Lia Quartapelle Procopio Master in Economics Programmes with reference to Africa 164164 Dissertation General Budget Support as Conditional Aid. The Case of Mozambique. This dissertation is submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree MSc Economics Programmes with reference to Africa of the School of Oriental and African Studies (University of London). Thursday, 15th of September 2005. I have read and understood regulation 17.9 (Regulations for Students of SOAS) concerning plagiarism. I undertake that all material presented for examination is my own work and has not been written for me, in whole or in part, by any other person(s). I also undertake that any quotation or paraphrase from the published or unpublished work of another person has been duly acknowledged in the work which I present for examination. I give permission for a copy of my dissertation to be held at the School’s discretion, following final examination, to be made available for reference. Word Count: 8781 Table of contents Abstract 1. Introduction 2. Budget Support in context: the failure of aid 4 5 7 2.1 Aid effectiveness disputed 7 2.2 Aid modalities disputed 8 2.2.1 The failure of conditionality 10 2.3 Consequences of the debate on the current practice of aid 11 3. The shift to Budget Support 12 3.1 Definition of Budget Support 12 3.2 Why a shift to supporting the budget 12 3.3 The flows to Budget Support 14 4. General Budget Support in Mozambique 17 4.1 Why Mozambique? 17 4.1.1 Donors-government relationship 17 4.1.2 Poverty in Mozambique as factor towards Budget Support 19 4.1.3 “O Plano de Acção para a Reducção da Pobreza Absoluta” 20 4.2 How General Budget Support is carried out in Mozambique 22 4.3 Aid flows to General Budget Support in Mozambique 23 5. The model 27 5.1 Actors and choices 28 5.2 Interactions and outcomes: a repeated game 33 6. Application of the model to General Budget Support in Mozambique 36 6.1 Assessing the model 36 6.1.1 Strengths 36 6.1.2 Weaknesses 37 6.2 Reasons underlying the limitations of the model 38 6.3 Further implications of the model 40 7. Conclusion 42 References 44 List of tables and figures Figure 1. Aid and growth in Africa Figure 2. Budget Support by Sectors for DFID Figure 3. Total GBS and BoP support to Mozambique 2003-2006 Figure 4. GBS and BoP support over the years for PAPs Figure 5. Share of DBS and BoP support by donors in 2005 Figure 6. The function h Figure 7. The game tree Figure 8. The pay-off matrix Table 1. Commitment to BS and SWAps Table 2. Mozambique position with the Fund 1 7 15 24 25 26 29 32 33 15 17 Abstract The paper investigates the recourse to General Budget Support (GBS) within the debate on ownership and conditionality, using a game theoretic approach. The model built to represent the power relationship between a generic group of donors and a recipient government shows that this form of aid is more conditional for the recipient, since GBS reduces the defection pay-off open to the recipient. The model is then assessed against a case-study, Mozambique. The analysis on the implementation of GBS in this country highlights that GBS is not as a conditional form of aid as modellised, since the Government of Mozambique has been allowed some slippage in the past. It is suggested that the model could be modified to include a more complex view of compliance and a more precise representation of the equilibria characterising the donor-recipient relationship. 1. Introduction The history of aid-giving is characterised by recurring cycles of dissatisfaction with aid doctrines and modalities. The ‘90s have seen an increasingly pessimistic approach to aid disbursements. Budget Support (BS) is the current solution proposed to contrast what the debate of the ‘90s has identified as the double failure of conditional aid: low coercion exercised through conditionality and the lack of recipient ownership of the policies tied to aid. My research aims to assess the effects and consequences of the recourse to BS. I intend to respond to the question “How ‘conditional’ General Budget Support is compared to policy-based lending?” My hypothesis is that while the rhetoric suggests that BS promotes country ownership, it was in fact devised in order to increase donors’ bargaining power on the destination of aid vis-à-vis the recipient’s ability to use the funds for its own intentional purposes. The research will employ a simple game-theoretic approach. Policy-based lending has been extensively studied game theoretically and this offers a good starting point for comparison. The study will be conducted against the experience of Mozambique, which has become the showcase for BS. Through the model I have found that BS is a more conditional form of aid in so far as it encourages the recipient government to stick to the conditions attached to the disbursements. However, the comparison of the model with what occurs in the practice of BS in Mozambique identifies that this aid modality gives the Government of Mozambique some space for outmanoeuvring the donors. This is in part determined by specific country characteristics, and partly by the fact that BS as an aid modality creates a situation akin to a nuclear threat. The analysis suggests the recourse to BS might encourage collusion. The paper will be structured as follows: section 2 provides a background of the literature reviewing policy-based aid and contributing to the shift of the aid doctrine towards BS. Part 3 defines BS, identifies its characteristics responding to the shortages outlined in Part 2 and quantifies the aid flows disbursed through BS. Part 4 outlines the context of the case study, Mozambique. Part 5 presents an extensive form game model that re-elaborates the 2 hypotheses of analogous models of aid relationships and represents the interactions between donors and a recipient government under BS. Part 6 assesses the findings of our model against the contingency of BS implementation in Mozambique. Part 7 concludes. 2. Budget Support in context: the failure of aid The shift to BS can be seen as a response to the aid doctrine characterising the second half of the ‘90s (Kanbur, 2003). This period sees an ensuing aid fatigue on the donors’ side1 accompanied by a generalised dissatisfaction with the concept and practice of aidgranting, the main questions concerning the interrelated assessments of the effectiveness of aid and the appropriateness of the modality of disbursements. 2.1 Aid effectiveness disputed The mid-‘90s aid fatigue is seen as a response to the disturbing relationship between aid and growth in Figure 1. Figure 1. Aid and growth in Africa (10 year moving average). Source: Easterly (2002:11). As a tentative explanation to this relationship, a part of the academia developed a debate on aid effectiveness. The 1997 paper by Burnside and Dollar (BD) for the World Bank, is the most controversial contribution to the debate. BD claim aid to be ineffective for growth but for in a “good policy” environment, defined as a mixture of fiscal, monetary and trade policies. Collier and Dollar (1999) extend these findings to a poverty-efficient allocation of aid. Besides the serious challenges that BD have faced, regarding the employment of econometric techniques (Rajan and Subramanian, 2005), the choice of data and specification (Roodman, 2003; Easterly et al, 2003), the paper is noteworthy because it identifies policies as the key determinant of aid effectiveness. This conclusion has influenced the behaviours of bilateral donors, that now base their disbursements on selectivity. 1 According to Round and Odedokun (2003), aid volumes in real terms in the years 1990-99 have decreased by 4.4% with respect to the previous decade. 3 The pessimistic outlook on aid effectiveness is challenged by some academics, the most prominent being Jeffrey Sachs. Sachs (2001) argues, along an established tradition, that certain countries are blocked in a poverty trap that can be broken only by a generous and immediate surge in aid. To evaluate Sachs’ ideas it is important to consider that large aid inflows generally bring about distortions on the recipient economy2. Sachs seem to neglect these concerns; his position is therefore to be considered more cautiously. 2.2 Aid modalities disputed The debate on aid effectiveness is closely linked to that on the effectiveness of the disbursing mechanisms of the ‘80s and ‘90s, project aid and financial programming. This second debate stems from the recognition that a part of aid ineffectiveness was a consequence of the mechanisms of disbursement. The criticism to project aid was fairly shared amongst academia. Project aid was criticised 3 because it “contributed to the fragmentation of development assistance” (Zoomers, 2005:1): the recipient country was flooded with uncoordinated donor projects, that hardly corresponded to the recipient preferences and priorities. Projects would address only specific areas and prevented the development of an integrated strategy, thus not tackling the problems with policies that many, especially within the “Washington consensus”, regarded as the chief obstacle to development. Project administrative requirements burdened the recipient administration which was so overwhelmed to avoid developing an internal capacity to design and implement autonomous interventions. Finally, projects lacked sustainability and promoted corruption. Financial programming was even more extensively under review, both from the left and the right, for its content and the consequences of its modus operandi. The critiques from the right focussed on the excessive number of conditionality and on the excessively broad operational field of the IFIs. The critiques from the left were two-folded. On the one side, the inadequacies of the economic and technical contents of financial programming were pointed out. Under review were: the disregard of side-effects (Cornia et al, 1987), the lack of an analysis of the structural differences characterising the economy of developing countries (Taylor, 1997) and the absence of serious concerns with poverty issues (Fine and Hailu, 2002). On the other side, the way financial programming was forced upon recipient countries and the consequences of this mechanism were considered. Under review were the political economy of implementation of the recipient country (van de Walle, 2001), the relationship between donors and recipients (Mosley et al, 1995), the mechanism of conditionality (Collier et al, 1997) and the related issue of ownership (Helleiner, 2000a). 2.2.1 The failure of conditionality One particular aspect of financial programming that was extensively analysed and that has an important role on the design of Budget Support is conditionality. Conditionality was devised as a compulsive instrument to enforce the recipient government in adopting policies that, from the donors’ perspective, would make the repayment of the development loan more likely. Conditionality then became a device used to force the adoption of policies that the lender saw as beneficial for the borrower (Mosley et al, 1995). 2 These can be exchange rate appreciation, Dutch disease effects, disincentives for the fiscal system, promotion of corruption, aid dependence, fungibility. 3 Project aid had already been reviewed and in part substituted within the multilaterals at the time of the debt crisis of the ‘80s and the shift to financial programme assistance (Mosley and Eeckhout, 2000). 4 The literature has analysed thoroughly both the policy content of conditionality 4 and the effectiveness of this instrument as a coercive device (Drazen, 2000 for a literature review). While some authors argue that conditionality is an instrument owned equally by donors and recipients, the reality of the implementation of conditionality tells us a different story: the World Bank itself (in Mosley et al, 1995) recognises that only about 60% of the conditionality attached to its loans have been implemented. This inadequacy has been explained with exogenous factors5, the nature of conditionality6, the low level of recipient ownership of policy reforms (Killick et al, 1998), the interaction with debt overhang (Sachs, 1989), the presence of a third party interests (Kanbur, 2000; Villanger, 2003), the system of incentives on the recipient side (Svensson, 2000b). The literature suggests that conditionality fails because donors and recipients have diverging aims that create a conflict of interests (Killick, 1997; 1998, Mosley et al, 1995; White and Morrissey, 1997). In particular, donors are torn between the necessity to “push aid out of the door” (Drazen, 2000; Easterly, 2002; Mosley et al, 1995) and the need to spend it efficiently, while recipients are constrained by their political economy, internal divisions (Mosley, 1992) and rent seeking appetites of the elites (Svensson, 2000a). 2.3 Consequences of the debate on the current practice of aid The aid doctrine of the ‘90s suggests that aid ineffectiveness is connected to the failure of conditionality in promoting good policies and sustaining their virtuous interaction with aid disbursements. Conditionality in particular failed because the diverging aims of donors and recipients lowered their coercive power. These findings motivated the rethinking of the mechanisms of disbursements. The new aid modality devised is Budget Support, which combines efficiency in disbursements and a more substantial form of conditionality. On the one side, BS is linked to the Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs), which strengthen the recipient’s commitment to policies and donors’ command over these policies. On the other side, BS includes strict mechanisms of expenditure reviews which should ensure a more effective control on the efficiency of aid expenditures. BS is chosen since it buys donors ‘a seat at the policy table’, aligning recipient policies and practices to donors’ preferences. 3. The shift to Budget Support 3.1 Definition of Budget Support According to the definition given by OPM and ODI in their 2002 report “Direct Budget Support refers to the channelling of donor funds to a partner government using its own allocation, procurement and accounting systems”. Direct Budget Support (DBS) can be carried out in three ways: Sector Budget Support (SBS), General Budget Support (GBS) and BS using the resources resulting from debt forgiveness (Mosley and Eeckhout, 2000). Some definitions do not include this last element in DBS, while some others differ in how they consider SBS. 4 Kanbur (2003) argues that the contents of the policies at the basis of conditionality depend directly on the state of the development doctrine. 5 Part of the conditionality were not implemented because the country suffered from external shocks or unforeseen events that changed its economic situation completely. 6 As explained by Mosley et al (1995) and by Kanbur (2003) conditionality can be possible or impossible to implement, and pro forma and correspondingly its implementation can be easier or more difficult. 5 This research, being concerned specifically with the relationship between donors and recipient, will concentrate on GBS7. GBS is financial assistance provided directly to the overall state budget and administered by the Ministry of Finance. GBS disbursements are connected to the preparation of a PRSP, to be approved by the donors. 3.2 Why a shift to supporting the budget It should be noted that GBS is not a completely innovative mechanism: it is the new generation form of financial programme assistance (FPA), whose defining inputs are funds and policy dialogue (White, 1999). FPA started off with IMF stabilisation and WB structural adjustment packages. Bilateral donors did not use as much FPA but they often linked their disbursements to the satisfaction of IFIs criteria and sometimes they added the surplus of their yearly budget to the BWIs funds. The first modality of BS to be elaborated as a response to the shortcomings of the ‘80s FPA was SBS, to be followed by GBS. GBS and SBS are the latest incarnation of FPA and are very similar to its previous forms, since they are all a way to provide forex to the recipient government 8. However, this similarity is limited, since BS focuses on “fiscal behaviour and budgetary mechanisms” (White, 1999:31). This allows an increase in government empowerment, ownership and accountability, in the predictability of funding and state effectiveness (ODI and OPM 2002) compared to other forms of FPA and bilateral assistance. GBS also reduces transactions costs and enhances donor coordination. The recipient benefits from being in a partnership with the donors (Axelrod, 2001) and from being able to reduce the administrative burden (Killick et al, 2005). Finally, GBS is linked to the PRSP mechanism which helps considerably the recipient to take more immediate, organic and strategic actions for poverty reduction than macroeconomic adjustment (Healey and Killick, 2000). Despite the fact that GBS implies a high fiduciary risk and that most studies commissioned by donor organisations outline the advantages accruing especially to the recipient government, there are advantages accruing to the donors as well. This modality was chosen by donors with the specific intent of bypassing the main problem with conditionality: that of not being able to influence adequately the policies of the recipient government. Considering GBS from the viewpoint of donors’ practice rather than the rhetoric (Helleiner, 2000b), it is clear that many elements of GBS correspond to donors’ preferences: the focus on poverty disguises the strictly orthodox content of the macroeconomic measures contained in the PRSP, the selectivity of the PRSP mechanism represents a stronger way to enforce donors’ priorities and wishes while the innovative mechanism reduces recipient alternative strategies for funding, thus increasing its dependence from a block of like-minded donors. This is further confirmed by Cordella and Dell’Ariccia (2003) who suggest that, under certain conditions, donors are more effective in promoting their idea of development through GBS rather than project aid. This is confirmed by several donor studies which show that reaching the ‘rhetoric aims’ of increasing ownership, targeting the poor and empowering the government is not a straightforward process, once GBS is in place. There is need for additional measures geared to those aims, yet to be put in place. This is an indication that the shift from conditionality to partnership is not yet completed because of donors’ priorities. 3.3 The flows to Budget Support 7 SBS, being an intermediate step from project assistance to GBS, is not considered, since it seems that donors are oriented to move their funding from SBS to GBS. 8 This similarity is clear in the data given by the Programme Aid Partnership for Mozambique, which register all the funds going to GBS and BoP under the same entry. 6 BS is being adopted by an increasing number of donors and applied to different countries. The donor groups for BS comprise on average eight donors, sometimes including the WB, but not the IMF, that can nonetheless be an observer (Driscoll et al, 2005). Usually, BS contributes to 15-20% of total government expenditures for the recipient9. Table 1 shows the commitment to BS and sector approach for the EU countries. It is clear from the table that almost the totality of donors uses sector approach and that there is a move towards BS: the more ‘progressive’ donors, which provide the highest share of ODA, are highly committed to this modality. It should be noted that internal factors can influence the choice over the disbursing form (as described by White (1999) for Sweden). This suggests that some countries in the table could be restrained from moving to BS by internal reasons. Table 1. Commitment to Budget Support and Sector Approach for the European countries in 2003. Country Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden UK EU Net ODA/ EU ODA 1,9 3,4 5,8 1,5 17,2 18,3 0,9 1,2 7 0,5 11,6 1,1 6,1 6,5 16,9 na Commitment to BS Low Low High High High Low … High Low Low High Low Low High High High Support to sector approach yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes yes no yes yes yes yes Source: EU Donor Atlas (2004). Author’s elaboration. Figure 2 shows how for a donor committed to programme assistance, as DFID, the share of GBS (the economic sector of BS) has increased vis-à-vis the other sectors of PA. 9 Mozambique, Malawi, and Uganda are an exception because they receive around 30% of the government spending. 7 Figure 2. Budget Support by Sectors for DFID. Source, www.dfid.gov.uk. The data provided illustrate that donors are increasingly more committed to BS and that within the shift to this form of FPA donors are increasingly adopting GBS. This is motivated by the comparative advantages of BS and GBS that offset the high fiduciary risk and fungibility. The donors’ main reason for shifting to this aid modality is the belief it constitutes a more effective way of employing funds within a fruitful policy dialogue. 4. General Budget Support in Mozambique 4.1 Why Mozambique? Budget Support is a form of aid which is applied selectively to certain countries, since it is connected with a high fiduciary risk and requires the country to be eligible for the Enhanced HIPC Initiative and to have prepared a sound PRSP that would guarantee an efficient use of resources for poverty reduction. This chapter reviews and describes the characteristics that make Mozambique eligible for GBS. 4.1.1 Donors-government relationship The relationship between donors and the Government of Mozambique (GoM) is long and trustful. Mozambique entered the IMF in 1984, started borrowing from the IFIs in 1987 and since then the relationship has been continuative. 8 Table 2. Mozambique position with the Fund. Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility/ Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility Structural Adjustment Facility/Trust Fund General Resources Account Year Purchases Loans Charges Paid Disbursements Repurchases Disbursements Repayments Total Purchases and Loans Interest Paid Disbursements Repayments Charges and Interest Paid 2005 0 0 0 1,620,000 8,400,000 309,263 1,620,000 8,400,000 309,263 2004 0 0 0 1,620,000 15,330,000 675,645 1,620,000 15,330,000 675,645 2003 0 0 0 8,400,000 14,810,000 728,323 8,400,000 14,810,000 728,323 2002 0 0 0 8,400,000 17,130,000 768,698 8,400,000 17,130,000 768,698 2001 0 0 0 8,400,000 20,975,000 810,727 8,400,000 20,975,000 810,727 2000 0 0 0 45,200,000 22,155,000 821,600 45,200,000 22,155,000 821,600 1999 0 0 0 21,000,000 22,820,000 1,122,137 21,000,000 22,820,000 1,122,137 1998 0 0 0 25,200,000 18,067,926 355,908 25,200,000 18,067,926 355,908 1997 0 0 0 25,200,000 10,980,000 693,651 25,200,000 10,980,000 693,651 1996 0 0 0 12,600,000 22,497,074 1,028,497 12,600,000 22,497,074 1,028,497 1995 0 0 0 0 9,455,000 729,087 0 9,455,000 729,087 1994 0 0 0 14,700,000 7,320,000 682,907 14,700,000 7,320,000 682,907 1993 0 0 0 15,250,000 4,270,000 601,201 15,250,000 4,270,000 601,201 1992 0 0 0 45,750,000 1,220,000 211,418 45,750,000 1,220,000 211,418 1991 0 0 0 30,500,000 0 463,896 30,500,000 0 463,896 1990 0 0 0 9,150,000 0 215,506 9,150,000 0 215,506 1989 0 0 0 12,200,000 0 166,538 12,200,000 0 166,538 1988 0 0 0 18,300,000 0 52,084 18,300,000 0 52,084 1987 0 0 0 12,200,000 0 34,094 12,200,000 0 34,094 Source: http://www.imf.org/external/country/MOZ/index.htm. Bilateral relations had started earlier but it is from the opening towards the IFIs that they got under way: in 1987 the abandonment of the Marxist way towards capitalism brought a surge in disbursements that since would be generally generous and prompt. In fact, disbursements to Mozambique, in the face of the situation determined by the civil war and of general compliance10 with IFIs criteria (World Bank, 1994), have generally been punctual, apart from the IMF in 1995 (Hanlon, 1996), which shows the trustfulness of the rapport. For example, recently disbursements have only once been withheld for a few months, during the 2002 bank scandal, which got a rapid and, from the donors’ viewpoint, satisfactory response. The quick response that the GoM has been able to give to any change in donors priorities, together with the mostly honest use of funds (Hanlon, 2002), the commitment to the programmes signed and the good results in terms of growth have managed to build the reputation of Mozambique as a star performer. 10 The World Bank 1994 Report on adjustment in Africa argues that Mozambique is a very poor performer for what concerns macroeconomic policies and civil sector reforms. Instead, it is a good performer on market liberalisation and on state enterprise divestiture. 9 This reputation is closely intertwined with the essential role donors have played in certain important times of the life of the country, such as during the civil war, in the delicate stages of the reconstruction after the war and after the devastating 2000-2001 floods. All these successful interventions have legitimised the credibility of donors actions: Mozambique is one of the few cases of a satisfactory intervention of peace-building and, together with Uganda and few other countries in Sub-Saharan Africa, is an example of how the donors are crucial for the success of poverty reduction actions. The relationships with donors, despite that they have generally been easy and by and large satisfactory for both sides, have been extensively criticised as a form of imperialism (Hanlon, 1991). While the GoM attempted to demonstrate its independence by implementing autonomously some reforms, as it did with the structural adjustment packages in 1984 and 1987, and in 1999 with the PARPA (Plano de Acção para a Reducção da Pobreza Absoluta, GoM 2001), the fact these were all immediately approved and financed by the IFIs, suggests that the writing up was closely followed by the IFIs (Fozzard, 2002). Therefore, it can be said that the relationship between the two has been trouble-free given the weak bargaining power of the GoM. This could motivate the easiness behind the donors decision to enter BS with Mozambique. Hanlon (2002) argues that the good GoM-donors relationship can be explained also with the fact that “Mozambique has become a donor playground, and the Mozambican elite has become highly skilled at giving the donors what they want”: while the donors believe to have captured the Mozambican state, the Mozambican elite has played on this sense of security in order to obtain concessions from the donors over slippages on the use of aid. This hypothesis has acquired further consistency during the bank scandal (Fauvet and Mosse, 2003). 4.1.2 Poverty in Mozambique as factor towards Budget Support The actions of the international community in Mozambique are determined by the difficult conditions of the country. Ravaged by a bloody war that ended in 1994, Mozambique begun a process of economic growth temporarily halted by the 2000-2001 floods. Notwithstanding the important progresses, 53.6% of the population live below the poverty line (INE 2004) while the GDP per capita is 210 dollars (WB, 2004a). The constant and high rate of GDP growth, at around 7% between 1993 and 2003, suggests an improvement of these conditions. However, these promising data hide a substantial regional disparity. For example in the region around Maputo, the 1999 GDP per capita was around 1189 dollars, while in the Northern regions, as Zambezia, the GDP per capita was 96 dollars (UNDP, in Hanlon, 2002). An analysis of the social indicators for Mozambique shows an important governmental effort towards meeting the Millennium Development Goals. The enrolment ratios for both sexes are increasing at every level: between 2002 and 2003, for primary school it increased by 6.9%, for secondary school by 17.4% (Source MINED, RoM 2004). However, the literacy rate in 2002 was 62.3% for males and 31.4% for females (WB 2005), showing that action is needed also to tackle the gender issue. Equally, life expectancy is still really low, at 40.7 years in 2003 (WB 2005), also given the effect of the HIV/AIDS epidemic, despite a 3.2% increase in the number of health care facilities between 2002 and 2003 (Source MISAU, quoted in RoM 20054). 4.1.3 “O Plano de Acção para a Reducção da Pobreza Absoluta” 10 As shown by the data above, the GoM is making a huge effort to improve the living conditions of Mozambicans. Its commitment towards poverty reduction and its strategy are stated in the PARPA, which is the Mozambican PRSP. The PARPA was elaborated just before the launch of the PRSP format and it is supposed to be more “authentic” than other PRSPs, even if it was written by a handful civil servants inside the MPF, in consultation with the IFIs, and it was submitted to the decentralised level and to a participatory forum only at a later stage (Fozzard, 2002). It identifies six core areas of intervention for poverty reduction: health, education, infrastructure, rural development, macroeconomic and financial policies and good governance. The PARPA identifies the main problems in each of these areas, the resources, competencies and institutional tools to be used and sets the priority targets and the actions to be undertaken. The PARPA is complemented on the operational side by the Performance Assessment Framework (PAF), “which is a multi-annual matrix of priority targets and indicators based on the PARPA, […] agreed through cross-governmental dialogue” (GoM and PAPs). The PAF is used by the GoM to direct its actions towards poverty reduction and by the Programme Assistance Partners (PAPs) to evaluate the efficiency of aid spending by the GoM for refinancing. The PARPA is a document elaborated entirely by the GoM, while the PAF stems from the policy dialogue with donors. The present donors-GoM relationship in GBS revolves around the PARPA and the PAF. GBS tranches are released every year after a Joint Donor Review (JR) of the progress over the PAF targets negotiated the previous year following the PARPA strategy. However, despite the long-standing and trustful GoM-donors relationship and the GoM commitment to poverty reduction, the donors-GoM relationships over the PAF and PARPA are not entirely harmonious. Given the evaluation by Fozzard (2002) on the IFIs influence during the PARPA elaboration and given the way the PAF targets are negotiated every year (Hanlon, 2005), the ownership rhetoric used to describe the PRSP process is slightly far-fetched. More appropriately, the relationship seems to be characterised by a conflict of interest between the GoM and the donors. In chapter 5 this conflict of interest will be modelled in order to understand whether GBS is more conditional than policy-based aid. 4.2 How General Budget Support is carried out in Mozambique This section draws on Borgarello et al (2004). GBS to Mozambique dates back to bilateral disbursements of the early ‘90s. Recently, these supports were harmonized and carried out through the Joint Donor Macro-Financial Aid Programme (JP) which is the programme used co-ordinately by the donors to provide aid directly to the Mozambican State Budget. The JP was started in 2000 by a group of nine donors, that have now become seventeen11. These are called the Programme Aid Partners (PAPs), and together with the GoM form the G1812 which is joined by the IMF, USA, Japan, UNDP and the African 11 The donors currently in the group are: Belgium, Canada, Denmark, the European Commission, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, The Netherlands, United Kingdom, the World Bank. The World Bank takes part in the JP through a Poverty Reduction Strategy Credit (PRSC) approved in 2004 (WB 2004b). Its participation is extraordinary. The number of seventeen of the donors is taken by the official site of the Programme Aid Partnership, which lists 17 donors that have given an indicative commitment for 2005 and 2006. Hanlon (2005) lists only 16 donors, excluding probably Denmark, while Killick at al (2005) and the MoU refer to 16 donors, excluding Spain, that joined the G18 only after the Joint Donor Review (JR) in May 2005. 12 Some documents refer to the PAPs as the G17, while others include the GoM in the G-group. In order to make things as clear as possible, I will refer to the group composed only of donors (and observers) as the PAPs, while the G18 is the PAPs plus the GoM (and observers). 11 Development Bank as observers. The JP is provided upon the strategy in the PARPA and conditional to the targets in the PAF. Due to space constraints, I will analyse only the workings of the JP, disregarding the mechanisms that regulate harmonisation, the access and the relationship with the GoM, as well as the budgeting and planning tools. There are two moments characteristic of the JP: collaboration amongst the PAPs and dialogue between the PAPs and the GoM. The PAPs meet periodically in different groups at various levels13, with the aim to analyse, discuss and evaluate technically and politically in itinere the JP. This process of evaluation amongst the PAPs is instrumental for the second stage of the JP dialogue, that with the GoM. The dialogue with the GoM revolves around the level of implementation of the PRSP and the use of funds. The monitoring of the effectiveness and efficiency in the use of funds is carried out using mainly the PAF and other instruments (an external audit, a Mozambican audit). Despite being a partnership, if the conditions underlying GBS are not met at all, that is if the PARPA strategy and PAF targets are worryingly disattended, the PAPs can decide to withhold a tranche. This last resort move was employed only once, in 2002, when GBS was suspended for a few months following the bank scandal. The G18 dialogue is characterised by the fact that the PAPs have agreed a common behaviour towards the GoM. This mechanism is a novelty with respect to what happened under policy-based lending, when recipients could employ strategies of playing one donor against the other (Mosley et al 1995). Thus, under GBS, the recipient bargaining power is weaker because it has to confront a cohesive group of donors that act co-ordinately. 4.3 Aid flows to General Budget Support in Mozambique Donors bargaining strength is enhanced under GBS also by the extent of aid flows. This aid modality can in fact be suspended more easily and the suspension can be linked more clearly to a government action than under project aid. In order to assess the relative strength of donors in Mozambique, it is thus important to analyse whether and to what extent they are moving towards this form of aid and to what degree the GoM is directly dependent on GBS. Mozambique is one of the countries most dependent on external aid in the world 14. Government finances heavily depend on aid: in 2003, the GoM fiscal revenues amounted to 14.3% of GDP while expenditures equalled 29.4% of GDP. Grants contributed to almost 30% of the state budget, constituting 10.6% of GDP (Hodges and Tibana, 2004). This data is even more worrying given the unaccounted share of aid that bypass the state budget. Furthermore, the mechanism of GBS, which in 2004 constituted one-fifth of the state budget and one-third of overall aid flows (Hanlon, 2005), make the state directly dependent on the aid released which is increasing, as shown in Figure 3. 13 Four groups characterise the PAPs dialogue: Heads of Mission group, Heads of Cooperation group, Economists Working group and a Troika (GoM and PAPs, 2004a). 14 According to DAC, the net ODA/GNI ratio was 25.2% in 2003, 60.3% in 2002 as a consequence of the aid for the floods and 29.8% in 2001. 12 The increased recurrence to GBS as aid modality interests most donors, notably the likeminded donors, as shown in Figure 4. While looking at the figure it should considered that aid commitments are generally made every 3 years thus some donors might present peaking surges corresponding to this. Moreover, data for 2005 and 2006 are indicative support and therefore they might be understated. Figure 4. GBS and BoP support over the years for PAPs. 80.000.000 Financial Contributions in U SD 70.000.000 60.000.000 50.000.000 40.000.000 2003 30.000.000 2004 2005 20.000.000 2006 10.000.000 W B UK nd er la en Sw itz Sw ed ain Sp al rtu g Po s he rla Th e Ne t Ire No rw ay nd ly Ita lan d y ce m an Ge r Fr an an d Fi nl EC ar k De nm da Ca na Be lgi u m 0 Source: Programme Aid Partnership. Author's elaboration. The quickly increasing number of donors entering the PAPs and their increasing commitment suggest that most donors are interested in influencing directly the GoM on its policy choices. The satisfaction with GBS as an aid modality fulfilling donors aims, chiefly that of ‘gaining a seat at the policy table’, is further confirmed by the fact that some PAPs 15 intend to further increase their contribution, while others (Canada and Germany) might do so in the future (Killick et al, 2005). Therefore the GoM direct dependence on GBS will increase, as the donors need to disburse GBS whatever the performance. This possible urge to ‘push aid out 15 These are Belgium, Finland, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland and the UK. 13 of the door’ will be felt more by those donors that, as DFID, the Netherlands and the Nordic countries, are shifting to GBS. The share of GBS given by these countries amount to 42% of the total in 2005, as shown in Figure 5. Figure 5. Share of DBS and BoP support by donors in 2005. 1% 1% Belgium Canada EC Finland 22% France 21% Germany Ireland Italy The Netherlands 2% 2% 2% 3% 2% 21% Norway Portugal Sweden Switzerland UK WB 9% 3% 6% 1% 4% Source: Programme Aid Partnership. Author’s elaboration. The aid flows analysis highlights that the move to BS, motivated by the country characteristics described in 4.1 and following the modality explained in 4.2, is increasing both GoM and major donors interests in punctual and quick disbursements. 5. The model This chapter intends to build a general model of an extensive form game in order to portray the interactions between donors and a government under GBS conditions. This will be carried out by adjusting some assumptions of previous game-theoretic models to the GBS conditions. While here I describe a general model of the interactions between unspecified donors and the recipient government, in part 6 I will adapt the model to the Mozambican situation. The use of game theory is not new to the study of donor-recipient relationship, and has been extensively employed in modelling behaviour under conditional aid. The gametheoretic approach, as summarized by Mosley et al (1995), is particularly appropriate for this task since the interaction of donors and recipient under conditionality can be seen as a game in the sense of being a relationship in which the two parties have (at least partly) opposed interests which they pursue by taking note of each other’s likely behaviour, and in which the outcome depends on the strategies pursued by each party. As explained in the previous chapters, there are differences between BS and ‘older’ forms of aid, which could make it difficult to reconcile this analysis and the novelty of BS. In fact, rhetorically, the PRSPs, which GBS is connected to, are a shared form of conditionality and should not present the same conflicting interests as conditional aid. However, given 14 firstly that donors enter this relationship to ‘gain a seat at the policy table’ (Driscoll et al, 2005), secondly that PRSPs are a ‘superconditionality’ (Booth, 2001) and that there is an unfavourable overall judgement over the novelty of the process (UNCTAD, 2002, Mosley and Booth, 2003), GBS relationship exhibits elements of the conflict of interests characteristic of conditional aid and therefore the use of a game-theoretic approach is still appropriate. 5.1 Actors and choices The model portrays the interactions between two players. On the one side, there are the donors that give aid in support to the budget, acting jointly as one individual; this group will be referred to as the groups of donors16. On the other side, there is the recipient government. The two actors display different and sometimes conflicting aims and choices, captured by an analysis of their utility functions. I assume that the group of donors utility UD is the sum of their individual and homogeneous utility functions. It can be hypothesized that the relationships between the donors within the donor group are to a certain extent structured along a form that is more easily described by game theory than by straightforward aggregation. However, if we were to formalise these interactions, we would obtain a model that would not contribute to our analysis of the power relationship between donors and recipient. I define the elements of the donors group utility function UD as: h a function of the quantity of aid and slippages a a variable for the quantity of aid s a binary variable referring to whether there is slippage or not t a parameter measuring donors satisfaction when granting aid. The donor utility function has been represented both as depending positively (Easterly, 2002, Mosley et al, 1995) and negatively (Lundborg, 1998) on the amount of aid disbursed. Drawing on Villanger (2003) and on the recent debate on aid effectiveness, I assume that UD is positively linked to disbursement of aid through GBS once the conditions to which it is attached are fulfilled and it is negatively linked to disbursements once the conditions are not fulfilled. That is, UD is dependent on h=h(a;s) which is a function of aid (a) and slippages (s). In our case, UD increases when no slippage occurs (s=0), all the aid resources are spent in pursuit of their intended aim17 and are not diverted for patronage, fund misappropriation by elites, etc. UD instead decreases when the Boolean variable s=1, which occurs when there are slippages and donors are still disbursing. I assume that donors prefer to disburse aid and to influence recipient behaviours rather than not to. 16 17 In the case of Mozambique, the group of donors is the PAPs. The aim is set accordingly to what stated in the PRSP. 15 Figure 6. The function h. h h(a,s0) h0 h(a,s1) h1 a a* Based on Villanger (2003). The UD depends also on a parameter t, that measures donors’ happiness and satisfaction when grating aid, determined by the fulfilment of their strategic interests linked to the concession of funds. This element is generally not considered in the game theoretic literature on aid, where the assumption on donors’ motives is simplistically that of donor altruism (Svensson, 2000b, Federico, 2001). In fact, the assumption of donor altruism has been widely debated (Kanbur 2003). The more recent literature that analyses specifically donor motives, both from an econometric perspective (Alesina and Dollar, 2000) and from a political economy one (Lundborg, 1998; Harrigan et al, 2004) shows that donors grant aid for egoistic reasons. Integrating these findings in the envisaged model, through the parameter t, instead of assuming donors’ altruism, does not mean that I consider donors efforts towards poverty reduction as a by-product of a concern over other interests. In certain cases donors are sincerely committed to poverty reduction, and at the same time this commitment corresponds to a political strategic behaviour: that of securing political support internally. The group of donors’ utility function can be formalized as: UD=UD(h(a;s),t). The recipient government utility is UR. My hypothesis is that the recipient government acts as a coherent actor. This is a heuristic simplification. As outlined by Van de Walle (2005), the recipient behaviour is often divided along the lines of the differing behaviours of the legislative versus the executive. Considering the recipient actions as coherent implies also to disregard the effects the flow of aid might have on the government equilibria: Kanbur (2000) outlines that often aid strengthens the reformist factions within the government. I define the elements of the recipient government utility function UR as: a the variable for the quantity of aid s a binary variable referring to whether there is slippage or not r a new parameter measuring the relationship between the absence of slippage in the first period with a disbursement in the second. Most models (Svensson, 2000a, 2000b and 2003, Murshed and Sen, 1995, Mosley, 1992 and Mosley et al, 1995) see UR as depending positively on the quantity of aid received and negatively on the tightness of conditionality. These assumptions can be slightly modified to suit GBS conditions: on the one side, the UR increases with an increase in the aid (a) disbursed. On the other side, UR increases if the recipient manages to make a slippage 16 (s=1), either on the PRSP targets that do not correspond to its own political agenda (Mosley et al, 1995) or on diverting a part of aid for the ruling elites (Svensson, 2000a). However, since the recipient government has entered the PRSP process leading to BS, and is to an extent committed to poverty reduction, I assume that it prefers to comply and receive aid, rather than the opposite. Finally, since we are analysing GBS, where donors and recipient are in a continuative partnership, it is legitimate to include a parameter r, -1>r>1, that captures the relationship between the absence of slippage in period one with the extent of aid flow in period two. When in period one s=0, r>0, the recipient utility increases because, given the continuative relationship, the recipient expects a higher flow of aid in period two. The recipient government utility can be formalized as UR=UR (a;s,r(s)) + + where + indicates that UR is directly dependent on the variables a and r. The choices open to the actors can be summarised in a game tree, where the donors group has two strategies, that of disbursing or not, while the recipient can either make a slippage or not. The donor is the first mover, since, GBS and PRSP processes are ultimately donor-driven, even if formally it is the government approaching the donors for financial support. Figure 7. The game tree. Donors group Disburse BS Do not disburse BS Recipient No slippage Recipient Slippage Donors group No slippage Donors group Disburse Not Not 1 2 3 Slippage Donors group Disburse 4 Donors group Disburse Not 5 6 Not 7 Disburse 8 Based on Villanger (2003) and Mosley et al (1995). Leaving aside momentarily that the game under GBS conditions is a repeated game and thus does not end after the third stage, we can employ the game tree to rank the desirability of each option for the players according to their utility. For the donors group, outcome 1 is the most desirable, since they have disbursed aid in the face of full compliance, while outcome 4 is the less desirable one. The desirability of the other options depend on whether donors prefer to disburse rather than see their strategic interests fulfilled and whether t expresses satisfaction of foreign policy interests rather than internal public opinion concerns over development issues. I will assume that donors in the GBS group strategically enter GBS in order to show their generosity to their public opinion. Thus outcome 3 is preferred over 4 and 5 over 6. For the recipient, the best outcome is 4, since 17 it gets aid while being allowed a slippage, while the least desirable is 6. The rankings of the other outcomes depend on what Axelrod, 2001, calls the ‘shadow of the future’ 18. 5.2 Interactions and outcomes: a repeated game As anticipated, this game-theoretic model differs from most models of conditional aid (Svensson, 2003; Azam and Laffont, 2003) which assume the interaction between donors and recipient to be a one-shot game. The GBS situation is similar to the repeated game developed by Mosley et al (1995) and Mosley (1992) in the event of a refinancing decision, since the donors group and the recipient are in a partnership (Axelrod, 2001). Following Axelrod’s suggestion, the analysis of how the game will proceed will be carried out using a payoff matrix referring to each stage of an iterated Prisoner’s dilemma game. The matrix identifies four outcomes: they are the two choices open to donor and recipient in the game tree. The matrix can be extended to include the representation of further ramifications of choices characterising a partnership, but I limit the description, given the parameter r and the assumption that the players will act rationally in response to the choices already taken by the counterpart19. Figure 8. The pay-off matrix. DONOR Cooperate Defect UR (a; s0, r) + + UR (a0; s0, r) + UD (h(a; s0) t) + + UD (h(a0; s0) t) ++ - OUTCOME ONE OUTCOME THREE UR (a; s1, r) + - UR (a0; s1, r) - UD (h(a; s1) t) + UD (h(a0; s1) t) + - OUTCOME TWO OUTCOME FOUR Cooperate RECIPIENT Defect Based on Axelrod (2001). In outcome one, the donor and recipient utility are at their highest: the donor is disbursing aid in the face of no slippage and it is satisfied in its strategic aim, while the recipient receives aid and, given its decision not to make slippages, receives also the promise for future aid. Generally, given that GBS scheme presupposes continuity in the relationship and a certain degree of direct aid dependence, the recipient utility is highest in outcome one than in two, since the shadow of the future is large enough. The donor utility in outcome two is lower, given that it disburses aid when a slippage is made but it keeps a good reputation for its generosity in the eyes of its public opinion. Outcome three, which is quite unlikely, sees recipient utility at its immediate lowest, with no gain in the present Axelrod (2001: 5) suggests that “the potential for mutual cooperation depends on the ‘shadow of the future’”, that is the rate at which the advantage coming from the next move is discounted relative to the present. If the shadow of the future is large enough, a stable cooperation can be established. 19 The parameter r together with the rationality assumption imply the further steps of the game under a partnership. 18 18 period and r acting as a bonus for the future, while the donors, satisfied with the fact that they do not disburse aid and see no slippage, are penalised by their public opinion. Finally, in outcome four, the recipient immediately gains by making a slippage, while the donors withhold aid and their public opinion sanctions them. It is evident from the matrix that GBS mechanism reduces the payoff of the temptation to defect for the recipient. The temptation payoff for the recipient is further reduced by the fact that GBS increases direct aid dependence and that it creates a cohesive groups of donors, thus decreasing the strategies for alternative sources of financing the recipient might find (Mosley et al, 1995). The incentives on the recipient side, in the form of present aid flows and promises of future disbursement, all act in favour of a cooperative behaviour. This is contrary to what happens in the Prisoner’s Dilemma, where the incentives make the payoff for unilateral defection the first best for the recipient. For the donors group, while the utility deriving from unilateral defection, even if lowered by public opinion sanctions, is high and constitutes a good incentive for defection, it is quite unlikely that in the face of no slippage they decide to exit the aid granting relationship. Therefore, the most likely outcome is a cooperative equilibrium, contrary to the findings of most papers on conditional aid that generally forecast Nash equilibria. Axelrod (2001) suggests that mutual cooperation is best sustained if the players employ a Tit for Tat strategy20 which, it can be shown21, is the likely strategy employed by the players under GBS. By modelling the donors’ group-recipient relationship I show that under GBS a cooperative equilibrium is reached and is rendered stable by the likely employment of a Tit for Tat strategy. I also show that the GBS mechanism has managed to reduce the choices of defection open to the recipient, partially solving some of the problems linked to the failure of conditionality. The donor-recipient relationship under GBS, therefore, seems to be characterised by a relative weakness of the recipient. Therefore, it can be said that by reducing the bargaining power of the recipient, GBS is a more conditional form of aid. The recipient weakness however is directly connected to the donors group provocability and to its willingness to retaliate, that are closely linked to the parameter t of the UD. These issues will be taken up analytically in the following part. “Tit for Tat cooperates on the first move, and then does whatever the other side did on the previous move. […] Tit for Tat’s robust success was due to its being nice, provocable, and forgiving. Its niceness means that it was never the first to defect. Not being the first to defect prevented it from getting into unnecessary trouble. Its provocability meant that it retaliated when the other side defected. By cooperating again as soon as the other player did, the forgiveness of Tit for Tat helped restore mutual cooperation”. Axelrod, 2001, 5-6. 21 In fact, the recipient tends to cooperate on the first move and maintain this posture. If it defects, the group of donors’ retaliation is a potent threat to reinsure cooperation. The donors group might not comply on the first move. If it cooperates from the start, then a stable cooperative equilibrium sets in. If it defects, which is quite unlikely especially in a repeated game, they end up in outcome 4, where their utility is very low and they have more incentives (in t and h1) to start cooperating. 20 19 6. Application of the model to General Budget Support in Mozambique Parts 2 and 3 have introduced GBS as an aid modality, part 4 has analysed how GBS is implemented in the case study, Mozambique, while part 5 has modelled the relationship between donors and recipient. This part will use the information regarding Mozambique provided in part 4 to assess the heuristic power of the model presented in part 5. 6.1 Assessing the model 6.1.1 Strengths The detailed yearly process of review of the GBS to the GoM confirms most of what assumed by the model: the establishment of a stable cooperative equilibrium between the donors and the recipient in which there is close adherence between donors policies priorities and recipient decisions. According to the JR 2005 (PAPs, 2005), the “overall performance has been satisfactory”, particularly in the areas of macroeconomic management, poverty reduction, service delivery, agriculture development and infrastructure delivery. The PAPs performance is similarly “good and improving” (Killick et al, 2005). The good health and stability of the existing partnership is further confirmed firstly by the punctual yearly decisions of refinancing taken by the PAPs, secondly by the increasing share of aid flows some PAPs destine to GBS and thirdly by the donors that continuously join the PAPs. The heuristic power of the model emerges also from the empirical validation of most assumptions. First of all, the periodical increase in aid inflows, documented in 4.3, confirms the assumption that donors tend to link disbursements and their utility in disbursing with conditionality compliance and extent of aid. These are the assumptions on which the function h(a;s) is based. Equally, the GoM satisfactory compliance along the years confirms that UR is determined by the extent of present and future aid flows 22 and that the existence of a partnership creates a virtuous trade-off between slippages and future disbursements. Finally, an analysis of the use of Mozambique as showcase in the international forums and media23 confirms that aid to this country is granted in response to the donors’ strategic aim (t) to show their generosity and ability to the internal public opinion. These elements support the inclusion of the parameter t. 6.1.2 Weaknesses The accuracy of the model, however, is limited. Its prediction of a pure cooperative solution with no slippage on the GoM side and entire collaboration by the PAPs is contrasted by certain elements. In fact, both the GoM and PAPs performance is not completely satisfactory, as can be understood from the review reports. In particular, the GoM performance has been particularly poor with regard to the governance, justice and corruption targets (PAPs 2005). Worryingly, the performance doesn’t seem to be set in the context of an improvement, as it is for the PAPs. Neither it seems a one-off occurrence, linked to particular contingencies or to over-ambitious targets, but an episode of a long series. Hanlon (2002; 2005) suggests that the behaviour of the GoM has been steadily deteriorating for what concerns the adherence to good governance standards. He also highlights the disturbing increase in corruption that characterises most levels of the 22 23 These are described by the variable a and the parameter r in the UR function. See for example, The Guardian 11/03/05 or La Repubblica 03/07/05. 20 political life and public administration. His observations are confirmed by other authors (Hodges and Tibana, 2004; Fozzard, 2002). The findings of the model are to be further reconsidered in the face of the 2001 bank scandal and the connected assassinations24. Then, it clearly emerged the widespread corruption of certain high-ranking members of the governing party, the Frelimo, as well as the extent of mismanagement and diversion of public funds. These behaviours were not sanctioned at all by the donors and there is enough evidence to believe that they have surfaced also during the land redistribution currently under way. Thus, it seems the relationships between donors and recipient do not follow the slippage-retaliate modality forecasted by the model. This brief assessment shows that the findings of the model are not entirely correct: we are not in the presence of a pure cooperative solution. It seems that on the one side the recipient-donors relations follow a less mechanistic path than forecasted, while on the other side there is a certain extent of slippages, that some authors see as continuously increasing, matched by a steady increase in disbursements. Thus it seems that in the case of Mozambique GBS is a less conditional form than predicted. The model must be reconsidered taking these elements into account properly. 6.2 Reasons underlying the limitations of the model The model is to an extent faulty because it is based on the doctrine assumptions about the comparative advantages of GBS. The aid doctrine tends to be too general: it condenses the complexity of certain country characteristics and its treatment of certain variables is exaggeratedly abstract and simplistic. First of all, the doctrine backing GBS avoids any country-specific consideration, maintaining that GBS is a universally good aid modality. This evaluation is particularly incompatible with what happens in Mozambique. There, the introduction of GBS and the reputation of the country as the showcase for this aid modality have radically modified the terms of the donors-recipient relationship as generally portrayed in the model. For the donors in fact it is difficult to behave as clear-cut as represented in the game tree. It is more likely that they would tend to be forgiving towards the GoM and avoid denouncing minor slippages by their exemplar partner. Similarly, as suggested by Hanlon (2002), the long-standing relationship between donors and the GoM has trained the Mozambican elites in “giving donors what they want” while at the same time “creating large spaces for predation and state capture”. Time and familiarity have changed the nature of the donorsrecipient interactions and have expanded their domain beyond what represented in the model. The disregard of country-specific considerations promoted by the literature has an influence on the model and specifically on the parameter t, that is unable to represent properly the ambiguity in donors motives for disbursing to Mozambique. In our case donors motives for disbursing are mixed and influence donors utility in opposite directions. On the one side they are forced to disburse (Easterly, 2001): Mozambique is a showcase and there are often specific spending lines for the country, as shown in 4.3 (Killick et al, 2005) that need to be fully used. On the other side donors are increasingly scrutinised by their public opinion which is more attentive to the situation in the country. 24 An account of the events can be found in Hanlon (2002) or Fauvet and Mosse (2003). 21 Thirdly, the binary variable s, which indicates the presence of slippages, is inadequate. The Boolean variable was chosen according to what postulated by the aid doctrine referring to selectivity and aid effectiveness: there are either good or bad performers that comply or make a slippage. In fact slippages on conditionality can not be represented univocally through a binary variable: given at least exogenous factors, complete compliance is quite unlikely, which means that s=0 rarely occurs. Often the donorsrecipient partnership continues when there are slippages and the performance of the partner is deemed satisfactory. The evaluation on compliance is a combination of quantity and quality of the conditions that are not respected. This binary vision drawn from the doctrine and embodied in the Boolean variable to represent this complex cut-off point is misleading and overlooks the complexity of the donors-recipient relationship. Gunning (2005:10) suggests that the binary vision at the basis of GBS pictured in the game tree is akin to a nuclear threat: “if the only options are doing nothing or imposing enormous damage the threat to “go nuclear” for any, possibly minor, infringement is not credible”. This explains why some slippages are allowed in a system that is constructed to be more conditional than policy-based lending. The nuclear analogy should not mislead us into thinking that no amount of slippages would trigger the withholding of a tranche. The recent events in Uganda show that it is possible to withhold aid beyond a certain extent of slippages which corresponds to more than predicted in our model. 6.3 Further implications of the model The assessment of the model through a country case study has shown that the findings of the model are not as clear-cut. In particular, while technically it seems that GBS is a more conditional form of aid, in practice a certain extent of slippage occurs. If we analyse it, it seems that the overall performance of Mozambique has been satisfactory for those targets, poverty reduction and Millennium Development Goals, linked to donors immediate motive for giving aid: that of rallying internal support and legitimacy as generous and effective institutions. This assessment suggests one possible development of the model: GBS can be studied as an aid modality that fosters collusion between donors and recipient. In fact, the donors-recipient relationship in the countries where GBS is employed are generally familiar and long. This makes the partners aware of the declared and hidden aims one of the other and their bargaining revolves around these. So, the GoM knows that it would be allowed to make some slippages given that it is a showcase, while the donors allow some slippages from the GoM given that it performs well on certain areas that are donors’ priorities. A second development of the model would regard the variable s. In order to represent the analysed process regarding the extent of the slippage, the variable s should be represented as a continuous variable including a threshold value that indicates the level of slippage to be considered as non compliance. This device would allow the model to be more representative of the cooperation and collusion relationship that links the donors and recipient, as described in 6.1.2 and 6.2. 22 7. Conclusion This paper has presented the issues regarding the adoption of General Budget Support as an aid modality. In particular, the paper has intended to respond to the question “How ‘conditional’ General Budget Support is compared to policy-based lending?”. GBS was elaborated at the end of the ‘90s as the solution to the problems connected with the effectiveness of project assistance and conditional aid. In particular, the main problem that prompted this elaboration concerns conditionality and its low coercive power given by the conflict of interests between donors’ and recipient’s aims. GBS is seen as the solution to this and to donors fragmentation, disorganic planning and implementation, state unaccountability and ownership that are consequences of project aid and financial programming. GBS in fact provides aid within a framework that promotes a close and frequent policy dialogue between donors and the recipient, aligns donors priorities to that of the recipient, favours donor harmonisation and strengthens state capacity and accountability. Given these comparative advantages, GBS is amongst the favoured aid instruments for many donors. The assumption that GBS represents a stronger form of conditionality is then modelled through game theory. The model is an innovative attempt to apply previous research referring to other forms of aid to the new version of FPA. The model suggests that GBS is a more conditional form of aid since it decreases the defection pay-off for the recipient, given that aid is locked in a continuative partnership, it is administered through a cohesive group of donors and that aid flows are increasingly disbursed through this channel. The model is then assessed against a case-study, Mozambique. The country characteristics that motivate the recourse to GBS, together with GBS flows and mechanisms of implementation, are analysed. This analysis is instrumental to an assessment of the soundness of the assumptions of the model. This assessment shows that for GBS in Mozambique the donors-recipient relationship is not as conditional as suggested by the model, since the GoM has been allowed some continuative slippages. The predictions of the model are to an extent faulty since the model is built around a too general aid doctrine that disregards the importance of country factors and simplifies the representation of certain variables and interactions. Certain amendments to the model are put forward in order to expand it to a more precise analysis of compliance and of GBS as promoting a certain degree of collusion between donors and the recipient. The model and these suggestions are an innovative attempt to consider and understand GBS from a theoretical point of view rather than from the implementation side, which is the preferred perspective of most studies. References African Development Bank and Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (2004), Mozambique, African Economic Outlook, World Bank, Washington D.C. Alesina, Alberto and David Dollar (2000), “Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why?”, Journal of Economic Growth 5, 33-63. Axelrod, Robert (2001), Theoretical Foundations of Partnerships for Economic Development, Draft prepared for the World Bank Conference on Evaluation and Development, The Partnership Dimension, 2001. Andersen, Ole Mølgård (2000), Sector Programme Assistance, in Tarp, Finn, ed, Foreign Aid and Development. Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London. 23 Azam, Jean-Paul and Jean-Jacques Laffont (2003), “Contracting for Aid”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 70, n. 1. Batley, Richard (2002), Mozambique. A Country Case Study, Study on donors’ practices commissioned by OECD, University of Birmingham. Birsdall, Nancy, Stijn Claessens and Ishac Diwan (2003), “Policy Selectivity Forgone: Debt and Donor Behaviour in Africa”, The World Bank Economic Review, vol. 17, n. 3. Boone, Peter (1995), Politics and the Effectiveness of Foreign Aid, Centre for Economic Performance, Discussion paper n. 272. Booth, Ann and Paul Mosley eds (2003), The New Poverty Strategies: What Have They Achieved? What Have We Learned?, Palgrave, Houndmills, Basingtoke, Hampshire, NY. Booth, David (2001), PRSP Processes in 8 African Countries, Paper for presentation to the WIDER Development Conference on Debt Relief, Helsinki. http://www.wider.unu.edu/conference/conference-2001-/parallel%20papers/1_2_booth.pdf Borgarello, Andrea, Fabio Melloni and Riccardo Sozzi (2004), “Programma di supporto finanziario al bilancio generale dello Stato (General Budget Support)”, Quaderni della Cooperazione Italiana, n.6, Cooperazione Italiana, Maputo. Branson, William and Nagy Hanna (2000), Ownership and Conditionality, OED Working Paper Series n. 8, Washington D.C. Burnside, Craig and David Dollar (1997), Aid, Policies, and Growth, Policy Research Working Paper n°1777, World Bank, Washington D. C. Burnside, Craig and David Dollar, (2004), Aid, Policies, and Growth: Revisiting the Evidence, Policy Research Working Paper 3251, World Bank, Washington D. C. Collier, Paul, Patrick Guillaumont, Sylviane Guillaumont and Jan Willem Gunning (1997), “Redesigning Conditionality”, World Development, vol. 25 n. 9. Collier, Paul and David Dollar (1999), Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction, The World Bank, Washington D.C. Collingwood, Vivien (2004), Power and Conditionality in Global Governance, Paper prepared for the Fifth Pan-European Conference on International Relations, The Hague 2004. Cordella, Tito and Dell’Ariccia Giovanni (2003), Budget Support versus Project Aid, IMF Staff Paper, IMF, Washington D.C. Cornia, Giovanni, Richard Jolly and Francis Steward (1987), Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth, Claredon Press, Oxford. Drazen, Allan (1999), What is Gained by Selectively Withholding Foreign Aid?, mimeo. Drazen, Allan (2000), Political Economy in Macroeconomics, Princeton University Press, Princeton. Driscoll, Ruth, Karin Christiansen, David Booth, with Paolo de Rienzo, Samantha Smith and Katarina Herneryd (2005), Progress Reviews and Performance Assessment in Poverty-reduction Strategies and Budget Support. A Survey of Current Thinking and Practice, Report submitted to the Japan International Cooperation Agency, ODI, London. Easterly, William (2001), The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics, MIT Press, Cambridge MA. Easterly, William (2002), “The Cartel of Good Intentions: the Problem of Bureaucracy in Foreign Aid”, Policy Reform 5(4). 24 Easterly, William (2003b), “Can Foreign Aid Buy Growth?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 17, n°3, Summer, pp. 23–48. Easterly, Willliam, Ross Levine and David Roodman (2003) New Data, New Doubts: Revisiting ‘Aid, Policies and Growth’, Working Paper 26, Centre for Global Development, Washington D.C. The Economist, How to Save the World, 28/10/2004. The Economist, Thinking Big, 17/03/2005. The Economist, Between Hype and Hope, 14/07/05. Fauvet, Paul and Marcelo Mose (2003), Carlos Cardoso. Telling the Truth in Mozambique, ABC Press, Cape Town. Federico, Giulio (2001), Samaritans, Rotten Kids and Policy Conditionality, mimeo, Nuffield College, Oxford. Fine, Ben and Dergol Hailu (2002), Convergence and Consensus: The Political Economy of Stabilisation, Poverty and Growth, mimeo, www.soas.ac.uk/cdprfiles/dp/DP22BD.pdf Foster, Mick (2003), The Case for Increased Aid: Mozambique Case Study, in Foster, Mick, Andrew Keith, Hugh Waddington and Alan Harding eds, The Case for Increased Aid. Volume 2: Country Case Studies, Final report to the Department for International Development, http://www.dfid.gov.uk/pubs/files/caseforaidvol2.pdf Fozzard, Adrian (2002), How, When and Why does Poverty get Budget Priority? Poverty Reduction Strategy and Public Expenditure in Mozambique, ODI Working Paper 167, ODI, London. Government of Mozambique (2001), Action Plan for the Reduction of Absolute Poverty 2001-2005, Ministry of Planning and Finance, Maputo. Government of Mozambique and Programme Aid Partners, Memorandum of Understanding between the Government of Mozambique and Programme Aid Partners for the Provision of Direct Budget and Balance of Payment Support, Maputo. Government of Mozambique and Programme Aid Partners (2004a), Programme Aid Partners (PAPs) Organisation Structure and Terms of Reference, www.pap.org.mz Government of Mozambique and Programme Aid Partners (2004b), Programme Aid Partners Performance Assessment Framework (PAPs’ PAF), Maputo. The Guardian, The Greatest Tragedy of Our Time: How the World Can Help and Why it Must Do So Now, 11/03/05. Gunning, Jan Willem (2005), Budget Support, Conditionality and Impact Evaluation, Paper for the Practioners’ Forum on Budget Support, Cape Town. Hanlon, Joseph (1991), Mozambique: Who Calls the Shot?, Currey, London. Hanlon, Joseph (1996), Peace without Profit: How the IMF Blocks Rebuilding in Mozambique, International African Institute in association with James Currey, London. Hanlon, Joseph (2002), Are Donors to Mozambique Promoting Corruption?, Working Paper 15, Crisis States Programme, London School of Economics. Hanlon, Joseph (2005), Donors and Government both Criticised, Report n. 86, Southern Africa Region Poverty Network. Harrigan, Jane, Chengang Wan and Hamed El-Said (2004), The Economic and Political Determinants of IMF and WB Lending in the Middle East and North Africa, Discussion paper 411, University of Manchester. 25 Healey John and Tony Killick (2000), Using Aid to Reduce Poverty, in Tarp, Finn, ed, Foreign Aid and Development. Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London. Helleiner, Gerry (2000a), Towards Balance in Aid Relationships: External Conditionality, Local ownership and Development, mimeo, CCIC. Helleiner, Gerry (2000b), Towards Balance in Aid Relationships: Donor Performance Monitoring in LowIncome Developing Countries, CIS Working Paper 2000-2. Helleiner, Gerry (2002), “Local Ownership and Donor Performance Monitoring: New Aid Relationships in Tanzania?”, Journal of Human Development, vol. 3 n. 2. Hodges, Tony and Roberto Tibana (2004), Political Economy of the Budget in Mozambique, www.dfid.gov.uk. Jones, Stephen and Andrew Lawson (2000), Moving from Projects to Programmatic Aid, OED Working paper Series n. 5, Washington D.C. Kanbur, Ravi (2000), Aid Conditionality and Debt in Africa, in Tarp, Finn, ed, Foreign Aid and Development. Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London. Kanbur, Ravi (2003), The Economics of International Aid, Ithaca, Department of Applied Economics and Management working paper WP 2003-39, N. Y., Cornell University. Killick, Tony (1997), “Principals, Agents and the Failings of Conditionality”, Journal of International Development, vol. 9, n. 4. Killick, Tony with Ramani Gunatilaka and Ana Marr (1998), Aid and the Political Economy of Policy Change, Routledge and Overseas Development Institute, London. Killick, Tony, Carlos Nuno Castel-Branco and Richard Gester (2005), Perfect Partners? The Performance of Programme Aid partners in Mozambique, 2004, Report to the Programme Aid partners and Government of Mozambique, Maputo. Koeberle, Stefan and Zoran Stavreski (2005), Budget Support: Concepts and Issues, Paper for the Practioners’ Forum on Budget Support, Cape Town. Kreps, David (1990), Game Theory and Economic Modelling, Claredon Press, Oxford. Lister, Stephen (ed) (2005), Joint Evaluation of General Budget Support 1994–2004. Burkina Faso, Malawi, Mozambique, Nicaragua, Rwanda, Uganda, Vietnam, International Development Department, University of Birmingham. Lundborg, Paul (1998), “Foreign Aid and International Support as Gift Exchange”, Economics and Politics, vol. 10, n. 2. Montes, Carlos and Stefano Migliorisi (2004), EU Donors Atlas. Mapping Official Development Assistance, Development Strategies with IDC, www.dev-strategies.com. Mosley, Paul (1992), A theory of conditionality, in Mosley, Paul (ed), Development Finance and Policy Reform Essays in the Theory and Practice of Conditionality in Less Developed Countries, St. Martin’s Press, New York. Mosley, Paul, Jane Harrigan and John Toye (1995), Aid and Power. The World Bank and Policy-based Lending, vol. 1, Routledge, London. Mosley, Paul and Marion J. Eeckeout (2000), From Project Aid to Programme Assistance, in Tarp, Finn, ed, Foreign Aid and Development. Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London. Mosley, Paul, Farhad Noorbakhsh and Alberto Paloni (2003), Compliance with World Bank 26 Conditionality: Implications for the Selectivity Approach to Policy-Based Lending and the Design of Conditionality, CREDIT Research Paper n. 03/20. Mosley, Paul, John Hudson and Arjan Verschoor (2004), “Aid, Poverty Reduction and the new Conditionality”, The Economic Journal, vol.114, June. Murshed, S. Mansoob and Somnath Sen (1995), “Aid Conditionality and Military Expenditure Reduction in Developing Countries: Models of Asymmetric Information”, The Economic Journal, vol. 105, n. 429. ODI and OPM (2002a), General Budget Support Evaluability Study Phase 1. Final Synthesis Report, Report for DFID, London. ODI and OPM (2002b), General Budget Support Evaluability Study Phase 2. Country Case Studies. Mozambique: Poverty, Aid and Policy in Mozambique 1992-2002, Report for DFID, London. OECD (2004), Aid to Mozambique, www.oecd.org. Pitcher, Ann (2002), Transforming Mozambique, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Plank, David N. (1993), “Cooperação e Condicionalidade: o Estado Moçambicano na Nova Ordem Mundial”, Cadernos de Pesquisas n. 3, Istituto Nacional do Desenvolvimento da Edução, Maputo. Programme Aid Partners (2005), Joint Review 2005. Aide-Mémoire, Final Version, Programme Aid Partners Secretariat, Maputo. Radelet, Steve (2005), From Pushing Reforms to Pulling Reforms: the Role of Challenge Programs in Foreign Aid Policy, Centre for Global Development Working Paper n. 53, Washington D.C. Rajan, Raghuram G. and Arvind Subramanian (2005), Aid and Growth: What Does the Cross-Country Evidence Really Show?, IMF Working Paper 127, Washington D.C. Republic of Mozambique (2003), PARPA Implementation Evaluation Report, Maputo. Republic of Mozambique (2004), Review of the Economic and Social Plan for 2003, Maputo. La Repubblica, Il Boom dell’Africa che Sorride, 03/07/05. Roodman, David (2003), The Anarchy of Numbers: Aid, Development, and Cross-country Empirics, Working Paper 32, Centre for Global Development, Washington D.C. Round Jeffery and Matthew Odedokun (2003), Aid Effort and its Determinants, Wider Discussion Paper 2003/03, WIDER, Helsinki. Sachs, Jeffrey (1989), Conditionality, Debt Relief and Developing Country Debt Crisis, in Sachs, Jeffrey (ed.), Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, vol. 1, Chicago University Press, Chicago. Sachs, Jeffrey (2001), “The Strategic Significance of Global Inequality”, The Washington Quarterly, vol. 24, no. 3. Sachs, Jeffrey (2005), The End of Poverty. Economic Possibilities of Our Times, Penguin Book, London. Svensson, Jakob (2000a), “Foreign Aid and Rent-seeking”, Journal of International Economics, vol. 51, 437461. Svensson, Jakob (2000b), “When is Foreign Aid Policy Credible? Aid Dependence and Conditionality”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 61, n. 1. Svensson, Jakob (2003), “Why Conditional Aid Does Not Work and What Can Be Done about it”, Journal of Development Economics, vol. 70, n. 1. Tarp, Finn, ed (2000), Foreign Aid and Development. Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London. 27 Taylor, Lance (1997), “The Revival of the Liberal Creed: The IMF and the World Bank in a Globalized Economy”, World Development, vol. 25, n°2. UNCTAD (2002), Economic Development in Africa. From Adjustment to Poverty Reduction: What Is New?, United Nations, Geneva. Van de Walle, Nicholas (2001), African Economies and the Politics of Permanent Crisis, 1979- 1999, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Van de Walle, Nicholas (2005), Overcoming Stagnation in Aid Dependent Countries, Centre for Global Development, Washington D.C. Villanger, Espen (2003), “Company Influence on Foreign Aid Disbursement: Is Conditionality Credible when Donors have Mixed Motives?”, Chr. Michelsen Institute Reports, WP 2003:4, Bergen. Weeks, John, David Andersson, Chris Cramer, Alemayehu Geda, Degol Hailu, Frank Muhereza, Matteo Rizzi, Eric Ronge and Howard Stein (2002), Supporting Ownership. Swedish Development Cooperation with Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda, Sida Evaluation n. 02/33, Stockholm. White, Howard (1999), Dollars, Dialogue and Development. An Evaluation of Swedish Programme Aid, Sida Evaluation Report 99/17, Stockholm. White, Howard and Oliver Morrissey (1997), “Conditionality when Donor and Recipient Preferences Vary”, Journal of International Development, vol. 9, n. 4. World Bank (1994), Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead, The World Bank, Washington D.C. World Bank (1998), Assessing Aid: What Works, What Doesn't, and Why, The World Bank, Washington D.C. World Bank (2004a), Mozambique at a Glance, The World Bank Group, Washington D.C. World Bank (2004b), Mozambique: World Bank Approves First Poverty Reduction Support Credit To Mozambique, News Release No:2004/8/AFR, The World Bank, Washington D.C. World Bank (2005), World Development Indicators. Mozambique Data Profile, The World Bank Group, Washington D.C. Zoomers, Annelies (2005), Three decades of Rural Development Projects in Asia, Latin America and Africa: Issues for Discussion, Paper presented at the 2005 WIDER Annual Conference, Helsinki. Websites www.ambafrance-mz.org consulted on the 26/07/05. www.delmoz.cec.eu.int consulted on the 26/07/05. www.dfid.gov.uk consulted until the 22/07/05. www.finland.org.mz consulted on the 26/07/05. www.imf.org consulted until the 01/09/05. www.italcoopmoz.com consulted on the 26/07/05. www.oecd.org consulted until the 21/07/05. www.pap.org.mz consulted until the 12/09/05. www.swisscooperation.org.mz consulted on the 26/07/05. www.worldbank.org consulted until the 29/08/05. 28