Rehabilitating the Industrial Revolution Author(s): Maxine Berg and Pat Hudson Source: The Economic History Review, New Series, Vol. 45, No. 1 (Feb., 1992), pp. 24-50 Published by: Wiley on behalf of the Economic History Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2598327 . Accessed: 28/05/2014 10:42 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. . Wiley and Economic History Society are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Economic History Review. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions EconomicHistoryReview, XLV, I(I992), pp. 24-50 Rehabilitating theindustrial revolution' By MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON T he historiography of the industrial revolution in Englandhas moved and earlynineteenth centuries as awayfromviewingthelateeighteenth a uniqueturning The notionof pointin economicand socialdevelopment.2 radicalchangein industry and societyoccurring overa specific periodwas in the I920s and I930s by Claphamand otherswho effectively challenged stressedthe long taprootsof development and the incomplete natureof economicand socialtransformation.' Afterthisit was no longerpossibleto claimthatindustrial societyemergedde novoat anytimebetweenc. I750 and i85o, buttheidea ofindustrial revolution survived intothe i960s and I970s. In i968 Hobsbawmcould state unequivocally that the British revolution wasthemostfundamental in thehistory industrial transformation in written oftheworldrecorded documents.4 Rostow'sworkwasstillwidely of whatwas seen as a new typeof class influential and the socialhistory to be written. The idea thatthelate eighteenth societywas onlystarting and early nineteenth centurieswitnesseda significant socioeconomic remained wellentrenched.' discontinuity In thelastdecadethegradualist has appearedto triumph. In perspective economichistoryit has done so largelybecauseof a preoccupation with at theexpenseofmorebroadlybasedconceptualizations growth accounting havebeenproducedwhichillustrate ofeconomicchange.New statistics the slowgrowthofindustrial outputand grossdomesticproduct.Productivity andinvestment grewslowly;fixedcapitalproportions, savings, changedonly emained workers' andtheirpersonal gradually; livingstandards consumption I Some of the argumentsin this articleappear in Berg, 'Revisionsand revolutions';and in Hudson, We are verygrateful to N. F. R. Craftsfordetaileddiscussionofthesubstance ed., Regionsand industries. of an earlierversion,and to seminargroupsat theInstituteof HistoricalResearch,London, theNorthern Economic HistoriansGroup, Universityof Manchester,the Universityof Glasgow, the Universityof Paris viii at St Denis, and the Universitiesof Oslo and Bergen.Althoughmanyof the argumentsin the paper apply as much to Scotlandand Wales as to England, we confinediscussionin thispaper to the industrialrevolutionin England in orderto avoid confusionwherethe existingliteratureis discussed. 2 For a broad surveyof this and othertrendsin the historiography of the industrialrevolutionsee Cannadine,'The past and the present'. thetrendawayfrommorecataclysmic interpretations 3Clapham is mostoftenassociatedwithinitiating in Economichistory of modern Britain,but the shiftin emphasisis obviousin otherworksof the interwar Heaton, 'Industrialrevolution';Redford, period and earlier,e.g. Mantoux, The industrialrevolution; revolutions; George,Englandin transition. Economichistory ofEngland;Knowles,Industrialand commercial 4 Hobsbawm, Industry and empire,p. I3. class identifiedthe industrialrevolutionperiod as 5Thompson in his Making of theEnglishworking growth,thoughchallengedover the greatturningpoint in class formation.Rostow's Stages of economic the precisefitbetweenthe model and Britishexperience,was a powerfulvoice in favourof significant Landes in UnboundPrometheus drew a convincingpicture and unprecedentedeconomicdiscontinuity. of the transformations initiatedby technicalinnovation. 24 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 25 largely unaffectedbefore I 830 and were certainlynot squeezed. The macroeconomicindicatorsof industrialand social transformation were not presentand so the notionof industrialrevolutionhas been dethronedalmost entirely leavinginsteadonlya longprocessofstructural changein employment fromagrarianto non-agrarian occupations.6 At the same time,and oftentakinga stronglead fromthe gradualismof economichistoryinterpretations, the social historyof the periodhas shifted away fromanalysisof new class formations and consciousness.7The postMarxian perspectivestressesthe continuitybetweeneighteenthand ninesocial protestand radicalism.Chartism,forexample,is seen teenth-century as a chronologicalextensionof the eighteenth-century constitutional attack on Old Corruption.8 Late eighteenth-century depressionsand theNapoleonic of social tensionswhichare viewed Wars are seen as the majorprecipitators and selectiveeconomichardshipratherthanfrom as arisingfromtemporary anynewradicalcritiqueor alternative politicaleconomy.9'The ancienregime oftheconfessional state'survivedtheeighteenth and earlynineteenth centuries substantiallyunchanged.'0 In demography,the dominantexplanationof the late eighteenth-century populationexplosionstressesits continuity with a much earlier-established demographicregimewhichremainedintactuntil at least the I840s.11 And an influentialtendencyin the socio-cultural of the last few yearshas argued that the English industrial historiography revolutionwas veryincomplete(if it existedat all) because the industrial bourgeoisiefailedto gainpoliticaland economicascendancy.'2Thus England neverexperienceda periodofcommitment to industrialgrowth:theindustrial in a great arch of continuitywhose revolutionwas a brief interruption economic and politicalbase remainedfirmlyin the hands of the landed in metropolitan and its offshoots finance.Gentlemanly aristocracy capitalism in the prevailedand the power and influenceof industryand industrialists Englisheconomyand societywere ephemeraland limited.'3 6 Crafts,Britisheconomic growth.See also Harley, 'Britishindustrialization'; McCloskey,'Industrial revolution';Feinstein,'Capital formationin GreatBritain';Lindertand Williamson,'English workers' livingstandards'.More radical social and culturalchange is implied in some of the recentliterature discussingincreasesin internalconsumption.See Brewer,McKendrick,and Plumb, Birthof consumer But we concentrate society. hereon thegradualismof supplyside approachesin economichistorybecause supplyside changesare vitalin underpinning any changein aggregatedemand. The so-calledconsumer revolutionof these years can only be understoodas part of a dynamicinterplaybetweenchanging consumptionpatternsand the transformation of employmentand production. 7 Characterized by Thompson,Makingof theEnglishworking class, and emphasizedby Foster,Class struggle. Chartism'. 8 StedmanJones,'Rethinking 9 Williams, 'Morals'; Stevenson,Popular disturbances, pp. ii8, I52; Thomis, Luddites,ch. 2. For and Randall, 'Comment';Randall, 'Philosophyof Luddism'. critiquesof thisliteraturesee Charlesworth For a balanced surveyof the debate on the 'moraleconomy',see Stevenson,'Moral economy'. 10The phraseis fromClark,Englishsocietywhichis heavilycriticalof the social historyof the I970S and i98os. For a critiqueof his position,see Innes, 'JonathanClark'. 11 Wrigleyand Schofield,Populationhistory. The argumentis summarizedin Wrigley,'Growthof population'and in Smith,'Fertilityand economy'. 12 See Wiener, English culture;Anderson,'Figures of descent'; Cain and Hopkins, 'Gentlemanly capitalism';Ingham,Capitalismdivided?;Leys, 'Formationof Britishcapital'. For the argumentthatthe landed aristocracy was an eliteclosed to new wealthsee Stone and Stone,Open elite?;Rubinstein,'New men'. 13 Ibid. The term'great arch' is fromCorriganand Sayer, The greatarch althoughthis work itself does not place exclusivestresson continuity. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 26 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON Though currentconsensus stronglyfavourscontinuityand gradualism, contemporariesappear to have had littledoubt about the magnitudeand industrialchange. In i8I4 importanceof changein the period,particularly PatrickColquhoun wrote: in GreatBritain the progressof manufactures It is impossibleto contemplate Its rapidity, withinthe last thirtyyearswithoutwonderand astonishment. war,exceeds of theFrenchrevolutionary sincethecommencement particularly The improvement of steamengines,but aboveall thefacilities all credibility. by to the greatbranchesof the woollenand cottonmanufactories afforded bycapitaland skill,arebeyondall calculation machinery, invigorated ingenious applicableto silk,linen,hosieryand various . . . thesemachinesare rendered otherbranches.14 RobertOwen in i820 identifieda key turningpoint: GreatBritain, in particular, It is wellknownthat,duringthelasthalfcentury increaseditspowersof production, beyondanyothernation,has progressively introduced in scientific and arrangements, improvements by rapidadvancement of productive moreor less, intoall the departments throughout the industry 15 empire. And in i833 Peter Gaskellwroteof the social and politicalrepercussionsof formingan imperiumum economicchange,seeingworking-class organizations in imperio"of the mostobnoxiousdescription'.'6In i85I the OweniteJames Hole wrotethat: havemenbecometo pursue Class standsopposedto class,and so accustomed of thatof others,thatit theirownisolatedinterests apartfromand regardless has becomean acknowledged maxim,thatwhena manpursueshisowninterest every alonehe is mostbenefitting society-amaxim. . . whichwouldjustify crime'and folly.... The principleof supplyand demandhas been extended but less to men.These haveobtainedthereby moreliberty, fromcommodities withthethraldom ofFeudalismtheyhavetaken bread.Theyfindthatin parting in fact.17 has ceasedin namebutsurvived on thatof Capital;thatslavery but it has been obscured Radical change was obvious to contemporaries in particularhas been in recenthistoriography, and industrialperformance traditionalpast. We argue here viewed as an extensionof a pre-industrial The nationalaccounts thatthe industrialrevolutionshouldbe rehabilitated. approach to economic growth and productivitychange is not a good The startingpoint forthe analysisof fundamentaleconomicdiscontinuity. errorsof measurementof growthusing thisapproachis proneto significant estimationwhich arise fromthe restricteddefinitionof economicactivity, fromthe incompletenature of the available data, and fromassumptions embodiedin the analysis.We arguethatgrowthand productivity changein we underestimated. the period are currently But, much more importantly, stressthatgrowthrateson theirown are inadequateto thetaskofidentifying and comprehendingthe industrial revolution. The current orthodoxy 14 15 16 17 Colquhoun, Treatiseon wealth,p. 68. Owen, Reportto thecountyof Lanark, pp. 246-7. populationof England,pp. 6-7. Gaskell,Manufacturing Hole, J., Lectureson social science,quoted in Briggs,Victoriancities,p. I40. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 27 underplayseconomicand social transformation because such developmentis not amenable to studywithinthe frameof referenceof nationalaccounts and aggregatestatistics.We examinefourareas in whichfundamentaland unique change occurred during the industrialrevolution:technical and organizational innovationoutsidethefactory sector,thedeployment offemale and childlabour,regionalspecialization,and demographicdevelopment.For each area we identifyboth problems of underestimationand of the measurementof fundamentalchange. We conclude by consideringthe importanceforsocial and politicalhistoryof our reassessmentof the extent in theseyears. and natureof transformation Unlike the earliernationalaccountsestimatesof Deane and Cole, recent calculationsshow veryslow growthratesbeforethe i83os and particularly in the last fourdecades of the eighteenth century.Explanationsforthisslow growthvaryconsiderablybut the workof Craftshas been the most widely influentialin currentassumptionsabout the industrialrevolution.'8Crafts calculatedthatchangein investment proportionswas verygradualuntilthe early nineteenthcentury and that total factor productivitygrowth in was onlyaround0.2 per cent per annumbetweenI760 and manufacturing i8oi and 0.4 per centbetweeni8oi and i83I. Even totalfactorproductivity growthacross the entire economy, inflatedin Crafts's opinion by the of agriculture, performance grewveryslowly:0.2 per centper annum I760i8oi, 0.7 per cent i80i-3I, reachingi.o per cent onlyin the period I83II86o.19 Severalpointsabout thesegrowthratescould be made. Perhapsthe most importantis that,althoughproductivity growthappearsgradual,it was high enoughto sustaina muchincreasedpopulationwhichunderearliereconomic would have perished.Crafts,however,chooses to emphasize circumstances the poor showingof manufacturing, arguingthat one small and atypical in which accelerated sector,cotton, growth sharply,accountedforas much in It was a modernsector as half of all productivity gains manufacturing. overallimpact. floatingin a sea of tradition,too small to have a significant For mostof industry,he concluded,'not onlywas the triumphof ingenuity slow to come to fruitionbut it does not seem appropriateto regard innovativenessas pervasive'.20 We believe that this opinion rests on two false assumptions.First, it is assumed that the innovativefactorysector functionedindependently of, and owed littleto, changesin the restof the and service economy. Secondly,innovationis assumed to manufacturing 18. Deane and Cole, Britisheconomicgrowth;Crafts,Britisheconomicgrowth;Williamson,'Why was Britisheconomicgrowthso slow?'; McCloskey,'The industrialrevolution'.WhereasCraftsstressesthe Williamson opportunities, oftheeconomybecauseofa shortageofhighreturninvestment lowproductivity arguesthatthe industrialrevolutionwas crowdedout by theeffectofwar debtson civilianaccumulation. For recentdebatebetweenthesetwoviewssee Crafts,'Britisheconomicgrowth';Williamson,'Debating'; Mokyr,'Has theindustrialrevolutionbeen crowdedout?'. See also Williamson,'Englishfactormarkets'; Heim and Morowski,'Interestrates'. 19 Crafts,Britisheconomic growth,pp. 3I, 8i, 84. 20 Ibid., p. 87. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 28 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON ofcapital-intensive plantand equipmentwhich concernonlytheintroduction has an immediatemeasurableimpact on productivity. We returnto these below but first importantpointsabout economicdualism and productivity brieflydeal withmeasurementproblemsof the nationalaccountsapproach toundermine periodwhichalonearesufficient duringtheindustrialrevolution confidencein the currentgradualistorthodoxy. II Industrialoutput and GDP are aggregateestimatesderived from the weightedaverages of theircomponentswhich, as Craftshimselfadmits, of assigning involves 'a classic index numberproblem'.2' The difficulties weightsto industrialand othersectorsof the economy,allowingforchanges in weightsover time and for the effectsof differential price changes and value-addedchangesin thefinalproduct,are insurmountable and willalways involvewide marginsof potentialerror.Errorsin turnbecomemagnifiedin residualcalculationslike thatof productivity growth.22 At the root of problemsconcerningthe compositionof the economyby sector in the national accounting frameworkare the new social and occupationaltablesof Lindertand Williamsonupon whichCraftsand others rely.23These give a higherprofileto the industrialsectorthan the earlier social structureestimatesof King, Massie, and Colquhounand fitwell with But the latitude currentworkon the importanceof proto-industrialization. for potentialerrorin these tables is great. Lindert himselfhas cautioned that for the large occupational groupingsof industry,agriculture,and commerceerrormarginscould be as highas 6o per centwhileestimatesfor shoemakers,carpenters,and othersare 'littlemorethanguesses'.24Lindert and Williamsonrelyon theburialrecordsofadultmalesas theirmainsource of occupationalinformation.Yet women and childrenwere a vital and workforceduringthe proto-industrial growingpillar of the manufacturing of allowingfordual and difficulties and earlyindustrialperiods.The further of with and dealing descriptionslike 'labourer',which tripleoccupations, give no indicationof sector,suggestthatno reliablesectoralbreakdownfor labourinputscan be made. Beforethe 1831 census,and withoutthe benefit of much more research,not only are sectoraldistributionslikely to be erroneous,but they are particularlylikely to underestimatethe role of growingsections of the labour force and of the vitallyimportant,often innovative,overlapsbetweenagrarianand industrialoccupations. Nor are the industrialmacrodataparticularlyrobust. Many of Crafts's derivedfrom estimatesof sectoroutputsand inputsrelyon usingmultipliers a handfulof examplesand only a sample of industriesis used. This omits 21 Ibid., p. I7. 22 Jackson,'Governmentexpenditure';Mokyr, 'Has the industrialrevolutionbeen crowded out?', p. 306. Lindertand Williamson,'RevisingEngland's social tables'; Lindert,'English occupations'. fromrural ruralnon-agricultural Ibid., p. 70I; Wrigleyalso uses theseestimates,and distinguishes of estimatesforagricultural agriculturalpopulation.Note, however,that he emphasizesthe fallibility populationbeforei8oo. See Wrigley,'Urban growthand agriculturalchange',p. i69. 23 24 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 29 increasein the economy: potentially vitalsourcesof outputand productivity for example, food processing,metal wares, distilling,lead, furniture, The coachmaking,and new industrieslike chemicals and engineering.25 of industryas a whole sectorswhichare includedshould be representative but in fact the sample is heavilybiased in favourof finishedratherthan goods. Changein thenatureand uses ofrawand semi-processed intermediate materialinputsprobablyresultsin bias because majorsourcesof innovation in the economyare neglected.26 In attemptingto measure the size and natureof the servicesectorthe encountersa virtuallyimpossibletask. Crafts macro accountingframework in the servicesector is forcedto relyon the assumptionthatproductivity increased no more than in industry.Behind this lies the even more problematicassumptionthatthe servicesectorexpandedat the same rateas in line withwhatlittlewe knowabout populationbeforei8oi and thereafter rents, (central) governmentexpenditure,and the growth of the legal of the servicesectorexcludesdirectevidence profession.Crafts'streatment of what was happeningin transport,financialservices,retailand wholesale trades,professionsotherthanthe law (iinotherwords,whatwas happening to transactions costs), to say nothingof personaland leisureservices.27And furthercontroversysurroundsCrafts's estimatesof agriculturaloutput because he relies on inferencesfromquestionableestimatesof population growth,agriculturalincomes,prices,and incomeelasticities.28 Large areas of economicactivityhave of courseleftno availablesourceof quantitativedata at all. Even in the twentiethcenturynational income accounting,whenused as an indicatorofnationaleconomicactivity,involves but these are magnifiedin earlier major problems of underestimation, applicationsbecause so mucheconomicactivitywas embeddedin unquantifiThe problemsofthenational able and unrecordednon-market relationships.29 for periods of fundamental are further compounded approach accounting economicchangebecause the proportionof totalindustrialand commercial activityshowingup in the estimatesis likelyto changeradicallyover time. If, as seems likely,entrythresholdsin mostindustrieswere low, industrial expansionmighttake place firstand foremostamong a myriadsmall firms is lost to historianswho whichhave leftfewrecordsand whosecontribution confinethemselvesto easily available indices. Finally, price data for the growth,pp. I7-27; Hoppit, 'Counting',p. i82. Crafts,Britisheconomic chs. II, I2; Rowlands, Mastersand men; Hudson, Genesis,ch. 6; Berg, Age of manufactures, Sigsworth,Black DykeMills, ch. I. 27 expenditure'; Hoppit, 'Counting',pp. I82-3; Price,'Whatdo merchantsdo?'; Jackson,'Government idem,'Structureof pay'. 28 Crafts,Britisheconomicgrowth,pp. 38-44; Mokyr, 'Has the industrialrevolutionbeen crowded out?'.,pp. 305-I2; Jackson,'Growthand deceleration';Hoppit, 'Counting',p. i83. Crafts,however,was certainenoughof theseand of his otherestimatesto writein i989 'The dimensionsof economicchange in Britainduringthe IndustrialRevolutionare now reliablymeasured.A numberof features. . . are research';Crafts,'Britishindustrialization likelyto be subjectto onlyminorrevisionas a resultof further context',p. 4i6. in an international pp. 27-36; 29 For discussionsof the problemsof nationalincomeaccountingsee Hawke, Economics, of growth,passim. For discussionof the embeddednessof economicactivitysee Usher, Measurement Polanyi, ed., Trade and market,pp. 239-306; Douglas and Isherwood, World of goods; Beneria, 'Conceptualisingthe labour force'. 25 26 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 30 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON eighteenthcenturyare sparse and highlypartial. This creates a problem because the nationalaccountsframework across requiresprice information the board to calculatevalue added in each sector. These considerations togetherprecludedrawingfirmconclusionsfromthe availableand suggestthatthe bias theycontainis likely estimatescurrently of productionand productivity in the secondary to resultin underestimation and tertiarysectorsof the economy. In thisconnectionit is worthnotingthatCrafts'srecentstatisticalanalysis of industrialoutput series for Britain,Italy, Hungary,Germany,France, Russia, and AustriashowsthatBritainand Hungarywerethe onlycountries to exhibita prolongedperiodof increaseof trendrateofgrowthin industrial In the light of the productionduring the process of industrialization.30 qualitativeevidence of the extentand speed of change in Germanyand Russia in particular,this findingsuggestseitherthat the macro estimates are farfromaccurateand/orthatpayingundue attentionto changesin the trendratesof growthat the nationallevel is not a helpfulstartingpointfor or understanding economictransformation. identifying III in Aggregativestudiesare dogged by an inbuiltproblemof identification posingquestionsabout the existenceof an industrialrevolution.As Mokyr has pointedout in the Englishcase: whichgrewslowlyweremechanising and switching to factories Someindustries likesoapandcandles)whileconstruction (e.g.paperafteri 8oi, woolandchemicals ruledsupreme withfewexceptions and coal miningin whichmanualtechniques untildeepin thenineteenth rates.31 century, grewat respectable Clearlytechnicalprogressis notgrowthand rapidgrowthdoes noteverywhere of productionfunctions.Can we justifyusing imply the revolutionizing manufacturing high aggregateinvestmentratios, high factorproductivity techniques,and theirimmediateinfluenceon the formalGDP indicatorsas In answeringthis our yardstickof industrialinnovationand transformation? question, we need to look more closely at the model of industrialization whichunderpinsmuch currentanalysis. of the industrialrevolutionrelyon an analytical The new interpretations divide between the traditionaland modern sectors: mechanized factory withhighproductivity on theone hand,and a widespreadtraditional industry industrialand servicesectorbackwateron the other. It is argued that the large size of the traditionalsector, combined with primitivetechnology, made it a drag on productivity growthin the economyas a whole.32But it is notclearhowhelpfulthisdivideis in understanding theeconomicstructure 30 This analysisemploysthe Kalman filterto eliminatethe problemof false periodizationand to distinguishbetweentrendchangesand the effectof cyclesof activity.See Crafts,Leybourne,and Mills, 'Britain'; idem,'Trends and cycles'. 31 Mokyr,'Has the industrialrevolution been crowdedout?', p. 3I4. 32 pp. 5-6; Crafts, revolution, growth, ch. 2; Mokyr,Economicsof theindustrial Crafts,Britisheconomic 'Britishindustrialization'. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 3I and earlynineteenth-century England.33In or the dynamismof eighteenthreality,it is impossibleto make clear-cutdivisionsbetweenthe traditional and the modern as there were rarely separate organizationalforms, technologies,locations,or firmsto be ascribedto either.Eighteenth-and cottonmanufacturers, servingdomesticas well as foreign nineteenth-century spinningin factorieswithlargemarkets,typicallycombinedsteam-powered scale employmentof domestichandloomweaversand oftenkept a mix of powered and domestichand weaving long afterthe powered technology becameavailable.This patternwas a functionofriskspreading,theproblems of earlytechnology,and the cheap labour supplyof womenand childrenin Thus fordecades the 'modern'sectorwas actuallybolsteredby, particular.34 and derivedfromthe 'traditional'sector,and not the reverse. Artisans in the metal-workingsectors of Birminghamand Sheffield frequentlycombinedoccupationsor changedthem over theirlife cycle in such a way that they too could be classifiedin both the traditionaland modern sectors.35Artisan woollen workersin West Yorkshireclubbed togetherto build millsforcertainprocessesand thushad a footin both the modernand traditionalcamps. These so-called'companymills'underpinned Thus the traditionaland the modern the success of the artisanstructure.36 were most often inseparable and mutuallyreinforcing.Firms primarily diversified into metal processingventuresas concernedwith metalworking a way of generatingsteadyraw materialsupplies. This and othercases of verticalintegration providemore examplesof the tail of 'tradition'wagging the dog of 'modernity'.37 The non-factory, supposedlystagnantsector,oftenworkingprimarilyfor domesticmarkets,pioneeredextensiveand radicaltechnicaland organizational change not recognizedby the revisionists.The classic textileinnovations were all developed withina rural and artisanindustry;the artisanmetal handprocesses,handtools,and newmalleable tradesdevelopedskill-intensive alloys. The wool textile sector moved to new products which reduced finishingtimes and revolutionizedmarketing.New formsof putting-out, wholesaling,retailing,creditand debt,and artisanco-operationweredevised in the face of the new as ways of retainingthe essentialsof older structures morecompetitiveand innovativeenvironment. Customarypracticesevolved to matchtheneeds ofdynamicand market-orientated production.The result 33 The use of a two-sector of development modelofindustrialchangeis reminiscent traditional/modern economics during the I950s and i96os which looked to a policy of accelerated and large-scale throughpromotionof the modernsectoras a spearheadforthe restof the economy. industrialization of thediverseand dependentlinkagesbetween This divisionwas abandonedin the I970S withrecognition the 'formal'and 'informal'and betweenthe 'traditional'and 'modern'sectors,yetit has gainedrenewed prominencein economichistory.See Moser, 'Informalsector',p. I052; Toye, Dilemmasin development. For fullerdiscussionof parallelideas in developmenteconomics,see Berg, 'Revisionsand revolutions', of the dynamismof the smallfirmsectorsee Sabel and Zeitlin, pp. 5i-6. For a particularinterpretation 'Historicalalternatives',pp. I42-56; also Berg, 'On the origins'. 34 See, forexample, Lyons, 'Lancashirecottonindustry'. 35 Berg, 'Revisions and revolutions',pp. 56, 59; idem,Age of manufactures, chs. II I2; Sabel and Zeitlin, 'Historical alternatives',pp. I46-50; Lyons, 'Vertical integration';Berg, 'Commerce and creativity', pp. I90-5. capital,pp. 70-80; idem,'From manorto mill'. Hudson, Genesisof industrial Wadsworthand Mann, Cottontrade; Hamilton, woollenand worstedindustry; Heaton, Yorkshire of southWales. John,Industrialdevelopment Englishbrassand copperindustries; 36 37 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 32 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON was considerabletransformation even withinthe framework of the so-called traditionalsector. The revisionists arguethatmostindustriallabourwas to be foundin those occupations which experiencedlittle change.38But the food and drink trades,shoemaking,tailoring,blacksmithing, and tradescateringforluxury consumptionsuccessfullyexpanded and adapted to provide the essential urbanserviceson whichtownlife,and hence much of centralizedindustry, was dependent.Furthermore, earlyindustrialcapitalformation and enterprise typicallycombinedactivityin the food and drinkor agricultural processing tradeswithmoreobviouslyindustrialactivities, creatinginnumerable external economies.39This was true in metal manufacturein Birminghamand Sheffieldwhereinnkeepersand victuallerswere commonlymortgageesand In the south Lancashiretool joint ownersof metal workingenterprises.40 tradesPeter Stubs was not untypicalwhen he firstappeared in I788 as a tenantof the WhiteBear Inn in Warrington.Here he combinedthe activity of innkeeper,maltster,and brewerwiththatof filemakerusing the carbon in barm bottoms(barrel dregs) to strengthen the files.41There are many and industry. examplesof thiskind of overlapbetweenservices,agriculture, These were the norm in business practiceat a time when entrepreneurs' to spreadthroughdiversification of portfoliosand where riskswere difficult so much could be gained fromthe externaleconomiescreated by these overlaps. We do not suggesthere thatproductivity growthat the rate experienced in cottontextileswas achievedelsewhere,but thatthe successof cottonand othermajorexportswas intimately relatedto and dependentuponinnovations in otherbranchesof the primary,secondary, and radical transformations and tertiary sectors.Dividingoffthe modernfromthe traditionalsectorsis an analyticaldevice which hides more than it reveals in attemptingto understandthe dynamicsof changein the industrialrevolution. IV More questionablethan theirassumptionof the separatenessand dependence of the traditionalsectoris the revisionists'evaluationof productivity of the changein the economyat this time. Throughoutthe historiography measureshave seldombeen clearlydefined, industrialrevolutionproductivity thelimitations ofmeasureshave rarelybeen explained,and figuresoflimited have been produced and widely accepted on trust. Total meaningfulness factorproductivity (TFP) is the measuremost used by Craftsand others was slow to growin and its use has led themto concludethatproductivity the period. TFP is usuallycalculatedas a residualafterthe rate of growth of factorinputshas been subtractedfromthe rate of growthof GDP. 38 Crafts, p. 69; Wrigley,People,citiesand wealth,pp. I33-57; idem,Continuity, Britisheconomic growth, chanceand change,p. 84. 39 Jones,'Environment'; Burley,'Essex clothier';Chapman,'Industrialcapital'; Mathias,'Agriculture and brewing'. 40 p. i83. Berg, 'Commerceand creativity', pp. 4-5. industrialist, 41 Ashton,Eighteenth century This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 33 There are severalmajor problemswiththe TFP measure.First,TFP as a residualcalculationis heavilyaffectedby any mistakesin the estimation of sectoraloutputsand factorinputs.If the originalsectorweightingswere wrong,TFP estimatesmaybe highlydistorted.Big differences in TFP may also arise fromvariationsin the estimatedgrowthof GDP. Secondly,if factorreallocationfromsectorswith low marginalproductivities to those withhighones was an important featureof theperiod,it will notbe possible to derive reliable economy-widerates of TFP growthsimplyby takinga weightedaverageacross sectors.The effectsof factorreallocationmust be incorporated.42 Thirdly,TFP embodiesa numberof restrictive assumptions rarelyacknowledgedby those who use the measure. These are perfect mobilityof factors,perfectcompetition, neutraltechnicalprogress,constant returnsto scale, and parametricprices.43The eighteenth-century economy did not matchthese assumptions.For example,the assumptionof neutral technicalprogressis suspect in view of the evidenceof long-termlaboursavingtechnicalchange. So too are assumptionsof constantreturnsto scale when set against evidence of increasingreturns;TFP calculationsshould allow forimperfect competitionand changingelasticitiesof productdemand and factorinputs.44Assumptionsof fullemploymentof labour and capital and of perfectmobilityare also inappropriate.Movementof populationwas often not a response to shortagesof labour in industry;indeed many industrialsectors came to be characterizedby flooded labour markets, particularlyfor the less skilled tasks. These were paralleled by massive immobilepools ofagricultural labourin manysouthernand midlandcounties. was endemicand chronicunder-utilization Structuralunemployment of both labour and capitalwas aggravatedby seasonal and cyclicalswings.45 TFP takesno accountofinnovationin thenatureofoutputs Furthermore, or of changein the qualityof inputs,yetwe know thatboth were marked featuresof the period. On the input side, labour needs to be adjusted in TFP calculationsforchangesin age, sex, education,skill, and intensityof work. Output per workeris also affectedby changesin the relativepower of employersto extractwork effortand in the power of employeesto withholdit.46Similarly,materialinputswerechangingconstantly as product innovationaffectedthe natureof raw materialsand intermediate goods as wellas finalproducts.The smallmetaltradeswerea case in point:innovation entailednot poweredmechanizationbut the introductionof niewproducts and the substitutionof cheap alloys forpreciousmetalsas raw material.47 42 Williamson,'Debating', p. 270; Mokyr,'Has theindustrialrevolutionbeen crowdedout?', pp. I2. 305- Link, Technological change,pp. I5-20. Eichengreen,'What have we learned?',pp. 29-30; Link, Technological change,p. I4. For discussion ch. 6; David, of evidenceof labour-savingtechnicalchange,see Rosenberg,Perspectives on technology, Technicalchoice,ch. I; Field, 'Land abundance,interest/profit rates',p. 4I I; Stoneman,Economicanalysis oftechnological change,pp. I 56-67.For evidenceand discussionofincreasingreturns,see David, Technical choice,chs. 2, 6. 45 Eichengreen,'Causes of Britishbusinesscycles'; Allen, Enclosure, ch. I2; Hunt, 'Industrialisation and regionalinequality'. 46 Link, Technological change,p. 24; Eichengreen,'What have we learned?',pp. 29-30; Elbaum and Lazonick, Declineof theBritisheconomy, pp. I-I7; Lazonick, 'Social organisation',p. 74. 47 Berg,Age of manufactures, chs. II, I2; Rowlands,Mastersand men. 43 44 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 34 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON in consumption patternsand habits.48 Productinnovationfuelleda revolution But because the nationalaccountsframeworkmeasuresthe replicationof goods and services,it cannot easily incorporateeitherthe appearance of entirelynew goods not presentat the startof a timeseriesor improvements frustrate overtimein the qualityof goods or services.New productsfurther effortsat productivityestimationbecause the initialprices of new goods wereusuallyveryhighbut declinedrapidlyas innovationproceeded,making the calculationof both weightsand value-addeda majorproblem.49 calculations Finally, the national accounts frameworkand productivity in the means of production cannot measure that qualitativeimprovement whichcan yieldshorterworkinghoursor less arduousor monotonouswork routines.50 Clearly, a broader concept of technologicalchange and of innovationis required than can be accommodatedby national income accounting.If the mostsensibleway to view the courseof economicchange is throughthe timingand impactof innovation,it is arguablethatthe use of nationalaccountinghas frustrated progress.Emphasishas been placed on at theexpenseofscience,economicorganization, savingand capitalformation the knacks skills,dexterity, new productsand processes,marketcreativity, and otheraspectsof economiclifewhich and workpracticesof manufacture, may be innovativebut have no place in the accountingcategories.5' The problemsinvolvedin measuringeconomy-wide productivity growth, and in regardingit as a reflectionof the extentof fundamentaleconomic change,are compoundedwhen one considersthe natureboth of industrial capital and of industriallabour in the period. Redeploymentof labour fromagrarian-basedand domesticsectorsto urban and more centralized manufacturing activitymay well have been accompaniedby diminishing in the shortrun. Green labour had to learn industrial labour productivity skillsas well as new formsof disciplinewhile,withinsectors,labour often shiftedinto processeswhich were more ratherthan less labour-intensive. The same tendencyto low returnsin the shorttermcan be seen in capital in theperiod.Earlysteamenginesand machinery investment wereimperfect and subjectto breakdownsand rapidobsolescence.Grosscapitalinvestment whenfed figures(whichincludefundsspenton renewalsand replacements), into productivity of the importanceand measures,are not a good reflection potentialof technologicalchangein the period. Rapid technologicalchange is capitalhungryas newequipmentsoonbecomesobsolescentand is replaced. Shiftsin the aggregatemeasuresof productivity growthare thus actually less likelyto showup as significant duringperiodsof rapidand fundamental economictransition thanin periodsofslowerand morepiecemealadjustment. This pointwas stressedby Hicks who notedthatthelonggestationperiod of technologicalinnovationmight yield Ricardo's machineryeffect:the returnsfrommajor shiftsin technologywould not be apparentforseveral wouldonlyincreaseunemployment decadesand, in theshortterm,innovation Brewer,McKendrick,and Plumb, Birthof a consumer society;Breen, 'Baubles of Britain'. Usher,Measurement, pp. 8-io. 50 Ibid., p. 9. 51Ibid., p. io. 48 49 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 35 and put downwardpressure on wages.52There was such a disjuncture betweenthe wave of innovationssurrounding the electricdynamoin thelate nineteenthcenturyand an accelerationin the growthof GNP. And the currentcomputerrevolutionwhichis transforming production,services,and workinglives across a broad frontis not accompaniedby rapidlyrising withinnationaleconomies.Resolvingthis income,output,or productivity apparent'productivity paradox' involvesrecognizingthe limitednatureof TFP as a measureof economicperformance and the longtime-frame needed to connect fundamentaltechnologicalchange with productivity growth.53 Thus, just as it is possible to have growthwithlittlechange,it is possible to have radicalchangewithlimitedgrowth.In factthe more revolutionary the changetechnologically, socially,and culturally,the longerthismaytake to workout in termsof conventionalmeasuresof economicperformance. V Anotherstrikingfeatureof the new orthodoxyis its restricteddefinition oftheworkforce; thisin turnhas implicationsfortheanalysisofproductivity change as well as the standard of living debate. Wrigleyassessed key productivitygrowthonly throughthe IO per cent of adult male labour which,in i83I, workedin industriesservingdistantmarkets.Williamson's documentationof inequalityand Lindert and Williamson'ssurveyof the standard of living considered only adult male incomes while Lindert's estimatesforindustrialoccupationsreliedon adult burialrecordswhichare almost exclusivelymale. But the role of women and childrenin both capital and labour intensivemarket-orientated manufacturing (in both the 'traditional'and the 'modern' sectors) probably reached a peak in the industrialrevolution,makingit a unique periodin this respect.54 to quantifythe extentof femaleand child labour It is extremelydifficult as both were largelyexcluded fromofficialstatisticsand even fromwage books. But analyses based only on adult male labour forcesare clearly forthisperiod. On the supplyside the inadequateand peculiarlydistorting labourof womenand childrenwas a vitalpillarof householdincomes,made more so by the populationgrowthand hence the age structureof the later reducedthe proportionof males of eighteenthcenturywhich substantially 52 question, ch. 4. If patentingcan be taken p. I53; Berg,Machinery history, Hicks, Theoryof economic thenwe have some evidencethatgrowthof TFP in nineteenthas a roughindicationof inventiveness, centuryEngland took place some 40 years afterthe accelerationof inventivepatentableactivity.See revolution. theindustrial Sullivan,'England's "age of invention"',p. 444; Macleod, Inventing 53 David, 'The computerand the dynamo'. 54 Wrigley,Continuity, chance and change,pp. 83-7; Williamson,Did Britishcapitalism?,passim; pp. 4-5. In growth, Lindertand Williamson,'Englishworkers'livingstandards';Crafts,Britisheconomic the woollenindustrywomen's and children'slabour accountedfor 75 per cent of the workforce,and child labourexceededthatof womenand of men. Women and childrenalso predominatedin the cotton industry;childrenunder I3 made up 20 per cent of the cottonfactoryworkforcein i8i6; thoseunder female,and i8, 5I.2 per cent. The silk, lace making,and knittingindustrieswere also predominantly suchas theBirmingham ofwomenand childrenin metalmanufactures therewereevenhigherproportions trades. See Randall, BeforetheLuddites,p. 6o; Nardinelli,'Child labour'; Berg, 'Women's work', pp. 70-3; Pinchbeck,Womenworkers, passim; Saito, 'Otherfaces',p. i83; idem,'Labour supplybehaviour', see Cunningham, pp. 636 and 646. For a recentcriticaldiscussionof child labour and unemployment passim. 'Employmentand unemployment', This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 36 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON workingage in the population.55The impactof the high dependencyratio in was cushionedby childrenearningtheirway at an earlyage, particularly On the demand side the need for hand skills, domesticmanufacturing.56 and workdisciplineencouragedthe absorptionof moreand more dexterity, femaleand juvenilelabour into commercialproduction.This was further in wages which may have been increasing encouragedby sex differentials underthe impactof demographicpressurein theseyears.57Employerswere much attractedby low wages and long hours at a time when no attention ofpaymentby resultsor shorterhours.58 was yetpaid to theincentiveeffects Thus factorsboth on the supply and on the demand side of the labour marketresultedin a labour forcestructurewith high proportionsof child and femaleworkers.They were the key elementsin the labour intensity, and low productioncostsfoundin late eighteentheconomicdifferentiation, centuryindustries.And this in turn influencedand was influencedby innovation.New workdisciplines,new formsof subcontracting and puttingout networks,new factoryorganization,and even new technologieswere triedout initiallyon womenand children.59 The peculiar importanceof youthlabour in the industrialrevolutionis in severalinstancesoftextileand othermachinery beingdesigned highlighted The spinningjennywas a celebratedcase; and builtto suitthe childworker. the originalcountryjennyhad a horizontalwheel requiringa posturemost forchildrenaged nineto twelve.Indeed, fora time,in the very comfortable earlyphases of mechanizationand factoryorganizationin the woollen and silkindustriesas well as in cotton,it was generallybelievedthatchildlabour was integralto textilemachine design.60This associationbetween child labour and machinerywas confinedto a fairlybriefperiodof technological United States it appears to have lasted from change. In the north-eastern c. i8I2 until the i83os, duringwhich time the proportionof women and labour forcerose fromIO to 40 per childrenin the entiremanufacturing cent. This was associatedwithnew large-scaletechnologiesand divisionsof labour specifically designedto dispensewithmoreexpensiveand restrictive skilled adult male labour.6' Similarly,the employmentof an increasing proportionof femalelabour in English industrieswas also encouragedby the readyreservesof cheap and skilledfemalelabour whichhad long been a featureof domesticand workshopproduction.In addition,in England, the process of many agriculturalregionsshed femaleworkersfirst--during 55 Childrenaged 5-I4 probablyaccountedforbetween23 and 25 per cent of the totalpopulationin the early nineteenthcentury,comparedwith 6 per cent in I95I. Wrigleyand Schofield,Population history, tab. A3.I, PP. 528-9. 56 Berg,Ageofmanufactures, ch. 6; Medick,'Proto-industrial familyeconomy';Levine,'Industrialisation and the proletarianfamily',p. I77. 57 Saito, 'Other faces', p. i83; idem,'Labour supplybehaviour',p. 634. 58 Hobsbawm, 'Custom, wages and workload',pp. 353, 355. 59 Berg, 'Women's work', pp. 76-88; Pinchbeck,Womenworkers. For modernThird World parallels see Elson and Pearson, 'Nimble fingersand foreigninvestments', pp. 2-3; Pearson, 'Female workers'. 60 Report. . . on thestateof children on the (P.P. i8i6, III), pp. 279, 343; ReportfromtheCommittee bill to regulatethe labourof childrenin the millsand factories(P.P. i83I-2, XV), P. 254. The issue is exploredin greaterdepth in Berg, 'Women's work'. 61 Goldin and Sokoloff, p. 747; Goldin,'Economic statusof 'Women, childrenand industrialization', women'. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 37 agriculturalchange,and much migrationwithinruralareas and fromrural to urban areas consistedof youngwomenin searchof work.62 By mid centuryfemale and child labour was decliningin importance througha mixtureof legislation,the activitiesof male tradeunionists,and pervasiveideologyof the male breadwinnerand of fitand the increasingly proper female activities.63A patriarchalstance was by this time also compatiblewith the economic aims of a broad spectrumof employers. Accordingto Hobsbawm, largerscale employers(as well as male labour) werelearningthe 'rules of the game' in whichhigherpayments(by results), shorterworkinghours,and a negotiatedterrainof commoninterestscould be substitutedforextensivelow-wageexploitationwithbeneficialeffectson productivity. The use of low-costchild and femalelabour was not, of course, new: it had always been vital in the primarysectorand had been integralto the spread of manufacturein the earlymodernperiod. What was new in the periodof the classicindustrialrevolutionwas the extentof its incorporation into rapidly expanding factoryand workshop manufacturingand its of work, and labour associationwith low wages, increasedintensification undoubtedlyhad an impact discipline.65The femaleand juvenileworkforce on the outputfiguresper unit of input costs in manyindustries,but this because some would not necessarilybe reflectedin aggregateproductivity femalelabour was a substituteformale: it increasedat timesand in sectors high.66The social costs wheremale wages werelow or male unemployment in transfer through.poor male labour payments (felt high of underutilized of allowing for male unemploymentin relief)as well as the difficulties sectoralweightingsare likely to offsetgains in the measurableeconomic oftheeconomy indicatorsoftheperiod.The potentialeconomicperformance limitedby the lack of incentiveto substitutecapital as a whole was further forlabourwhenthe labourof womenand childrenwas so abundant,cheap, and disciplinedthroughfamilyworkgroupsand in theabsenceof traditions of solidarity.67 The full effectsof this expandedrole of femaleand juvenilelabour can 62 Pollard,'Labour', p. I33; Bythell,Sweatedtrades;Berg, 'Women's work'; Allen,Enclosure,ch. I2; Snell, Annals, chs. I and 4; Souden, 'East, west-home's best?', p. 307; cf. Williamson,Copingwith citygrowth. ch. 6; Seccombe, 'Emergenceof male breadwinner';Rose, 63 Lown, Womenand industrialization, Harrison,'Class and gender',pp. I22-38, I45; 'Genderantagonism';Davidoffand Hall, Familyfortunes; Roberts,Women'swork. 64 Hobsbawm, 'Custom, wages and workload',p. 36i. 65 families, Levine, 'Industrialisationand the proletarianfamily',pp. I75-9; Levine, Reproducing regionsis economiesof the industrializing pp. II2-5. The low wage characterof the export-orientated pp. 937-45. pp. I3I, I36-4I. See also Hunt, 'Industrialisation', by Lee, TheBritisheconomy, highlighted Mokyr,echoingMarx, suggeststhatlow wagesmayhave been a keyfactorbehindthegrowthof modern hours, industry:'Has the industrialrevolutionbeen crowdedout?', p. 3i8. See also Bienefeld,Working p. 4I. For parallelswiththe Third World see Pearson, 'Female workers'. hypothesis'. 'Relativeproductivity 66 Saito,'Labour supplybehaviour',pp. 645-6;Goldinand Sokoloff, of thissee Mincer,'Labour forceparticipation',and For a standardtheoreticaland empiricaltreatment Greenhalgh,'A labour supply function'.The male occupationalstatisticsupon which productivity estimatesrely,necessarilytake no accountof unemployment. ch. I2; Boyer, 'Old poor law'; Lyons, 67 Lewis, 'Economic development',p. 404; Allen, Enclosure, 'The Lancashirecottonindustry';Berg, 'Women's work'. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 38 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON only be completelyunderstoodat a disaggregatedlevel by analysingits impact upon sectorsand in regionswhere it was cruciallyimportant.A regionalperspectiveis also uniquely valuable in assessingthe extentand natureof economicand social changein the period. VI The industrialrevolutionwas a periodof greatdisparityin regionalrates regionswere of change and economicfortunes.Expandingindustrializing of matchedby regionsof decliningindustry,and chronicunderutilization agriculturewas similarly labour and capital. The storyof commercializing patchy.Slow-moving aggregateindicatorsfailto capturethesedevelopments, and self-reinforcing drivecreatedby the developmentof yetthe interactions industryin markedregionalconcentrations gave rise to major innovations. For example,an increasein the outputof the Britishwool textilesectorby centuryseems verymodest but I50 per cent duringthe entireeighteenth this conceals the dramaticrelocationtakingplace in favourof Yorkshire, whose sharein nationalproductionrose fromaround20 per centto around 6o per cent in the course of the century.If the increasehad been uniform in all regions,it could have been achievedsimplyby the gradualextension commercialmethodsand productionfunctions.But Yorkshire's oftraditional embodieda revolution in organizational intensivegrowthnecessarily patterns, commerciallinks, credit relationships,the sorts of cloths produced, and productiontechniques.The externaleconomiesachievedwhen one region took over more than halfof the productionof an entiresectorwere also of key importance.68 All the expanding industrialregions of the late eighteenthand early nineteenthcenturieswere, like the West Riding, dominatedby particular sectorsin a way neverexperiencedbeforenor to be experiencedagain after the growthof intra-sectoral century. spatialhierarchiesduringthe twentieth sectoralspecializationand regionalintegrity togetherhelp to Furthermore, explain the emergenceof regionallydistinctivesocial and class relations which set a patternin English political life for over a century.These considerationspromptthe view thatregionalstudiesmay be of more value in understanding the processof industrialization thanstudiesof the national economyas a whole.69 The main justification which Craftsuses for employingan aggregative approachto identifythe nature,causes, and corollariesof industrialization in Britainis that the nationaleconomyrepresented,formanyproducts,a well integratednational goods marketby the early nineteenthcentury. Althoughthe spread of fashionableconsumergoods was increasingand nationalmarketsformuchbulk agricultural producewereestablishedbefore the mid eighteenthcentury,it cannotbe shownbeforethe second quarter of the nineteenthcenturythatthe economyhad a 'fairlywell integratedset 68 The argumenthere and throughoutthis sectionis much influencedby Pollard,Peacefulconquest, ch. I. 69 Fuller discussionof this can be found in Hudson, Regions,ch. i. For anotherexample of this of Tyneside. approachsee Levine and Wrightson,The making,on the earliertransformation This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 39 of factormarkets'. 70 The reallyimportant spatialunitforproductionfactors, especiallycapitaland labour,and forinformation flow,commercialcontacts, and credit networksin the pre-railwayperiod was the economic region, which was oftenclearlyidentifiable.7'Constructionof the improvedriver and canal systemson whicheconomicgrowthdependeddid muchto endorse the existenceof regionaleconomies,fora timeincreasingtheirinsularity(in relationto the nationaleconomy).72 Nor werethe railwaysquick to destroy regionallyorientatedtransportsystems.Most companiesfound it in their best intereststo structurefreightrates so as to encouragethe trade of the regionsthey served, to favourshorthauls, and thus to cementregional 73 resourcegroupings. Industrialization accentuatedthe differences betweenregionsby making themmore functionally distinctand specialized.Economicand commercial circumstances werethusincreasingly experiencedregionally and socialprotest movementswiththeirregionalfragmentation can onlybe understoodat that level and in relationto regionalemployment and social structures.Issues of nationalpoliticalreformalso came to be identifiedwithparticularregions, forexamplefactoryreformwithYorkshire,the anti-poorlaw campaignwith Lancashireand Manchester,or currencyreformwithBirmingham.Regional identitywas encouragedby the links createdaround the great provincial cities,by theintra-regional natureofthebulk ofmigration, by theformation ofregionallybased clubs and societies,tradeunions,employers'associations, and newspapers.74 In short, dynamicindustrialregionsgenerateda social and economic interaction whichwould have been absentif theircomponentindustrieshad not been spatiallyconcentratedand specialized.Intensivelocal competition combined with regionalintelligenceand information networkshelped to stimulateregion-wideadvances in industrialtechnologyand commercial organization.And thegrowthof specializedfinancialand mercantileservices withinthe dominantregionsservedto increasethe externaleconomiesand reduced both intra-regional and extra-regional transactionscosts significantly.75 Macroeconomicindicatorsfailto pick up thisregionalspecialization and dynamismwhich was unique to the period and revolutionary in its impact. Crafts,Britisheconomic growth,p. 3. Hunt, 'Industrialisation and regionalinequality';idem,'Wages', pp. 6o-8; Allen,Enclosure,ch. I2; Williamson,'English factormarkets';Clark and Souden, eds., Migrationand society,chs. 7, io. On capital and credit marketssee Hudson, Genesis.See also Pollard, Peaceful conquest,p. 37; Presnell, Countrybanking,pp. 284-343; Anderson,'Attorneyand the early capital market'; Hoppit, Risk and failure,ch. I5. 72 Freeman, 'Transport', p. 86; Langton, 'Industrialrevolutionand regional geography',p. i62; Turnbull,'Canals', pp. 537-60. 73 Freeman,'Transport',p. 92; see also Hawke, Railways. 74 Langtonprovidesa stimulating surveyof the regionalfragmentation of tradeunions,of Chartism and othermovements,and of regionaldifferences in work practicesand work customs,in 'Industrial revolution',pp. I50-5. See also Read, Englishprovinces;and Southall, 'Towards a geography'which concentrates on the artisantrades. 75 See Pollard,Peacefulconquest, pp. I9, 28-9. 70 7I This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 40 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON VII The work of Wrigleyand Schofieldrightlydominatesthe population historyof this period but theiroriginalcausal analysisillustratessome of of aggregativestudiesof economicand social transformation. the difficulties They arguethat,despiteconsiderablegrowthin numbersand the disappeartherewas no significant in ance of major crises of mortality, discontinuity demographicbehaviourin England between the sixteenthand the mid There was no sexual, social, medical,or nutritional nineteenthcenturies.76 revolution.The population regime was and remained marriagedriven: nuptialityand hence fertility throughoutthe three centuriesvaried as a delayed responseto changesin livingstandardsas indicatedby real wage trends.77But the dangerin usingnationaldemographicvariablesto analyse patternsof individualmotivationis that national estimatesmay conflate opposing tendenciesin differentregions,sectors of industry,and social of themainsprings of aggregatedemographic groups.Accurateidentification trendswill onlycome withregional,sectoral,and class breakdownsbecause sortsof workersor social groupswithindifferent different regionalcultures stimulior reacted differently to the same probablyexperienceddifferent economictrends,thus creatinga rangeof demographicregimes.78 The factthatdemographicvariablessuch as illegitimacy ratesand age of marriageexhibitenduringspatialpatternsin the face of changingeconomic fortunesis suggestive.79Parish reconstitution studies indicate that local behaviour did not parallel the movementof the aggregateseries. Such diversitycasts doubt upon the use of the nationalvital rates for causal analysisof demographicbehaviour.The mostimportantcausal variablesin local reconstitution studiesappear to range well outside the movementof real wages. The local economic and social setting,broadlydefined,was crucial. It included such thingsas proletarianization, price movements, and the natureof parishadministration, of economicinsecurity, particularly the poor laws.80 Despite this, a national culturalnorm continuesto be stressed,withthe assumptionthatregionsand localitiestendedtowardsit. The result,as with the macroeconomicwork of Craftsand others,is an excessivepreoccupationwithnationalcomparisons('the French versusthe Englishpattern')and withthe idea thatlowerclasses and backwardregions lag behindtheirsuperiors,but eventuallyfollowthemon the nationalroad to modernityand progress.8' 76 Wrigleyand Schofield,Populationhistory, chs. I0, i i. For summariesof theircausal analysissee Smith,'Fertility,economyand householdformation';Wrigley,'Growthof population'. 77 There has been considerable theanalysis. methodunderlying debateoverthisviewand thestatistical See Gaunt,Levine, and Moodie, 'Populationhistory';Anderson,'Historicaldemography';Mokyr,'Three centuriesof populationchange'; Olney, 'Fertility';Lindert, 'English livingstandards';Lee, 'Inverse projection';idem,'Populationhomeostatis'. 78 See Levine, in Gaunt, Levine, and Moodie, 'Populationhistory',p. I55. 79 See for example, Levine and Wrightson,'Social context of illegitimacy',pp. i6o-i; Wilson, 'Proximatedeterminants'. 80 Wrightsonand Levine, Povertyand piety.For the importanceof the local economic settingsee Levine and Wrightson,The making,ch. 3; Sharpe, 'Literallyspinsters'.For Levine, Familyformation; familyreconstitution resultssee Wrigleyand Schofield,'Englishpopulationhistory'. 81 Seccombe, 'Marxismand demography', p. 35. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 4I and the Recently,the effectsof proto-industrialization, proletarianization, changingcompositionof the workforcehave receivedattentionin relation todemographic change.82This opensthedoorfora moreradicalinterpretation of the structuralcauses of fertility change. The need to look more closely at those structuraland institutional changeswhichresultedin the marked declinein age of marriagein the second halfof the eighteenthcenturyhas been emphasized, as has the importanceof a growinggroup of 'young barriers' in the populationwhose actionsappear unaffected by the general pressureson real wages.83Evidence of radical discontinuity is reappearing at all levels of analysis.84 The influenceoftheWrigley/Schofield approachmayalso haveunjustifiably divertedattentionaway frommortalityand its significant discontinuities. The CambridgeGroup aggregatedata suggestthatrisingfertility was twoand-a-halftimes more importantthan fallingmortalityin producingthe accelerationin population growthin the eighteenthcentury. But the markedincreasein theproportionof thepopulationlivingin townstogether withthe substantialurbanmortality penaltymakesdiachronicstudiesof the national aggregate population particularlylikely to underestimatethe A centralrole for importanceof mortalitychangesin relationto fertility. in urbanlifeexpectancyin fuellingpopulationgrowthduring improvements theindustrialrevolution is perfectly compatiblewithsignificant contemporary shiftsin fertility and even withsuch shiftsbeing apparently moresignificant at the nationallevel.86 ofradicalstructural The significance shiftsin thecompositionand location in mortality of the population,as well as of improvement rates,tendsto be overlookedif causal explanationsbased on aggregatedata are used. This has resultedin the currentliteraturebeing dominatedby discussionof fertility ratherthan of mortality and of continuity ratherthanof discontinuity. VIII The evolutionof social class and of class consciousnesshas long been integral to popular understandingof what was new in the industrial revolution.Growingoccupationalconcentration, loss of proletarianization, independence,exploitation,deskilling,and urbanizationhave been central ofworking-class cultureand consciousness, to mostanalysesoftheformation while the ascendancy of Whig laissez-fairepolitical economy has been as a class.87But recent associatedwiththe new importanceof industrialists families,chs. 2, 3; idem,'Proletarianfamily',pp. i8i-8. See Levine, Reproducing Schofield,'English marriagepatterns'.This studyfindsthat, in the eighteenthcentury,age of and marriagebecame more importantthan variationin celibacyin accountingforchangesin fertility, thatage of marriagewas relativelyunresponsiveto real wage indicesafterI700. On youngmarrierssee Goldstone,'Demographicrevolution'. 84 For a recentexamplesee Jackson,'Populationchangein Somerset-Wiltshire'. 85 Wrigley,'Growthof populationin the eighteenthcentury',pp. I26-33. 86 This pointis made in Kearns, 'Urban penalty';cf. Thompson, Woods, 'Populationredistribution'. The making,pp. 356-66; Perkin,Origins. 87 Prothero,Artisansand politics;Morris, Class and class See, for example, Foster, Class struggle; Seed, 'Unitarianism'. consciousness; 82 83 This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 42 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON economichistoryhas rightlyemphasizedthe complexityof combinedand unevendevelopment.Putting-out, workshops,and sweatingexistedalongside and werecomplementary to a diversefactorysector.It is no longerpossible to speak of a unilinearprocessof deskillingand loss of workplacecontrol. The diversityof organizationalforms of industry,of work experience of compositeand irregularincomes,and accordingto genderand ethnicity, of shiftsof employmentover the lifecycle and throughthe seasons meant that workers'perceptionsof work and of an employingclass were varied and contradictory.88 Nor can one speakofa homogeneousgroupofindustrial betweenthe attitudeand outlook employers.There weremarkeddifferences of small workshopmastersand factoryemployers.And withinthesegroups therewere variationsof responseto competitiveconditionsrangingfrom outrightexploitationto paternalism,withmanymixturesof the two. There fromagentsdown to foremenand was also a wide rangeof intermediaries leaders of familywork groups to deflectoppositionand tension in the workplace.89And we now have a much more sophisticatedunderstanding of the complexinterplayof customaryand marketrelationships. Any simple notionof the latterreplacingthe formeris to be discarded.90In addition, recentwriting,includingpost-structuralist approaches,has questionedany suggestionof deterministic relationshipsbetween socioeconomic position and politicalconsciousness.9' of thiswork,theseinterpretations should not be Despite the significance allowed to edge out all idea thatthe industrialrevolutionperiod witnessed radical shiftsin social relationsand in social consciousness.Much recent social historyhas been based on an unquestioningacceptanceof the new gradualistviewoftheeconomichistoryoftheperiodwhich,we have argued, severelyunderplaysthe extentof radical economicchange and of parallel the mass of the population.Balanced analysesof the developmentsaffecting combinedand uneven natureof developmentwithinindustrialcapitalism should not obscure the fact that the industrialworld of I850 was vastly differentfor most workersfrom that of I750. There were more large workplaces,more poweredmachines,and along withthesetherewas more directmanagerialinvolvementin the organizationand planningof work. A clearernotionof the separationof work and non-worktime was evolving partlyout of thedeclineoffamilyworkunitsand ofproductionin thehome. had acceleratedand the life chances of a much larger Proletarianization proportionof the populationwere determinedby the marketand affected and disease. Capitalistwage labourand theworkingclass by urbanmortality 88 Joyce,'Work'; idem,'Introduction'in idem,Historicalmeanings; Samuel, 'Workshop'; Sabel and Zeitlin,'Historicalalternatives';Reid, 'Politicsand economics';Hobsbawm, 'Marx and history'. 89 Davidoff and Hall, Family fortunes;Behagg, Productionand politics;Rodger, 'Mid Victorian employers';Joyce,'Work'; Huberman,'Economicoriginsof paternalism';Rose, Taylor,and Winstanley, 'Economic origins. . . objections';Huberman,'Reply'. 90 Williams,'Custom'; Bushaway,By rite;Randall, 'Industrialmoral economy'; Berg, ed., Markets and manufacture. Sonenscher,Workin France; 91 StedmanJones,'RethinkingChartism';Sewell, Workand revolution; Foster, 'Declassing of language'; Gray,'Deconstructionof the Englishworkingclass'; idem,'Language chs. I-3; Patterson,'Postof factoryreform';Reddy, Money and liberty;Scott, Genderand history, structuralism'. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 43 but withgreaterspeed thanin earlier and incompletely developedirregularly of similarities of workexperience centuries.And the regionalconcentration to producesocial sufficiently and of the tradecycleadvancedclass formation protestand conflicton an unprecedentedscale, involvingan arrayof anticapitalistcritiques.92 nationally, While the factoryneverdominatedproductionor employment in certainregionsto create widespreadidentitiesof it did so sufficiently interestand political cohesion. And where it did not exist it exercised enormous influencenot only in spawning dispersed production, suband sweating,but also as a majorfeatureof the imageryof the contracting, age. The factoryand the machineas hallmarksof the periodmayhave been mythbut they were symbolicof many other changes attendanton the emergenceof a more competitivemarket environmentand the greater discipliningand alienationoflabour.This symbolprovideda focusofprotest and opposition and was a powerfulelement in the formationof social consciousness.93 Finally,we mustconsiderthe prominencerecentlygivento the economic power and political influenceof the landed aristocracy,rentiers,and merchantsin the nineteenthcentury.94This prominenceis, in part, a of industrialchange and response to the new gradualistinterpretations The division in social and politicallife accumulation. the industrial major of nineteenth-century England is argued to have been that between the dominantgentlemanly capitalismof the aristocraticand rentierclasses and a subordinateindustrialcapitalism.But how valid is this?Is it yetanother which(whilealertingus to thecomplexity aspectofthecurrenthistoriography divertsattentionundulyfromthe impactof changesin of industrialization) industryand industrialpowerin the period? The gentlemanly capitalismthesishas been shownto have overestimated the dominance of rentierand mercantilecapital in elite wealthholding theseparationof interestsand cultures patterns,and to have overemphasized between these groups and industrialists.The thesis also exaggeratesthe and cohesionof gentleman-capitalists on the one hand internalhomogeneity and industrialcapitalistson theother.95BeforeI830, or evenperhapsbefore the economic role of industryand industrialistsshould not be I850, minimized.The dynamismofindustrializing regions,thepatternand finance of theiroverseastrading,theirpowerin politicallobbying,and changesin theirlocal governmentsuggestotherwise.The metropolitan economymay well have become the major locus of servicesectorgrowthand of wealth accumulationby the thirdquarterof the nineteenthcentury,but in the 92 Randall,'Industrialmoraleconomy';idem,'Philosophyof Luddism'; Behagg,'Democracyofwork'; Gray, 'Languages of factoryreform'; Hilton, Age of atonement.For similar views among small Kirk, 'Defence Behagg, Politicsand production; see Davidoffand Hall, Familyfortunes; manufacturers of class'; Foster, 'Declassing of language'. 93 Berg,Machinery Randall, question;idem,'Progressand providence';Behagg,Politicsand production; 'Industrialmoral economy';idem,'New languages'. 94 This interpretation is seen in varyingformsin thefollowingworks:Cain and Hopkins,'Gentlemanly capitalism';Anderson,'Figures of descent'; Wiener,Englishculture;Ingham,Capitalismdivided. 95 Daunton, 'Gentlemanlycapitalism';Gunn, 'Failure of middle class'; BarrattBrown, 'Away with greatarches'. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 44 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON industrialrevolutionperiod itselfit is more likelythat regionalindustrial revolutionsdictatedthecourseof structural changeand colonialexpansion.96 In short,althoughindustrialtransformation gave rise to a complicated mass of differing experiencesand social relations,manyinnovationsin the organizationand use of labour if not in technologywere commonto all industries and sectors. Furthermore,changes in markets and in the competitiveclimatehad an impacton all English capitalistswhetherthey were metropolitanor provincialand whetherfinanciers,farmers,small masters,factoryemployers,or involvedin the servicesector. Ix The industrialrevolutionwas an economicand socialprocesswhichadded up to much morethanthe sum of its measurableparts.The periodsaw the sectoralspecializationof regionsand the growthof regionallyintegrated an industrialand social economiessome of whichwere clearlyexperiencing revolution,no matterhow thistermis defined,whileothersdeindustrialized. The movementof aggregatequantitativeindicatorsignores this and, as presentlycalculated,failsto give an accurateaccountof the structuralshift in the natureand deploymentof theworkforce because the calculationsrely on adult male labour. The natureof innovationand of industrialand social transformation is also currently and underestimated. Landes misrepresented of discontinuities has warnedof maskingthe significance by concentrating on the absence of shiftsin quantitativeindicators:to him these were the thevirtue historians''butterfly underglass or frogin formaldehyde-without of wholenessto compensatefortheirlifelessness': of . . . societyand eventhenin termsthat numbers describethesurface merely of unchanging nomenclature. Beneath defineawaychangeby usingcategories and... itwastheythatdetermined thissurface, thevitalorgansweretransformed themetabolism oftheentiresystem.97 It is timeto moveon fromthemacroaccountingframework and to rebuild the nationalpictureof economicand social change fromnew researchat regionaland local level. We need to adopt a broaderconceptof innovation, to insiston a greaterawarenessof femaleand childlabour,and to recognize thatthe economic,social, and culturalfoundationsof an industrialcapitalist order rest on much more than conventionalmeasures of industrialor If thisis done it shouldnotbe longbeforethenotion economicperformance. of an industrialrevolution,occurringin Englandin the late eighteenthand earlynineteenthcenturies,is fullyrehabilitated. University of Warwick University of Liverpool 96 Porter,'Capitalismand empire'; Allen, Enclosure, ch. I2; Hudson, Regions,ch. I; Saville, 'Notes on PerryAnderson';BarrattBrown,'Away withgreatarches'. 97 Landes, UnboundPrometheus, p. I22. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 45 Footnote references Officialpublications Report. . . on thestateof children. . .in manufactories (P.P. i8i6, III). on thebill to regulatethelabourof children ReportfromtheCommittee in themillsandfactories (P.P. i83I- 2, XV). Secondary sources Allen, R. A. C., Enclosureand theyeoman(Oxford,forthcoming). Anderson,B., 'The attorneyand the earlycapital marketin Lancashire',in F. Crouzet, ed., Capital in theindustrial formation revolution (1972), pp. 223-55. Anderson,M., 'Historicaldemographyafterthe populationhistoryof England',J. Interdisc.Hist., I5 (i985), pp. 595-607. Anderson,P., 'The figuresof descent',New LeftRev., i6i (i987), pp. 20-78. Ashton,T. S., An eighteenth-century industrialist: PeterStubsofWarrington, I756-i806 (Manchester,I939). BarrattBrown,M., 'Away withall the greatarches:Anderson'shistoryof Britishcapitalism',New Left Rev., i67 (i988), pp. 22-5I. Behagg, C., 'The democracyof work, i820-i850', in J. Rule, ed., Britishtradeunionism,1750-i850 (i988), pp. i62-7. Behagg, C., Politicsand production in nineteenth century England(i990). Beneria,L., 'Conceptualisingthe labour force:the underestimation of women'seconomicactivities',in R. Pahl, ed., On work(Oxford,i988), pp. 372-9I. Berg, M., The machinery questionand themakingofpoliticaleconomy, 18i5-1848 (Cambridge,ig80). Berg, M., The age of manufactures: industry, innovation and workin BritainI700-i820 (London, i985). Berg, M., 'Women's work, mechanisationand the early phases of industrialisation in England', in P. Joyce,ed., The historical meanings of work(Cambridge,i987), pp. 64-98. Berg,M., 'Progressand providencein earlynineteenth-century politicaleconomy',Soc. Hist., I5 (990), pp. 365-75. Berg,M., 'Revisionsand revolutions:technologyand productivity in eighteenthchangein manufacture and innovation centuryEngland', in J. A. Davis and P. Mathias,eds., Technology fromtheeighteenth to thepresentday (Oxford,I991), pp. 43-65. century Berg, M., 'Commerceand creativityin eighteenth-century Birmingham',in idem,ed., Marketsand in earlyindustrial manufacture Europe(London, I991), pp. I73-205. Berg, M., 'On the originsof capitalisthierarchy',in B. Gustafsson,ed., Power and economic institutions I991), (Aldershot, pp. I73-95. Bienefeld,M. A., Working hoursin Britishindustry: an economic history (1972). Boyer, G., 'The old poor law and the agriculturallabour marketin southernEngland: an empirical analysis',J. Econ. Hist., XLVI (I986), pp.-I 3-36. Breen, T., "'Baubles of Britain":the Americanand consumerrevolutionsof the eighteenthcentury', P. & P., II9 (i988), pp. 73-Io5. Brewer,J., McKendrick,N., and Plumb, J. H., The birthof a consumer society:thecommercialisation of eighteenth century England(i982). Briggs,A., Victoriancities(i963). Bruland, K., 'Industrialconflictas a source of technicalinnovation:threecases', Econ. & Soc., XI (i982), pp. 9I-II2. and Europeanindustrialization Bruland,K., Britishtechnology (Cambridge,i989). Burley,K. H., 'An Essex clothierof the eighteenthcentury',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XI (1958), pp. 289-30I. Bushaway,R., By rite:custom,ceremony and community in England,I700-i880 (i982). Bythell,D., The handloomweavers(Cambridge,i967). Bythell,D., The sweatedtrades(I978). Cain, P. J. and Hopkins, A. G., 'Gentlemanlycapitalismand Britishoverseasexpansion,I: The old colonialsystem,I688-I850', Econ. Hist.Rev., 2nd ser.,XXXIX (I986), pp. 50I-25; 'II: New imperialism, i850-I945', Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XL (i987), pp. I-26. Cannadine,D., 'The past and the presentin the English industrialrevolution,i880-i980', P. & P., I03 (I984), pp. I49-58. Chapman,S., 'Industrialcapitalbeforetheindustrialrevolution,I730-I750', in N. Harteand K. Ponting, and economic eds., Textilehistory history (Manchester,I973), pp. II3-37. A. and Randall, A. J., 'Comment:morals,marketsand the Englishcrowd',P. & P., II4 Charlesworth, (i987), pp. 200-I3. Clapham,J. H., An economichistory of modern Britain,3 vols. (Cambridge,I926-38). social structure and politicalpracticeduringtheancien Clark, J.C.D., Englishsociety,I788-I832: ideology, regime(Cambridge,i987). Clark, P., 'Migrationin England during the late I7th and early i8th centuries',in P. Clark and D. Souden, eds., Migrationand societyin earlymodern England(i989), pp. 2I3-53. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 46 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON England(i989). Clark, P. and Souden, D., eds., Migrationand societyin earlymodern on thewealth,powerand resources oftheBritishempire(i8I4; secondedn, i8I5). Colquhoun,P., A treatise as culturalrevolution (Oxford,i985). Corrigan,P. and Sayer,P., The greatarch:Englishstateformation revolution (Oxford,i985). growthduringtheindustrial Crafts,N. F. R., Britisheconomic of interpretation', Exp. Econ. Crafts,N. F. R., 'Britisheconomicgrowth,I700-i850: some difficulties Hist., 24 (i987), pp. 245-68. in an international context',J. Interdisc.Hist., XIX (i989), Crafts,N. F. R., 'Britishindustrialisation pp. 4I5-28. Crafts,N. F. R., Leybourne,S. J., and Mills, T. C., 'Trendsand cyclesin Britishindustrialproduction, I700-I9I3', J.R.S.S., I52 (i989), pp. 43-60. Crafts,N. F. R., Leybourne,S. J., and Mills, T. C., 'Britain',in R. Syllaand G. Toniolo, eds., Patterns in nineteenth-century Europe(forthcoming). of industrialization of childrenin England,c. i680-i85I', P. & P., and unemployment Cunningham,H., 'The employment I26 (i990), pp. II5-50. Daunton, M., 'Gentlemanlycapitalismand Britishindustry,i820-I9I4', P. & P., I22 (i989), pp. Ii959. paradox in a not-too-distant David, P. A., 'The computerand the dynamo.The modernproductivity mirror',WarwickEconomic ResearchPapers, 339 (i989). and economic growth(Cambridge,I975). David, P. A., Technicalchoice,innovation menand womenof theEnglishmiddleclass,I780-I850 (i987). Davidoff,L. and Hall, C., Familyfortunes: growth,I688-I959 (Cambridge,2nd edn. i969). Deane, P. and Cole, W. A., Britisheconomic (Harmondsof consumption Douglas, M. and Isherwood,B., The worldofgoods:towardsan anthropology worth,ig80). Eichengreen,B., 'The causes of Britishbusiness cycles, I833-I9I3', J. Eur. Econ. Hist., I2 (i983), pp. I45-63. in Eichengreen,B., 'What have we learnedfromhistoricalcomparisonsof incomeand productivity?', 1750-1939, Ninth andproblems ofmeasurement, productivity comparisons P.K. O'Brien, ed., International Congressof the Int. Econ. Hist. Assoc. (Berne, i986), pp. 26-36. perspectiveon Britishdecline',in idem,eds., Thedecline Elbaum, R. and Lazonick, W., 'An institutional (Oxford,i986), pp. I-I7. of theBritisheconomy in idem,eds., Women'semployment Elson, D. and Pearson,R., 'Nimble fingersand foreigninvestments', in Europe(i989), pp. I-I2. and multinationals in GreatBritain',in P. Mathiasand M. M. Postan,eds., Cambridge Feinstein,C. H., 'Capital formation economichistory of Europe,7, Pt. I (Cambridge,I978), pp. 28-96. American and British rates and nineteenth-century Field, A. J., 'Land abundance, interest/profit technology', J. Econ. Hist., XLIII (i983), pp. 405-3I. and the industrialrevolution: earlyindustrialcapitalismin threeEnglishtowns Foster, J., Class struggle ( I 977). Foster, J., 'The declassingof language',New LeftRev., I50 (i985), pp. 29-47. Britain,I780-I9I4 Freeman,M., 'Transport',in J. Langtonand R. Morris,eds., Atlas of industrialising (i986), pp. 60-9. Freudenberger,H., Mather,K. J., and Nardinelli,C., 'A new look at the earlyfactorylabour force', J. Econ. Hist., XLIV (i984), pp. io85-90. Gaunt, D., Levine, D., and Moodie, E., 'The populationhistoryof England, I54I-i87I: a review symposium',Soc. Hist., 8 (i983), pp. I39-68. (Harmondsworth, George,D., Englandin transition I930). Goldin, C., 'The economic status of women in the early republic: some quantitativeevidence',J. Interdisc.Hist., i6 (i986), pp. 375-405. in the early republic: evidence Goldin, C. and Sokoloff,K., 'Women, childrenand industrialisation fromthe manufacturing censuses',J. Econ. Hist., XLII (i982), pp. 72I-74. the American hypothesisand industrialisation: Goldin, C. and Sokoloff,K., 'The relativeproductivity case, I820-I850', Qu. J. Econ., XCIX(i984), pp. 46I-87. Goldstone,J. A., 'The demographicrevolutionin England: a re-evaluation',Pop. Stud., XLI (i986), PP. 5-33. of the Englishworkingclass', Soc. Hist., ii (i986), pp. 363-73. Gray,R., 'The deconstruction Gray, R., 'The languagesof factoryreformin Britain,c. I830-I860', in P. Joyce,ed., The historical meanings of work(Cambridge,i987), pp. I43-79. Greenhalgh,C., 'A laboursupplyfunctionformarriedwomenin GreatBritain',Economica,XLIV (I977), pp. 249-65. Gunn, S., 'The "failure"of the Victorianmiddle class: a critique',in J. Wolffand J. Seed, eds., The cultureof capital: art,powerand thenineteenth century middleclass (Manchester,I989), pp. I7-44. to i8oo (I926). Hamilton,H., The Englishbrassand copperindustries beforeI84I: evidenceof slowergrowthduringthe industrial Harley, C. K., 'Britishindustrialisation revolution',J. Econ. Hist., XLII (I982), pp. 267-89. This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 47 Harrison,B., 'Class and genderin modernBritishlabour history',P. & P., I24 (i989), pp. I2I-59. Hauseman, W. J. and Watts, J. M., 'Structuralchange in the eighteenthcenturyBritisheconomy:a testusing cubic splines',Exp. Econ. Hist., I7 (ig80), pp. 400-Io. (Cambridge,1980). Hawke, G. R., Economicsforhistorians Heaton, H., 'Industrialrevolution',Encyclopediaof thesocial sciences,VIII 0932), pp. 3-I2. (Oxford,2nd edn. i965). woollenand worstedindustry Heaton, H., The Yorkshire Heim, C. E. and Morowski,P., 'Interestratesand crowdingout duringBritain'sindustrialrevolution', J. Econ. .list., XLVII (I987), pp. II7-39. history (Oxford,i969). Hicks, J.R., A theory of economic thought, on socialand economic I785-i865 theinfluence of evangelicalism Hilton, B., The age of atonement: (Cambridge,i988). oflabour Hobsbawm,E. J., 'Custom,wages,and workload',in idem,Labouringmen:studiesin thehistory (I964), pp. 344-70. and empire(i968). Hobsbawm, E. J., Industry Hobsbawm, E. J., 'Marx and history',New LeftRev., I43 (i984), pp. 37-50. Hoppit, J., 'Understandingthe industrialrevolution',Hist.J., 30 (I987), pp. 2II-24. Hoppit, J., Risk and failurein Englishbusiness,I700-I800 (Cambridge,i987). Hoppit, J., 'Countingthe industrialrevolution',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XLIII (I990), pp. I73-93. (Oxford,i984). Howe, A., The cottonmasters Huberman,M., 'The economicoriginsof paternalism:Lancashirecottonspinningin the firsthalf of the nineteenthcentury',Soc. Hist., I2 (i987), pp. I77-92. Huberman,M., 'The economicoriginsof paternalism:replyto Rose, Taylorand Winstanley',Soc. Hist., I4 (i989), pp. 99-I04. Hudson, P., 'From manor to mill: the West Riding in transition',in M. Berg, P. Hudson, and M. beforethefactory(Cambridge,i983), pp. I24-46. in townand country Sonenscher,eds., Manufacture c. I750-I850 capital:a studyof theWestRidingwooltextileindustry, Hudson, P., The genesisof industrial (Cambridge,i986). (Cambridge,I990). Hudson, P., ed., Regionsand industries and regionalinequality:wages in Britain,I760-I9I4', j. Econ. Hist., Hunt, E. H., 'Industrialisation XLVI (i986), pp. 935-66. Britain,I780-I9I4 Hunt, E. H., 'Wages', in J. Langton and R. Morris, eds., Atlas of industrialising (i986), pp. 6o-8. in Britishsocial development (i984). Ingham,G., Capitalismdivided?:thecityand industry Innes, J., 'JonathanClark,social historyand England's"ancienregime"', P. & P., II5 (i987), pp. i6520I. Jackson,R.V., 'Growthand decelerationin Englishagriculture,I660-I790', Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., xxxviii (i985), pp. 333-5I. Britain',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XLI Jackson,R. V., 'The structureof pay in nineteenth-century (i988), pp. 56I-70. century:some expenditureand Britisheconomicgrowthin the eighteenth Jackson,R. V., 'Government problemsof measurement',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XLIII (I990), pp. 2I7-35. borderareas,I70I-I800: a regionaldemographic Jackson,S., 'Populationchangein theSomerset-Wiltshire study',SouthernHist., 7 (i985), pp. II9-44. development of southWales, I750-I850 (I950). John,A. H., The industrial Agric.Hist., LI (I977), pp. 49I-502. Jones,E. L., 'Environment,agricultureand industrialisation', England(Brighton,ig80). Joyce,P., Work,societyand politics:thecultureof thefactoryin late Victorian meanings of work(Cambridge,i987). Joyce,P., ed., The historical 3 vols. (Cambridge, I990), II, of Britain, I750-I950, Joyce,P., 'Work', in Cambridgesocial history pp. I3I-94. Kearns, G., 'The urban penaltyand the populationhistoryof England', in A. Brandstromand L. transition (Stockholm,i988), Tedebrand, eds., Society,healthand populationduringthedemographic pp. 2I3-36. in GreatBritainduringthenineteenth and commercial revolutions century Knowles, L. C. A., The industrial (I92I). (Cambridge,i969). Landes, D. S., The unboundPrometheus Langton,J., 'The industrialrevolutionand the regionalgeographyof England', Trans.Inst.Brit. Geog., 9 (I984), pp. I45-67. and productivity growthin Britainand theU.S., I820-I9I3', in P. K. Lazonick,W., 'Social organisation and problemsof measurement, I750-I939, Ninth productivity comparisons O'Brien, ed., International Congressof the Int. Econ. Hist. Assoc. (Berne, i986), pp. 66-75. Lee, C., 'The servicesector,regionalspecialisationand economicgrowthin the Victorianeconomy',J. Hist. Geog., IO (I984), pp. I39-55. sinceI700: a macroeconomic perspective (Cambridge,I987). Lee, C., The Britisheconomy This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 48 MAXINE BERG and PAT HUDSON Lee, R. D., 'Inverse projectionand back projection:a criticalappraisal and comparativeresultsfor England, I539-I87I', Pop. Stud., 39 (I985), pp. 233-48. Lee, R. D., 'Populationhomeostasisand English demographichistory',J. Interdisc.Hist., xv (I985), pp. 635-60. Levine, D., 'Industrialisation and the proletarianfamilyin England', P. & P., I07 (I985), pp. i68203. (Cambridge,I987). of Englishpopulationhistory Levine, D., Reproducing families:thepoliticaleconomy Levine, D. and Wrightson,K., 'The social contextof illegitimacyin early modernEngland', in P. history Laslett, K. Oosterveen,and R. M. Smith,eds., Bastardyand itscomparative (ig80), pp. I5875. society:Whickham, Levine, D. and Wrightson,K., The makingofan industrial I56o-I765 (Oxford,i99i). Leys, C., 'The formationof Britishcapital',New LeftRev., i6o (i986), pp. II4-20. Lindert,P. H., 'English occupations,I670-I8II',J. Econ. Hist., XL (I980), pp. 685-7I2. Lindert,P. H., 'English livingstandards,populationgrowthand Wrigleyand Schofield',Exp. Econ. Hist., 20 (I983), pp. 385-408. Lindert,P. H. and Williamson,J. G., 'RevisingEngland's social tables', Exp. Econ. Hist., I9 (I982), PP. 385-408. Lindert,P. H. and Williamson,J. G., 'Englishworkers'livingstandardsduringtheindustrialrevolution: a new look', Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd-ser.,XXXVI(1983), pp. I-25. changeand productivity growth(1987). Link, A. N., Technological England(Cambridge,i9g90). genderat workin nineteenth century Lown, J., Womenand industrialization: of thepowerloom, I8I5-50' (unpub. Lyons, J. S., 'The Lancashirecottonindustryand theintroduction Ph.D. thesis,Univ. of California,Berkeley,I977). in the Britishcottonindustry,I825-I850: a revision',J. Econ. Hist., Lyons, J. S., 'Verticalintegration XLV (1985), pp. 4I9-25. McCloskey,D. N., 'The industrialrevolution:a survey',in R. C. Floud and D. N. McCloskey,eds., The economichistory ofBritainsinceI700, I, I760-i860 (Cambridge,I981), pp. I03-27. revolution (Cambridge,i988). Macleod, C., Inventingtheindustrial revolution an outlineof thebeginnings of themodern in theeighteenth Mantoux,P., The industrial century: in England(I928). factory system Mathias, P., 'Agricultureand the brewingand distillingindustriesin the eighteenthcentury',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., v (1952), pp. 249-57. eds., Essaysin social familyeconomy',in P. Thane and A. Sutcliffe, Medick, H., 'The proto-industrial 2 (Oxford,i986), pp. 23-53. history, Mokyr,J., 'Three centuriesof populationchange',Econ. Dev. & Cult. Change,32 (I983), pp. I83-92. revolution of theindustrial (Totawa, N.J., I985). Mokyr,J., ed., The economics on Craftsand Williamson', Mokyr,J., 'Has theindustrialrevolutionbeen crowdedout? Some reflections Exp. Econ. Hist., 24 (1987), pp. 293-3I9. and economic (Oxford,i9g90). creativity progress Mokyr,J., The leverof riches:technological in theindustrial revolution (I979). Morris,R. J., Class and class consciousness Moser, C., 'Informal sector or petty commodityproduction: dualism or dependence in urban i6 (I978), pp. I04I-75. development?',WorldDevelopment, Nardinelli,C., 'Child labour and the factoryacts',J. Econ. Hist., XL (I980); pp. 739-55. Nardinelli,C., 'Were childrenexploitedduringthe industrialrevolution?',Res. Econ. Hist., ii (i988), pp. 243-76. revolution (Bloomington,i9g90). Nardinelli,C., Child labourand theindustrial (1978). O'Brien, P. K. and Keyder,C., Economicgrowthin Britainand France, I780-I9I4 of Wrigley Olney,M. L., 'Fertilityand the standardof livingin earlymodernEngland:in consideration and Schofield',J. Econ. Hist., XLIII (1983), pp. 7I-8. and otherwritings Owen, R., Reportto thecountyofLanark (I820) in idem,A newviewof society (I927), pp. 245-98. post-modernism: implicationsforhistorians',Soc. Hist., I4 (1989), Patterson,T. C., 'Post-structuralism, pp. 83-8. Pearson,R., 'Female workersin the Firstand Third Worlds:the greeningof women'slabour', in R. E. Pahl, ed., On work(Oxford,i988), pp. 449-69. and theindustrial revolution, I750-I850 Pinchbeck,I., Womenworkers (1930; new edn. i98i). in Polanyi, K., Arensberg,C., and Pearson, H., eds., Trade and marketin theearlyempires:economics and theory history (New York, I957). economic Pollard,S., 'Labour in the Britisheconomy',in P. Mathiasand M. M. Postan,eds., Cambridge history of Europe,VII, pt. 2 (Cambridge,I978), pp. 97-I79. of Europe,I760-1970 (Oxford,I98I). Pollard, S., Peacefulconquest:theindustrialisation revolution (Oxford,I956). Presnell,L. S., Countrybankingin theindustrial London:JohnGast and his times(1979). century Prothero,I., Artisansand politicsin earlynineteenth This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions REHABILITATING THE INDUSTRIAL REVOLUTION 49 Randall,A. J., 'The philosophyof Luddism: thecase ofthewestofEnglandwoollenworkers',Technology & Culture,27 (i986), pp. I-I7. weaversin theeighteenth century', Randall,A. J., 'The industrialmoraleconomyof the Gloucestershire tradeunionism, I750-I850 (I988), pp. 24-5I. in J. Rule, ed., British Randall, A. J., 'New languagesor old? Labour, capitaland discoursein the industrialrevolution',Soc. Hist., I5 (I990), pp. I95-2i6. in theEnglishwoollenindustry, I776and machinery Randall,A. J.,BeforetheLuddites:custom,community I809 (Cambridge,i99i). (i964). Read, D., The Englishprovinces,I760-i960: a studyin influence understanding (Cambridge, Reddy, W. M., Moneyand libertyin modernEurope: a critiqueof historical I987). of England(1931). Redford,A., The economichistory Reid, A., 'Politics and economicsin the formationof the Britishworkingclass: a responseto H. F. Moorhouse',Soc. Hist., 3 (I978), pp. 347-6i. Roberts,E., Women'swork,i840-i940 (I988). Rodger,R., 'Mid Victorianemployers'attitudes',Soc. Hist., II (i986), pp. 77-80. Rose, M., Taylor, P., and Winstanley,M.J., 'The economicoriginsof paternalism:some objections', Soc. Hist., I4 (I989), pp. 89-99. Rose, S., 'Gender antagonismand class conflict:exclusionarystrategiesof male trade unionistsin nineteenthcenturyBritain',Soc. Hist., I3 (I988), pp. I9I-208. on technology (Cambridge,I976). Rosenberg,N., Perspectives growth(Cambridge,i960). Rostow,W. W., The stagesof economic Rowlands, M., Mastersand men in the west midlandsmetalwaretradesbeforethe industrialrevolution (Manchester,I975). Rubinstein,W. D., 'New men of wealth and the purchase of land in nineteenthcenturyEngland', P. & P., 92 (I98I), pp. I25-47. to mass production',P. & P., I08 (I985), pp. I33-76. alternatives Sabel, C. and Zeitlin,J.,'Historical Saito, O., 'Labour supply behaviourof the poor in the.English industrialrevolution',J. Eur. Econ. Hist., I0 (i98i), pp. 633-52. Saito, O., 'The otherfacesof the industrialrevolution:a reviewessay', Keizai Kenkyu,39 (I988), pp. I80-4. 3 (I977), pp. 6-72. Samuel, R., 'The workshopof the world',Hist. Workshop, Saville,J., 'Some noteson PerryAnderson's"Figuresof descent"', in C. Barberand D. Nichols, eds., debate(Manchester,i988), pp. 34-45. The development ofBritishcapitalistsociety:a marxist Schofield,R. S., 'Englishmarriagepatternsrevisited',J. Fam. Hist., I0 (I985), pp. 2-20. Seccombe,W., 'Marxismand demography',New LeftRev., I37 (I983), pp. 22-47. of themale breadwinner stabilised:theconstruction wage normin nineteenthSeccombe,W., 'Patriarchy centuryBritain',Soc. Hist., II (i986), pp. 53-76. I830Seed, J., 'Unitarianism,politicaleconomyand the antinomiesof liberal culturein Manchester% 50', Soc. Hist., 7 (I982), pp. I-25. in France: thelanguageoflabourfromtheold regime to i848 (Cambridge, Sewell,W., Workand revolution I980). of local economyand demographyin Colytonin Sharpe, P., 'Literallyspinsters:a new interpretation the seventeenthand eighteenthcenturies',Econ. Hist. Rev., XLIV (I99I), pp. 46-65. withintroductory on thedevelopment of theworsted chapters Sigsworth,E. M., Black Dyke Mills: a history in thenineteenth industry century (Liverpool, I958). Smith,R. M., 'Fertility,economyand householdformationin England over threecenturies',Pop. & Dev. Rev., 7 (1981), pp. 595-622. poor:socialchangeand agrarianEngland,i66o-i900 (Cambridge, Snell, K. D. M., Annalsofthelabouring I985). Frenchtrades(Cambridge, Sonenscher,M., Workand wages:naturallaw, politicsand theeighteenth-century I989). Souden, D., 'East, west-home's best? Regionalpatternsin migrationin earlymodernEngland', in P. Clark and D. Souden, eds., Migrationin earlymodern England(I989), pp. 292-333. of early Southall,H., 'Towards a geographyof unionisation:the spatial organisationand distribution Britishtrade unions', Trans.Inst. Brit. Geog., I3 (I988), pp. 466-83. StedmanJones,G., 'RethinkingChartism',in idem,Languagesof class: studiesin Englishworkingclass history, I832-I982 (Cambridge,I983), pp. 90-I78. in England,I700-I870 (I979). Stevenson,J., Popular disturbances Stevenson,J., 'The "moraleconomy"of the Englishcrowd',in A. Fletcherand J.Stevenson,eds., Order in earlymodern and disorder England(Cambridge,I985), pp. 2I8-38. Stone, L. and Stone, J. F. C., An openelite?England,I540-I880 (Oxford,I984). change(Oxford,I983). Stoneman,P., The economic analysisof technological This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions MAXINE 50 BERG and PAT HUDSON Sullivan,R., 'England's "age of invention":the accelerationof patentsand patentableinventionsduring the industrialrevolution',Exp. Econ. Hist., 26 (i989), pp. 424-47. Thomis, M. I., The Luddites(Newton Abbot, I970). class (Harmondsworth, i968). Thompson,E. P., The makingof theEnglishworking in development on thecounterrevolution reflections theoryand policy Toye, J., Dilemmasin development: (Oxford,I987). Turnbull,G., 'Canals, coal and regionalgrowthduringthe industrialrevolution',Econ. Hist. Rev., 2nd ser., XL (I987), pp. 537-60. of economic growth(Oxford,ig80). Usher, D., The measurement tradeand industrial Lancashire,i6oo-I780 (Manchester, Wadsworth,A. P. and Mann, J. de L., Thecotton I931) spirit,i850-I980 (Cambridge,i98i). Wiener,M. J., Englishcultureand thedeclineof theindustrial Williams,D. E., 'Morals, marketsand the Englishcrowd',P. & P., I04 (I984), pp. 56-74. Williamson,J. G., 'Why was Britisheconomicgrowthso slow duringthe industrialrevolution?',J. Econ. Hist., XLIV (I984), pp. 689-7I2. (I985). Williamson,J. G., Did Britishcapitalismbreedinequality? Williamson,J. G., 'Did Englishfactormarketsfailduringthe industrialrevolution?',Oxf. Econ. Pap., 39 (I987), pp. 64I-60. Williamson,J. G., 'Debating the Britishindustrialrevolution',Exp. Econ. Hist., 24 (I987), pp. 269-92. revolution (Cambridge,i9g90). Williamson,J. G., CopingwithcitygrowthduringtheBritishindustrial in England, i600-I799', in L. Bonfield, of maritalfertility Wilson, C., 'The proximatedeterminants of populationand social R. M. Smith,and K. Wrightson,eds., The worldwe have gained: histories to PeterLaslett(Oxford,i986), pp. 203-30. essayspresented structure: on the level of mortalityin nineteenth-century Woods, R., 'The effectsof populationredistribution England and Wales',J. Econ. Hist., XLV (I985), pp. 645-5I. Wrightson,K. and Levine, D., Povertyand pietyin an Englishvillage: Terling,I525-I700 (New York, I 979). Wrigley,E. A., 'The growthof populationin eighteenthcenturyEngland: a conundrumresolved', P. & P., 98 (I983), pp. I2I-50. Wrigley,E. A., People, citiesand wealth(Oxford,I987). changein Englandand thecontinentin theearlymodern Wrigley,E. A., 'Urban growthand agricultural period', in idem,People, citiesand wealth(Oxford,I987), pp. I57-97. in England chance and change: the characterof the industrialrevolution Wrigley,E. A., Continuity, (Cambridge, i989). summary Wrigley,E. A. and Schofield,R. S., 'English populationhistoryfromfamilyreconstitution: results, I600-I799', Pop. Stud., XXXVII (I983), pp. I57-84. of England,I54I-I87I Wrigley,E. A. and Schofield,R. S., The populationhistory This content downloaded from 128.205.114.91 on Wed, 28 May 2014 10:42:09 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions (I98I).