is operating more (less) inefficiently than the average bank. In contrast, for a $95 million bank that generates 20% of its net revenues from noninterest income, the appropriate correctedEFFRAT benchmark is a higher 66.5%. By using adjustments like this, the analyst can add some flexibility to accounting-based cost ratio analysis without going through the complicated process of estimating an efficient cost frontier. Of course, Equation (2) is only one example. Quadratic and double-log specifications yielded slightly better statistical fits than did this simple linear model, but made similar predictions. By adding additional righthand-side variables to the fix-up equation, the analyst might be able to control for other inter-bank biases in EFFRAT, such as organizational form (banks that are affiliates of holding companies might incur fewer overhead expenses) or local economic conditions (banks in low growth regions might incur higher expenditures to administer problem loans). The analyst should not, however, add variables that are directly influenced by bank management. For example, including the nonperforming loan ratio in the formula will likely set too high a corrected-EFFRAT benchmark, because nonperforming loans are often caused by poor (i.e., inefficient) loan portfolio management. III. Scale, Scope, and Technological Change For most commercial banks, cost inefficiencies are a potential source for large cost savings. But moving closer to the best practice cost frontier is not the only way a bank can improve its cost structure. Some banks could reduce per unit costs simply by growing larger, others by changing the mix of financial services they produce. For the vast majority of banks, however, the savings available from changing the scale or scope of their operations are small relative to the potential savings from eliminating cost inefficiencies. DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY Furthermore, as time passes and new production methods cause the cost frontier to shift down, the efficiency gains from becoming a best practice bank can become larger. A. Technological Change Technological change can shift the cost frontier in a number of ways. New low-cost technologies such as ATMs can be substituted for existing high-cost technology such as brick-and-mortar branch locations. Computer systems, high-speed check readers, and check imaging systems can allow banks to reduce costs by substituting physical capital for labor. Deregulation can also provide an opportunity to reorganize inputs in a lower-cost fashion. As federal and state laws restricting branch banking eroded, banks were able to reduce overhead costs by abandoning some of the Byzantine multibank holding company arrangements previously necessary to circumvent these restrictions. Expanded powers can allow banks to provide new financial services (e.g., securities underwriting, mutual fund sales, mortgage servicing) using overhead originally put in place to service depositors and loan customers. Increases in market competition can produce pressure to more quickly adopt cost-reducing technologies. It is important to distinguish between shifts in the efficient cost frontier and the position of banks relative to the cost frontier. For example, say that a bank’s distance from the cost frontier increased from 10% of costs to 12% of costs, but the cost frontier itself fell by 5% of costs due to technological progress over the same time period. Then the bank’s expenses would have decreased by roughly 3% (5% minus 2%) despite having fallen further behind the best practice banks. Exhibit 6 characterizes in rough fashion how our SCF operating cost frontier changed position between 1985 and 1994. Exhibit 7 reports three sets of results, by asset size, that correspond to the moving cost frontier in Exhibit 6: shifts in the cost frontier, changes in the average bank’s position relative to the frontier, and the combined effect of these two changes.13 13 To make these inter-temporal comparisons, we used a technique similar to that used by Elyasiani and Mehdian (1990) in a bank production model. First, we calculated 1985 cost inefficiency by comparing banks’ actual 1985 costs to the 1985 cost frontier. Second, we calculated how 1985 banks would have fared relative to 1994 best practice banks by comparing banks’ actual 1985 costs (converted to 1994 dollars) to the 1994 cost frontier. This resulted in two sets of inefficiency estimates for each bank, which we then averaged by size class and compared to each other to determine whether, and in which direction, the cost frontier moved over time. The years 1985 and 1994 make good points of comparison, because in each year the economy was expanding and few banks were experiencing serious credit quality problems. Both cost frontiers are expressed in 1985 dollars. 27 Our results suggest that the cost frontier pivoted somewhere around $100 million in assets between 1985 and 1994. For the average bank smaller than $100 million, the cost frontier fell by roughly 1.5%. This small reduction enhances the best practice potential for thousands of banks (about 80% of the industry) and is a relatively impressive decline when compared to the increases in the cost frontier for larger banks. The frontier rose by about 7% for banks with between $100 and $300 million in assets and by between 10 and 11% for banks larger than $300 million. On average, banks of all sizes moved closer to the cost frontier over the course of the decade, which suggests that the banks that survived the structural upheaval of the 1980s and 1990s either were more cost efficient to start out or stayed alive (i.e., did not fail or were not acquired) by becoming more cost efficient. Hence, the cost efficiency gap between average banks and best practice banks shrank over time, but not by enough to offset the upward movement in the cost frontier for large banks. Although our results do not correspond with the conventional notion of technology marching inexorably ahead over time, they are consistent with other studies. Bauer, Berger, and Humphrey (1993) found that the cost frontier for all commercial banks moved up at an annual rate of about 1 or 2% from 1977 through 1988, and Grabowski, Rangan, and Rezvanian (1994) concluded that the cost frontier for a random sample of 669 commercial banks moved up by about 4% between 1983 and 1987. None of these results, however, necessarily indicate technological regress, because technological advancements do not always reduce costs once they are applied. For example, a new technology might enhance service quality while leaving costs unchanged or higher. ATMs improve service quality for depositors by making banking more convenient, but because depositors are likely to use this convenient service more frequently than they used the branch, adoption of the new technology doesn’t necessarily reduce the costs of servicing depositors. This may be one reason why the cost frontier moved up for large banks, which own and operate ATM networks more intensively than do small banks. Furthermore, the disparate movements in the cost frontier for small and large banks may not be related at all to technological change. Large banks were more likely to incur transitional expenses related to acquisitions made during the post-deregulation period, and bank regulators eased some of the costly regulatory reporting requirements for small banks during the 1990s. B. Scale Economies Following industry deregulation, commercial banks 28 FINANCIAL PRACTICE AND EDUCATION — SPRING / SUMMER 1997 Exhibit 6. Estimated Total Operating Cost Frontiers—All US Commercial Banks in 1985 and 1994 Exhibit 7. Estimated Changes in Cost Inefficiency at US Commercial Banks Between 1985 and 1994 Averag e Asset Size (1985 Dollars) < $100 million Number of Banks in 1985 Change in Positio n of Cost Frontier Change in Cost Inefficiency for Average Bank Appro ximate Net Change in O perating Costs 10,206 fell by 1.5% fell 2.9% fell 4.4% 1,660 rose by 6.6% fell 2.5% increased 4.1% $300 million - $1 billion 458 rose by 11.0% fell 3.0% increased 8.0% $1- $10 billion 257 rose by 10.5% fell 2.3% increased 8.2% 25 rose by 10.2% fell 3.2% increased 7.0% $100 - $300 million > $10 billion grew larger by acquiring other banks, by absorbing their fellow bank holding company affiliates, and by exploiting the chance to enter new geographic and product markets. By growing larger, a bank might be able to reduce its per unit costs by capturing scale economies, i.e., cost savings from spreading fixed costs over larger amounts of output and from making better use of specialized labor and capital inputs. To evaluate a bank’s potential for scale economies, we must consider two components of expenses. Exhibit 8 illustrates these two components in terms of costs per dollar of assets, or per unit cost. First, consider the point at which the cost advantages of growing larger are exhausted—this is generally referred to as minimum efficient scale, or simply MES. The conventional view among banking economists is that MES in banking is somewhere between $100 to $300 million of assets, which implies that banks larger than this pursue growth for reasons other than cost savings. This view is based on scores of studies that include banks of all sizes—naturally, studies that include only large banks (over $1 billion of assets) find higher estimates of MES. Evanoff and Israilevich (1991) and Berger, Hunter, and Timme (1993) provide reviews of this literature. However, recent studies that explicitly account for the costs associated with risk conclude that MES might be substantially higher than $300 million. McAllister and McManus (1993) note that larger banks follow business strategies that expose them to higher risk, which necessitates extra expenditures on labor to monitor riskier loans and higher interest rates to compensate the bank’s creditors for default risk. They perform a crude correction for this and find scale economies up to $500 million. Clark (1996) estimates the economic cost of bank production (i.e., including the opportunity cost of capital) and finds scale economies up to $3 billion in assets. Hughes and Mester (1994) suggest that bank managers might DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY 29 Exhibit 8. An Example of Scale Efficiencies and Scale Economies actually prefer to employ high levels of labor and equity capital to reduce risk but can economize on these inputs as their banks grow larger and become more diversified. These authors allow for risk-averse managerial preferences in their cost model, and conclude that scale economies are available to even the largest banks.14 The second important component is the amount by which a bank’s costs decline as it grows from its present size to MES size. Evanoff and Israilevich (1995) call this scale inefficiency, and it is illustrated in Exhibit 8 by the vertical distance YZ. Using results from a number of existing bank cost studies to make their point, the authors show that scale inefficiencies can be as much as 25% of costs for banks that are initially very far below MES. However, their estimates suggest that the bulk of these scale inefficiencies are eliminated by the time banks reach even one-tenth to one-quarter of MES (roughly $30 to $75 million in assets by conventional estimates) after which scale inefficiencies amount to only around 5% of costs. Savings of this magnitude are substantially smaller than the potential savings available to the average bank by moving closer to the best practice frontier and are limited to small banks.15 14 Clark (1996) points out that these results may be artificially amplified by the relatively narrow definition of output used by Hughes and Mester. 15 Evanoff and Israilevich’s estimates of scale inefficiencies could be overestimates, because they base their estimates predominantly on the results of conventional cost functions, rather than on frontier cost functions. Conventional cost functions tend to confound scale inefficiency and cost inefficiency for the very smallest banks. C. Scope Economies After financial markets were deregulated in the early 1980s, banks’ largest commercial loan customers began to go directly to financial markets for credit, and banks found themselves competing for deposit customers with thrift institutions, credit unions, and mutual funds. Commercial banks responded by offering a broader array of deposit and investment products (e.g., interest-bearing checking, money market accounts, mutual funds), by further diversifying their portfolios into consumer and real estate loans, and by generating more noninterest income (e.g., insurance sales, mortgage servicing, credit enhancements). By producing a more heterogenous output mix, a bank might be able to capture scope economies, i.e., cost savings from using the same inputs to produce several different types of output. The production costs of a multiproduct bank that produces deposit services, loans, and fee-based financial services might be less than the aggregate costs of three single-product banks that collectively produce the same output mix. For example, in the course of providing financial services for a checking account customer, a bank generates a great deal of information about that customer’s income, purchasing habits, and other cash flows. This information might be recycled to evaluate the depositor ’s creditworthiness should she apply for a loan, or to identify the most likely set of investment or insurance products to cross-sell to the customer. Strong evidence of cost synergies at multiproduct banks would strengthen arguments for expanding banks’ powers 30 FINANCIAL PRACTICE AND EDUCATION — SPRING / SUMMER 1997 to offer more non-traditional financial services (e.g., investment banking services, insurance underwriting), and would weaken proposals to protect the deposit insurance fund by separating “narrow” banks (insured depositories that take deposits and invest them only in risk-free Treasury securities) from other intermediaries (institutions that make risky loans but fund themselves with uninsured deposits and commercial paper). Until recently, banking cost studies have generated little reliable evidence of scope economies at commercial banks. Conclusions of scope diseconomies were not unusual, and point estimates of scope economies often exceeded economically reasonable magnitudes. Mester (1987) and Clark (1988) provide reviews of this literature. Measuring scope economies presents a number of technical problems, however, and recent studies that employ innovative statistical methods produce more economically reasonable estimates. Berger and Humphrey (1991), Pulley and Braunstein (1992), and Pulley and Humphrey (1993) have found that multiproduct banks, defined as producing various loan and deposit outputs, have between a 10 and 40% cost advantage over single product producers. However, even these estimates greatly overstate the cost savings available to the typical commercial bank from scope economies, because most banks already produce deposit services and several types of loan products. IV. Conclusions Accounting-based cost ratios are popular tools for analyzing the efficiency of banks because they are simple to construct and easy to use. However, bank efficiency is a complex phenomenon for which simple analysis can yield misleading conclusions. Comparing the cost ratios of two different banks is inappropriate unless both banks are nearly identical in terms of product mix, bank size, market conditions, and other characteristics that can affect the banks’ expenses. Alternatively, a bank’s cost ratio might be compared to the average of the cost ratios across a peer group of the bank’s rivals, but the effort required to construct an appropriate peer group can overwhelm the simplicity that made cost ratio analysis attractive in the first place. Cost frontier analysis is rapidly becoming a standard analytical tool for financial economists studying commercial bank performance, and it solves some of the problems associated with cost ratio analysis. Given adequate data, a cost frontier allows the analyst to estimate the cost inefficiencies of hundreds or even thousands of banks at a time. Cost frontier analysis solves the peer group problem, because each individual bank is compared with a hypothetical best practice benchmark that corresponds exactly to that bank’s individual characteristics. However, performing cost frontier analysis can require the analyst to invest a great deal of time and statistical expertise. With this in mind, we have proposed a modified hybrid approach that combines the simplicity of cost ratios with the flexibility of cost frontiers. In closing, note that both cost frontier analysis and accounting-based cost ratio analysis are incomplete measures of bank efficiency. A bank that offers betterthan-average service quality generally must incur additional expenses, which will make the bank appear to be cost inefficient—however, the bank’s earnings need not fall, and may even increase, because the marketplace is usually willing to pay higher prices for higher quality. Similarly, two banks might be operating at equal distances above the cost frontier, and hence be equally cost efficient—however, one of these two banks might be earning higher revenues by pricing its assets more aggressively than the other. Finally, a bank that spends large amounts on underwriting and monitoring its loan portfolio will appear to be relatively cost inefficient in the short run—however, the bank will probably be more cost efficient in the long run due to lower nonperforming loan expenses. Hence, bank analysts should be careful to supplement cost efficiency analysis with an analysis of bank earnings. Although high cost ratios and/or high frontier cost inefficiency estimates are generally good indicators of inefficient operations, the analyst can draw a stronger conclusion if earnings ratios are also subpar.16 n 16 Recent papers by Berger, Hancock, and Humphrey (1993), Akhavein, Berger, and Humphrey (1996), and DeYoung and Nolle (1996) have estimated efficient profit frontiers, which consider both the revenue efficiency and the cost efficiency of commercial banks. Such efforts are still in their exploratory stages, and numerous empirical and theoretical questions have yet to be answered. Like cost frontier analysis, these techniques are accessible only to analysts well-versed in statistics who have access to data from a large number of banks. Because profit frontier analysis assumes that the firm seeks to maximize profits, it should not be applied to credit union data. DEYOUNG — MEASURING BANK COST EFFICIENCY 31 References Akhavein, Jalal D., Allen N. Berger, and David B. Humphrey, 1997, “The Effects of Bank Mega-mergers on Efficiency and Prices: Evidence from the Profit Function,” Review of Industrial Organization 12 (No. 1, January), 95-139. Evanoff, Douglas D. and Philip R. Israilevich, 1991, “Productive Efficiency in Banking,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives 15 (No. 4, July), 11-32. Bauer, Paul W., Allen N. Berger, and David B. Humphrey, 1993, “Efficiency and Productivity Growth in US Banking,” in H.O. Fried, C.A.K. Lovell, and S.S. Schmidt, Eds., The Measurement of Productive Efficiency: Techniques and Applications, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 386-413. Evanoff, Douglas D. and Philip R. Israilevich, 1995, “Scale Elasticity versus Scale Efficiency in Banking,” Southern Journal of Economics 61 (No. 4, April), 1036-1047. Berger, Allen N., 1993, “‘Distribution-Free’ Estimates of Efficiency in the US Banking System and Tests of the Standard Distributional Assumptions,” Journal of Productivity Analysis 4 (No. 3, September), 261-292. Berger, Allen N., and Robert DeYoung, 1997, “Problem Loans and Cost Efficiency in Commercial Banks,” Journal of Banking and Finance (forthcoming). Berger, Allen N., and David B. Humphrey, 1991, “The Dominance of Inefficiencies over Scale and Product Mix Economies in Banking,” Journal of Monetary Economics 28 (No. 1, August), 117-148. Berger, Allen N., Diana Hancock, and David B. Humphrey, 1993, “Bank Efficiency Derived from the Profit Function,” Journal of Banking and Finance 17 (No. 2/ 3, April/May), 317-347. Berger, Allen N., William C. Hunter, and Stephen G. Timme, 1993, “The Efficiency of Financial Institutions: A Review and Preview of Research Past, Present, and Future,” Journal of Banking and Finance 17 (No. 2/3, April/May), 221-249. Clark, Jeffrey A., 1988, “Economies of Scale and Scope at Depository Financial Institutions: A Review of the Literature,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review 33 (No. 2, September), 16-33. Clark, Jeffrey A., 1996, “Economic Cost, Scale Efficiency, and Competitive Viability in Banking,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28 (No. 3, August), 342-364. D e Yo u n g , R o b e r t , 1 9 9 4 , “ F e e - B a s e d S e r v i c e s a n d C o s t Efficiency in Commercial Banks,” in Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, (May), 501-519. DeYoung, Robert, 1997, “X-Efficiency and Management Quality in National Banks,” Journal of Financial Services Research 11 (No. 3, September), forthcoming. DeYoung, Robert and Daniel E. Nolle, 1996, “Foreign-Owned Banks in the US: Earning Market Share or Buying It?,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28 (No. 4, November), 622-636. Elyasiani, Elyas and Seyed M. Mehdian, 1990, “A Nonparametric Approach to Measurement of Efficiency and Technical Change: The Case of Large US Commercial Banks,” Journal of Financial Services Research 4 (No. 2, July), 157-168. Grabowski, Richard, Nanda Rangan, and Rasoul Rezvanian, 1994, “The Effect of Deregulation on the Efficiency of US Banking Firms,” Journal of Economics and Business 46 (No. 1, February), 39-54. Hughes, Joseph P. and Loretta J. Mester, 1994, “Evidence on the Objectives of Bank Managers,” Bank Structure and Competition, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (May), 496-500. Humphrey, David B., 1994, “Delivering Deposit Services: ATMs Versus Branches,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly 80 (No. 2, Spring), 59-81. Jondrow, James, C.A. Knox Lovell, Ivan Materov, and Peter S c h m i d t , 1 9 8 2 , “ O n t h e E s t i m a t i o n o f Te c h n i c a l Inefficiency in the Stochastic Frontier Production Function Model,” Journal of Econometrics 19 (No. 2-3, August), 233-238. Mester, Loretta J., 1987, “Efficient Production of Financial Services: Scale and Scope Economies,” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, Business Review (January/February), 15-25. Mester, Loretta J., 1996, “A Study of Bank Efficiency Taking into Account Risk-Preferences,” Journal of Banking and Finance 20 (No. 6, July), 1025-1045. McAllister, Patrick H. and Douglas McManus, 1993, “Resolving the Scale Efficiency Puzzle in Banking,” Journal of Banking and Finance 17 (No. 2/3, April), 389-405. Pulley, Lawrence B. and Yale M. Braunstein, 1992, “A Composite Cost Function for Multiproduct Firms with an Application to Economies of Scope in Banking,” Review of Economics and Statistics 74 (No. 2, May), 221-230. Pulley, Lawrence B. and David B. Humphrey, 1993, “The Role of Fixed Costs and Cost Complementarities in Determining Scope Economies and the Cost of Narrow Banking Proposals,” Journal of Business 66 (No. 3, July), 437-462. Reports of Condition and Income, 1985-1994, Washington, DC, Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council. Rhoades, Stephen A., 1995, “Bank Mergers and Industrywide Structure, 1980-94,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Working Paper. Schmidt, Peter, and Robin C. Sickles, 1984, “Production Frontiers and Panel Data,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 2 (No. 4, October), 367-374. Toevs, Alden, and Robert Sitka, 1994, “Straight Talk on Bank Efficiency,” Journal of Retail Banking 16 (No. 2, Summer), 11-13.