Pro…t Maximization Philip A. Viton May 8, 2012 Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 1/1 Introduction So far we have studied the problem of cost minimization: the problem of choosing inputs to produce a given (target) output at least cost. But we have not addressed the problem of where that target output comes from. For private-sector producers (…rms), clearly the appropriate behavioral assumption is that it selects output to maximize pro…ts. We now study the decisions of these private-sector producers, in a non-spatial setting. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 2/1 Pro…ts We have: Pro…t = Total Revenue Total Cost So maximizing pro…ts involves (1) making total revenues as large as possible; and (2) making total costs as small as possible. Therefore a pro…t-maximizer will also engage in cost minimization. So our previous results on cost functions apply to a pro…t-maximizing …rm. We have: Pro…t = Total Revenue C (q; r ) where C (q; r ) is the minimum Total Cost function. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 3/1 The Competitive Firm Behavioral motivation: pro…t maximization. The …rm is a price-taker in all input markets. The competitive …rm is a price-taker in the output market as well: it acts as though, no matter how much output it produces, the market price p will not change. Usual justi…cation: the …rm is a small participant in a large industry. Clearly this is not always applicable: you need to decide in any speci…c case if the model of the competitive …rm is appropriate or not. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 4/1 Pro…t Maximization by the Competitive Firm Suppose the …rm is producing a small quantity of output, say q1 units. Suppose it increases output by 1 unit. Total revenues increase by p (because it is a price-taker in the output market and all output is sold at price p). Total costs increase by MC (q1 ). So increasing output by 1 unit will increase pro…ts if p > MC (q1 ). So the …rm should go on increasing output as long as p > MC . It should stop increasing output when p = MC . Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 5/1 Pro…t Maximization by the Competitive Firm The same reasoning works in the other direction as well. If the …rm is producing a lot of output, we ask, should it cut back by one unit? If it does so, revenues fall by p. But costs fall by MC . So pro…ts go up as long as the cost savings ( = MC ) are greater than the revenue loss (p ). So the …rm should cut back on output as long as MC > p. And it should stop cutting back when MC = p. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 6/1 Pro…t Maximization by the Competitive Firm Either way, we see that for the competitive …rm, the pro…t-maximizing level of output is where MC = p (p is the given market price). For a technical reason, we need to check that MC is rising at the pro…t-maximizing output. In the long run, the …rm will shut down (go out of business) if p < AC . And if the …rm is operating in the short-run, it will only stay in business if p > AVC . Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 7/1 Pro…t-Maximization (Calculus) Price-taking behavior in the output market implies that total revenues from output q are p q. So pro…ts are Π=p q C (q; r ) First-order condition for a maximum is d Π/dq = 0 so p dC /dq = 0 or p MC (q ) = 0 : so p = MC . Second-order condition requires d 2 Π/dq 2 < 0 so dMC (q )/dq < 0 or dMC (q )/dq > 0 : at a pro…t maximum, marginal cost must be increasing with output. This is the “technical reason” referred to previously. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 8/1 Pro…t-Maximizing Choice of Output: Long Run $ MC AC At output (market) price p1 the pro…t-maximizing output is q1 . At market price p2 it is q2 (and not q3 , since MC is falling at q3 ) . p1 p2 p3 At price p3 the …rm shuts down (p3 is below AC). q3 Philip A. Viton q2 q1 q CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 9/1 Pro…t-Maximizing Choice of Output: Long Run $ At price p1 : MC AC p1 Total Cost = q1 hatched area. AC(q1) q1 = AC (q1 ) = Di¤erence is the …rm’s pro…ts at price p1 . q1 Philip A. Viton Total Revenue = p1 shaded area. q CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 10 / 1 Pro…t-Maximizing Choice of Output: Short Run At price p1, pro…t-maximizing output is p1 . $ SRMC SRAC p1 p2 p3 SRAVC SRAFC q2 q1 Philip A. Viton q At price p2 , output is p2 but the …rm makes a loss. However, it more than covers variable costs and hence makes a contribution to the unavoidable …xed costs. Therefore it should accept the loss and stay in business. At price p3 , the …rm shuts down, since it cannot even cover its variable costs. CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 11 / 1 Supply Function The supply function of the pro…t-maximizing competitive …rm shows, for each market price p, how much the …rm will produce. So the supply function is given by the relevant portion of the …rm’s marginal cost function. If the …rm is operating in the short run, the supply function is that portion of SRMC above SRAVC. In the long run, it is the portion of (LR)MC above (LR)AC. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 12 / 1 Monopoly The monopolist is the sole seller in a market. Clearly it makes no sense to suppose that the monopolist is a price taker in the output market: the monopolist is the market. Another way to put it is that the monopolist perceives the full (market) downward-sloping demand function. So if the monopolist want to sell more, it must reduce the price it charges. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 13 / 1 The Monopolist’s Revenue Function The demand function represents the monopolist’s Average Revenue Function: it tells him what price he must charge per unit, if he wishes to sell some quantity of output. If the Average Revenue ( = Demand) Function is p (q ) (reading up and across, from quantity to price) then the Total Revenue function is R (q ) = q p (q ). Suppose the monopolist wants to sell one more unit of output. To do so, it must reduce the price it charges to all customers. The change in total revenue resulting from this is the monopolist’s Marginal Revenue (MR) function. Formally, for small changes in output, Marginal Revenue is the slope (derivative) of the Total Revenue function. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 14 / 1 Monopoly — Pro…t Maximization Suppose the monopolist is selling some small quantity of output (and it is pro…table). Should it increase output by one unit? If it does so, then its revenue increases by its Marginal Revenue And its costs increase by its Marginal Cost So its pro…ts will increase as long as MR > MC Clearly it should go on increasing output as long as MR > MC, ie until MR = MC Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 15 / 1 Monopoly — Marginal Revenue with Linear Demand If the demand function is linear, then to construct the marginal revenue function: $ Pick any price, say p1 : draw a horizontal line to the demand curve (= AR). p1 Bisect that line (point A). A MR AR q Philip A. Viton MR connects the mid-point (A) with the intercept on the price axis. CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 16 / 1 Proof Using Calculus If the demand (= average revenue) function is linear, its equation is AR = α + βq So Total Revenue is TR = AR q = q (α + βq ) = αq + βq 2 Marginal Revenue is the derivative of Total Revenue, so MR = α + 2βq. This is the equation of a straight line. MR has the same intercept (α) when q = 0 and has twice the slope (2βq vs βq) as the demand function. This is just what our geometric construction has shown. Philip A. Viton CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 17 / 1 Monopoly — Pro…t Maximization Pro…t-maximizing output is qM where MC = MR MC pM MR qM Philip A. Viton To sell this output, the monopolist charges price pM , according to the demand (= AR) function AR q CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 18 / 1 The Competitive Industry I The competitive industry is made up of many competitive …rms. $ S1=MC1 S1+2 S2=MC2 Industry supply is the horizontal summation of the individual supply functions. p1 Firm 1 has supply (=MC) function S1 . At price p1 is produces output q1 q1 Philip A. Viton q2 q1+q2 q Firm 2 has supply function S2 : at p1 it produces q2 CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 19 / 1 The Competitive Industry II $ S1=MC1 S1+2 S2=MC2 At price p1 the total output of these two …rms (horizontal summation) is q1 + q2 p1 This determines the (aggregate, industry) supply function S. q1 Philip A. Viton q2 q1+q2 q CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 20 / 1 Equilibrium in the Competitive Industry Industry equilibrium is determined by equality of aggregate demand (D) and industry supply (S) $ S S2=MC2 S1=MC1 As shown, the equilibrium price is p . * p Industry equilibrium output is q D q1 Philip A. Viton q2 q* q Each …rm takes p as given, so we can determine the outputs of (here) …rms 1 and 2. CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 21 / 1 Monopoly vs Competition Suppose we have a competitive industry with price pc and output qc . $ S pM This leads to the monopolist producing output qM and charging price pM . pc MR qM Philip A. Viton qc Now suppose it is monopolized. The monopolist bases its output on the MC=MR condition. D q Compared to competition, monopoly involves less output and higher prices. CRP 781()— Pro…ts May 8, 2012 22 / 1