Chapter 16: Suggested Answers to Textbook Questions 1. (a) The value of the dollar has fallen relative to the mark and the value of the mark has risen relative to the dollar. However, no conclusions can be made about the overall strengths of the currencies. (b) It is more likely that the dollar/yen rate has gone up than down, although it is possible that it could have declined. (c) It is more likely that the mark/yen rate has gone down than up, although it is possible that it could have increased. Export Quantity Import Quantity (a) 10 m .002 m (b) 10 m .002 m (c) 10.5 m .002 m (d) 11 m .0019 m (e) 14 m .0018 m In Dollars: Export Price Import Price Export Revenue Import Spending Trade Balance $10 $50,000 $100 m $100 m 0 $10 $55,000 $100 m $110 m $ −10 m $10 $55,000 $105 m $110 m $ −5 m $10 $55,000 $110 m $104.5 m $5.5 m $10 $55,000 $140 m $99 m $41 m In Euros: Export Price Import Price Export Revenue Import Spending Trade Balance 20 euros 100,000 euros 200 m euros 200 m euros 0 18.18 euros 100,000 euros 181.8 m euros 200 m euros −18.2 m euros 18.18 euros 100,000 euros 190.9 m euros 200 m euros −9.1 m euros 18.18 euros 100,000 euros 200 m euros 190 m euros 10 m euros 18.18 euros 100,000 euros 254.5 m euros 180 m euros 74.5 m euros 2. 3. (a) In parts (d) and (e) of question 2, the trade balance improves, whereas it worsens in (c) and (b). This is a result of the fact that the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied in (d) and (e) but not in (b) and (c). (b) In case (e), import spending does not change. This is a result of the fact that import elasticity is one. (c) In case (d), export elasticity is one, and therefore export revenue in euros is unchanged. (d) The initial trade balance would be −$50 million. The 10 percent devaluation will lead to the same percentage change in quantities as in the above case, as the elasticities have not changed. However, since the initial quantity of imports is larger, there will then be a larger absolute change in imports, import revenue, and the trade balance. 4. (a) The devaluation will increase the domestic price of imports, and there will then be a movement along the import demand curve from B to A. The effect on total import spending in the domestic currency will be ambiguous. Export demand will shift outwards, thus leading to an increase in export revenue. (b) If import elasticity exceeds one, then total spending on imports will fall, as the percentage fall in import quantity will exceed the percentage increase in the price of imports. Since total revenue from exports unambiguously increases, the trade balance must improve. 5. (a) Start from TB = X(E) − EM(E). Differentiate with respect to E: dTB/dE = dX(E)/d(E) − M(E) − E dM(E)/dE Divide by M(E) and note that dTB/dE = 0 0 = dX(E)/dE − 1 − (E/M(E))(dM(E)/dE) Note that the last term is εm. When the trade balance is zero, X(E) = EM(E). Rearranging and using this fact, we obtain: 1 = (dX(E)/dE) (E/X(E)) + εm and note that εx = (dX(E)/dE) (E/X(E)) Thus, the Marshall-Lerner condition is obtained. (b) If we start from an initial trade deficit, then dTB/dE is not zero. The Marshall-Lerner condition can then be shown to be too weak by following the same steps as in part (a). (c) (i) Yes. This would imply that E TB* = 0 and thus TB* = 0. (ii) No. dTB/dE = E dTB*/dE + TB* Since TB = E TB*, this can be rewritten as dTB/dE = E dTB*/dE + TB/E (iii) If TB < 0, dTB/dE < E dTB*/dE (iv) If TB > 0, dTB/dE > E dTB*/dE (v) If TB = 0, dTB/dE = E dTB*/dE (d) (i) Using the answer to c (iii), its possible that the trade balance can improve in terms of foreign currency while worsening in terms of domestic currency. (ii) The contradiction can be reconciled by the fact that d(E TB*)/dE = dTB*/dE + TB* Therefore, although dTB/dE and dTB*/dE are of opposite signs, it will be the case that dTB/dE and d(E TB*)/dE are the same sign. If the country is initially in a deficit, and a devaluation restores balanced trade, then dTB/dE is negative, and TB* is negative, therefore, although dTB*/dE will be positive, the overall effect d(E TB*)/dE will also be negative. 6. (a) [εm εx(1 + σm+ σx) − εm εx(1− εm − εx)]/[( σm + εm)( σx + εx)] > 0 [σx(εm εx −σm(1 −εm)+ εx σm) + (1 + σm) εm εx]/[( σm + εm)( σx + εx)] > 0 The denominator of the above expression is unambiguously positive. Therefore, the Bickerdickie-Robinson-Metzler condition requires that σx(εm εx − σm(1 − εm) + εx σm) + (1 + σm) εm εx > 0 This can be rearranged to get εm(εx (1 + σm + σx) + σmσx) − σmσx(1 − εx) > 0 Taking the limit as σm σx goes to infinity will yield [σmσx(−1 + εm + εx)]/[ σm σx] > 0 This simplifies easily to the Marshall-Lerner condition. (b) This condition is less stringent than the Marshall-Lerner condition. If the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied, then the above is always satisfied, whereas there may be situations where the above is satisfied and the Marshall-Lerner condition is not.