Synergy of Government and Nongovernmental Bodies Involvement in Monitoring and Evaluation The presentation dwells on short falls and positive effects of country led evaluation systems based on a survey of monitoring and evaluation (M&E) procedures under two types of projects being implemented by Ministry of Labor and Social Policy. The EU Pre-Accession and International Projects Directorate with the ministry is in charge of PHARE projects. For the current financial year the PHARE Program amounts to EUR 40 m round. Currently the Bulgarian Social Investment Fund (BSIF) with the same ministry runs a development World Bank and Labor Ministry joint project named Social Investment and Employment Promotion Project of total capitalization of EUR 66.7 m. These specific projects with a single ministry help us sample the M&E process with all the development projects of the WB and PHARE funded projects on the national scale. The ultimate goal of M&E process is to present to beneficiaries and stakeholders a fair and unbiased perception of project progress achieved. Progress measures with the extent which the original project goals have been achieved to. On operational level the goals to be achieved are commonly presented under the form of Goal Matrix based on benchmark indicators (key performance indicators). Effectiveness of M&E process measures with consistency of the fundamentals which are principles, regulations and organizational arrangements set up with managing authorities and beneficiaries. Effective M&E process attempts to follow principles that are inherent to each effective organization dealing with public funds: transparency; objectivity; centralization-vs-decentralization; delegation; accountability, coordination-vscommunication. Strike an effective balance between centralization and decentralization of data collection, analysis and finally, decision making is topical to setting up the M&E institutional framework. Duly abiding by principles and institutional framework is incumbent upon government, non-government bodies and specific projects’ management units. Strike an effective balance between them is a challenge. It relates to the strategic issue of institutionalizing M&E. Actually a complex matrix of responsibilities evolves where a variety of interests commingle. That could prove counter productive to effective M&E. What generally is needed is a good political will and general competence of the central authority to allow for implementing the arrangements that had been reckoned relevant. Challenges to M&E Effectiveness The mainstay of issues to be considered is secure M&E effectiveness through involving outside, ie, non-government bodies. Why is that topical? 1 1) Including outside bodies stands for an integral and autonomous M&E structure which does not necessarily follow the administrative (functional) line structures. The problem points to avoiding administrative weaknesses through overcoming the inevitable restrictions of communication. There exists a formal, meaning depersonalized and legally bound, set of relationships. Expertise is critical to administrations that are vertically integrated. What happens to M&E effectiveness in the instances of poor coordination and narrow technical expertise? Obviously M&E process endures serious short falls due to lack of balance between communication and coordination. Communication loses effectiveness which is concomitant to poor analytical value of the final M&E produce. 2) Unlike decision making M&E needs intensive communication on the account of coordination, ie, on the account of mitigating the harshest effects of a rigid line administration. The functional organizational structure becomes less effective and irrelevant when a ministry’s administration diversifies its programs endeavoring to cover broader beneficiaries’ needs. M&E could be likened to a specific function that for the sake of its effectiveness needs more autonomy within the classic and, I am afraid, obsolete for project management, administrative structure. It is well known from management that in order to overcome these shortfalls in communication and coordination divisional structure is put forward. It would allow M&E process to assume an autonomous discretion and institutional framework within a distinct administrative entity, be it ministry’s directorate, project management unit or like. In a word, delegation of power to outside M&E bodies would allow for introducing flat M&E structure as a counterweight to the rigid line administrative structure. 3) Apart from the above including outside bodies stands for 1) a larger participation of beneficiaries’ organization; 2) building capacity at local level. 4) Therefore, increasing effectiveness and efficiency of M&E would call for overcoming the deficiencies of the centralized line administration without challenge it. The latter implies as well decentralization of data collection, processing, analysis and decision making as a direct effect of instituting more or less flat administrative structure earmarked for M&E. But is it possible to decentralize M&E within the official structures? Two patterns of M&E organization that had been adopted for the PHARE funded project and SIEP Project help answer the question. 2 M&E Patterns: PHARE Program with the Labor Ministry EU Pre-Accession and International Projects Directorate Financial Department - Financial Coordinator - Technical Coordinator -financial Controller (Representative of the State Agency for Internal financial Control) M&E Unit in charge of operational monitoring Regional Level (28 Regional Coordinators) Beneficiary Level M&E Patterns: SIEP Project Steering Committee Based on Tri-Partite Principle Executive Director Departments Technical Financial Advisory Services Legal Advisor M&E Coordinator Local Level Monitoring – By Competitively Selected Private Inspection Companies Local Communities and Municipalities LocalLevel Level–(Communities & Municipalities) 3 Both M&E patterns evidence a high level of centralization of communication and decision making regarding M&E, in particular. Primarily, that is because the M&E arrangements follow the line functional structures of the respective official institutions. Is it possible under these circumstances to decentralize M&E within the official structures? I am afraid the answer is “no” because: 1) Both development projects and EU funded projects have been designed, planned and implemented at the Government’s discretion. They are Government led projects and intend to meet challenges the Government reckons relevant. The respective Government institutions are supposed to have justified their relevance to the donors. 2) M&E is a multi-faceted process but financial/accounting audit plays the leading role within it. By rule financial audit is centralized because the official institutions which are in charge of project implementation use their own centralized bodies for this purpose. Save of institutional financial control a heavily centralized national body which is the State Agency for Internal Financial Control enforces and institutes a centralized pyramidal pattern of financial control. 3) Lack of integrated to the Labor Ministry’s (or whatever else ministry being in charge of PHARE project or development project implementation) Management Information System (MIS) poses serious problems to M&E. Integrated MIS is a stepping stone for designing more complex organizational structures allowing for both flat M&E institutional arrangements and coordinated data analysis and decision making based on the ministry’s administrative regulations. When imbedded in a ministry’s communication and decision making regulations individual data collection and subsequent analysis for the purposes of M&E can not be but centralized. The issue of M&E information sharing evolves as well. The official bodies run a variety of projects of specific individual M&E arrangements but for the sake of political expediency the use of information produced has been always subjected to huge centralization. It would not be physically possible to uphold a flat structured M&E system based on decentralized data processing and analysis and centralized data release arrangements. The other way round, centralization of compound data use services as a sort of justification for centralizing the entire M&E process. 4 Evidences and Lessons Learned 1) Mechanical divide between financial and technical monitoring is available. Financial monitoring is formal; technical monitoring is substantial. Evaluating projects’ impact requests integrity of both formal and substantial approaches. There is more to M&E effectiveness than financial accountability. Sometime perfect financial accountability can prove a shield for technical, ie, substantial improprieties (poor quality, poor beneficiary need identification, cost inefficient project appraisal, inflated administrative costs, short falls in attaining critical performance indicators etc.). M&E procedures are being based on a clear-cut goal matrix and performance indicators. Gauging headway made against them entails sound analytical work that requests specialized professional skills. The below presented SIEP Project Key Performance Indicators sample the requirement of integrated analysis of technical and financial individual information. The synergy impact on reducing poverty and generating sustainable jobs is equally due to financial efficiency and accountability, capacity building with vulnerable communities, and instituting sustainable patterns of project implementation and follow-through. Gauging progress against such indicators as Number of Community Based Organizations Established and Number of Partnerships with Private and Public Institutions Established relates to the very process of identification, facilitation and training local communities and their local organizations. Working with a pre-set number of formal indicators implies introducing many other informal or supporting indicators. For instance, counting the number of Community Based Organizations implies defining the scope and specifics of local community which is per se analytical work. We fall in the same situation when measuring the level of satisfaction of infrastructure rehabilitated with local communities and municipalities. Key Performance Indicators (accomplishment as of July 2005) № 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 7.1 8 8.1 Indicators Reduced L/T Poverty in the Targeted Poor Communities Number of Beneficiaries Number of Municipality Infrastructure Microprojects Number of Community Based Microprojects Number of Municipality SubProjects Completed Number of Community SubProjects Completed Project Cost (BGN) – Additional Resources to Poor Communities Community Project Cost (BGN) – Additional Resources to Poor Communities Contract Cost Community Contract Cost Average Total Targeted 16.36 Accomplishment 15.67 104.39 99,133,003.00 72.4 432,840.00 321.00 55.00 174.00 224,301.87 71,776,598.11 125,199.94 196,382.01 99,240.75 6,885,996.59 60,682,040.47 5,458,241.12 5 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 Percentage of Poor Communities/Municipalities Targeted Unemployment Rate in Targeted Poor Communities/Municipalities Number of Beneficiaries Cost/Beneficiary Percentage of Effective Microprojects Number of Effective Microprojects Out of Them: Municipality MP Out of Them: Community Based Duration (month) Mandays Number of employees Cost/employee Long Term Unemployed Labor Content Percentage of Microproject Wage Payments Going to Unskilled Workers % Average Gross salary Average Gross salary to National Average % Number of Municipalities Participating Number of Community Based Organizations Established Number of Partnerships with Private and Public Institutions Established Administrative Costs as % of Project Expenditures B.A. (satisfaction%) Level of satisfaction of local infrastructure (%) Satisfaction of local authorities’ responsiveness Correspondence to citizens' priorities Project disbursement (loan) 29.33 23.64 17.21 137.36 700,000.00 92.42 25.00 117.96 99,356,164.00 36.13 432,840.00 179.20 36.01 3.85 2,015.43 17.45 12,617.82 3.49 29.49 376.00 321.00 55.00 1,446.00 646,954.62 5,601.64 1,120.33 19.05 294.54 101.22 376.00 0.24 35,894,041.33 Source: SIEP Project Appraisal Document and MIS 2) The above stands for a comprehensive M&E process covering all the project cycle. There is no specialized body to monitor and evaluate the effectiveness of each of the phases of the Project Cycle under the projects in questions. M&E specialists either organized in special unit or single-handedly enter the game too late when in the implementation and hand-over phases possible flaws of the previous phases may make themselves felt. For instance poor community identification and facilitation necessarily entails ineffective capacity building and thus, poor project sustainability, let apart dubious financial accountability and control by the community itself. 3) Regarding individual data collection and on-site control M&E effectiveness is additionally smothered by the centralized pyramidal project managing authorities’ administrations. It is not accidental when beneficiaries lack capacity to institute their own M&E procedures. In order to overcome this deficiency official M&E procedures 6 should be complemented with beneficiaries’ own monitoring system. Had both monitoring systems been formally integrated a true synergy of institutional and informal, ie beneficiaries’, monitoring efforts would have been attained. 4) In my understanding M&E should commence with planning and designing a relevant goal matrix based on strategic sector priorities (poverty reduction, sustainable employment generation, social inclusion of vulnerable minorities etc.). In a word M&E should be initially imbedded in project planning attempting to track down whether project goal matrix has been tailored to relevant beneficiaries’ needs. Unfortunately this is not the case so far. Planning is far from being perfect. First, there is a mechanical divide between financial (commissioned to the Finance Ministry) and substantial planning (which falls in the ambit of line ministries); second, local communities in their capacity of direct beneficiaries are not present at all. 5) Therefore, planning relevant goal matrices proves topical to the overall project performance. Obviously a line-ministry’s bodies should take the lead as early as the project fiche/project appraisal document is being prepared. But involvement of nongovernment bodies is strongly recommended, especially when the goal matrix is to be set up. Instituting a consistent way of planning target strategies and goal matrices where government and non-government bodies are represented on equal footing is a task of immediate precedence. Within this context the big issue of who the planning authority should be arises. 6) But even though we stay in the scope of formal/official M&E procedure it becomes obvious that the monitoring process has not been fully institutionalized. M&E complements project implementation rather than to be an autonomous process which is incumbent upon a specialized formal structure which is committed to monitoring the whole project cycle. 7) M&E system has not been comprised in an integrated Management Information System (MIS) so far. The SIEP Project’s MIS made a steady progress with this regard where its M&E Module had been linked to the other modules. Thus, on-line information on the project’s current status is available. But generally viewed, integration of individual projects’ MIS to line-ministries’ one is a challenge far from having been satisfactorily tackled so far. 8) The above mentioned types of projects evidence both short falls and strengths in view of centralization and decentralization of M&E. Centralization of information flows allows for expedient data processing and minimizing data distortion due to vested interests and lack of expertise. The relevant principle to be followed with this regard is first, elaboration of as simple as possible measurable indicators (mandays created, long term unemployed hired, wage earned etc.) to be covered with individual 7 data by local bodies, local communities inclusive; and second, centralization of data collection and processing. Involving private companies specialized in monitoring and control is strongly recommended at least at the initial stage of data collection. Decentralization allows for involving beneficiaries to take part in data processing and project evaluation on local and regional level. But securing similarity of data compilation and interpretation stays a challenge under this system. 9) The main source of restrictions to instituting a more flexible project management system, M&E arrangements in particular, stems from the formal nature of EU and WB funded projects. Primarily, they have been demanded by the government and, thus, they play instrumental role to its overall policy toward meeting the EU standards. The main contradiction lies in the incapacity of the official authorities to set strategy apart from operational matters. Having a hold on strategic issues (defining Target and Allocation Strategies, project capitalization, defining Goal Matrix etc.), and rightly, the official institutions feel obliged to keep their hold on operation management too. The only way to do so is commissioning operational project management, M&E in particular, to their line administrations, which the least is not cost efficient. Alternatives 1) Radical Alternative. It takes stock from the fact that M&E has not been fully institutionalized. Deficiencies of the now existing M&E systems that have been evidenced by the above projects stand for an autonomous M&E bodies where Government, Non-Government and private sector are represented on equal footing. In this way final beneficiaries would be much more effectively enabled to have a say on project implementation. But the line-ministries should keep their lead since the projects in question service primarily Government priorities and budget commitments. The M&E bodies would be involved in the whole Project Cycle along with the official institutions. The M&E bodies would develop flat administrative structure which is conducive to more effective communication and individual data collection. M&E should integrate financial and substantial (technical) audit/monitoring. Possible risk and weakness is the administration of integrated MIS and coordination of data processing and analysis, in particular. 2) Realistic Alternative. It takes stock from the centralized way EU and international development projects, mostly WB funded, have been planned and implemented so far by the state administration. This pattern of project financing persists. The only way to avoid the subsequent flaws is outsourcing. Outsourcing M&E services with independent private bodies would mitigate the negative effects of centralization of communication and knowledge sharing. Primarily this 8 would provide M&E with own quasi-autonomous administrative structure which would be free enough to set up formal relationships with beneficiaries’ monitoring bodies. Blagovest Georgiev 9