Tijdschrift voor Economie en Management Vol. XXXV, 4, 1990 Leasing and the Pie Approach to Capital Structure by E. DURINCK, K. JANSEN, E. LAVEREN" and C. VAN HULLE*" I. INTRODUCTION In the finance literature there exists a large number of models for the valuation of financial leases. See for example Herst (1982). Many of these models approach leasing only from a lessee's point of view. By analyzing differential cash flows between leasing and alternative methods of financing, and by determining appropriate discount rates for the various flows, they try to obtain the value of leasing for a lessee. More complete models do not consider lease payments as given, but as a result of market forces between lessors and lessees (e.g. Miller and Upton (1976), Lewellen, Long and MC Connell (1976)). These equilibrium models often start from a perfect market situation where leasing adds no value, and subsequently introduce several market imperfections in order to see how they affect the irrelevancy of leasing, thus obtaining insight in the incentives to lease. Most of the literature analyzing corporate leasing policy concentrates on the tax-related incentives to lease or buy, but non-tax incentives are considered as well, and can be very important (see for example Smith and Wakeman (1985)). Only a few models try to integrate personal taxes into their approach of financial leasing valuation. Generally leasing is compared with borrowing. This is because borrowing in a Modigliani and Miller (MM) world with corporate taxes (M.M. (1963)) is never dominated by equity. Equity may be cheaper however when the personal tax dis* Departement Bedrijfseconomie, U.F.S.I.A., Antwerpen * * Departement Toegepaste Economie, K.U.Leuven advantage of borrowing, where personal taxes on debt income exceed those on equity income, is larger than the corporate tax advantage (Miller (1977)). Brealey and Young (1980) analyze leasing in a Miller world where leasing is compared with equity financing. The same analysis, with inclusion of investment tax credits, can also be found in the textbook by Franks, Broyles and Carleton (1985). In this paper we will try to give a more integrated approach of the leasing phenomenon in perfect but not taxless markets. Our aim is to see how financial leasing influences the distribution of cash flows, generated by investment projects, between the government and the final beneficiaries, i.e. the personal security holders. The foundation for our analysis is the pie approach of capital structure, and leasing is just one way to divide the total pie. To include personal taxes in the analysis without complicating too much our model, we will assume that personal interest income on debt is taxed at a uniform rate across investors, while equity income is not taxed at all at the personal level. This is in fact Miller's assumption in his famous paper of 1977'. It is however easy to work out the present model under the assumption that there is a non-zero uniform personal tax rate on equity income. This will only complicate the formulas a bit, but won't change anything essential2. Under different assumptions about the relationship between corporate and personal tax rates, we will obtain similar results as in the classical MM world, but also as in the analysis of Brealey and Young in Miller's world. The model in this paper will be very simplified, since it is our intention to get an as clear as possible insight in the mechanism of cash flow distribution. Therefore we purposely exclude all imperfections but corporate and personal taxes in a simplified form, to the extent that leasing becomes almost indistinguishable from borrowing. This can serve as a starting point for a deeper understanding of the value of financial leasing when several imperfections are introduced. 11. PERFECT CAPITAL MARKETS AND THE VALUE ADDITIVITY PRINCIPLE We start with the assumption that capital markets are perfect, i.e. there are no transaction costs, information costs or financial distress costs ; investors and firms have equal access to the market ; they have homogeneous expectations ; there are no government restrictions which interfere with capital market transactions ; financial assets are infinitely divisible ; and markets are competitive. Schall (1972) has shown that in transaction costless, competitive capital markets the value additivity principle (VAP) holds, i.e. the total equilibrium market value of any stream Y, received by investors in the market is independent of how it is divided into separate income streams of one or more firms (Y,, ...,Y,) in being made available to the market: n if Y, n 1 Yi i = l = then V[Y,] C V[Yi], i = l = where V[Y] denotes the equilibrium market value of the stream Y. We assume that there are only two types of security holders : bondholders entitled to promised payments and equityholders receiving residual payments3. The VAP also holds with corporate taxes, and since we assumed uniform personal taxation on debt income, also if there are personal taxes. In the last situation, investors value streams in the form they really receive them, i.e. after personal taxes. The assumption of uniform personal taxation has the advantage that we are able to follow the distribution of cash flows up to the point they are received by individuals. This gives us a better idea of how cash flows are divided between investors and the government. 111. THE PIE APPROACH T O CAPITAL STRUCTURE The capital structure of a firm is the pattern of the firm's liabilities that in total represent the claims against the future cash flows of the firm. These future cash flows are generated by the firm's operations (investments). The manner in which these operations are financed determines the distribution of the total claim against these cash flows, the total pie, between various parties : stockholders, bondholders, the government (taxes), lawyers (bank-ruptcy costs), etc.. As we will see in the next paragraph, also leasing is no-thing more than a particular way to cut the total pie into pieces. No matter how the pie is divided, and no matter who gets the parts, they must still add up to the total cash flow, and the value is unaltered by the capital structure. This is in fact the essence of the Modigliani-Miller theory (M.M. (1958)). However as Ross and Westerfield (1988) notice there is an important difference between claims such as those of stockholders and bondholders, which are marketed claims, and those of the government which are nonmarketed. Marketed claims for instance can be bought and sold in financial markets, while nonmarketed claims cannot. By the value of a firm one generally means the value of the marketed claims. But this value can change with changes in the capital structure. So, the financing decisions in general have an influence on the value V of the firm. By the pie theory however, any increase in V must imply an identical decrease in the value of the nonmarketed claims. Hence, a firm trying to maximize its value equally can try to minimize the value of the nonmarketed claims. We further assume that the value of the claims from the existing debtholders does not change by the undertaking of a new investment project4 (see for example Haley and Schall (1981)). S'ince any new security holders (who finance the project) will pay the market value of the claims they receive, the net present value of the project V - I (with V the value of the marketed claims generated by the project, and I the investment outlay necessary to finance the project) precisely equals the value to the existing shareholders from undertaking the investment. Hence, under this assumptions firm value maximization is equivalent to the maximization of the existing shareholders' wealth. IV. FINANCIAL LEASING IN PERFECT CAPITAL MARKETS WITH TAXES In a financial lease agreement, the lessor purchases an asset and then immediately grants the lessee exclusive use of the asset for most of its economic life in return for periodic lease payments. The contract is not cancellable, the failure to meet lease payments can force the lessee into bankruptcy (or reorganization) and the lease is fully amortized (that is, the lessor receives lease payments which repay the full .~ the lessor is the legal owner of cost of the leased a s ~ e t )Although the asset, the contract is otherwise closely analogous to a loan secured by the asset. We assume that capital markets are perfect, but for the existence of corporate taxes, and personal taxes on debt income. Financial leasing is considered to be completely equivalent to debt financing, i.e. they are perfect substitutes and have exactly the same risk. This is naturally the case in a perfect market. One dollar of a lease obligation has the same value as one dollar of a debt obligation unless there are imperfections causing lease payments to be less (or more) certain than debt payments. Consider a firm having the opportunity to invest in an asset that generates a future operating cash flow X in perpetuity. This investment requires an initial outlay I. We assume that the project is completely isolated from other projects, so that no transfer of taxable losses between projects is possible. For the same reason, we suppose that taxable losses cannot be carried forward (or backward). The firm has the choice between buying the asset and financing the purchase price with a mixture of debt and equity, or leasing the asset from a lessor. Suppose also that capital good markets are perfect so that the invest. ~ look at the distribution ment cost I is the same for any i n v e ~ t o rLet's of the total pie X under the two alternatives. All cash flows are considered to be perpetuities ; in particular payments to bondholders will be all interest, and there is no salvage value to the invested asset. A. Purchase alternative where DP = (dividend) payments to equityholders of the purchaser; RP = payments to bondholders of the purchaser before personal taxes ; FP = RP(1-TB) = payments to bondholders after personal taxes (TB is the tax rate on interest income); TcP = corporate taxes paid by the purchaser ; TaxP = total taxes paid by the purchaser and its security holders. The next figure shows this distribution of the total pie X, i.e. the distribution of the total operating cash flow X between the security holders and the government. FIGURE 1 total operating cash flow 1 PaYy-n'. equityholders PaYpts bondholders 1 TanP payments to the government The net present value V of the project equals V = V[DP] + V[FP] - value of the marketed claims I = V[X] - V[TaxP] - I investment outlay value of the value of the investment total pie nonmarketed claims outlay (2) B. Lease alternative where D" = (dividend) payments to equityholders of the lessee ; L = payments to the lessor ; Taxe = total taxes paid by the lessee and its security holders. It is assumed that except for the lease claims, the lessee is all equity financed. Possibly the project might support more debt than the lease obligations, so that the lessee could take additional debt, hence increasing the value of the project to its security holders7. Our aim however is to compare the lease and purchase alternatives. In order to make leasing and purchasing comparable we assume, following Myers et al. (1976) and Franks and Hodges (1978), that the purchaser takes as much debt as to equate his debt associated cash flows with those of the lessee.' Since these flows are of the same risk, as we assumed, we have two comparable alternatives. Stated differently, the amount of debt is chosen in such a way that the yearly after tax flows received by equityholders are identical under both alternatives (i.e. under leasing and under purchasing). Any additional debt might increase the value of the project, but it won't change the difference in value between the purchase and the lease alternative^.^ The value V" to the lessee equals L however is received by the lessor and divided into payments to its debt- and equityholders by its financing decision : where D' = (dividend) payments to equityholders of the lessor; R' = payments to bondholders of the lessor before personal taxes ; F' = Rr(l-TB) = payments to bondholders after personal taxes ; Tcr = corporate taxes paid by the lessor; Taxr = total taxes paid by the lessor and its security holders. The value V' to the lessor equals From (3) and (5) we get the distribution of the total pie X under the lease alternative : The value to the lessee and the lessor together equals V" +V = V[De] + V[Dr] + V[Fr] value of the marketed claims = V[X] - (V[Taxe] value of the total pie - I investment outlay + V[Taxr]) valuz of the nonmarketed claims - I investment outlay (8) C. The net advantage of leasing The net advantage of leasing is the value of the cash flows to the security holders of lessee and lessor together, compared with the value of the cash flows to a purchaser, i.e. the difference between the value of the marketed claims associated with the two alternatives. But this is also equal to the difference in value of the nonmarketed claims, i.e. the difference between the taxes corresponding to the purchase and the lease alternatives. Consequently, we obtain for the net advantage of leasing (NAL) (see also the appendix): NAL = V[TaxP] - V[Taxe] - V[Taxr] (9) So leasing has a net advantage whenever the tax leaks associated with the purchaser exceed those of the lessee and lessor together. The net advantage of leasing to the lessee is equal to the value of the cash flows to the security holders of the lessee, compared with the value of the cash flows to a purchaser. Under the leasing alternative, the security holders of the investing firm (the lessee) do not have to supply the investment outlay and neither do they have the tax obligations associated with the purchase alternative. They do however have their own tax obligations and they have to pay lease rentals to the lessor. It follows that the net advantage of leasing to the lessee (NALe) is given by (see also the appendix) Finally, the lessor supplies the investment outlay and pays his taxes, while he receives lease rentals as income. The net advantage of leasing to the lessor (NALr), which equals the value of the project to the lessor in this case, is thus given by (see also the appendix) If lessor and lessee are in a bargaining position, they could agree on maximizing their combined value, the net advantage of leasing, and sharing the profit following a certain sharing rule (see for example Hull (1982)). This can be done by appropriately choosing L (notice that taxes depend on L). More likely, L will be determined as an equilibrium in the leasing market, and no lessor and lessee will come to an agreement unless leasing has a positive value for both of them (i.e. NALe > 0 and NALr > 0). For example, if there is perfect competition between lessors, they will compete until V = 0, and all the benefits go to the lessee (e.g. Lewellen et al. (1976), Hull (1982)). We shall assume that a lease agreement is only possible if > 0. NALe > 0 and NALr Moreover, the project must have a positive net present value to the purchaser or to the lessee. Since we want to concentrate on the value and the possible advantage of leasing, we will assume however that this condition is fulfilled and that the project is acceptable in one way or another. V. FINANCIAL LEASING WITHOUT NON-CASH TAX DEDUCTIONS Taxes are determined by cash payments such as interest and lease payments, which are tax deductible to the payer and taxable to the receiver, but also by non-cash tax deductions such as depreciation. Leasing causes a transfer of cash andlor non-cash tax deductions from lessee to lessorlO, and hence changes the taxable earnings of both firms. A second important point, considering personal taxes, is the influence of leasing on the distribution of cash flows between interest and dividend income. In this paper we assume the absence of any non-cash tax deductions such as depreciation and investment tax credit. Suppose that the marginal corporate tax rates of lessor and lessee (purchaser) are TICand T, respectively. Let TBbe the personal tax rate on debt income, while equity income is not taxed. Let's calculate the taxable earnings of our different firms. The taxable earnings of a purchaser equal Hence, If TB < T, there is an advantage of debt financing to equity financing, since part of the total pie X is transferred from a tax regime T, into a tax regime TB,which causes a decrease in total taxes, and hence an increase in the marketed streams. If there are no restrictions on the amount of debt a firm can take and if there are no imperfections such as bankruptcy or agency costs, the firm will only use debt financing, hence reducing its corporate tax bill to zero.'' If TB = T, debt financing causes no increase in value. If TB > T, equity financing is the best option. The taxable earnings of lessee and lessor equal1' Hence, and Formula (18) clearly shows how the pie distribution has its influence on the taxes. The first term of this formula indicates a taxation of the total pie at the tax rate of the investing firm (the lessee). Part of the pie (the lease rental L) however is transferred to the lessor and falls into another tax regime. This correction is affected by the second term. Finally, the last term expresses the influence of the lessor's interest payments which are free of corporate taxes but fall under the personal tax regime of interest income. Without the non-cash tax deductions, leasing is exactly the same as a corporate borrowing arrangement between the lessor and the lessee. So if leasing is the best alternative, it means that the optimal choice for the investing firm is to borrow from the lessor.13 Using the tax formulas derived in this section it is possible to obtain explicit expressions for the net advantage of leasing under different assumptions about the tax rates (see also the appendix). Hence, let us consider now some different situations for the relation between the corporate tax rates of lessee and lessor, and the personal tax rate on bond income. In particular, when TB = 0, we obtain the classical Modigliani-Miller case. As we already noticed, the purchaser will prefer 100% debt financing. But to be comparable with the leasing alternative we assume that he takes as much debt as to equate his debt associated cash flows to those of the lessee. By debt associated cash flows we mean the difference between the cash flows to the stockholders of the firm and those of an all equity financed firm. As we show in the appendix the equivalent loan must satisfy RP = L, i.e. to have the same debt obligations as the lessee the purchaser borrows as much as to make his interest payments equal to the lease rentals. Hence it follows from (12) and (14) that the taxable earnings of the purchaser EP are equal to those of the lessee E". It is clear that the lessor cannot borrow more than the amount that makes interest payments equal to L. Without other imperfections the lessor will be all debt financed. This means R' = L and Er = 0. For the net advantage of leasing we obtain now (see Appendix): NAL = 0, Under this tax scenario, leasing has no advantage and there exists a unique value for the lease payments which makes lessee and lessor indifferent to leasing, i.e. NALe = NALr = 0. This value is given by If the interest rate on debt is equal to r, the discount rate for cash flows of the same risk applie by investors in the market equals r(l-TB). Hence and consequently Purchase or leasing are equivalent alternatives and the cost of leasing and debt financing is the same. The taxable earnings of the purchaser are identical to those of the lessee, while personal taxable earnings are transferred from debtholders of the purchaser to debtholders of the lessor. As a result total taxes and consequently total marketed streams remain the same. For the purchaser equity financing will be the alternative to leasing. The lessor however still wants to have 100% debt in its capital structure, i.e. RP = 0 and R' = L. For the taxable earnings we now have : Leasing causes a decrease in taxable earnings, and consequently in corporate taxes. However, personal taxes increase by TBRr = TBL. Hence, NAL = (T,-T,)V[L] <0. Transferring a stream L in a tax regime T, to a tax regime TB, with TB > T,, can never be advantageous. Now the purchaser prefers debt financing, but the lessor will be all equity financed : RP = L, Rr = 0. The taxable earnings are given by Leasing causes an increase in taxable earnings and consequently in corporate taxes. However, personal taxes decrease by T,RP = T,L. Hence, NAL = (TB-T,,)V[L] >O Transferring a stream L in a tax regime TB to a tax regime T,,, with T,, < TB, is always advantageous. Leasing, which is just a corporate borrowing arrangement under our present assumptions, is the cheapest form of financing since the lessor has a lower corporate tax rate than the lessee and than individual debtholders. As we noticed before however, lessor and lessee will only come to an agreement if leasing has a positive value for both of them. So, the feasible values of L must satisfy the equations NALr 10 and NALc 2 0. It follows that acceptable values of L are bounded by an upper and lower bound as in the next relation (see appendix) and using the discount rate r(1-TB) to value L, we get The upper bound is the maximal acceptable value of L, which leaves the lessee with a zero net advantage, while the lower bound is the minimal acceptable value leaving the lessor in a neutral situation. D. TB > T , TB > T,, Now both purchaser and lessor prefer equity financing : RP = R' = 0. Hence, There is no change in taxable earnings and there are no personal taxes. Under this assumptions, leasing just causes a transfer of taxable earnings L from a tax regime T, to a tax regime T,,. Consequently, NAL = (T,-T,,)V[L] . The relation between T,, and T, now becomes relevant. If T,, > TIT, leasing has a negative present value, but if T,, < T, leasing is advantageous. If TIT,, < T, the possible values of L are given by (see Appendix) And if debt with the same risk as L requires a before tax return r, we have VH. CONCLUSION In this paper we investigated how the way of financing, in particular financial leasing, influences the distribution of cash flows, generated by investment projects, between the government and the final beneficiaries, i.e. the personal security holders. In order to obtain a fundamental insight, we excluded all imperfections, but corporate and personal taxes in a simplified form (uniform personal taxation on debt income and tax free equity income). We even disregarded depreciation and other non-cash tax deductions, and only looked at separated projects with no salability of tax losses and no possibility to carry them forward (or backward). The basic (logical) result is that the best way to finance an investment project is the one which directs the generated cash flows to the most favourable tax regime. If the tax rate on personal income is smaller than the corporate tax rates, leasing has no value since both lessee and lessor will take as much debt as possible so that the final tax rate at which the cash flows are taxed is the personal one. If for some reason the lessor could not be fully debt financed, leasing will not be the most favourable form of financing. If the personal tax rate on debt income is larger than the corporate tax rate of some firm, debt financing will not be the best choice for this firm. Leasing can only have value then, when the corporate tax rate of the lessor is smaller than that of the lessee. Firms with small tax rates should lend, which is equivalent to lease, to firms with larger tax rates in this situation. Under our perfect assumptions, financial leasing has the same risk as debt financing. Consequently, in the absence of non-cash tax deductions, a lease agreement or a corporate debt agreement with a certain lessor are completely equivalent from an economic point of view. In spite of this equivalence, we still represented leasing in a way as if there was a difference between the two forms of financing. This is not the case under our present assumptions, but this manner of representation gives one the opportunity to introduce imperfections into the model (causing leasing to be a really special form of financing) and to study the consequences for the value of leasing. It shows that essentially financial leasing is nothing more than another form of debt financing, which obtains its characteristic features from a number of imperfections. In the present paper we only tried to create the basic view and understanding, which can serve as a starting point for further investigations. APPENDIX In this appendix we derive some formulas for the net advantage of leasing under different assumptions about the tax rates. As defined in the text, the net advantage of leasing (NAL) is equal to the value of the cash flows to the security holders of lessee and lessor together, compared with the value of the cash flows to a purchaser: NAL = V" + = V[De] V' - VP + VID1] + = V[TaxP] - V[TaxC] V[Fr] - V[DP] - V[FP] VITaxl] - Using (2).(4) and (6) we find that the net advantage of leasing to the lessee is equal to NAL" = V" - VP = V[De] = I - V[L] and to the lessor - + V[TaxP] V[DP] - V[FP] - V[TaxL], +I From (13), (16) and (17) it follows that the net advantage of leasing is given by: NAL = V[TaxP] = T,V[EP-E'] V[TaxC] - V[Taxr] - - T,,VIE1] + TBV[RP-R']. + V[Tax" - V[TaxL] + T,V[EP-E"] + TBV[RP], NAL" = I - V[L] = I - V[L] = V[L] = V[L] - I - T,,V[Er] - TBV[Rr] NAL' I - VITaxl] - Let us now discuss as in the text the different cases for the relation between the corporate tax rates of lessee and lessor, and the personal tax rate on bond income. Case l : TB < T,, TB < T,, We first apply the equivalent loan principle, i.e. we equate the debt associated cash flows of the purchaser with those of the lessee. As mentioned in the text we mean by debt associated cash flows, the difference between the cash flows to the stocltholders of the firm and those of an all equity financed firm. For the purchaser this gives : and foi- the lessee Hence the equivalent loan must satisfy RP = L and it follows from (12) and (14) that EP = E". As already noticed in the text, we also have R' = L and E' = 0. For the net advantage of leasing we can then use (19),(20) and (21) to obtain NAL = 0. + TBV[L] = I - (1-T,)V[L], NALe = I - V[L] - I 5 T, < T,, NAL' = V[L] Case 2 : T, - T,V[L] = (l-T,)V[L] - 1. As we explained above RP = 0 and R' = L. Using (12), (14) and (15) we see then that the taxable earnings are given by: E"=X,EC=X - L,E1=O. Hence we have by (19) (20) and (21) NAL NAL" T,V[L] - TBV[L] = (T,-T,)V[L], I - V[L] + T,V[L] = I - (1-T,)V[L], NAL' = V[L] - I - TBV[L] = (1-T,)V[L] - I. = = Case 3 : T,, 5 TB < T, We now have that RP = L, Rr = 0. Hence Again we obtain from (19), (20) and (21) = -T,,V[L] + TBV[L] = (TB-T,,)V[L], NAL" = I - V[L] TBV[L] = I - (1-TB)V[L], NAL' = V[L] - I - T,,V[L] = (l-T,,)V[L] - I. NAL + Requiring that leasing has a positive value for both the lessor and the lessee, i.e. NAL' > 0 and NAL" 1 0 , it follows that Using the discount rate r(1-TB) to value L; we get for the net advantage of leasing NAL = (TB-T,,)L l (l-TB)] , = I - L!r , NAL' NALr = (l-T,,)L / (l-T,)r - I. Case 4 : TB > T,, TB > T,, Since in this case R' = 0 it follows that RP = Consequently, it follows for the net advantage of leasing NAL = T,V[L] NALC = I NALr = - V[L] - V[L] - I T,,V[L] = (T,-T,,)V[L], + T,V[L] - = I - (1-T,)V[L], T,,V[L] = (1-T,,)V[L] - 1. If T,, < T, the feasible values of L making leasing acceptable to both the lessor and the lessee are thus given by NOTES 1. There is much controversy about this assumption however, certainly in Belgium where the withholding tax on dividends vastly exceeds the taxon interest income at the moment. 2. If this tax rate on equity income exceeds the tax rate on debt income, clearly debt financing will be preferred above equity financingand a result similar to case one of the present paper will be obtained. 3. Dividends can be considered as residual, since dividend policy is irrelevant in perfect markets (see for example FIaley and Schall (1981)). 4. This happens for instance when the existing debt is risk free. 5. We assume away the complications of purchase option and salvage value in this paper. 6. Imperfections of the capital good markets, such as specialization and market power can of course be an important justification for the existence of leasing. A differepce in investment cost between purchaser (investor) and lessor could readily be built in into our model. In this paper however we concentrate on the basic tax aspects. For more details on non-tax incentives to lease see for instance Smith and Wakeman (1985). 7. See for example Haley and Schall (1981). S. By debt associated cash flows we mean the difference between the cash flows to the stockholders of the firm (purchaser or lessee) and those of an all equity financed firm. 9. This "equivalent loan" principle to determine the value of a lease agreement can only be applied however, when there are no restrictions on the amount of debt a lessee or purchasel- can take, other than those caused by the debt associated cash flows themselves. For example; if the debt claims increase, agency costs and financial distress costs will increase as well (in an imperfect world). This process will limit the debt capacity, but has the same influence to purchaser or lessee, and comparison by an equivalent loan is still possible. If there are other limitations on debt capacity, having a different effect for purchaser or lessee, the equivalent loan principle cannot be applied and a direct comparison with absolute debt amounts is necessary. In this case one has to include an interest term R e in equation (3). 10. The depreciation deduction is only transferred from lessee to lessor in the American leasing system. In a number of countries, for example in Belgium, the lessee is considered to be the fiscal ownel- of the asset and he has the right to keep the depreciation deduction. 11. As explained before, we assume that if the conditions for the equivalent loan principle are fulfilled, the lessee does not take additional debt and the purchaser uses as much debt as to equate his debt associated cash flows to those of the lessee. 12. We deduct the whole lease payment L as an expense from the operating cash flow X, while L is treated as a gain to the lessor. This is the American system of leasing, which silnultaneously gives the lessor the right to deduct depreciation from its income for tax purposes. The lessor is the fiscal owner of the asset. In Belgium, the lessee is the owner from a fiscal point of view. H e can not deduct the whole L as an expense however, but only a part of L which is considered to be the interest part of the implicit loan. The implicit interest rate or the (before tax) cost of leasing is equal to the internal rate of return, equating the present value of the lease payments to the initial investment outlay. For our perpetuity model we get: But this means that the whole L can be considered as interest, and the two different systems are equivalent except for the transfer of the depreciation in the American system. Since in this paper we are ignoring depreciation, the two systems are equal. 13. In our analysis we compare leasing with personal debt and equity financing. Although NAL 0, it is possible that there are other corporate financing methods which are still more valuable. In fact under our perfect markets assumption and without depreciation deductions, leasing is just a particular corporate borrowing arrangement. Other corporate financing methods can b e analyzed in the same way however as we do for leasing, i.e. we follow the distribution of cash flows until they reach their final destination (the personal security holders). For the role financial intermediaries can play in the valuation of firms and the distribution of cash flows and taxes, when these intermediaries provide equity financing, see for example Franks and Pringle (1982). Because of the resemblance between financial leasing and borrowing, one can ask what remains under our perfect markets assumptions of the essential features of leasing. Typical for lelrsing is what is generally called 100% financing. The lessor always finances the investment for an amount equal to the investment outlay I, since he buys the asset instead of the lessee. Even if a project supports more debt than I, this additional debt can only be obtained by borrowing arrangements other than leasing. So, this 100% value I is also an upper bound on the amount of lease financing (if lease payments are due in advance there is of course less than 100% financing). REFERENCES Brealey, R. and S. Myers, 1984, Principles of Corporate Finance, (McGraw Hill, N.Y.). Brealey, R. and C. Young, 1980, Debt, Taxes and Leasing - A Note, Journal of Finance 35. Copeland, T. and J. Weston, 1988, Financial Theory and Corporate Policy, (Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Reading Mass.). DeAngelo, H. and R. Masulis, 1980, Optimal Capital Structure under Corporate and Personal Taxation, Journal of Financial Ecolzomics 8, March. Durinck, E. and J. Fabry, 1983, Evaluatie van financiele leasing in Belgie, Working Paper 83-91, UFSIA, CBB. Franks. J.; J. Broyles and W. Carleton, 1985, Corporate Finance : Concepts and Applications, (Boston, Mass. Kent). Franks, J. and S. Hodges, 1978, Valuation of Financial Lease Contracts : A Note, Jounzal of Finance 33, May. Franks, J. and J. Pringle, 1982, Debt Financing, Corporate Financial Intermediaries and Firm Valuation, Journal of Finance 37, June. Haley, C. and L. Schall, 1981, The Theoly of Financial Decisions; (McGraw Hill, N.Y.). Herst, A., 1982, De leasekoopbeslissing, (Stenfert Kroese, Leiden). Hull, J., 1982, The Bargaining Positions of the Parties to a Lease Agreement, Financial Management 11, Autumn. Lewellen, W., M. Long and J. McConnell, 1976, Asset Leasing in Competitive Capital Markets, Journal of Finance 31, June. Miller, M,, 1977, Debt and Taxes, Jo~ournalof Finance 32, May. Miller, M. and C. Upton, 1976, Leasing, Buying and the Cost of Capital Services, Jo~~t7zal of Finance 31, June. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller, 1958, The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment, Anzericarz Economic Review 48, June. Modigliani, F. and M. Miller, 1963, Corporate Incomes Taxes and the Cost of Capital : A Correction, Anzerican Economic Review 53, June. Myers, S., D. Dill; and A. Bautista, Valuation of Financial Lease Contracts, Jour7zal of Finance 31, June. Ross, S. and R. Westerfield, 1988, Corporate Finance, (Times MirrorIMosby College Publishing, St. Louis, Miss.). Schall, L., 1972, Asset Valuation, Firm Investment and Firm Diversification, Journal of Business, Januaq~. Schall, L., 1974, The Lease-or-Buy and Asset Acquisition Decisions, Journal of Finance 29, September. Smith, C. and L. Wakeman, 1985, Determinants of Corporate Leasing Policy, Jour.nal of Finance 40, July.