Firms and Markets Horizontal mergers Christine Zulehner Department of Economics Johannes Kepler University Linz Winter term 2011/12 Zulehner, Firms and Markets 1 / 45 Motivation 450 402 400 356 347 335 350 330 Number of notified cases 313 300 277 276 274 259 247 250 224 200 211 168 150 131 95 110 100 69 64 59 59 91 92 93 50 11 0 90 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 March time [year] notified cases Zulehner, Firms and Markets 2 / 45 Outline Introduction Unilateral effects Coordinated effects Merger control in the EU Merger simulations Zulehner, Firms and Markets 3 / 45 Terminology Merger firm A and firm B transfer their shares to a new firm C A and B cease to exist horizontal, vertical or conglomerate Acquisition or takeover firm A (“acquirer”) buys out all the shares of firm B (“target”) Joint venture firm A and firm B set up and operate new firm C A and B remain independent firms Zulehner, Firms and Markets 4 / 45 Categorization of mergers Categorization: horizontal merger: mergers between actual or potential competitors in the same market, A and B operate in the same industry vertical merger: mergers between undertakings on different levels of distribution or production, A is supplier of B conglomerate merger: neither horizontal nor vertical, A and B operate in completely different industries (merge for financial or tax reasons) Business language: hostile takeover: target’s other owners and/or management oppose the takeover defensive merger: firms merge to respond to deregulation of their industry, to threat of competition from abroad, etc white knight, etc Zulehner, Firms and Markets 5 / 45 Why do firms merge? Demand-side synergies (i.e. increase in efficiency) Sony acquired film studio Columbia quality movies to complement the “hardware” produced by Sony Cost-side synergies Nestlé and General Mills joint venture for breakfast cereals Bargaining power Philip Morris and Kraft merged large number of food products which they sell through supermarket chains Market entry Nestlé acquired Rowntree (Smarties, After Eight, KitKat, etc) to enter British market Zulehner, Firms and Markets 6 / 45 Effects of mergers Increase of market power merged firms can set higher prices, outside firms can also charge higher prices EU: “single-firm dominance”(US: “unilateral effects”) same mode of competition before and after the merger? Increased scope for collusion i.e. merger facilitates explicit or tacit agreements between competitors to raise price above competitive level EU: “joint” or “collective dominance” (US: “coordinated effects”) Cost reductions: efficiency gains (or “synergies”) might lead to a reduction in prices Zulehner, Firms and Markets 7 / 45 Impact of mergers on consumers Horizontal mergers increase concentration (i.e. reduce the number of competitors in the industry) → prices likely to increase Vertical mergers are intended to internalize double marginalization → prices may decrease Firms claim that prices will not increase because merger implies cost efficiencies and the decrease in cost will be passed on to the consumers fixed cost vs. marginal cost scientific evidence on this is mixed Zulehner, Firms and Markets 8 / 45 Impact of mergers on other firms Concentration increases also for outside firms, not just for the merging firms Outside firms benefit: can increase prices, too! Example: in August 1998 BP announced takeover of Amoco → stock prices of most major oil companies (e.g. Mobil) soared Exception: merging firms become so efficient that merger is in fact “bad news” for the outside firms. Example: BA proposed merger with AA → Virgin Atlantic painted its aircraft with the clear message “BA/AA No Way” Zulehner, Firms and Markets 9 / 45 Merger failures Strikingly high failure rate - by any standard you might apply 50% of US mergers (and 43% of mergers worldwide) report lower profits than comparable non-merged firms (see Gugler et al 2003) more than half of all merged firms end up being divested (Porter 1987) Examples Daimler Benz/Chrysler: in 1998, Daimler Benz bought US auto maker Chrysler for $37 billion; in 2007, sold Chrysler to Cerberus for a mere $7 billion. Quaker/Snapple: in 1994, Quaker Oats purchased fruit drink producer Snapple for $1.7 billion, only to sell it again for $300 million after 27 months. Reasons: uncertainty, lack of experience, managers’ incentives not in line with firm value maximization Zulehner, Firms and Markets 10 / 45 Public policy toward mergers in US and Europe, all mergers above a certain threshold are subject to merger control US: Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and Department of Justice (DoJ) Europe: European Commission and national competition authorities Goal: clear those mergers that are good for consumers, block the others For merger to be good for consumers, efficiency gains must more than outweigh market power effects Zulehner, Firms and Markets 11 / 45 Problems in merger control Looking into the future: authorities cannot perfectly quantify consequences of mergers ex ante (and if merger is blocked, they will never know) Regarding efficiency gains: merging firms know best what possible efficiency gains are, but they have every incentive to overstate them Regarding price increases: may not only arise from increased concentration (“unilateral effect”) but also from facilitated collusion (“coordinated effect”) Be more lenient towards mergers involving: small firms industries where entry is easy target firms close to bankruptcy (“failing firm defense”) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 12 / 45 Unilateral effects absent efficiencies a merger increases market power factors that affect unilateral market power concentration market shares and capacities entry demand variables buyer power failing firm defence efficiency gains (efficiency defense) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 13 / 45 Modeling unilateral effects of mergers modeling mergers and their effects is difficult basic feature: creation of a new firm which combines the assets of the merging parties two modeling strategies that capture the essence of a merger, i.e. asset based models models of product differentiation where assets at hand are the product varieties sold by the firms models where the firms produce a homogenous good but differ in their production capacities for that reason, the simple Cournot model does not capture the idea of a merger, i.e. combination of assets, but treats the merger simply as a reduction of one firm Zulehner, Firms and Markets 14 / 45 Product differentiation and merger assume three single product firms with equal and constant marginal cost c consumers’ utility: 3 3 γ 3 3 2 2 U = ν i =1 qi − 2(1+γ) ( i =1 qi + 3 ( i =1 qi ) ) + y where γ ≥ 0 is the degree of substitution which gives the direct demand function: γ n qi = 1 (ν − pi (1 + γ) + j=1 pj ) 3 3 product choice is exogenous now a merger allows coordination of the outputs of the different products but the merger does not lead to one of the products being eliminate Zulehner, Firms and Markets 15 / 45 Before the merger before the merger there are three identical single-product firms with a profit function πi = (pi − c)qi , where qi is given by above demand function FOCs are ∂πi ∂pi = 0 → pi = 3ν+(3+2γ)c+γpj +γpk , 2(3+2γ) i, j, k = 1, 2, 3; i = j = k assuming symmetry: pb = πb = 3ν+(3+2γ)c and 2(3+γ) (ν−c)2 (3+2γ) 4(3+γ)2 qb = (ν−c)(3+2γ) 6(3+γ) note: as the substitutability of products increases (higher γ), equilibrium prices and profits decrease consumer welfare CS = U(qb ) − 3pb qb CSb = (ν−c)(3+2γ)2 8(3+γ)2 Zulehner, Firms and Markets and Wb = (ν−c)2 (27+24γ+4γ 2 ) 8(3+γ)2 16 / 45 A merger between two firms suppose a merger takes place between firms 1 and 2 in the industry there is now firm I selling two products and firm O selling one product with profits 2 pi −c γ πI = i =1 3 (ν − pi (1 + γ) + 3 (p1 + p2 + p3 )) p −c γ πO = i 3 (ν − p3 (1 + γ) + 3 (p1 + p2 + p3 )) ∂πI ∂pi = 0, i = 1, 2 and ∂πO ∂p3 = 0: 3ν + c(3 + γ) − 2(3 + 2γ)pi − 2γpj + γp3 = 0, i, j = 1, 2; i = j 3ν + c(3 + γ) − 2(3 + 2γ)p3 + γ(p1 + p2 ) = 0 post-merger equilibrium pI , pO as: pI = c(2+γ)(3+2γ)+ν(6+5γ) 2(γ 2 +6γ+6) Zulehner, Firms and Markets and pO = c(3+γ)(1+γ)+ν(3+2γ) (γ 2 +6γ+6) 17 / 45 A merger between two firms cont’d post-merger quantities qI , qO and profits πI , πO : qI = πI = 2 (3+γ)(6+5γ)(ν−c) (v−c) and qO = (3+2γ) 18(γ 2 +6γ+6) 9(γ 2 +6γ+6) 2 2 3 (3+γ)(6+5γ) (ν−c) (v−c)2 and πO = (3+2γ) 36(γ 2 +6γ+6)2 9(γ 2 +6γ+6)2 effect on prices and consumer surplus the merger increase prices, i.e. pI > pb and decreases consumer surplus, i.e. CSI < CSb insiders’ profit: πI > πb outsiders’ profit: πO > πb effect on total welfare: Wb > Wm Zulehner, Firms and Markets 18 / 45 Sources of efficiency gains Market structure failures (e.g. entry barriers) Economies of scale and of scope Reallocation of production across plants (to favor more efficient but underutilized plants, or to save on transportation cost) Avoiding duplication of fixed costs of distribution, marketing and administrative activities Externalities in advertising or R&D Replacement of inefficient management “Market for corporate control”: threat of takeovers important in disciplining managers (Marris, QJE 1963) empirical evidence is mixed Zulehner, Firms and Markets 19 / 45 Efficiency gains If efficiency gains affect fixed costs: no impact on equilibrium prices however, higher welfare due to elimination of duplications. If efficiency gains affect variable costs and are large enough: outweigh the increase in market power → lower prices. outsiders lose from the mergers (outsiders’ incentive to complain when there are efficiency gains...) consumers and total welfare benefit from the merger Zulehner, Firms and Markets 20 / 45 Coordinated or pro-collusive effects Does the merger increase the scope for collusion? Factors that facilitate (overt or tacit) collusion: concentration and number of firms high entry barriers observability of other firms’ behavior: exchange of information, competition clauses, transparency of prices and public bids symmetry multimarket contacts short information lags and frequent interactions (...) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 21 / 45 Merger Control in the EU applies to all changes in market structure (as opposed to “market conduct”) with the Merger Control Regulation 1989 European merger control was established Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 of 20 January 2004 on the control of concentrations between undertakings (EC Merger Regulation) OJ [2004] L 24/1 under certain conditions Art. 101 and 102 TFEU apply (which regulate market conduct, i.e. agreements between firms and abuse of dominance) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 22 / 45 Definition and forms of concentration Concentration = change of control on a lasting basis (Art. 3 ECMR) Merger of two or more previously independent undertakings (Art. 3 para. 1 (a) ECMR) Acquisition of direct or indirect control of another undertaking (Art. 3 para. 1 (b) ECMR) decisive influence on an undertaking rights or contracts which confer decisive influence (e.g. shares): majority confers decisive influence ownership or the right to use all or part of the assets Joint venture: concentration if the joint venture performs on a lasting basis all the functions of an autonomous economic entity no concentration if the joint venture is limited to specific functions for the parent companies (e.g. R&D joint ventures) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 23 / 45 Community dimension ECMR applies to all concentrations with a Community dimension (Art. 1 ECMR). Commission has sole jurisdiction on mergers with a Community dimension (Art. 21 ECMR) member states are not allowed to apply their national competition laws (“one-stop-shop”) referral from Commission to the competent authorities of a Member State and vice versa possible no one-stop-shop principle outside the EU: e.g. GE-Honeywell was subject to merger control both in the EU and the US! Zulehner, Firms and Markets 24 / 45 Community dimension: measured by quantitative thresholds because of the size of the undertakings concerned (Art. 1(2) ECMR): worldwide turnover of all undertakings combined > 5bn euro community-wide turnover of at least two undertakings each > 250m euro. because of effects in several member states (Art. 1(3) ECMR): worldwide turnover of all undertakings combined (a) > 2.5bn euro. community-wide turnover of at least two undertakings each (d) > 100m euro. affecting at least three member states (b and c): combined aggregate turnover in at least three member states > 100 m euro, turnover of at least two of the undertakings in three member states > 25m euro) Zulehner, Firms and Markets 25 / 45 Community dimension Overall, about 2% of all European mergers have Community dimension, hence go through EC merger control. A concentration has no community dimension if each of the undertakings achieves more than two-thirds of its aggregate community-wide turnover in one member state (Art. 1 (2 and 3)) Concentrations with relevance for only one member state shall remain in the jurisdiction of that member state. Zulehner, Firms and Markets 26 / 45 Substantive analysis Market Definition: Product market and geographic market Quantitative criteria: cross-price elasticities, price correlation tests, etc. Qualitative information: interviews, questionnaires Assessment of market power concentration and distribution of market shares elasticity of market demand elasticity of supply of rivals and degree of excess capacity potential entrants buyer power Zulehner, Firms and Markets 27 / 45 Substantive analysis Effect of the concentration on competition Anti-competitive effects arise if the concentration creates or strengthens a dominant position. Dominant position is defined as: “...a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition [from] being maintained on the relevant market by giving it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumers.” (see e.g. ECJ United Brands ibid. para. 65; ECJ Hoffmann-La Roche ibid. para. 38 and others). Zulehner, Firms and Markets 28 / 45 How to assess a dominant position Market structure esp. market shares very high market shares usually show dominance (> 70-75%) low market shares usually preclude dominance (< 25 %) between 25%-70% additional criteria have to be examined: actual and potential competition, market share and strength of competitors, buyer power. Properties of the undertaking technological advantage, economic and financial strength market behavior behavior that shows the ability to act independently Zulehner, Firms and Markets 29 / 45 Substantive analysis cont’d Horizontal mergers (> 80% of all merger cases) Creation or strengthening of a dominant position (the same analysis as under Art. 102 TFEU, also in regard to market definition) Unilateral and coordinated effects are considered Vertical mergers (about 10% of all cases) are examined mainly whether they result in foreclosure (entry barriers) Conglomerate mergers (about 5% of all cases) are less likely to significantly impede effective competition than horizontal mergers Zulehner, Firms and Markets 30 / 45 The EU merger control procedure Informal talks between firms and EC merger announcement (to the press) merger “notification” (to the EC) Phase I decision (25 working days) cleared (80% - 90%) cleared with remedies raise serious doubts → Phase II (1% - 5%) Phase II decision (90 working days) cleared cleared with remedies blocked Zulehner, Firms and Markets 31 / 45 Merger remedies Merger remedies increasingly important in the EU and US Two types of remedies Structural remedies firms are obliged to divest part of their assets to create more symmetric industry structure post-merger, include divestiture of an entire ongoing business or partial divestiture (possibly a ‘mix and match’ of assets of the different firms involved) preferred by the EC (if feasible) Non-structural or behavioral remedies firms’ engagements not to abuse of certain assets available to them, including compulsory licensing or access to property rights. Zulehner, Firms and Markets 32 / 45 Notifications vs. cleared mergers 450 402 395 400 356 346 Number of notified cases s/ ompatible merg gers Number of co 350 335 330 325 320 347 340 313 296 300 259 256 249 250 274 270 277 276 224 219 247 238 241 222 211 200 168 150 100 89 59 64 60 59 56 59 91 92 93 95 131 132 110 119 107 64 69 50 7 11 0 90 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 March Zulehner, Firms and Markets 33 / 45 Phase I vs. Phase II phases over time (bar diagram) 450 450 386 400 336 350 350 326 305 311 NumberofphaseIIevaluations NumberoffphaseIevaluatiions 400 291 300 300 267 249 242 250 238 232 250 214 212 200 200 150 150 100 124 115 102 100 85 56 55 64 53 50 50 7 0 6 4 4 6 7 6 11 11 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 20 18 21 7 9 8 10 13 15 10 5 4 2 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 0 0 99 00 01 March Page 1 Zulehner, Firms and Markets 34 / 45 Number of cases with remedies vs. prohibited mergers 45 2 40 Num mber of cases w with remedies/ Nu umber of prohiibited cases 35 30 1 5 25 20 40 2 0 0 15 15 02 03 15 27 23 10 1 0 16 2 1 5 1 6 7 91 92 0 3 6 4 0 3 2 0 90 Zulehner, Firms and Markets 93 9 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 35 / 45 Techniques in merger control Estimate impact of the merger on concentration, then relate concentration to price Problems: market definition concentration-price relation Direct estimation of impact of merger on consumer prices e.g. Staples/Office Depot: compare price level in cities with two or more suppliers to cities with only one supplier Merger simulations e.g. Volvo/Scania: calculate post-merger prices Zulehner, Firms and Markets 36 / 45 Merger analysis - examples/cases Beer market “Nearly ideal demand system” effects of a hypothetical merger Office superstores → presentation Staples/Office Depot Price - market structure estimations Insurance market → presentation Zulehner, Firms and Markets 37 / 45 Merger simulation: Cournot model pre-merger let’s assume there are n firms with constant marginal cost ci , i = 1, . . . , n and who face a linear demand function p(q) = a − bq firms maximize πi = (p − ci )qi = (a − bq − ci )qi FOC: p(q) − ci + ∂p(q) ∂qi qi = 0 price-cost margins without using cost data use of price and output data only we need an estimate for μ finally, we can regress ĉ on cost shifters to obtain estimates for the marginal cost function linear marginal cost: ĉ = c0 + c1 w1 + . . . + ck wk + ω new equilibrium after the merger of two firms calculate new prices and quantities Zulehner, Firms and Markets 38 / 45 “Nearly ideal demand system” compatible with utility maximization multi-stage budgeting → restrictions on the cross-price elasticities market level: product (all cars) - yes/no segments k, m (small cars, estate cars, people carriers, etc) choice of a specific good - brands i, j corresponding to these three decision levels, there are three levels at which demand equations are estimated elasticity for the market as a whole middle level equations estimate elasticities for segments within the market lower level equations estimate elasticities within each segment Zulehner, Firms and Markets 39 / 45 “Nearly ideal demand system” Stage 1: sit = αi + βi log (yGt /Pt ) + J j=1 γij log (pjt ) + it , sit share at expenditures in segment of brand i at time t; yGt expenditures in the segment Pt price index for expenditures in the segment pjt price of brand j at time t. K Stage 2: log (qmt ) = αm + βm log (yBt ) + k=1 δmk log (πkt ) + mt qmt revenues in segment m at time t yBt expenditures for the product (i.e. across all segments) πmt price index for segment k at time t Zulehner, Firms and Markets 40 / 45 “Nearly ideal demand system” cont’d Stage 3: ut = β0 + β1 log (y1 ) + β2 log (Πt ) + δZt + it ut overall revenues for the product at time t y1 deflated income Πt deflated price index for the product Zt further exogenous variables at time t Consistency checks: relative size of elasticities individual elasticities should be (in absolute values) larger than the segment elasticities which in turn should be larger than the overall elasticity Zulehner, Firms and Markets 41 / 45 Beer market Hausman, Leonard, and Zona 1994; Bishop and Walker 2002 demand function: “Nearly ideal demand system” market level: beer - yes/no segment k, m: premium beer, light beer and popular beer choice of brand i, j: Budweiser, Miller, etc. estimated price elasticities elasticity standard error Budweiser -4.2 0.13 Molson -5.4 0.15 Labatts -4.6 0.25 Miller -4.4 0.15 Coors -4.9 0.21 Molson Light -5.8 0.15 Source: Hausman, Leonard and Zona, 1994 Zulehner, Firms and Markets 42 / 45 Beer market light segment own and cross elasticities Genesee Genesee -3.763 (0.072) Coors 0.569 (0.085) Old Milwaukee 1.233 (0.121) Lite 0.509 (0.095) Molson 0.683 (0.124) Source: Hausman, Leonard Zulehner, Firms and Markets Old Coors Milwaukee 0.464 0.397 (0.060) (0.039) -4.598 0.407 (0.115) (0.058) 0.956 -6.097 (0.132) (0.140) 0.737 0.587 (0.122) (0.079) 1.213 0.611 (0.149) (0.093) and Zona, 1994 Lite 0.254 (0.043) 0.452 (0.075) 0.841 (0.112) -5.039 (0.141) 0.893 (0.125) Molson 0.201 (0.037) 0.482 (0.061) 0.565 (0.087) 0.577 (0.083) -5.841 (0.148) 43 / 45 Merger simulation: Bertrand oligopoly with differentiated products before the merger Max: Πi = (Pi − MCi )Qi (P1 , . . . , Pn ) Pi −MCi i FOC: Qi (P1 , . . . , Pn ) + (Pi − MCi ) ∂Q = μ1ii ∂Pi = 0 ↔ Pi using an estimate for the demand elasticity marginal cost can be backed out merger: brand i and j Max: Πi = (Pi − MCi )Qi (P1 , . . . , Pn ) + (Pj − MCj )Qj (P1 , . . . , Pn ) m l FOC: sk + l=1 Pl −MC sl μlk = 0 Pl with m to be the number of products produced by the merged firm and market share sk of product k calculate new equilibrium assuming marginal cost do not change efficiency gains Zulehner, Firms and Markets 44 / 45 Hypothetical merger: beer market Hypothetical merger between Coors and Labatts Simulation based on a non-cooperative model without entry and reposition of product supply Cross price elasticities show that price of Coors is more restricted by the prices of Miller and Budweiser than by the price of Lababtts price of Labatts is more restricted by the price of Molson than by the price of Coors price changes after the merger Reduction in marginal cost 0% 5% Coors 4.4% -0.8% Labatts 3.3% -1.9% Source: Hausman, Leonard and Zona, 1994 Zulehner, Firms and Markets 10% -6.1% -7.0% 45 / 45