Absolute and Relative gains in European Constitution building – and Why? Thomas König and Stephanie Daimer Paper for presentation at the ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops 2005, Granada, April 14-18 Please do not quote without authors’ permission Abstract: How does the European constitution provide for change, and why do some states gain more from the outcome than others? Why do these states accept a reform which changes the balance of power in the Council, modifies the access to the Commission, distributes differently the seats in the European Parliament, shifts competences to the EU and changes the “rules of the game” for specific policy areas? While the broader scholarly debate centered around the impact of absolute and relative gains for cooperation, we ask whether the multistage dynamics of the constitution-building process, the principal agent-problem and the twolevel nature of constitutional bargains and the elements of the bargaining/deliberating environment can explain actors’ relative and absolute gains? This paper is a first attempt to explore reasons for actors’ absolute and relative gains in the European constitution-building process, which included actors from the domestic and European level. Using data on the positions of the 173 actors involved in the various stages of constitution building and the outcome of the constitutional text signed in June 2004, we confirm previous work: conflict in the domestic arena and ratifyers with status quo-bias tend to promote absolute and relative gains, while the size of a member state, GDP per capita and membership duration can hardly explain winning and losing. Most importantly, actors win when they are located close to the bargaining mean and are supported by actors in their own stage. While being close to British positions increases an actors’ absolute gains, a lucky position close to one of the big states does not help for winning in relative terms. Research Institute for Public Administration, Freiherr-vom-Stein-Str. 2, 67324 Speyer, Germany tkoenig@dhv-speyer.de daimer@foev-speyer.de 1 Introduction The creation of the European constitution is one of the most significant today’s real scale political events. Although this constitution has still to be ratified, the adoption of a draft by the Laeken Convention and the signing of the constitutional text by all 25 governments has already been a great surprise and success for all supporters of European integration. The Laeken Convention started a reform process, which has almost reached completion. In June 2004, the 25 heads of state and governments agreed on a constitutional text which proposes to change the institutional framework of the European Union (EU) by abolishing the voting weights for qualified majority voting in the Council, introducing a long-term Council president and a Minister for Foreign Affairs, reforming the Commission and strengthening the European Parliament (EP), further integrating the Common Foreign and Security Policy and extending qualified majority voting to a number of important policy fields (see König et al. 2005, Tsebelis 2005). But how does this constitution provide for change, and do some states gain more from the outcome than others in absolute and relative terms? And which states do profit from a reform which changes the balance of power in the Council, modifies the access to the Commission, distributes differently the seats in the EP, shifts competences to the EU and changes the “rules of the game” for specific policy areas? While the broader scholarly debate has centered around the question whether absolute or relative gains can explain constitutional outcomes (Buchanan and Tullock 1961, Waltz 1979, Snidal 1991a, 1991b), we ask whether the multi-stage dynamics of the constitution-building process, the principal agent-problem and the two- level nature of constitutional bargains and the elements of the bargaining environment, such as the support by other members, the role of the supranationals and the closeness to the status quo can explain actors’ absolute and relative gains? The findings may have important implications for research on cooperation among states in general, and EU constitution building in particular. By exploring the reasons for absolute and relative gains, we hope to provide empirical evidence to relevant theoretical claims highlighted in the prominent controversy between the realist and institutionalist schools of thought (Waltz 1959, 1979 Grieco 1993, Keohane 1984) as well as between voting power (Hosli 1996, Felsenthal et al. 2001) and spatial analysts (Tsebelis and Garrett 2001, Albert 2004). We begin our study by introducing into the EU constitution-building process, which suggests that various actors with different power resources were involved in the drafting, amending and deciding stage leading to a constitutional text. We then derive expectations on three different explanatory factors: bargaining environment, domestic arena, 2 and multi-stage nature of the process. Before we statistically analyze their relative explanatory power, we describe our data of actors’ positions on key reform constitutional issues. We find that bargaining environment is the most important explanatory factor and that closeness to the three big states does not necessarily support an actor’s success. Only being close to UK positions increases an actors’ absolute gains, while a lucky position close to one of the large countries does not promote relative gains. Moreove r, conflict in the domestic arena and ratifyers with status quo-bias tend to promote absolute and relative gains, whereas the size of a member state, GDP per capita and membership duration hardly explain winning and losing. We confirm previous research which has revealed the importance of the domestic arena for explaining EU outcomes. Our results point to considering not only the positions of the actors involved but also the nature of the process which provides the actors’ with different power resources. Although we find that actors participating in the later stages of the process were more successful, the delegates of the Laeken Convention were however able to set the agenda for constitutional change. Understanding EU constitution building thus seems to require considering the positions of all actors involved, and the focus on one stage risks to bias findings. This suggest that a two- level multi-stage conception can accurately explain EU constitution building. The remainder introduces into the EU constitutio n-building process, derives expectations on absolute and relative gains, presents the data and the statistical analysis. The Process of European Constitution building The process of constitution building in the EU has almost reached completion. After the disillusioning treaty revisions by the Amsterdam (1996) and Nice (2000) IGC, there was little hope that the member states would agree on a reform of the EU’s obsolete framework following the accession of ten Eastern and Southern European countries. 1 The macroeconomic indicators of the 25 new and old member states suggested that their interests in European integration will differ widely (König and Bräuninger 2004). Even the FrenchGerman collaboration, for a long time the motor of European integration, stagnated. Despite these unfavourable conditions, the enlarged EU adopted a draft text on a constitutional treaty in June 2004, which had been prepared by the Laeken Convention under the Presidency of Valéry Giscard d’Estaing. The Laeken Convention worked out the key reform issues for a 1 Both intergovernmental conference have been marked by last minute agreements on a package boiled down to the lowest common denominator. At the Amsterdam IGC, for example, the most controversial issues on institutional reform were simply removed from the bargaining table (Hug and König 2002), the Nice IGC ended with a compromise over the qualified majority voting threshold, which was even more complicated than it was before (see Tsebelis and Yatangas 2002): 3 constitutional treaty including the basic principles of the EU, the regulation of material policy competencies and a reform of the institutional framework. This reform proposes a change in the power balance among the member states of the Council as well as between the Council, the Commission and the European Parliament (EP). The Laeken Convention has been a new method for drafting reform proposals of a widening and deepening EU. The Convention was composed of 207 members 2 and 13 observers, of which only 66 had the right to vote on the final document. In anticipation of the following stages, the representatives of the 15 member states sent one governmental and two parliamentary representatives, and the accession states’ delegates were invited to discuss the draft without having a voting right about the text. After the first listening phase, the Presidency initiated a second so-called study phase in September 2002 establishing a system of eleven working groups. In spring 2003, the Convention came into the decisive phase, which was called the drafting period. In the end, the delegates adopted a draft constitutional text after hectic and intensive debates on 13 June 2003 (König et al. 2005). Like previous reforms, the adoption of the constitutional draft text required IGC consensus. Intensive pre-coordination processes began in the 25 member states and accession countries as well as in the Commission and the EP (for details, see König and Hug, 2005). In preparation for the summit in mid-December 2003, these 27 collective actors had to formulate their positions on the issues central to the constitution. They circulated the draft text among core (domestic) actors, held hearings and discussions on particular topics, and evaluated strategies for the upcoming summit (König 2005). In many countries, the institutional reform was especially contested, in particular the modification of the Council voting rules, the modus of the Presidency and the Commission appointment procedure. Smaller countries feared losses in their agenda setting, discretionary and veto powers (Tsebelis 2005). Large countries offered concessions to smaller countries in terms of the number of Commissio ners, but Spain and Poland blocked the adoption of the text in December 2003. In Poland, the Sejm had tied the hands of the unpopular minority government Miller, which was forced to vote for the status quo regulations of the Nice treaty. However, after the surprising deselection of the Spanish conservative government in the course of the Madrid terrorist attacks, Poland could no longer withstand the collective pressure, and the Irish Presidency presented a compromise that was accepted in June 2004. These events indicate how challenging is the analysis of relative and absolute gains in the process of EU constitution building. The process has involved a large number of actors 2 This number includes the 102 alternates for the full members. There were no alternates for the 3 members of the presidency. 4 from the European and domestic level, and discussions included a large set of issues. In opposition to intergovernmentalist claims (Moravcsik 1998), smaller countries seem to have had a decisive say, and the positions of delegates from the same country on the constitutional text also diverged at times. Some actors – such as the Spanish and Polish governmental delegations – have changed positions over time; others revealed different standpoints at the domestic and the European level. This points to the collective and strategic nature of actors’ positions which resulted in an agreement on the constitution after intense preparation and summit negotiations. The entry into force of the constitution still depends on the support of ratifying parliamentarians and populations, and we still do not know whether the ratifying principals will diverge from their delegated agents who signed the text in June 2004. Looking for the relevant factors of this multi-stage two- level process, a number of approaches and explanations circulate in the literature on EU integration, international and comparative politics. Perhaps the most prominent approach is Andrew Moravcsik’s “liberal intergovernmentalism”, who argues that the outcomes can be understood by examining the socio-economic preferences of domestic actors within the EU’s three largest member states, Germany, France, and the UK. Moravcsik (1998) explains the most important outcomes from Messina to Maastricht, and later Moravcsik and Nicolaidis (1999) applied the approach to the Amsterdam treaty, and Magnette and Nicolaidis (2004) to the outcome of the Constitut ional Convention. These studies conclude that IGC outcomes result from intergovernmental bargains, in which the large member states have the decisive say. While intergovermentalists suggest a bargaining solution which is weighted by the power of France, Germany, and the United Kingdom, others argue that supranational actors may have power at IGCs (Christiansen 2002, Falkner 2002). Hix (2002) concludes that EP was a constitutional agenda setter at the Amsterdam IGC, which has been confirmed by neither Pollack (1999) nor Slapin (2005). Another explanation is suggested by the two- level game literature regarding domestic constraints. The two- level game logic supposes that bargainers benefit at the negotiating table from having their hands tied by a high and skeptical domestic ratification constraint (Schelling 1960, Putnam 1988). This concept has stimulated formal research examining exactly how and when domestic constraints matter (see Iida 1993, 1996; Hammond and Prins 1999; Mo 1994, 1995; Milner and Rosendorff 1996, 1997; Pahre 1997, 2001, Schneider and Cederman 1994). More recently researchers have begun to test these models in quantitative studies, all of which have focused on IGCs (Hosli 2000, König and Hug 2000, Hug and König 2002, König and Slapin 2004, Slapin 2005). Their empirical results show that domestic 5 constraints explain the outcome of IGCs because EU ratification must often overcome higher institutional hurdles than government formation and delegation do (König and Hug 2000, Hug and König 2002, see also Schulz 2003 for the enlargement negotiations). Although the two- level game literature differentiates between negotiators and ratifyers, the dominant conception is a one-shot game, in which the delegated negotiator and the ratifying principal decide simultaneously about the outcome (Hammond and Prins 1999; Mo 1994, 1995; Milner and Rosendorff 1996, 1997). In empirical studies on the EU, only the delegates negotiate outcomes, while the principals are constraints with single peaked positions (König and Hug 2000, Hug and König 2002, König and Slapin 2004, Slapin 2005). Some studies have yet tackled the problem of delegation in negotiations with references to the principal-agent literature (Stasavage 2004, Mnookin and Susskind 1999, Segendorff 1998).3 The EU constitution-building process suggests that actors performed different principal-agent roles in the various stages, each producing collective outcomes. The delegates of the Laeken Convention, consisting of governmental and parliamentary representatives, were responsible for the drafting of a text, while governmental delegates finally decided about the adoption of the constitution at the following IGC summit. In the preparatory stage of the IGC, intensive coordination included domestic (governmental) actors trying to amend the draft text. Due to their different powers of drafting, amending and signing (vetoing), the question is whether the different roles and powers of the actors are decisive for their success. Explaining Success in the Constitution-building Process The following study attempts to explore why some actors were more successful in the EU constitution-building process than others by an empirical analysis of the specific reasons for their absolute and relative gains from the constitutional outcome. For this empirical purpose, we propose to examine how often are actors’ positions absolutely reflected in the outcome of the contested issues, and why some actors more often hit those outcomes than others do. This view is complemented by a realist perspective which relates the absolute hits of an actor to those of the other actors. We want to know whether and how these factors explain gains, and if so, to what extent do we find similar and different answers for actors’ absolute and relative success? Our analysis of absolute and relative gains is related to one of the most important 3 Most of the delegation literature deals with American politics (e.g. Epstein and O’Halloran 1999, McCubbins and Schwartz 1984, Bendor and Meirowitz 2004, Huber and Shipan 2002), some applications address Western democracies (Strom, Müller and Bergmann 2003, Hallerberg and Döring 2004, Thatcher and Stone-Sweet 2002), and most recently EU politics, where the member states are conceptualized as principals who control supranational agencies, primarily the Commission (Pollack 1997, 2003, Franchino 2000a, 2000b, Ballmann, Epstein and O’Halloran 2002). 6 controversies in political science between the institutionalist school of thought, which claims that absolute gains should sufficiently condition EU constitutional cooperation, and the realist IR literature that emphasizes the limiting effect of relative gains for international cooperation (Aron 1973; Carr 1964; Gilpin 1975 1981, 1987; Grieco 1988, 1990, 1993; Jervis 1978, 1988; Krasner 1976, 1985, 1991; Morgenthau 1973; Waltz 1959, 1979). 4 Instead of focusing on one type of gains and analysing its explanatory power for cooperation, we attempt to examine relative and absolute gains using three broad explanatory categories: those suggesting that the bargaining environment is relevant, those referring to the domestic arena and those which point to the importance of the multi-stage nature of the EU constitution-building process: 1. Bargaining environment. Success and power in bargaining have attracted considerable attention in the literature on international and European politics (Black 1958: 141, Banfield 1961: 331, Bueno de Mesquita and Stokman 1994, Thomson et al. 2006). Bargaining theories are based on mean solutions, sometimes weighted by the formal power and resources of the actors (Achen 2006). This does not mean that the support of other actors – in other words, the size of the coalition – is irrelevant for relative and absolute gains, whether this support includes the support across all or only the particular stage. In some bargaining analyses, the location of the status quo also biased the outcome (Tsebelis 2002, König and Slapin 2005, Mokken et al 2000), i.e. an actor can receive more concessions, as she is expected to be more patient in the negotiations (Rubinstein 1982). However, it is often difficult to evaluate whether an actor receives gains due to her power or even luck (Barry 1980). In addition to the closeness to the status quo, another reason thus might simply be that an actor is closely located to another powerful actor, i.e. close to one of the large countries and/or to a supranational actor. 2. Domestic arena. An important resource in bargains is credibility. Threats and promises are prominent strategies to receive more concessions, and the knowledge about the situation in the domestic arena can help to increase an actor’s credibility and thus the effectiveness of her strategy (Schelling 1960). Such information can be provided by the size of the core, which indicates how contested an issue is in the domestic arena (König and Slapin 2005). In particular when the pivotal ratifying actor is closely located to the status quo, an actor should have good arguments to receive 4 Snidal (1991a: 706) added to the widely used assumption that states would only care on either type of gains, be it absolute or be it relative, “that states seek relative gains in combination with absolute gains, with the pure absolute and relative gains models seen as limiting cases.” (see also 1991b as well as Grieco, Powell and Snidal 1993). Whether actors are primarily concerned with absolute or relative gains may also vary among the negotiators (Berejekian 1997, Mosher 2003). 7 concessions (Putnam 1988). Another source of information about the domestic arena is the public support for European integration. Compared to ratification, public support could indicate the audience costs of an actor (Fearon 1994, Schneider and Cederman 1994). If support of ratifying actors is lacking, this might help the negotiator to receive concessions. If public support is high, the costs of a negotiator might be lower. 3. Multi-stage process. Each stage of EU constitution-building conferred different powers to the actors involved. They performed different roles in the drafting stage of the Laeken Convention, the amending stage when preparing the IGC in the domestic arena and the negotiation stage at the summit. If these stages do provide different powers, actors may have different possibilities for being successful. If positions tend to converge in the course of bargaining (Stokman and Thomson 2004), closeness to the bargaining mean and high support should be particularly important in the final IGC negotiation stage. We additionally control for some other variables mentioned in the literature, such as population size, GDP per capita, netpayer in the EU and duration of EU membership. Data: Actors’ Positions on Key Reform Issues Our data contain information about the positions of the 25 IGC member state delegates, 100 actors involved in the preparatory stage of domestic coordination and 48 delegates of the Laeken Convention with only two governmental delegates missing. Before the completion of each stage, we interviewed delegates (IGC and Laeken) and asked experts (domestic coordination), which positions actors had on the set of contested constitutional issues. 5 The data contain positions of the actors involved during the constitutional process on 36 contested issues with mainly institutional issues (28) and some regarding the regulation in specific policy fields (8). This set covers the highly contested issues such as the composition and threshold for qualified majority votes in the Council, the future number of commissioners and appointment of the Commission president, the reform of the presidency of the (European) council, the external representation of the EU (Foreign Minister), the role of national parliaments in monitoring the principle of subsidiarity, Council decision rules for vital policy areas like foreign and security policy, Area of Freedom, Security and Justice, tax harmonization as well as social policy and social security rights. Issues dealing with the division of competences among the different levels are included for foreign policy, tax 5 The data about the domestic coordination stage have been collected in a common effort by the DOSEI (“Domestic structures and European Integration”) research group, coordinated by Thomas König, see http://dosei.dhv-speyer.de/. 8 harmonization, the Area of Freedom, Security and Justice, and agricultural, economic, employment and social policies. The data enables us to relax widely used assumptions on state unitariness and one-shot bargains, containing information on 173 actors’ positions of the following three stages: (1) the agenda-setting stage at the Laeken Convention, (2) the stage of domestic coordination, where, in response to the Laeken draft, official national positions were formed by national sub-units like ministries, parties, interest groups, and (3) the negotiation stage at the IGC. Table 1 overviews our sample across countries, showing that we have almost a complete data set for the EU-25 over the three stages. Except for Cyprus and the United Kingdom, where the government’s delegations of Laeken are missing, our data covers two Convention delegates from each country, one representing the national government and one representing the national parliament, and one delegate per country for the IGC stage.. Since we asked experts to indicate the relevant domestic actors, their number varies across countries. Table 1 about here Analysis: Examining Absolute and Relative Gains With reference to previous empirical studies, we operationalize absolute gains as closeness of an actor’s position to the outcome in the constitutional text signed in June 2004 (Bueno de Mesquita and Stokman 1994, Hug and König 2002, König and Slapin 2005, Slapin 2005). We have created a hitrate variable by counting how often an actor’s position hits the outcome and dividing this number by the total number of positions of this actor. 6 The theoretical range of our absolute gains’ indicator goes from 0 to 1 with 1 meaning, that all positions of an actor are equal to the IGC outcome; empirically, this value varies between 0.25 and 0.83. The relative gains estimator relates these values to the other actors’ gains. For each issue, we subtract the absolute value of an actor using the share of other actors’ values. This procedure intends to weight those cases higher with few winners per issue. Relative gains could also range from 0 to 1 with 1 indicating the extreme case, in which only one actor would have won “the complete pie” of all 36 issues, i.e. all other actors would receive 0 across all issues. Empirically, this value varies between 0.21 and 0.91 (multiplied by 100 to adjust this scale, see table 2 below). 6 This divisor was 36 for cases without missings. Otherwise the number of missing positions was subtracted from 36. 9 Table 1 lists the average hitrate for each country’s actors in the three stages, showing that the values are highest for actors of the domestic coordination stage. However, it is still surprising how often the initial Laeken positions correspond to the final outcome, suggesting that the Laeken Convention could set the agenda for the following process. For most countries absolute and relative gains vary largely across the three stages, with highest relative gains of the actors of the domestic coordination stage. However, only the distributions in the domestic stage differ. According to figures 1 and 2 lower (and more) absolute gains have been allocated to the actors in the Convention stage while actors of stages 2 and 3 have higher (and more) relative gains. Briefly summarized, for both types of gains and across all stages winners come from Estonia, Ireland, Lithuania, and Luxembourg. Some countries’ delegates, like those from Belgium, Finland, Denmark, Hungary, Cyprus and Malta were more successful in the earlier stages, while German, Greek, Spanish, British, Polish and Czech actors performed better in later stages. This indicates that the type of gains and stages might affect results on winning and losing. Figures 1 and 2 about here In order to evaluate absolute and relative gains in a systematic manner, we run regression statistics using three classes of variables. We evaluate the impact of the bargaining environment by checking how close an actor is to the mean position (transformed to pseudometric scores) as the bargaining outcome. Values close to 0 indicate that an actor is centrally located, while higher values express having more extreme positions. Another indicator for bargaining environment is the size of a coalition, respectively the support for a specific position. We differentiate between average support of an actor in her own stage and across all stages. Empirically, these values range from 27 to 62 per cent across all stages, and from 33 to 67 per cent in the actors’ own stages (see table 2). We also consider status quo-bias and calculate the closeness of an actor to this reference point. We use the number of an actor’s hits with the status quo in relation to the number of possible hits, i.e. higher scores mean being closer to the status quo. Finally, we control for being lucky by calculating the closeness to the positions of each of the three big states (Germany, UK, France) and to both supranational actors (Commission, EP). Table 2 about here 10 The second class of variables estimates the impact of the domestic arena. We compute the size of the domestic core to indicate how contested issues were among the actors of each country (using pseudo- metric transformation we calculated the distance between the two most extreme domestic actors across all issues, averaged by dividing through the number of issues). This yields higher scores for countries with both non-unitary domestic positions on average and high contestation for few issues. We consider domestic ratification restraints if a parliamentary or decisive partisan actor in parliament prefers the status quo. For measuring audience costs, we use Flash Eurobarometer of June 2004, which asked people about their support for a constitution (support ranges from 50 per cent in Sweden (and 51 per cent in the UK) up to above 90 per cent in Spain and Italy). Taking into account the multi-stage nature of the process, we use dummy variables to qualify actors of the Convention and from the domestic arena. They participated in the earlier stages of constitution building which provided them with drafting power at the Convention stage and amending power at the coordination stage. We also control for economic indicators using a dummy variable for netpayers (based on 2002 figures of the Commission) 7 and a GDP per capita comparison, which ranges from 0.425 for Latvia to 2.133 for Luxembourg (the EU25 average corresponds to the value 1) 8 . Moreover, we consider population size and duration of EU membership. By using the natural log of these two variables, we assume that size and duration matter at a decreasing rate. In the absolute gains’ regression model 1, two outliers cause high leverage and large residuals: the Swedish and the Danish government delegates at the Convention (with absolute and relative gains at the lowest ends of the scales). This model also has different variance of the error terms across observations. 9 Deleting the two outliers from the sample solves this problem and reveals that our findings only modestly change. According to table 2 both models fit our data structure with about 87 per cent (model 1) and 84 per cent (model 2) of variance. Some explanations differ for absolute and relative gains, but the findings in both models point to the high relevance of the bargaining environment. The strongest predictors are the distance to the (bargaining) mean and the support of an actor in her own stage, the closeness to the status quo as well as to the French position. The closer an actor is to the mean position, the closer an actors to the status quo and the higher the support for an actor in her 7 The accession states have been assumed to be netreceivers. Source: Eurostat, forecast figures 2003. 9 Test results indicate that the regression results for absolute gains are indeed heteroscedastic. Breusch-Pagan / Cook-Weisberg test: chi2=8.34 (significant at the 1 per cent level). 8 11 own stage, the higher are her absolute and relative wins. Moreover, closeness to the United Kingdom and France as well as to the Commission and EP also matter for absolute gains. While only actors close to the UK positions are lucky absolute winners, perhaps due to the fact that this was the status quo-coalition, closeness to the supranational institutions and France means losses in terms of actors’ absolute gains. 10 Only the French position matters for relative gains, however in a negative way. Actors were also less successful when they were close to the positions of one of the supranational actors. Factors of the domestic arena turn out to be significant, too: the size of the domestic core, a sceptical ratifying actor and public opinion significantly support success in absolute and relative terms. In accordance with the paradox of weakness, domestic non-consensus (as implied by a larger domestic core) and parliamentary or partisan actors with status quo-bias seem credibly to tie the hands of negotiators. 11 Actors with low audience costs are also winners in the constitutional process. The stage variables confirm our expectation: The negative coefficients of the Convention stage and domestic coordination stage variables underline the importance of the latest stage of IGC bargaining for absolute wins. However, on closer inspection, the range of the gains of IGC actors is similar to that of domestic actors. This suggests that the final stage only modestly changed the outcome. In model 2, there is only statistical evidence for the Convention stage. From the country-specific control variables, we find that size and the status of a net contributor to the EU budget tend to confer some bargaining strength. However, smaller countries seem to have won more often than larger countries. Note that 9 of the 10 new member states (except for Poland) are small, which means that small states have a large majority in absolute numbers. 12 Table 3 about here To illustrate the some of the important variables, figures 3 and 4 display their impact for predicting (absolute) gains, holding all other variables at their mean (due to high similarity we do not illustrate their effects for relative gains). A close location to the (bargaining) mean 10 Deleting the outliers reveals that being close to the German position positively explains performance on absolute gains. Being distant to the supranational actors becomes statistically significant by the “Closeness to the Commission” variable. 11 The status quo bias of the ratifyer turns out to be insignificant in the model without the outliers. 12 After deleting the outliers, the GDP variable performs with a small negative coefficient at a statistically significant level. This unexpected sign (after we find the status of a netpayer with a positive relationship to absolute gains) can be explained by the wealthy Luxembourg, which appears as an outlier on this variable, but has not the highest gains. 12 remarkably explains higher gains. In addition, as support in the actor’s own stage increases, absolute gains are predicted to increase. At the same time, we see how strong the argument of the status quo is. Figure 4 illustrates the effects of the “luck”-variables, which are significant for absolute gains, although they have less explanatory power than the variables of the bargaining environment. Only closeness to British positions helps for winning. Similarly, as actors are closer to the French positions and to the positions of a supranational actor, their absolute gains decrease. The mixed results for the closeness variables to the three big states remind us (supported by the negative coefficient of the population size variable) that we can hardly assume that big states share a common interest against smaller countries nor should one focus on only the three big states. Figures 3 and 4 about here The findings on German and French actors rather suggest that the German-French motor sometimes stagnated. On closer inspection of this relationship, we see that these countries has the same positions on the double majority principle for future QMV voting, the reduction of the Commission, an elected long-term Presidency for the Council, the EU Foreign Minister and further integration in the Common Foreign and Security Policy etc. However, in those cases, both were less successful, while France and Germany were split in questions of further delegation of competencies to the EU level, i.e. regarding economic or social policies. The gains of British actors are related to the status quo-bias of the outcome. British actors have successfully defended their “red lines”, i.e. their vetoes in foreign and security policy, tax harmonization and social security. Conclusion: A Two-level Multi-Stage Bargaining Process This analysis tried to shed light on winning and losing in European constitution building. While the scholarly controversy centered around the impact of absolute and relative gains for cooperation, we examined which factors explain winning and losing in both terms. Such an analysis requires data on actors’ positions, which we gathered for the different stages of the constitution-building process. The distribution of absolute and relative gains reveals that the positions of actors – even from those of the Convention and domestic stages, are considerably reflected in the outcome. However, IGC actors were more successful than actors of the earlier stages. 13 Most significantly the bargaining environment, in particular the closeness to the mean and to the status quo significantly explain actors’ success. Although closeness to the UK (and partly to Germany) increases an actor’s absolute gains, we do not find evidence for intergovernmentalist claims that country size confers power. More interestingly with respect to ratification might be that closeness to France is reversely related to winning. Likewise, the positions of the supranational actors are located far away from the outcome, i.e. their support is negatively related to actors’ success. Our analysis confirms previous findings of two- level game analyses lending credence that domestic contestation of issues and sceptical ratifying actors can help actors reaching concessions at the bargaining table. In fact, the results suggest that the larger the size of the domestic core, i.e. the more contested issues are, the higher an actor wins, in particular in relative terms. 14 REFERENCES Achen, Christopher. (2006) “Institutional Realism and Bargaining Models”, in Thomson, Robert, Frans Stokman, Christopher Achen and Thomas König (eds.) The European Union Decides. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (forthcoming). Albert, M. (2004) “The Voting Power Approach: Unresolved Ambiguities”, European Union Politics 5(1): 139 – 146. Aron, Raymond. (1973) International Relations: A Theory of Peace and War. Garden City, N.J.: Doubleday. Ballmann, Alexander, David Epstein and Sharyn O’Halloran. (2002) “Delegation, Comitology, and the Separation of Powers in the European Union”, International Organization 56(3): 551-574. Banfield, Edward C. (1961) Political Influence. New York: The Free Press. Barry, B. (1980). “Is It Better to be Powerful or Lucky. Part I and Part II”, Political Studies 28: 183-194, 338-52. Black, Duncan. (1958) Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Bendor, J. and A. Meirowitz. (2004) “Spatial Models of Delegation”, American Political Science Review 98 (2): 293-310. Berejekian, Jeffrey. (1997) “The gains debate. Framing state choice”, American Political Science Review 91 (4): 789-805. Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce and Frans Stokman. (1994) European community decision making: models, applications and comparisons. New Haven: Yale University Press. Carr, E.H. (1964) The Twenty Years Crisis, 1919-1939: An Introduction to the Study of International Relations. London and New York: Harper Torchbooks. Christiansen, Thomas. (2002) “The role of supranational actors in EU treaty reform” Journal of European Public Policy 9(1): 33-53. Epstein, David and Sharyn O’Halloran. (1999) Delegating Powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Fearon, JD (1994) “Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes”, American Political Science Review, 88: 577–92. Falkner, Gerda. (2002) “How Intergovernmental are Intergovernmental Conferences? An Example from the Maastricht Treaty Reform.” Journal of European Public Policy 9(1): 98-119. Felsenthal, Dan S. and Moshé Machover (2001) ‘The Treaty of Nice and Qualified Majority Voting’, Social Choice and Welfare 18(3): 431-64. 15 Franchino, Fabio. (2000a) “Commission’s Executive Discretion, Comitology”, Journal of Theoretical Politics 12(2): 155-181. Information and Franchino, Fabio. (2000b) “Control of the Commission’s Executive Functions”, European Union Politics 1 (1): 63-92. Gilpin, Robert. (1975) U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Econonmy of Foreign Direct Investment. New York: Basic Books. Gilpin, Robert. (1981) War and Change in World Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gilpin, Robert. (1987) The Political Economy of International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Grieco, Joseph, Robert Powell and Duncan Snidal (1993) “The Relative-Gains Problem for International Cooperation”, American Political Science Review 87 (3): 729-743. Grieco, Joseph M. (1993) “Understanding the problem of international cooperation: The limits of neoliberal institutionalism and the future of realist theory”. In Baldwin, David (ed.) Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The contemporary debate. New York: Columbia University Press. Grieco, Joseph M. (1990) Cooperation Among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Grieco, Joseph M. (1988) “Anarchy and the limits of cooperation: a realist critique of the newest liberal institutionalism”, International Organization 42 (3): 485-507. Herbert Döring, Herbert and Mark Hallerberg. (2004) Patterns of Parliamentary Behavior. Aldershot: Ashgate. Hammond, Thomas H. and Brandon C. Prins. (1999) “The Impact of Domestic Institutions on International Negotiations: A Taxonomy of Results for Complete-Information Spatial Models.” Prepared for Presentation at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, Georgia, September 2-5, 1999. Hix, Simon. (2002) “Constitutional Agenda-Setting Through Discretion in Rule Interpretation: Why the European Parliament Won at Amsterdam.” British Journal of Political Science. 32: 259-280. Hosli, Madeleine (1996) ‘Coalitions and Power: Effects of Qualified Majority Voting in the Council of the European Union’, Journal of Common Market Studies 34(2): 255-73. Hosli, Madeleine O. (2000) “The Creation of the European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU): Intergovernmental Negotiations and Two Level Games.” Journal of European Public Policy. 7(5):744-766. Huber, John D. and Charles R. Shipan. (2002) Deliberate Discretion: The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy. New York: Cambrige Unversity Press. 16 Hug, Simon and Thomas König. (2002) “In View of Ratification. Governmental Preferences and Domestic Constraints at the Amsterdam Intergovernmental Conference.” International Organization. 56(2). pp 447-476. Iida, Keisuke. (1993) “When and How Do Domestic Constraints Matter: Two-Level Games with Uncertainty.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 37(3): 403-426. Iida, Keisuke. (1996) “Involuntary Defection in Two-Level Games.” Public Choice 89: 283303. Jervis, Robert. (1988) “Realism, Game Theory and Cooperation”, International Organization 40: 317-49. Jervis, Robert. (1978) “Cooperation under the Security Dilemma”, World Politics 30: 167185. König, Thomas (2005) “Methods and Measuring Positions in European Constitutionbuilding”, European Union Politics 3 (forthcoming). König, Thomas and Thomas Bräuninger (2004) “Accession and Reform of the European Union. A Game-Theoretical Analysis of Eastern Enlargement and the Constitutional Reform.” European Union Politics 5 (4): 419-439. König, Thomas and Simon Hug. (2000) “Ratifying Maastricht: Parliamentary Votes on International Treaties and Theoretical Solution Concepts.” European Union Politics. 1(1): 93-124. König, Thomas and Simon Hug (eds.) (2005) Preference Formation and European Constitution-building. A Comparative Study in Member States and Accession Countries. ECPR/Routledge Series (forthcoming). König, Thomas and Jonathan Slapin. (2004) “Bringing Parliaments Back In: The Sources of Power in European Treaty Negotiations.” Journal of Theoretical Politics. 16(3): 357394. König, Thomas and Jonathan Slapin. (2005) “Winners and Losers of the Constitutional Convention: An Empirical Analysis of European Constitution Building.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 7-10, Chicago. König, Thomas, Andreas Warntjen and Simone Burkhart (2005) “The Laeken Convention: Consensus without Unity.” in Thomas König and Simon Hug (eds). Preference Formation and European Constitution-building. A Comparative Study in Member States and Accession Countries. ECPR/Routledge Series (forthcoming). Krasner, Stephen D. (1976) “State Power and the Structure of World Trade”, World Politics 28: 314-47. Krasner, Stephen D. (1985) Structural Conflict: The Third World against Global Liberalism. Berkeley: University of California Press. 17 Krasner, Stephen D. (1991) “Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier”, World Politics 43: 336-66. Magnette, Paul and Kalypso Nicolaidis. (2004) “The European Convention: bargaining in the shadow of rhetoric.” West European Politics 27(3): 381-395. McCubbins, M.D. and T. Schwartz. (1984) “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrol vs. Fire Alarms”, American Journal of Political Science 28: 165-79. Milner, Helen, and Peter B. Rosendorff. (1996) “Trade Negotiations, Information and Domestic Politics: The Role of Domestic Groups.” Economics and Politics. 8(2): 145-189. Milner, Helen, and Peter B. Rosendorff. (1997) “Democratic Politics and International Trade Negotiations: Elections and Divided Government as Constraints on Trade Liberalization.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 41(1): 117-146. Mnookin, R. H. and L.E. Susskind. (1999) Negotiating on Behalf of Others: Advice for Lawyers, Business Executives, Sports Agents, Diplomats, Politicians, and Everybody Else. Thousand Oaks, C.A.: Sage. Mo, Jongryn. (1995) “Domestic Institutions and International Bargaining: The Role of Agent Veto in Two-Level Games”. American Political Science Review. 89(4). pp 914-924. Mo, Jongryn. (1994) “The Logic of Two-Level Games with Endogenous Domestic Coalitions.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 38(3). pp 402-422. Mokken, Robert J., Diane Payne, Frans N. Stokman and Frans W. Wasseur. (2000) “Decision Context and Policy Effectuation: EU Structural Reform in Ireland”, Irish Political Studies 15: 39–61. Moravcsik, Andrew. (1998) The Choice For Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press. Moravcsik, Andrew and Kalypso Nicolaidis. (1999) “Explaining the Treaty of Amsterdam: Interests, Influence, Institutions.” Journal of Common Market Studies. 37(1): 59-85. Morgenthau, Hans J. (1973) Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace. 5th ed. New York: Knopf. Mosher, James S. (2003) „Relative Gains Concers When the Number of States in the Internatinal System Increases“, Journal of Coflict Resolution 47 (5): 642-668. Pahre, Robert. (1997) “Endogenous Domestic Institutions in Two-Level Games and Parliamentary Oversight of the European Union.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 41(1): 147-174. Pahre, Robert. (2001) “Divided Government and International Cooperation in AustriaHungary, Sweden-Norway, and the European Union.” European Union Politics. 2(2): 131-162. 18 Pollack, Mark. (2003) The Engines of European Integration. Delegation, Agency and AgendaSetting. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Pollack, Mark. (1999) “Delegation, Agency and Agenda Setting in the Treaty of Amsterdam.” European Integration Online Papers (EIOP). 3(6) http://eiop.or.at/eiop/texte/1999006a.htm Pollack, Mark. (1997) “Delegation, Agency and Agenda-Setting in the European Community”, International Organization 51 (1): 99-134. Putnam, Robert D. (1988) “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two Level Games” International Organization 42(3): 427-460. Rubinstein, Ariel. (1982) “Perfect Equilibrium in an Bargaining Model”, Econometrica 50(1): 97-110. Schelling, Thomas C. (1960) The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Schneider, Gerald and Lars-Erik Cederman. (1994) “The Change of Tide in Political Cooperation: A Limited Information Model of European Integration.” International Organization. 48(4): 633-662. Schulz, Tobias. (2003) “Explaining gains and losses in EU accession negotiations”, Paper proposal for the ECPR Conference, Marburg, September 18 to 21. Segendorff, Björn. (1998) “Delegation of Bargaining and Power”, Working Paper. Stockholm School of Economics Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance No. 248. Slapin, Jonathan. (2005) “Who is Powerful? Examining Preferences and Testing Sources of Bargaining Strength at European Intergovernmental Conferences.” Under review at European Union Politics. Snidal, D. (1991a). “Relative Gains and the Pattern of International cooperation”, American Political Science Review 85 (3): 701-726. Snidal, D. (1991b). “International cooperation among relative gains maximizers”, International Studies Quarterly 35: 387-402. Stasavage, David. (2004) “Open-Door or Closed-Door? Transparency in Domestic and International Bargaining”, International Organization 58 (4): 667-703. Stokman, Frans and Robert Thomson. (2004) “Winners and Losers in the European Union”, European Union Politics 5(1): 5-23. Strom, Kaare, W.C. Müller and T. Bergman (eds.). (2003) Delegation and Accountability in Parliamentary Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Thatcher, Mark and Alec Stone-Sweet. (2002) “Theory and Practice of Delegation to NonMajoritarian Institutions”, West European Politics 25 (1): 1-22. 19 Thomson, Robert, Frans Stokman, Christopher Achen and Thomas König (eds.). (2006) The European Union Decides. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (forthcoming). Tsebelis, George. (2002) Veto Players. How political institutions work. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Tsebelis, George. (2005) “The European Convention and the Rome and Brussels IGCs: A Veto Player Analysis”, in: König, Thomas and Simon Hug (eds), Preference Formation and European Constitution-building. A Comparative Study in Member States and Accession Countries. ECPR/Routledge Series (forthcoming). Tsebelis, George and Geoffrey Garrett (2001) ‘Even More Reasons to Resist the Temptation of Power Indices in the EU’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 13(1) 2001: 99-106. Tsebelis, George and Xenophon Yataganas. (2002) “Veto Players and Decision Making in the EU After Nice: Policy Stability and Bureaucratic/Judicial Discretion.” Journal of Common Market Studies 40(2): 283-307. Waltz, Kenneth N. (1959) Man, the State, and War: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Columbia University Press. Waltz, Kenneth N. (1979) Theory of International Politics. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. 20 Table 1: Actor types and absolute and relative gains Country Actors in dataset Conv. Dom. IGC TOTAL Austria 2 3 1 6 Belgium 2 7 1 10 Cyprus 1 2 1 4 Czech R. 2 4 1 7 Denmark 2 2 1 5 Estonia 2 3 1 6 Finland 2 4 1 7 France 2 7 1 10 Germany 2 5 1 8 Greece 2 2 1 5 Hungary 2 5 1 8 Ireland 2 3 1 6 Italy 2 8 1 11 Latvia 2 3 1 6 Lithuania 2 4 1 7 Luxembourg 2 2 1 5 Malta 2 2 1 5 Netherlands 2 3 1 6 Poland 2 2 1 5 Portugal 2 2 1 5 Slovac R. 2 4 1 7 Slovenia 2 6 1 9 Spain 2 7 1 10 Sweden 2 3 1 6 Un. Kingdom 1 7 1 9 SUM 48 100 25 173 mean max. min. per country Absolute gains Conv. Dom. IGC 0,5200 0,4815 0,5833 0,5696 0,4563 0,3611 0,5833 0,5758 0,4800 0,3344 0,5764 0,6286 0,5100 0,6111 0,4412 0,5635 0,6204 0,7778 0,5400 0,6389 0,4848 0,4486 0,5714 0,4722 0,4306 0,6222 0,6111 0,4300 0,3889 0,6111 0,5000 0,7500 0,5556 0,5083 0,6667 0,6667 0,4006 0,6597 0,5278 0,4306 0,6667 0,3889 0,4722 0,7778 0,6667 0,5556 0,6667 0,7188 0,5278 0,7500 0,4444 0,4200 0,6111 0,5882 0,3750 0,6389 0,6944 0,4722 0,5556 0,5278 0,4444 0,4583 0,4545 0,3848 0,6204 0,4857 0,3996 0,6508 0,7500 0,3889 0,6204 0,5429 0,4167 0,6151 0,6071 0,4651 0,5833 0,3344 0,6100 0,7778 0,3889 0,5628 0,7778 0,3611 country 0,5283 0,4624 0,5464 0,5131 0,5208 0,6539 0,5546 0,4974 0,5546 0,4767 0,6019 0,6139 0,5294 0,4954 0,6389 0,6470 0,5741 0,5398 0,5694 0,5185 0,4524 0,4970 0,6001 0,5174 0,5463 Conv. 0,4831 0,5441 0,6234 0,2553 0,4994 0,5591 0,4929 0,3737 0,3504 0,3614 0,4616 0,4690 0,3703 0,3620 0,4282 0,4839 0,4505 0,3645 0,3091 0,4135 0,3764 0,3227 0,3073 0,3544 0,3871 Relative gains Dom. 0,4093 0,3747 0,6395 0,5672 0,6507 0,6990 0,5958 0,5310 0,6170 0,3159 0,7081 0,7303 0,7113 0,6554 0,8147 0,6434 0,8321 0,5810 0,6418 0,5218 0,4267 0,5644 0,6300 0,6001 0,5842 IGC 0,5083 0,3493 0,4850 0,6116 0,4554 0,7722 0,4641 0,4007 0,6277 0,6233 0,5228 0,7411 0,4539 0,3776 0,6739 0,7664 0,3703 0,5243 0,7622 0,5638 0,5094 0,4721 0,7309 0,5012 0,6807 0,4161 0,6234 0,2553 0,6018 0,8321 0,3159 0,5579 0,7722 0,3493 in bold: Top ten winners per category; Country scores for Convention and domestic stages are means of the actors' scores 21 country 0,4669 0,4227 0,5826 0,4781 0,5352 0,6768 0,5176 0,4352 0,5317 0,4335 0,5641 0,6468 0,5118 0,4650 0,6389 0,6312 0,5510 0,4899 0,5710 0,4997 0,4375 0,4531 0,5561 0,4852 0,5506 Figure 1: Absolute and relative gains by stage Convention stage (1) A B S O L U T E Domestic coordination stage (2) IGC negotiation stage (3) G A I N S RELATIVE GAINS Means: Absolute gains: 0.5631; Relative gains: 0.5399 22 Figure 2: Absolute and relative gains by country 1 = Convention delegates; 2 = Domestic actors; 3 = IGC delegates 23 Means: Absolute gains: 0.5631; Relative gains: 0.5399 Table 2: Variable summaries Variable Independent Variables Absolute gains (hitrate IGC outcome) Relative gains (shares) Bargaining environment Distance to int. Mean Support (across all stages) Support (own stage) Closeness to SQ Closeness to Germany Closeness to UK Closeness to France Closeness to Commission Closeness to EP Domestic arena Size of domestic core Ratif. actor closer to SQ (dummy) Public support Multi-stage process Convention delegate (dummy) Domestic actor (dummy) Control variables Netpayer (dummy) Population Size GDP per capita Duration of membership Mean SE Min Max 0,5631 0,5399 0,1190 0,1488 0,2500 0,2077 0,8333 0,9089 0,1911 0,5401 0,5863 0,4687 0,6331 0,5844 0,6187 0,6015 0,6211 0,0313 0,0485 0,0526 0,1353 0,1060 0,1073 0,1308 0,1319 0,1107 0,1276 0,2665 0,3255 0,2000 0,2000 0,2800 0,3000 0,1250 0,2000 0,3329 0,6244 0,6748 0,8056 0,9722 1 1 0,9412 0,8611 0,3576 0,6012 0,7723 0,0587 0,4911 0,1278 0,2723 0 0,5000 0,4719 1 0,9400 0,2775 0,5780 0,4490 0,4953 0 0 1 1 0,4798 2,2477 0,9486 2,1195 0,5010 1,4634 0,3461 1,6941 0 -0,9238 0,4250 0 1 4,4132 2,1330 3,8712 24 TABLE 3: OLS Models for absolute and relative gains Model 1: absolute gains as unit of analysis Independent variables Bargaining environment Distance to int. Mean Support (across all stages) Support (own stage) Closeness to SQ Closeness to Germany Closeness to UK Closeness to France Closeness to Commission Closeness to EP Domestic arena Size of domestic core Ratif. actor closer to SQ Public support Multi-stage-process Convention delegate Domestic actor Control variables Netpayer Population Size GDP per capita Duration of membership constant adj. Rsqu. F / prob. F. N coef. s.e. p Model 2: relative gains as unit of analysis coef. s.e. p -1,8455 0,5201 0,3684 0,3031 0,0490 0,1259 -0,1921 -0,1519 -0,2330 0,3957 0,3397 0,1352 0,0423 0,0932 0,0555 0,0634 0,0887 0,1060 0,000 0,128 0,007 0,000 0,600 0,025 0,003 0,089 0,029 -2,4290 0,1497 0,3644 0,4793 0,1407 -0,0331 -0,3094 -0,3305 -0,1491 0,5569 0,4781 0,1903 0,0595 0,1312 0,0781 0,0892 0,1248 0,1491 0,000 0,755 0,057 0,000 0,285 0,672 0,001 0,009 0,319 0,1615 0,0170 0,1156 0,0701 0,0093 0,0345 0,023 0,068 0,001 0,2376 0,0320 0,1484 0,0987 0,0130 0,0485 0,017 0,015 0,003 -0,0253 -0,0194 0,0125 0,0109 0,045 0,078 -0,0439 -0,0179 0,0176 0,0154 0,014 0,245 0,0347 -0,0102 -0,0241 0,0012 0,0146 0,0041 0,0247 0,0057 0,019 0,015 0,330 0,838 0,0370 -0,0155 -0,0429 0,0071 0,0206 0,0058 0,0347 0,0080 0,074 0,008 0,218 0,377 0,4149 0,87 67,16 173 0,2116 0,051 0,7448 0,84 51,29 173 0,2972 0,013 0 25 0 Figure 3: Predicted absolute gains as closeness to bargaining mean and SQ, and support increase Figure 4: Predicted absolute gains as closeness to large states and supranational actors increases 26