Causes and Consequences of Low Prices in the Cotton Sector Aluisio de Lima-Campos Economic Advisor Embassy of Brazil in Washington Delegate of Brazil to the ICAC Conference on Cotton and Global Trade Negotiations Washington, DC July 9, 2002 Causes and Consequences of Low Prices in the Cotton Sector Aluisio de Lima-Campos Economic Advisor Embassy of Brazil Delegate of Brazil to the ICAC Conference on Cotton and Global Trade Negotiations Washington, DC July 8, 2002 Before I begin, I would like to say that I have been asked by the ICAC to address this conference on the impact of low cotton prices in the cotton sector and, in that process, report on the injury suffered, as a result of those low prices, by several producing countries. The basis of my information on injury is the collection of country reports produced by individual countries, in the context of the Working Group on Government Measures (WGGM). The Standing Committee of the ICAC established the WGGM on January of this year with the purpose of gathering more information on the effects of low cotton prices. So, these injury reports are hopefully just the begining of our work in the WGGM. That said, I would like to start by saying that it is a basic and elemental notion that lower prices for a particular commodity generate negative impacts for the producers of that commodity. It is also true in the case of cotton that lower prices are caused by a combination of factors. What is not clear, however, is whether the lower prices we have seen for cotton in the last few seasons are the result of one or more dominant factors. In attempting to answer that question, three important aspects need to be examined: the level of prices with respect to the cost of production, the length of time prices remain low and, most importantly, is the market sufficiently transparent to affect every agent the same way. I would like to review these three notions and conclude with some remarks about the impact of cotton prices on some specific countries. According to the latest Survey of the Cost of Production of Raw Cotton, published by the ICAC in September 2001, the net cost of producing one pound of cotton in countries that export the fiber, excluding land rent and seed value, ranges between 68 cents in the United States and 21 U.S. cents in Burkina Faso. Given that the present average cotton price from the Cotlook A Index is around 42 U.S. cents per pound it is easy to see why some higher-cost producers need subsidies to be competitive. According to the same survey, cotton exporting countries in Africa, Asia and Latin America have lower costs of production than industrial countries with the exception of Australia. Economic theory suggests that, in an open market, at the margin, cotton production is determined by costs. Prices tend to follow the costs of most efficient producers, and it is expected that, over time, those producers with higher costs would eventually reduce production. Yet, the experience of recent years shows that this notion has been highly distorted by government subsidies in the cotton market. There is really no rational reason for a farmer to decrease cotton production or shift into profitable crops, in response to lower cotton prices, if his or her revenues are guaranteed by government aid. This season, production in non-subsidized countries like Australia and Brazil, both among the most efficient producers, declined by 12% and 20%, respectively. In Latin America and the Caribbean production also declined, by 24% this season. In Africa, cotton production has been stagnant since 1997/98 at 1.8 million tons. In South and East Asia, excluding China (Mainland), production fell by 5%, from a peak of 5.5 million tons in 1999/00. These statistics suggest that prices are low even with respect to most efficient producers worldwide. Indeed, the Cotlook A Index, a measure of international prices, fell to 35 cents per pound in November 2001, at the height of the marketing season. While production in most developing countries and Australia has declined, production elsewhere has more than offset such declines, despite the severe weakness of prices. Production has increased so much elsewhere in the world, that it reached this season a record 21.2 million tons, after four years of prices below the long-term average. Prices today are about 42 cents per pound, still 30 cents lower than their long-term average. As indicated earlier, this is the fourth season that prices are below the longterm average of 72 cents per pound. Further, the ICAC estimates that prices are not expected to fully recover in the next few years. Despite an expected reduction of 9% in world production next season and a recovery in consumption to record highs, world stocks are not expected to decline sufficiently to move prices substantially above current levels. The ICAC expects that the Cotlook A Index is going to be still 10 to 20 cents below the long-term average in most years this decade. Low prices today can be attributed to a combination of factors. On the demand side, cotton consumption has been relatively weak during the last two years due to lower world economic growth. Nonetheless, demand for cotton is improving due to lower prices and promotion efforts. Other things being equal, according to the application of the ICAC World Textile Model to over 40 years of data, a 20% decline in prices leads to a 1% increase in cotton consumption. Since December 2000, cotton prices have declined by 32%. Thus, cotton consumption, which remained at about 19.8 million tons in the last two years, is expected to increase by 2.5% to a record 20.4 million tons in 2002/03. On the supply side, the development of new technologies, production in new cotton areas, and the strength of the U.S. dollar, have contributed to the rise in world stocks. Area dedicated to cotton from genetically engineered varieties increased from 2% of world planted area in 1996/97 to 20% today. Genetically engineered cotton can lead to higher yields by providing better pest protection, and to lower costs per hectare. The development of new areas of cotton, particularly in Central Brazil and Eastern Turkey, are also contributing to higher world cotton production. Brazilian production, for example, has recently rebounded from a record low level of 300,000 tons in 1996/1997, as a result of large private investments in high-tech production in a new production frontier (with ideal soil, topography and rainfall combination). Growing domestic consumption, which had not been met by domestic production since 1991, fueled these investments. As a result, after 10 years of lagging behind, production met domestic consumption once again in 2001, at 900,000 tons. In Turkey, new production in what is known as the GAP region accounts today for over 50% of production in the country, compared to just 25% in 1994/95. Production has also been sustained in several countries where currency devaluation with respect to the U.S. dollar has occurred. The decline of international cotton prices in dollars has been mitigated by currency devaluation, and, thus, has alleviated the income of producers in exporting countries in Africa and Latin America, as well as in Australia. The CFA Franc, the currency of Francophone Africa, devalued by 32% against the U.S. dollar between 1998 and 2001. The Brazilian real and the Colombian peso devalued by 90% and 50%, respectively, during the same period. Similarly, the Australian dollar fell in value by 16% against the U.S. dollar. This, of course, has prevented production from falling further than it has in those countries. Despite these market factors, the most dominant cause of low prices today seems to be government measures on cotton production and trade. The world cotton industry is viewed by many as one of the most transparent international commodity markets. Indeed, the cotton market has never been involved in a commodity agreement. Nonetheless, as shown in the ICAC report on Production and Trade Policies Affecting the Cotton Industry, prepared for this conference, government support programs are heavily affecting the cotton market. As indicated in that document, today 73% of world production in 14 countries is under some form of direct income or price support. Most developing countries, in compliance with the Uruguay Round of negotiations that resulted in the creation of the WTO, discontinued direct price or income support in agricultural markets during the 1990s. However, lower cotton prices during the second half of the decade, caused by the combination of factors described earlier, as well as by well established subsidy programs in industrial countries and China (Mainland), moved governments in developing countries to reinstate past subsidies. Brazil, Egypt, Mexico and Turkey, countries that had discontinued their support programs during the mid 1990s, have had to implement some form of emergency assistance to growers in order to help them cope with the situation. This season, six additional developing countries, Argentina, Benin, Colombia, Côte d’Ivoire, India and Mali, had to resort to direct assistance in order to avoid a total bankruptcy of the sector. Nonetheless, the emergency assistance being provided by these ten developing countries accounts for just 14% of assistance provided worldwide. The remaining 86%, which amounts to $4.2 billion, is provided by three industrial countries and China (Mainland). The United States and China alone, the world’s two largest producers, account for 76% of the world’s cotton production subsidies and 100% of cotton export subsidies. In dollar terms, it should be noted, cotton export subsidies pale by comparison with domestic subsidies. It is estimated by the Secretariat of the ICAC that a removal of direct subsidies worldwide would have a net positive effect of 31 cents on average cotton prices this season. In other words, in the absence of subsidies, average cotton prices would be 73 cents per pound, which is 74% higher than the 42 cents being realized this season. Since, according to the ICAC, the econometric models used to calculate this subsidy impact on prices already takes into account market factors, such as changes in demand and in non-subsidized production, this impact of 74% on prices is net of most market factors I have just discussed and thus almost entirely attributable to government subsidies. Through the Working Group on Government Measures, originated from a mandate from the ICAC’s Plenary, several member governments of the ICAC have reported their assessment of the injury caused by low cotton prices. Argentina estimates that lower prices resulted in a decline of $225 million in gross revenue per year over the last three years and that the country lost $500 million as a result of declines in exports related to lower prices during the three-year period. Brazil estimates that the injury caused by low prices this season alone is $640 million. In Colombia, the loss between 1991 and 2001 is calculated at $570 million and in India the loss in the value of production is estimated at $1.3 billion this season. The level of injury caused to producers and export dependent countries by the collapse of cotton prices is particularly severe. According to ICAC estimates, the loss to the economies of producing countries this season caused by the decline in nominal cotton prices to their lowest level in three decades is $14 billion. The accumulated loss over the last four seasons, from the same ICAC estimates, is $34 billion. Since these very high numbers do not take into account losses in employment and in related industries, these are still quite conservative estimates. Ladies and gentlemen, in conclusion to the main question raised at the beginning of my presentation, the recent dramatic decline in international cotton prices has a dominant cause and, undoubtedly, it is not a market factor. I hope that the facts discussed here today, have clearly established, to your satisfaction, that the decline in prices can unquestionably be attributed, in its greatest measure, to government subsidies, to both production and exports of cotton, in major producing countries. I would also hope to have conveyed that the injury caused by these low prices to developing countries has been significant. The future, I am sorry to say, does not look any brighter on this matter. Recent developments indicate that things are likely to get worse before they get any better. The U.S. farm bill, for example, will make an additional $180 billion in subsidies available to American farmers starting this season. Of those, according to the ICAC, based on government disbursements in previous years, 36 billion could be paid to U.S. cotton farmers over the next 10 years. If this continues, subsidy-free production in developing countries will become less and less feasible, as long as the alternative is total bankruptcy of those countries’ own cotton industries. Barring any significant change of circumstances, I am sorry to say, the present trend is going in the opposite direction of free and fair trade and towards increasing financial burdens for developing countries. As I indicated earlier, developing countries are, in general, the most cost-efficient producers of cotton and, as such, they are ready to compete fairly in the market place. And they should be allowed to do so. What they cannot do and should not attempt do is compete with developed countries’ Treasuries. Ladies and gentlemen, there is a perverse cycle in motion playing havoc with the markets. As all of us involved in cotton matters know, governments of the very top producing countries are protecting their respective domestic producers from market forces, through massive government subsidies, that are leading to higher world production and, in turn, to lower prices and then again to even higher subsidies. For the sake of a healthy world cotton industry and to alleviate the injury that is being inflicted on the economies of developing countries, I strongly suggest that we work hard and together at the regional and multilateral levels to ensure that these unfair practices are terminated for good, in the shortest feasible time. Thank you. NET COST OF PRODUCTION (Selected Countries) Cents/lb 70 35 i A us a tr al ia Eg yp A t rg en tin a Pa ki st Zi an m ba bw e B ra B ur zil ki na F. Sy r U SA 0 COTLOOK A INDEX US Cents per pound 120 100 80 60 40 20 80/81 84/85 88/89 92/93 96/97 00/01 DIRECT SUBSIDIES TO PRODUCTION IN 2001/02 er O th Eg yp t il ra z B Tu rk e y a di In EU C hi na (M U SA L) Billion U.S. dollars 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 INJURY CAUSED BY LOW COTTON PRICES (Selected Countries) Country Million U.S. Dollars Argentina Brazil Colombia India Uzbekistan $1,175 $ 640 $ 570 $1,300 $1,479 Period 1999/00-2000/01 2001/02 1991-2001 2001/02 1998-2001