Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 1 ************************************************* Economic Reform Australia For a just and sustainable society. ERA NEWSLETTER ISSN 1324-5929 Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 IN THIS ISSUE Page D. Phelps The Worship of Economic Growth 3-5 G. Jukes A plea for brevity in understanding Economics 5 J. Hermann Do banks lend out their depositors funds? 6-13 D. Dorney Debt Sinks Revisited 13-14 ERA Media Release Nuclear energy fails the cost effective test 15 L. Manning & R Manji A New Financial Deal for Christchurch 16-17 D. Keane Recent Australian Economic Trends 18-20 W. Mitchell Limits of public assistance 21-22 C. Hamilton Tackle Big Coal at your own risk 22-24 J. Coulter The cost of nuclear generated electricity 24 D. Elliot Fukushima Fallout 25-27 R. Buckley Resilience and global financial governance 28-32 *********************************** Disclaimer: The views expressed in these articles are the sole responsibility of their authors and do not necessarily reflect those of Economic Reform Australia. Editor Co-Editor Peter Lock, 4/20 Everard Street, Frances Milne, 14 Gallimore Av. Largs Bay SA 5016. Balmain NSW 2041. Phone-Fax 08 - 8242 0566 Phone-Fax 02 - 9810 7812 Email pblock@arcom.com.au Email frmilne@aol.com Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 2 ************************************************* ECONOMIC REFORM AUSTRALIA ERA is a non-party-political organization, formed in 1993 as a union of the Economics Review Association and other economic reform groups. Its long-term goal is to achieve a socially, environmentally and financially sustainable economic system. ERA’s commitment to economic sovereignty seeks to return control of the economic and financial system to the people. This requires full public scrutiny and accountability for all economic processes and a recognition that economic systems must serve the people for the global good. Membership of ERA is open to all who agree with its objectives and overall philosophy, and may be effected by sending A$20.00 per annum to the Treasurer (address below), together with address, telephone and fax numbers, and email address. It would be appreciated if new members would calculate the part of the year remaining and remit the appropriate pro-rata amount, or alternatively pay for the following year as well. All members are entitled to receive the regular 32-page ERA newsletter, and are entitled to vote at monthly meetings and participate in organized activities. ****************************************************** ERA Patrons : Professor Stuart Rees, Professor Frank Stilwell, Professor Michael Pusey, Associate Professor Evan Jones, Associate Professor Steve Keen, Professor David Shearman, Dr. Ted Trainer, Dr. Shann Turnbull. ****************************************************** ERA (NSW DIVISION) Inc. We are committed to maintaining our links and meet twice a year. All Meetings are normally held at 14 Gallimore Avenue, Balmain 2041. Details : Frances or Bruce Milne Ph. 9810 7812 ERA (SA DIVISION) INC. Meetings are held on the last Saturday of the month at the Conservation Council Centre, Level 1, 157 Franklin Street Adelaide. Meetings start at 2pm with the policy recommendation forum before official business begins. Details - John Hermann Ph. 8264 4282 ****************************************************** ERA Web Site Home Page: www.era.org.au EMAILnetwork editor: Dr John Hermann: hermann@picknowl.com.au Postal address: PO Box 505, Modbury, SA 5092, Australia National Treasurer and Membership Officer: Victoria Powell : PO Box 505, Modbury, SA 5092, Australia Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 3 ************************************************* The Worship of Economic Growth Doris Phelps ERA SA Economists and politicians hold up "economic growth" as an ideal to be aimed at, but this worship of growth leads to some contradictions. One is that we welcome the invention of labour-saving devices, and yet governments go to great lengths, and brag about, the number of jobs they have `created'. Another contradiction is that while most of us can see that many of our resources are finite, the need for economic growth means that they are being used up faster and faster, instead of being saved up for the use of future generations. "But", we are told, "If we don't have growth, there will be a recession. There won't be enough money in the community to keep business and government supplied." Apparently there is no way in which we can have a steady-state economy. We must always seesaw between "growth" and recession. What is overlooked is that the reason we must have growth in order to keep the money flowing, is the way in which our money supply comes into existence. It comes into existence when it is issued through the banking system to businesses for all forms of production (manufacturing, retailing, farming, mining, etc.) as an interestbearing debt. It is not issued by governments as many people believe, and as the populace is encouraged to believe. Those who believe that our money supply is created and issued by the Government, need to answer some relevant questions. First, how is this money then distributed into the community? Second, why then do governments ever need to borrow and get into debt? Third, why do governments need to tax their citizens to raise money for necessary expenses? When, as an adult, in an effort to understand the economic system, I studied high school economics and sat for the exam, I obtained a number of previous exam papers. I noticed that not one of them asked the question, "Explain where our money supply comes from and how it comes into existence". And yet the answer is there in the text books, "Bank advances create bank deposits". When I said to a young man who had studied economics as one of his uni subjects, that banks create our money supply in the process of lending, he refused to believe me. He believed, as most people do, that banks lend money which has been deposited with them, so I told him to look up his text books and read the chapter on credit creation. The Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 4 ************************************************* next time I saw him, I said "Well?", and he said, "That's incredible!" What really is incredible is that thousands of economics students have gone through their courses without the significance of this fact being explained. (No doubt because it is not included in exam questions!) When America issued trillions of dollars to save its financial institutions from collapse, anyone who talked about it, referred to the American Government "printing money". Did they really have visions of trillions of printed banknotes? How many Fort Knoxes would have been needed to store them? The bulk of money these days is not even figures in bank books. It is just electronic figures somewhere in a computer, and can be created or transferred with the click of a computer key. The important point is to realise who has the privilege of clicking the key, and an even more important point is that the institutions who click the key and create this money and lend it to businesses and governments, have the added privilege of charging interest. So, if a bank creates and lends $10 000 at 5% interest in one financial period, the only place the repayment of the loan plus the interest ($10500), can come from, is from the next round of borrowing. Because, as money (credit) is being borrowed into existence all the time, it is also being paid back and cancelled all the time. This is the reason that there is a necessity for continual economic growth. Each round of borrowing must be a little larger than the previous one in order to repay the loan plus interest. But this does not apply to just one bank. It describes the whole private banking system and the creation of our money supply. (In this respect, our economic system could be regarded as a giant Ponzi scheme, needing ever more injections of credit to prevent the whole house of cards from collapsing.) Early forms of money came into use as a convenient means of exchange to replace barter, and eventually came to be issued by rulers and governments. If money were still to be issued by governments (as, ironically, many people believe it is) it could be issued interest-free, and the need for continual "growth ", could be eliminated. There have been some attempts by members of governments to regain control of the money supply, such as Abraham Lincoln with his issue of greenbacks, and Australian politician, King O'Malley, in conjunction with the then Governor of the Commonwealth Bank, Sir Dennison Miller, in financing the 1914-18 war effort (see D.J. Amos "The Story of the Commonwealth Bank" or Peter Lock "The Saga of the People's Bank"). But these sensible measures were nipped in the Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 5 ************************************************* bud by those whose interests they threatened. It is just amazing when you think of all the brilliantly clever things that man can do in the way of electronics and medicine and space exploration, that the short-comings and the contradictions of the money system, which, after all, was invented by man, have not been sorted out. The reason cannot be that man is not clever enough to sort them out. The reason is, of course, that it suits some very powerful people to keep things the way they are. During the past 100 years the flaw in the system, and possible ways to remedy it, have been pointed out in numerous books and pamphlets, but unfortunately the above-mentioned powerful people have control of the media. One early advocate who received much publicity and then dropped right out of the news, referred to it as a conspiracy of silence. In recent times we have seen things happen that we would never have believed possible. They have happened because individuals now have the ability to communicate with thousands of other individuals without depending on the controlled and controlling media. The conspiracy of silence is now not so easy to impose. Perhaps there is hope that, before all our finite resources are used up and our world laid waste in this passion for "growth", voters will learn that there is a way to avoid the need for extravagant growth, and will insist that their politicians put it into practice.■ ************************************ A plea for brevity in understanding economics. A quote from "Critics of Henry George" by Robert V. Anderson. Professor of Philosophy Auburn. U.S.A. Quote. A book should be so written that it's message can be presented in a single sentence, The argument of "Progress and Poverty" may be stated thus "That the natural land ought everywhere to be regarded as a community, rather than as a private resource and that it's rental value should be recaptured as public revenue by the Community, thereby eliminating the need of any taxes upon productive enterprise.” The root cause of so much of the world's misery, poverty, war, unemployment and famine, can be traced directly back to this same single abuse, i.e. the unlimited individual appropriation of the fixed resource of land, the sole source of all life. Henry George said. "I do not say that Justice is the greatest quality in the Moral Hierarchy but it is the FIRST."■ From George Jukes ERA SA ******************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 6 ************************************************* Do banks lend out their depositors’ funds? John Hermann ERA SA There is a large amount of misunderstanding and confusion in the minds of both the general public and the business community about the nature, operational status and legal status of banking deposits. And it is my contention that much of this misunderstanding has been created by the banking industry itself, as a by-product of its ongoing (and largely successful) attempt to obfuscate and mislead others about the mechanics of banking in the modern world. Make no mistake that financial economists fully recognise the role of commercial banking institutions in introducing new credit money into the economy. This is money which is created out of nothing when depositories expand their portfolio of financial assets. Most of the money supply (money accessible to and used by the nonbank community) is bank credit money - that is, it has no tangible existence and only takes the form of entries in the accounts of bank customers. In the modern world those entries are digitized using computers. The role of reserves Most of the reserve funds used within the banking system also take the form of entries in creditary accounts - but in this case the accounts are those of commercial banks with the central bank. Currency (coins and notes) in the hands of the public make up only a small fraction of the money supply, while currency in the hands of bankers usually make up only a small fraction of their supply of reserves. In practice reserve funds are required for (a) net exchange settlements at the end of each day (either by the central bank or by a check-clearing agency answerable to the central bank), and (b) maintaining sufficient liquidity to allow for spending, advancement of loans, and withdrawals from banking institutions in the form of legal tender (both "normal" withdrawals and withdrawals under a stress scenario). None of these require, as a necessity, a one-to-one correspondence between reserves and deposits. There are never enough reserves in existence (under a normallyoperating fractional reserve banking system) to allow for an exchange of bank credit money with legal tender. If a major run on banks occurred, then the shortage of liquidity could only be addressed by the rapid injection of a large quantity of new reserves into the banking system, insofar as this is possible. And that would amount to a complete abandonment monetary policy, probably for a Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 7 ************************************************* considerable time-span. Reserve funds in Australia Whenever money is exchanged between two commercial bank accounts via cheque or electronic transfer, an equal quantity of reserve funds is transferred. This transfer is manifested as an exchange of reserve funds in the accounts of those banking institutions with the central bank. The U.S. maintains a statutory requirement, meaning that commercial banking institutions are obliged to hold reserves equal to a prescribed fraction of their deposits. Australia, New Zealand and Canada have no statutory reserve requirement. However they do possess reserve funds, in the form of cash held in their tills and vaults in conjunction with positive balances maintained in their accounts at the central bank. In Australia the balances with the Reserve Bank of Australia are not called reserves, they are called exchange settlement funds. In the process of implementing liquidity and risk management practices, each Australian commercial banking institution effectively determines the matching ratio - between reserve funds and demand deposits - which is perceived to best meet its needs. The Australian institutions authorised to create credit money, known as ADIs (authorised deposit taking institutions), are the registered banks, credit unions and building societies. All of these are legally authorised to describe themselves as "banking institutions" and their business as "banking". What is "bank funding"? The bankers' use of the term "funding" in regard to deposits is often misinterpreted. The term "funding" more properly applies to an ordinary intermediary, e.g. a finance company, which borrows in order to lend at a profit. If the word "funding" is to be used at all in the context of banking, I believe it should be applied either to the acquisition of funds from financial markets (which funds are subsequently used to purchase financial assets at a higher rate of return) or to the acquisition of excess reserves. My objection to the use of the word "funding" in the context of deposits is that it can give the impression that commercial banks on-lend their customers' deposits. However neither deposits nor reserves are ever loaned out to the retail customers of banking institutions. In regard to fractional reserve banking, commercial banks obtain a substantial part of their stock of excess reserves from the acquisition of interest-bearing deposits (that is, reserves are usually Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 8 ************************************************* freed up whenever credit money is transferred from a demand account to an interest-bearing account). This is a strong incentive for banks to retain those deposits, since by doing otherwise they would lose the excess reserves. Assets and liabilities A bank's financial assets are its loans, investments and reserve funds, while its financial liabilities are its deposits and its borrowings. The difference between the two categories are the bank's net worth, or capital. The essential requirements for an expansion of bank lending are (a) adequate capital, (b) adequate reserves, (c) a willingness to lend and (d) a willingness to borrow. "Adequate capital" refers to an excess of capital over that required to accommodate the bank's existing loans. "Adequate reserves" refers to an excess of reserves over that required to accommodate the bank's existing deposits. Neither borrowing from the financial markets nor the acquisition of deposits change a bank's capital (because in each case the assets and liabilities acquired are equal), however by expanding a bank's capability to advance new financial assets - resulting in new interest income - they indirectly generate the growth of new capital. Security of deposits Deposits are "secure" in the sense that they are a special class of liability which - unlike funds borrowed from the wholesale markets must be held securely by the depository for the sake of the stability of the payments system and the workability of the prevailing monetary model. Banks also have an incentive to do so in their own self-interest, because they would like to retain the excess reserves which they obtain with interest-bearing deposits. However, under a fractional reserve monetary system, deposits are not necessarily "secure" in the sense of protecting depositors from the risk of a bank's default on its obligation to pay all of its depositors legal tender on demand -- unless adequate insurance and/or government guarantees on deposits are implemented. Is a deposit a borrowing? Some arguments advanced for the proposition that bank deposits are borrowings rely on a scenario where a customer walks into a branch of a bank carrying either legal tender (cash coins/notes) or a precious metal like gold (coins/bars) with the intention of making a deposit. Firstly, that is not how most Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 9 ************************************************* deposits are made in the modern world. Overwhelmingly, deposits take the form of (a) credit money transferred between two bank accounts, or (b) newly created credit money, placed in a demand account of a bank's customer when the bank advances a loan to that customer. And secondly, for the small component of bank deposits which involve the transfer of something tangible, currency is the accepted form - not bullion. Moreover, after that currency has been handed over to the custody of the bank, it is no longer regarded by the central bank as being part of the money supply. Any currency (coins and notes) held by a depository forms part of its stock of reserves. Thus all funds held in depository accounts consist of credit money, and as such form the overwhelming part of the money supply (currency held by the public form a much smaller part). It is essential, for the workability and the stability of the monetary system, that those funds should be held by the depository and not on-loaned at the discretion of the bank. In practice - and without a single exception - that is how it works, notwithstanding any legal decisions which might imply the contrary. The simple fact is that the payments system could not work otherwise, nor could fractional reserve banking. One of the characteristics of borrowed funds is that they become the property of the borrower, and may be disposed of in any way the borrower sees fit. That is demonstrably not a description of deposited funds. I have never observed any notices of withdrawal in my credit union account, made at the discretion of the institution, in order to accommodate loans to new borrowers. Legal status of deposi ts It has been argued (see, for example, J.H. de Soto: Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles, 2nd Ed., 2009) that a deposit contract is different in nature to a loan contract. I reproduce extracts from the early part of this book: The Deposit Contract Whereas loan contracts (commodatum and mutuum) entail the transfer of the availability of the good, which shifts from the lender to the borrower for the duration of the term, another type of contract, the deposit contract, requires that the availability of the good not be transferred. Indeed, the contract of deposit (depositum in Latin) is a contract made in good faith by which one person - the depositor entrusts to another - the depositary - a movable good for that person to Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 10 ************************************************* guard, protect, and return at any moment the depositor should ask for it. Consequently, the deposit is always carried out in the interest of the depositor. Its fundamental purpose is the custody or safekeeping of the good and it implies, for the duration of the contract, that the complete availability of the good remain in favor of the depositor, who may request its return at any moment. The obligation of the depositor, apart from delivering the good, is to compensate the depositary for the costs of the deposit (if such compensation has been agreed upon; if not, the deposit is free of charge). The obligation of the depositary is to guard and protect the good with the extreme diligence typical of a good parent, and to return it immediately to the depositor as soon as he asks for it. It is clear that, while each loan has a term of duration during which the availability of the good is transferred, in the case of a deposit this is not so. Rather a deposit is always held and available to the depositor, and it terminates as soon as he demands the return of the good from the depositary Resulting effects of the failure to comply with the essential obligation in the irregular deposit When there is a failure to comply with the obligation of safekeeping in a deposit, as is logical, it becomes necessary to indemnify the depositor, and if the depositary has acted fraudulently and has employed the deposited good for his own personal use, he has committed the offense of misappropriation. Therefore, in the regular deposit, if someone receives the deposit of a painting, for example, and sells it to earn money, he is committing the offense of misappropriation. The same offense is committed in the irregular deposit of fungible goods by the depositary who uses deposited goods for his own profit without maintaining the equivalent tantundem available to the depositor at all times. This would be the case of the oil depositary who does not keep in his tanks a quantity equal to the total deposited with him, or a depositary who receives money on deposit and uses it in any way for his own benefit (spending it himself or loaning it), but does not maintain a 100-percent cash reserve at all times. The Spanish criminal law expert Antonio Ferrer Sama has explained ("El delito de apropiadEndebida", Publicaciones del Seminario de Derecho Penal de la Universidad de Murcia: Editorial Sucesores de Nogu 1945) that if the deposit consists of an amount of money and the obligation to return the same amount (irregular deposit), and the depositary takes the money and uses it for his own profit, we will have to determine which of the following situations is the correct one in order to determine his criminal liability: at the time he takes the money the Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 11 ************************************************* depositary has sufficient financial stability to return at any moment the amount received in deposit; or, on the contrary, at the time he takes the money he does not have enough cash of his own with which to meet his obligation to return the depositors money at any moment he requests it. In the first case the offense of misappropriation has not been committed. However, if at the time the depositary takes the deposited amount he does not have enough cash in his power to fulfil his obligations to the depositor, he is guilty of misappropriation from the very moment he takes the goods deposited for his own use and ceases to possess a tantundem equivalent to the original deposit. The essence of this is that the receiver of a financial deposit, if intending to do anything with the deposited money, is obliged to have on hand an amount of money equal to the deposit. The implication is that, under a fractional reserve monetary system, depositories which attempt to on-lend their depositors' funds should be liable for criminal prosecution for misappropriation of funds. The author favours the original interpretation of the word deposit under Roman law. He implies elsewhere that fractional reserve banking would have been "fraudulent" under the Roman rules of law on these matters. Some authors within the Austrian school of economics apparently prefer to view fractional reserve banking as fraudulent in itself, as do authors from other schools and disciplines. DeSoto is saying "the Romans got it right", and advocates changes in the rules for banking. Deposits are not on-loaned under the system as we have it. But this is for a different mechanical reason than it would be under Roman law without fractional reserves. Essentially an irregular deposit of money in Roman law treated the depository as a "money warehouse" similar to a grain warehouse or a warehouse of fungible money. A regular deposit (enclosed in a tamper-proof container) and a loan (interest paid meant the depositor implicitly authorized on-lending of the sum) were also quite separate entities. We have modern equivalents using slightly different terms and rules for all of these things. But the modern legal interpretation of a deposit is not the Roman view. Today fractional reserves are held against deposits, and contemporary courts have tended not to treat this as a fraudulent or illegal custom. Does bank credit money represent base money? To what extent does bank credit money represent base money? Base money is the conjunction of exchange settlement funds (the creditary component of reserves) and all currency (coins and notes Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 12 ************************************************* held by both the public and by banking institutions). Thus base money is money which has been created by the central bank. Despite what many economics text books might claim, it is arguable whether bank credit money is ever exchanged (or exchangeable) with base money. When a bank customer makes a withdrawal and demands payment in the form of currency, the monetary mechanics is quite clear: (a) currency is exchanged between the bank and the customer, (b) the bank's stock of reserves is reduced by that amount, and (c) bank credit money is destroyed - by the same amount. Neither base money nor the money supply are affected by the overall transaction. There has been no exchange between bank credit money and base money in this transaction. The word exchange can be taken to imply that something was destroyed in one form and created in the other form. In this case, bank credit money was destroyed but base money was unaffected. And the reverse argument applies in the scenario where a customer takes currency into a bank branch and requests a deposit. The counter-argument is that the scenario described above is not complete. When a bank customer withdraws currency against an account, the depository loses reserves. Other things being equal, that would cause a shortage of reserves in the banking system and thus an increase in the interest rate on central bank funds. To maintain control of that interest rate, the central bank would feel obliged to inject additional base money into the system to replenish the lost reserves. As a result, this argument goes, base money normally would increase when currency is withdrawn from a bank, and conversely. However I don't believe that the operation of monetary policy is a good argument in favor of the viewpoint that bank credit money is inter-convertible with base money. For a financial system which embraces the use of base money in the form of currency, one may argue that (a) although the operation of monetary policy is a possible reaction to any (actual or likely) loss or gain of reserves by the financial system, it has no direct connection with the transaction mechanics of deposits and withdrawals; (b) the gross withdrawal of currency is roughly counterbalanced by the gross return of currency to the banking system, even if there is a net growth or decline in currency over time (which I would expect to be a small fraction of gross turnover) due to other factors such as Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 13 ************************************************* population growth and seasonal preferences; and (c) currency may be viewed as an intermediary, or catalyst, which facilitates the ultimate movement of bank credit money between different accounts (with a time delay) - so there is an association between currency and bank credit money - rather than an interconversion. ■ ******************************************************** Debt Sinks Revisited Denis Dorney, ERA Dunedin New Zealand In the last edition of the ERA Newsletter, Richard Giles commented on my previous article on Debt sinks but appears to have completely misunderstood it even though I thought the logic of my argument was simple. Is it possible, when space allows, to publish the attachment which I hope clarifies the issue. Incidentally the article refers obliquely to the need for clear definitions. Your article on negative money values emphasises the importance, since, if people realised that money is issued as a negative value, there is absolutely no way that it can be cancelled, or acquire an intrinsic value. It therefore annoys me that, even within ERA, some correspondents talk as if money is merely a symbolic token. It is much more that that. I think it is important that ERA not only discusses but comes to a definition of what money is. I would like to contribute such a debate and also to a debate on land tax and ownership, which is where I was hoping my article on debt sinks would lead. I was initially pleased that someone chose to respond to my article on debt sinks, because I think the concept is important, and was then bewildered that Richard Giles had written a learned thesis to reject my definition of 'economic rent', a phrase that I did not mention, even less define, and would not have used even if I understood it. All too often the layman is told that economics is too hard for his little brain and he should leave it to the experts. Events of the last few years (and ongoing) show there are no experts and the layman has a right and duty to get involved in economic debate, so it bothers me immensely when people use esoteric jargon, which exclude him, sometimes quite deliberately, from the discussion. Dr Bill Mitchell's article on deficit spending was totally jargon free and was, I believe, understandable to all who read it, whatever their views on the matter and should set a standard. Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 14 ************************************************* The essential point in my article was that if the value of all goods or commodities could be measured purely in terms of the labour input, which can only be altered slowly, and since the quantity of such goods cannot be increased rapidly, especially in an over-heated economy, then there is little opportunity for banks to dump large amounts of debt into the economy because of the time lag in dramatically changing either the value or quantity of goods. Booms and busts could not then easily happen. The trouble is that debt sinks (commodities which are not measurable by their labour input) do exist, the value of land being one of the most important ones. Rent, economic or not, is irrelevant to the logic of the argument. However, as the writer of "Henry George and good government" would be quick to point out, land tax is one of the possible solutions. I still hope that someone will agree, or not, with my argument because the ramifications are quite fundamental to monetary reform. Lastly, thanks for sending my newsletter by post but I am quite happy to receive it by email, if that is not a problem, since it saves you money and I can more easily forward bits of it to other likeminded people. I had tried initially to send this by email to Peter Lock unsuccessfully. The error message implied a wrong address. ■ ************************************* This short article by Dennis Dorney, in response to the criticism by Richard Giles which appeared in the most recent (March-April) issue of the ERA Newsletter, points out that Dennis did not mention the term economic rent, which is correct. However I mentioned the term in my introductory remarks, because I identified "debt sinks" with financial and real estate asset bubbles. Richard rightly pointed out that - in classical economics - economic rent is not a super profit, but a surplus production due to location. Although this might be technically correct, I would prefer to define economic rent in terms of the generation of economic value and wealth independently of labour input and human productivity. This seems to align with the views of Dennis. Thus the component of interest received which exceeds the level of inflation would fall within this definition, and those who receive such interest income may be described as the rentier class. John Hermann. *************************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 15 ************************************************* Economic Reform Australia (ERA) MEDIA RELEASE Wednesday, 12 April, 2011 Nuclear energy fails the cost effective test A range of items must be considered when comparing the overall costs of nuclear and other technologies as sources of electrical power. Modern nuclear fission power plants are horrendously expensive to construct. We are talking about an order of magnitude higher than comparable plants which use other technologies. Not to mention the radioactive materials storage and transport costs, and the decommissioning costs. Also largely hidden from view is a need to use fossil fuels in connection with construction, maintenance and decommissioning of the reactors and other infrastructure. Hence it is simply untrue to assert, as the nuclear industry often does, that nuclear power makes no contribution to greenhouse gas emissions into the atmosphere. Moreover, there is also a hidden effective insurance cost, which thus far has not had to be borne by the nuclear industry for accidents of the type we are now witnessing in Japan. In every country the size of the required coverage has been limited and in the event of an accident the general public has been required to carry the financial (to say nothing of the health) risk of a serious accident. Regardless of the final expense of coverage, the “openended” liability for governments remains elusive. ‘Most governments have effectively hidden the reality of costs from the public’ said economist Dr David Robinson, of the Oxford Institute of Energy Studies. This raises the question: if the nuclear industry had to pay the full cost of insurance against these catastrophic accidents, what would be the impact on the consumer price of nuclear generated electricity? The answer to this question is becoming increasingly clear to us. ■ ****************************************************** For an harmonious social order, it is not a question of individual rights preceding the demands of society, nor who comes first or last, the individual or the community, the part or the whole. Parts are only parts when they are parts of a whole. Otherwise, they are merely accumulations of bits of stuff. The parts of the whole and the whole itself together come both first and last. P. Lock. ****************************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 16 ************************************************* Sustento Institute: A New Financial Deal for Christchurch By Lowell Manning and Raf Manji CHRISTCHURCH RENEWAL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT There’s a much better way to pay for Christchurch’s renewal and for national development too. It’s a win-win for the government and the people of New Zealand. While the government discusses borrowing yet more debt and bringing in a new tax to pay the costs of rebuilding Christchurch we propose issuing new cash E-notes to do the same job. E-notes are exactly the same as the bank notes we all carry in our wallets and handbags except that they exist only in bank accounts. The New Zealand Reserve Bank needs no authority to issue new cash. When the commercial banks want cash they buy it from the Reserve bank and pay for it with a cheque issued against their own accounts. The Reserve Bank deducts its costs of producing the cash and passes the profit to Treasury. The profit, otherwise known as seigniorage, is most of the face value of the currency, so selling cash improves the Government’s accounts. That already happens every day. There is no reason at all why the Reserve Bank cannot issue new money in the form of electronic cash or E-notes using exactly the same method. Instead of selling the notes to the banks, the Reserve Bank simply gives the profit, or face value of the electronic E-notes to the Treasury. The issue gets treated in every other respect just like an "ordinary" cash issue. The economic term for this is quantitative easing which has been used very widely around the world since the Global Financial Crisis began a few years ago, but not in New Zealand and, unfortunately for the rest of the world, not in the form we are proposing. In major economies like Japan and the USA, this process has been carried out by buying securities from banks in return for new money. This has improved the balance sheets of the banks but not helped the economy. In our proposal the Treasury receives the E-notes from the Reserve Bank and then it simply disburses them in payment for goods and services to improve New Zealand’s investment in infrastructure, health and education, including earthquake relief for Christchurch. The process is no different from any other Government spending except that it is paid for using cash instead of using debt and taxes. The money could sit in a Government Infrastructure Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 17 ************************************************* account until required. The important point is that the new money goes directly into the economy and not onto the balance sheets of the banks. After the Government has spent the E-notes they will pass into the bank accounts of workers and businesses. The E-notes will then become part of the banks' reserves that increase the liquidity of the banking system without significantly increasing its lending capacity. By using E-notes the Government will be doing the job the New Zealand banking system should be doing, but isn’t: freeing up the money we need to get the country moving again and get people back to work. The banks have failed to do their job in part because they are struggling to prepare to comply with stricter lending requirements under the new international Basel III banking regulations. That’s largely why they are being so tough on new lending. While the banks fiddle with their regulations the New Zealand economy and the economies of many other countries are being destroyed because there is not enough money available to get people working and to increase incomes and consumption. An E-note injection of at least NZ$5b is unlikely to be inflationary with current unemployment at close 7%. Our modelling suggests $5b represents about $6.5b of new GDP, which would reduce unemployment by around 3%. The E-note cash injection will help get the country moving again. It will reduce the Government fiscal deficit by, at the very least, reducing dependency on social welfare as well as by providing about NZ$2.5b in new tax revenue. The new money will fund new infrastructure projects and investments in health and education and assist the rebuilding of Christchurch. It will also save at least $200m in interest the government would otherwise have to pay if it were to use NZ$5b of new debt instead of the electronic cash E-notes we are proposing. The rate of E-note injection will allow its effects to be continuously monitored. If there are no major problems the E-note issue should be extended to include retiring NZ$ denominated government debt as it matures. That will quickly reduce the Government’s debt burden. Allowing the Government to go back to the failed old ways of tax increases and new debt will simply dig the country further into the economic hole that has been growing for the past thirty years or more. For further information please contact: Lowell Manning 04 298 6890 manning@kapiti.co.nz Raf Manji 0274 185 119 raf@sustento.org.nz 26/2/11 ■ ****************************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 18 ************************************************* RECENT AUSTRALIAN ECONOMIC TRENDS By David Keane, 14/March/2011 PO Box 582, Gosnells 6110, WA Email: keane@nw.com.au Recent Trends Let us first view an abridged table of recent liabilities as a % of GDP. Date GDP $Billions F Equity %ofGDP F Debt %ofGDP F Liab %ofGDP Dom Cr %ofGDP TotLiab %ofGDP AnnInc %ofGDP Jun-06 1150.644 45.7 77.6 123.3 123.3 246.6 1191.654 55.4 87.4 142.8 137.4 280.3 33.7 1237.320 51.5 92.1 143.7 150.1 293.8 13.5 1255.241 47.0 98.5 145.5 152.3 297.8 4.0 1258.077 53.8 97.9 151.7 152.4 304.1 5.3 1266.203 55.4 99.8 155.2 152.0 307.2 6.9 1273.610 55.9 99.8 155.7 152.7 308.4 10.8 1283.795 52.0 103.3 155.4 152.6 307.9 10.1 1292.333 54.4 101.0 155.5 152.2 307.7 3.6 1300.986 57.4 98.0 155.4 152.1 307.6 0.4 Jun-07 Jun-08 Jun-09 Sep-09 Dec-09 Mar-10 Jun-10 Sep-10 Dec-10 The first thing to note, is that Australia’s total liabilities as a % of GDP has been stationary at 307% to 308% for over a year now. This suggests very intentional government policy. It is a vast relief from the bad old days when the Howard/Costello government was increasing total Australian liabilities by 30% to 35% of GDP each year. Under a Liberal government, the Australian economy was run on exponentially expanding and uncontrolled debt. Yet the Liberal Party economic platform seems just as debt driven as under the Howard government. The basis by which the Liberals are able to slam the present Labor government over new green taxes, is essentially that the Liberals want the Australian economy to return Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 19 ************************************************* to the running on increasing debt model. Thankfully, I believe the global depression will hit before Australians go again to the national polling booths. This will be an extremely hard lesson, but something has to happen to bring the real economic issues to the forefront of public debate. The problem is, that by the Labor having a steady policy to not increase total liabilities as a % of GDP, this does absolutely nothing to offset the disastrous consequences of the inevitable global economic collapse, global depression and crashing of the commodities market. If the Australian government wants to offset the disastrous consequences of a global commodities market collapse, then we should have been reducing the Australian foreign debt by 4% of GDP each year. But this has not happened and we can tell it is not going to happen until a global economic collapse brings new issues onto the public radar. When the global economic collapse does happen therefore it will mean extreme pain for all sectors of the Australian economy. We can no longer avoid that pain. We can only lift up the true economic issues so that our present youth generation have hope of living in a world where common sense prevails and our economy becomes based upon sustainable economic principles (in contrast to the present debt driven economic principles). When Will the Global Economic Collapse Happen? The global collapse should have happened last year, when the Greek economy was close to bankruptcy. But the economic spin merchants have somehow persuaded the global public that good (increasingly debt driven) times will continue. Now both Greece and Ireland have massive loans from the European Union, which only exacerbates the overall debt problem in Europe. The crunch will come soon when the larger nations of Spain and Italy approach bankruptcy. Many economic commentators believe that their national economies are too large for the European Union to bail them out, with the consequences that the Euro itself would then go into free downfall. Then there is the problem that the US economy has never really pulled itself out of recession. They is no longer in a technical recession, but the US economy is so sluggish and most States highly indebted that a small negative factor could now throw the global stock markets into panic selling. If the inevitable European debt crisis does not bring that about, we have the Chinese dampening Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 20 ************************************************* their over heating policies and the price of oil is starting to go through the roof with war and turmoil emerging in the Middle East. The debt promoting spin merchants are still holding the public confidence, and it will take perhaps another six months for the public panic to really set in. I look now to October 2011 as the time for possible global economic collapse. I am waiting for the first tangible sign of collapsing public confidence before I release my second letter to Senators (and independents and Greens in the lower house). From April 2002, I have been producing analyses every three months, and sending these assessments out in a quarterly publication Recent Australian Economic Trends which is available by email to anyone contacting me and requesting to be placed upon the email distribution list. Any assessment of Australian financial management and bank regulatory policy, must begin with an assessment of the current state of Australia’s financial affairs. In particular, it is vital that we analyse such significant national financial indicators as Gross Domestic Product, Gross Foreign Equity, Gross Foreign Debt, Gross Foreign Liabilities, Domestic Credit, and Total Australian Liabilities. Figures for these data are available on Internet at the website for the Reserve Bank of Australia (http://www.rba.gov.au/statistics/ ). In this article, I have taken quarterly data from June 2006. You can confirm these data by looking up Gross Foreign Debt, Gross Foreign Equity and Gross Foreign Liabilities on Reserve Bank table H4, seasonally adjusted Domestic Credit on table D2, and Gross National Product on table G10, and Net Foreign Liabilities (Equity and Debt) from table H5. These figures are provided by the Australian Reserve Bank every quarter. The Australian Reserve Bank has on 3/March/11 published the December 2010 figures for GDP. So now we have available all the information for all these statistical categories up until the end of September 2010. I simply rearrange the Reserve Bank figures which helps with comparison and trend analysis, and so it can be easily understood by the lay person. I add together the figures for Gross Foreign Equity, Gross Foreign Debt and Domestic Credit to come up with an overall figure of “Total Australian Liabilities”. These three-monthly analyses tend to forecast turbulent weather ahead, much in the manner of a barometer. [Other relevant tables and comments can be obtained from David at above address.] ■ ********************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 21 ************************************************* Limits of public assistance This article has been extracted from a very recent blog by Prof Bill Mitchell (University of Newcastle, NSW). This is the part of the blog where I have to be sensitive. The same situation occurs after a major bushfire which regularly is the case in Australia. I recognise that economists (even the most progressive of our species) take a particular view of things which at times, might seem cold and calculated to those who live in the world of emotion. I recognise that many people have died in the floods. Sure, there is some criticism of Australia that we are being insensitive to the Brazilian catastrophe which in numerical terms is infinitely more severe than our floods. The news coverage of the Brazilian situation has been dominated by the Queensland floods that is true. There has also been fairly detailed coverage of the Latin American disaster. But when the water is rising in your own backyard and people are being airlifted off roofs then the attention does get focused locally. I don't think we should feel guilty about that. I also recognise that people to the north of me (Queensland, Northern NSW) and now people to the south of me (Victoria) have been hit by very severe floods which have cast aside their dreams and the more concrete realities - their houses and all that was within them. So empathy for the troubles that those who have lost their loved ones and had their material lives compromised is important at all times. Especially now that it turns out that the insurance industry is once again taking the technical route to minimise their exposure - as always. In the mountain areas around Melbourne where I grew up there are very salubrious houses (within commuting distance of the city) and the bush amenity is gorgeous. The residents enjoy larger blocks of land, an ambience with trees, peace, etc. The physical amenity delivers rewards to these residents that are not enjoyed by other people in the city. And no-one forces them to build houses in these areas. The reality is that bushfires ravage these areas from time to time but when a major fire goes through there, considerable loss of life and property is normal. At that point, everyone expects the public sector to bail out the homeowners. The robustly private citizens thus Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 22 ************************************************* do not take all the risk of their own decisions. I always thought that if the insurance industry had any purpose it was to assume this risk. The reality is different and the private insurance industry does all it can to shed this risk - often with dodgy small print in contracts that most of us cannot understand. And when disaster strikes the private benefits give way to social bailouts. There is a case to be made for a national insurance body to offer low cost but full coverage insurance for all citizens. Those who live in disaster prone areas would pay the premium commensurate with the risk and not expect public handouts when disaster strikes. I find it inconsistent that those who eschew government action for the disadvantaged and the poor in normal times are always ready to accept government aid during times of disaster for the consequences of what are essentially (but not always) poor private decisions. Conclusion So a rising budget deficit is required to meet this national disaster and that will reflect responsible fiscal leadership from the Federal government. Anyway whoever wants offsetting (more or less) tax rises and/or spending cuts elsewhere does not understand how budgets work and what their role is. Unfortunately, I suspect the government itself is in that camp. ■ *************************************** Tackle Big Coal at your own risk Clive Hamilton February 3, 2011 The Age As alarm among scientists about runaway global warming intensifies so do efforts by the coal industry and its backers in government to stifle citizen protests. This week in Newcastle campaigners from the Rising Tide group face prosecution for a protest last September that shut down for a day the city's two coal export terminals operated by Port Waratah Coal Services (PWCS), a company owned by the mining giants Rio Tinto and Xstrata. Those who engage in civil disobedience expect to face the legal consequences, but PWCS has upped the ante by asking the police to prosecute seven activists under victims-of-crime laws, demanding they hand over hundreds of thousands of dollars. In an Orwellian inversion of the meaning of words, corporate goliaths whose activities threaten the conditions of life on earth - Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 23 ************************************************* whose daily business is already, according to the World Health Organisation, contributing to tens of thousands of deaths around the world each year - claim they are being victimised. The coal industry's action is designed to have a chilling effect on protests against the burning and export of coal. The action by PWCS has all the hallmarks of a SLAPP, a Strategic Lawsuit Against Public Participation. The purpose of a SLAPP is to frighten citizens with the loss of their houses and get them bogged down for years in court proceedings. Legal costs can amount to hundreds of thousands of dollars, chickenfeed for a big corporation but bankruptcy for ordinary citizens. The intimidatory effect can be paralysing. One favourite tactic is to deliver writs on Christmas Eve so those who receive them have to sweat for a fortnight before they can get legal advice that may allay their fears. A pattern is emerging in efforts to deter protests against Australia's coal industry. After meeting with state attorneys-general in December 2008, Martin Ferguson, the federal Energy Minister (and climate science denier), urged state governments to toughen up laws to impede protests against ''energy infrastructure''. Ferguson seems to have been spooked by opposition to the Hazelwood power plant in Victoria (the dirtiest in the country) and by the acquittal of six Greenpeace activists over a protest at Kingsnorth power station in Britain. The jury accepted they acted to prevent greater harm. Since the meeting with Ferguson, state governments have begun passing draconian legislation aimed specifically at deterring protests against the coal industry. The Labor government in Victoria introduced harsh new laws against climate change protests, with up to one year's jail merely for standing in the grounds of a coal-fired power plant, and two years for anyone painting a slogan on a smokestack. The Kingsnorth defence of ''lawful excuse'' can no longer be made in Victoria, no matter how much damage Hazelwood is causing to the climate. In Queensland, the Labor government is considering similar laws. NSW has not yet followed the Victorian example, but since the meeting between Ferguson and the attorneys-general, climate activists have several times been threatened with victims' compensation claims. An adverse court decision in Newcastle this week would set an alarming precedent not just for climate activism but for all protests in NSW. A corporation experiencing any disruption due to protests Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 24 ************************************************* would be emboldened to go after the assets of protesters. A democracy in which citizens are afraid of going to jail for peacefully protesting or losing their homes because of intimidatory lawsuits is no democracy at all. Yet Labor governments have been as willing as the Howard government was to silence dissenting voices, especially in defence of the energy industries. Victims' support legislation was designed to compensate victims of violent crimes, including families of homicide victims, not to provide global corporations with a stick to beat their critics. The average amount received by a victim of crime in NSW is $12,300. For having its coal loader shut down for a few hours, PWCS is demanding the courts award the company $525,000. Big Coal has taken the gloves off and has signalled it will use every device available to defend its continued profitability. Its attitude seems to be that if the rights of citizens are collateral damage, then so be it. ■ Clive Hamilton is professor of public ethics at Charles Sturt University. ********************************** John Coulter questions the cost of nuclear generated electricity. So much has been claimed for the cheapness of nuclear generated electricity and in recent times so much attention has been paid to what is happening in Japan. However little coverage has been given to the fact that across the world nuclear has not had to carry the cost of insurance against the sorts of accidents that we are now witnessing in Japan. In every country the size of the required coverage has been limited and in the event of an accident the general public is required to carry the financial (to say nothing of the health) risk of a serious accident. The attached paper could not be downloaded. It gave a brief run-down of the situation in a number of countries and also comments on how this unsatisfactory situation is often kept from public attention. It raises the question: if nuclear had to pay the full cost of insurance against these catastrophic accidents what would nuclear generated electricity cost? It also raises the interesting question of how does one estimate the acceptability of a technology in which the risk of an accident happening may be very low but the consequences if an accident does occur can be enormous and very long lasting. For example, hundreds of square kilometres of country around Chernobyl are still off limits and will remain so for decades or centuries. It's like asking the mathematical question: zero x infinity = ? ■ ********************************************* Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 25 ************************************************* Fukushima Fallout Posted by Dave Elliott on April 10, 2011 After the Fukushima disaster, Electricite de France CEO Henri Proglio said ‘Nuclear is a formidable source of energy.’ Maybe a nuance there lost in translation? Regardless, views do seem to have changed. In a public opinion poll in France just after the Japanese disaster, 55% said they were not in favour of a proposal by France’s main green party to drop nuclear power, but 42% were in favour. This in the most pro-nuclear country in the world. As you might expect, in anti-nuclear Spain a 40-year old Spanish plant built to the same design as Fukushima’s reactor 1, became engulfed by calls for a shut down. In anti-nuclear Germany all the old plants were shut and there were massive anti-nuclear demonstrations, a swing to the Green Party in the regional elections, and talk of closing all the plants by 2020, a position now backed by the German Association of Energy and Water Industries (BDEW). And even in allegedly pro-nuclear UK, support for nuclear fell 12%, from 47% to 35%. A safety review followed in the UK, and stress tests were carried out across the EU. Meanwhile China halted all new nuclear projects and initiated a review of policy.. Given that the core containments seem mostly to have held so far, the Fukushima accident wasn’t seen as being of the same order as Chernobyl, although it did involve several reactors, rather than just one, as well as several spent fuel storage ponds, including material stored above the reactor, some of which was evidently scattered around. But we have yet to see what exactly the final impact will be. [Changed now to the same order as Chernobyl. Ed.] At the time of the quake/ tsunami in Japan, there were 3,400 tons of spent fuel in seven storage pools at Fukushima, some of it still very active, plus 877 tons of active fuel in the cores of the reactors. That totals 4,277 tons of nuclear fuel at Fukushima - the storage pool above reactor 4 alone contained 135 tons of spent fuel. For comparison, the Chernobyl reactors had about 180 tons when the accident occurred in 1986 and about 6% of that was released into atmosphere. We don’t know yet what percentage was released in the air, land and sea at Fukushima - it will presumably be much lower in percent terms - but leakages are still ongoing. Chernobyl recounts Although there were deaths due to the explosions, so far no radiation deaths have been reported at Fukushima, and some commentators have argued that it will remain so. This hopeful view Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 26 ************************************************* was buttressed by a new report from the United Nations Scientific Committee on the Effects of Atomic Radiation published in February, which says that the known death toll from Chernobyl was just 28 fatalities among emergency workers, plus 15 fatal cases of child thyroid cancer by 2005, some of which may have been avoided if iodine tablets had been taken (as they have now in Japan). And it says ‘To date, there has been no persuasive evidence of any other health effect in the general population that can be attributed to radiation exposure’. It doesn’t speculate about future deaths ‘because of unacceptable uncertainties in the predictions’, but previous IAEA/WHO reports have talked of around 4000. For a very different view see ‘Chernobyl: Consequences of the Catastrophe for People and the Environment’ published in 2010 by the New York Academy of Sciences and authored by Russian biologist Dr. Alexey Yablokov; Dr. Alexey Nesterenko, a biologist /ecologist in Belarus; and Dr.Vassili Nesterenko, a physicist and at the time of the accident director of the Institute of Nuclear Energy of the National Academy of Sciences of Belarus. Its editor is Dr. Janette Sherman, a physician and toxicologist involved in studying the health impacts of radiation. It concludes that, based on records now available, some 985,000 people died, mainly of cancer, as a result of the Chernobyl accident, between when the accident occurred in 1986 and 2004. More deaths, it projects, will follow. High estimates like this raised some hackles, including some bitter comments from the Guardian’s George Monbiot, a new convert to the nuclear cause. However, there are clearly differing view on the impacts of radiation, one view being that some low level emitters, if ingested/breathed in, can cause much more damage than is usually assumed. A review of the New York Academy’s report in the journal Radiation Protection Dosimetry .concluded that it makes clear ‘that international nuclear agencies and some national authorities remain in denial about the scale of the health disasters in their countries due to Chernobyl’s fallout. This is shown by their reluctance to acknowledge contamination and health outcomes data, their ascribing observed morbidity/mortality increases to nonradiation causes, and their refusal to devote resources to rehabilitation and disaster management.’ The debate over numbers will no doubt continue. One might hazard a guess that the truth is somewhere in between the extremes. For example the independent 2006 TORCH report Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 27 ************************************************* estimated the final death toll as likely to be 30,000-60,000, which seems more credible. www.chernobylreport.org However it’s clearly an area of continuing dispute, which will no doubt become even more fraught given the estimate by Prof. Chris Busby that there could eventually be over 400,000 deaths from Fukushima: http://llrc.org/fukushima/fukushimariskcalc.pdf While predictions like this may be provocative, the reality seems to be that we just don’t know for sure, or at least can’t agree, and it’s that uncertainty that may be the most worrying thing to many people. What next? We now await the various safety reviews and policy responses Some other countries have already moved quickly (some say too quickly) to change, or reassert, existing policies. But it seems unlikely that the UK government will make radical changes. Although he accepted that there could now be more financial problems, Energy Secretary Chris Huhne was still upbeat. He told the House of Commons on 24th March ‘We have to put an emphasis on safety. That is why we commissioned Dr Mike Weightman’s report’. However, although he said that ‘we will have to wait to see its results and base the debate on the facts’, he added ’ I do not anticipate that it will lead to enormous changes’. And later on he was quoted as saying ‘There is no intention for us to do anything but learn the lessons… for example, about the back up for cooling.’ That seems to be the very minimum necessary, and even that would surely require the government to reconsider the conclusions of its ‘Nuclear Justification’ exercise: the still to be completed ‘Generic Design Assessment’ for the new plants has already been extended. One thing seems clear, if we still do go ahead, with all the proposed new plants and their waste stores being at sea level on the coast, the extra cost of improving safety, tightening regulation and upgrading insurance cover and evacuation procedures could be large. Huhne has said that: ‘We can do the 80% reduction in emissions by 2050 without new nuclear, but it will require a big effort on carbon capture and storage and renewables.’ It could well be that the balance has now tipped and that this alternative approach, with energy efficiency also included, could be preferable and could cost less. U.S. Energy Secretary Steven Chu recently claimed that wind and solar may compete with fossil fuels, without subsidies, within the next decade. Can the same be said of nuclear? ■ ****************************************************** Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 28 ************************************************* Resilience and global financial governance Ross Buckley is Professor of International Finance Law at the University of New South Wales (This chapter appears in Resilience and Transformation: Preparing Australia for Uncertain Futures. Steven Cork (Editor). CSIRO Publishing, Melbourne.) Resilience is generally seen as a positive attribute that should be enhanced. When a system is dysfunctional and needs to change its structure and identity, however, resilience can be a negative. As this chapter illustrates, our system of global financial governance works to benefit the elites in international banks and developing countries at the direct expense of the common people in those countries. The system is deeply unfair and dysfunctional and displays great negative resilience. This chapter analyses ways in which this negative resilience could be reduced. Introduction A range of concepts is commonly used in analysing the global financial system, including stability, volatility, efficiency and others. Resilience is not among them. Yet we have a very resilient global financial system. It is unstable, volatile, narrowly efficient and highly resilient, principally in the negative sense of being resistant to change. Resilience is the capacity of a system to withstand external shocks and retain its essential characteristics; its identity. Generally resilience is a positive feature. But when a system needs to change fundamentally and be restructured, resilience can be a marked negative. The global financial system is somewhat functional from the perspective of OECD nations and the international commercial banks, and quite dysfunctional from the perspective of developing countries. It displays a high degree of negative resilience. Even the global financial crisis (GFC) has so far led to little substantive change in the system that produced it. The GFC has led to higher capital requirements, particularly for trading, tighter liquidity controls, closer supervision and restrictions on bankers’ bonuses, but none of these changes are fundamental. If one considers how profoundly different the global financial system is today from what it was 30 or 40 years ago, these changes are merely cosmetic. Even the macro-prudential regulatory function in which systemic risk across the financial system is to be assessed and monitored, which is to be carried out by institutions such as the new European Systemic Risk Board, is but a belated example of Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 29 ************************************************* regulation beginning to catch up with market changes that are decades old. The only real change to the system as a result of the GFC has been the handover of economic coordinating authority from the G7 to the G20 nations. Comprising 19 nations and the European Union, the G20 represents 85% of global gross domestic product (GDP), 80% of world trade and two-thirds of the world’s people. In addition to the G7 nations, it includes Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Turkey, Australia, South Africa and others. This is an important change. Brazil, China and India not having a voice in economic policy coordination was becoming increasingly ridiculous. This change, however, is yet to result in any fundamental changes to the system, in part because the G20 is merely a gathering of national leaders; it is not a formally constituted international organisation and lacks the capacity to enforce its decisions. So why is a system that, for so many of its participants, is deeply dysfunctional so resilient? The answer lies in whom the current system serves and the general paucity of knowledge, outside those it serves, about how it works and its effects. The strong negative resilience of the global financial governance system Resilience science teaches us that strongly resilient systems have strong feedback loops. This concept of feedback loops, developed in analysing systems, explains much of the resilience of our global financial system. The feedback loops in global financial governance show that the system tends to reward the international commercial banks and the elites in developing countries at the expense of the common people in the debtor countries. A few examples will suffice. After the debt crisis struck in 1982 a way was needed to allow many hundreds of creditors to negotiate with many hundreds of debtors in each debtor nation. The commercial banks appointed steering committees comprising representatives from six to eight banks to represent all creditors and persuaded the sovereign debtor to also represent all other debtors within its jurisdiction (including state governments, state-owned industries and private corporations). This was sensible. The banks, however, went further and persuaded the debtor nations to bring all debt incurred by all entities within their jurisdiction under their sovereign guarantee. This was completely unnecessary and, from the perspective of the common people in the debtor nations, appalling. The inevitable, Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 30 ************************************************* massive shortfall between what the sovereign now owed the bank creditors and what it could recover from the original debtors became a charge on government revenues. The people paid in reduced services so that the foreign banks could receive a free credit upgrade on most of their assets. Likewise in Indonesia after the Asian economic crisis, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the foreign commercial banks insisted that the Republic of Indonesia assume the obligations of the local banks to foreign lenders and then seek to recover the funds from the local banks; by selling their assets if necessary. This again proved a difficult task and only about 28% of the total liabilities assumed have been recovered (Asian Development Bank 2009). Almost three-quarters of the costs of repaying those foreign loans has thus been borne by the Indonesian people. Yet there was no reason for Indonesia to assume responsibility for these loans. The market mechanism, if left to work, would have seen many of these Indonesian banks placed into bankruptcy by their Western creditors who would have received a proportion, presumably in the order of 28%, of their claims in the bankruptcy proceedings. Instead, insolvent local banks were put into bankruptcy by Indonesia, the creditors were repaid in full and the Indonesian people bore most of the cost of that repayment. The funds to repay the creditors came from the long-term loans organised by the IMF and invariably were described as bail outs of the debtor nations. Yet these loans were required to be used to repay outstanding indebtedness; so the bail outs were of the foreign banks. In Indonesia, the IMF coordinated a restructuring that socialised massive amounts of private sector debt (Buckley 2002). Similarly, the centrepiece of the G20 response to the GFC in April 2009 was a US$500 billion additional credit facility for debtor nations. The conditions required to be eligible for these loans, however, exclude virtually all African and most Latin American nations. While it is not apparent on the face of the conditions, they are carefully crafted so that most of these loans will go to their intended destination; the East European countries. The German banks are heavily over-exposed to these countries. So this additional credit facility, in large measure, is designed to bail out the German banks. The funds lent come from the G20 nations, which know they will be repaid; official credit always is. The loss will fall on the people of these Eastern European nations, who will labour under massive debt burdens for decades to come. Once again normal Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 31 ************************************************* market processes, which in Eastern Europe would have led to German banks incurring large losses on their ill-judged, excessive lending to the region, are abrogated to prefer foreign banks at the direct expense of the people of the poorer nations. The benefits of our system of global financial governance to the commercial banks are thus manifestly clear. The market is given full rein when yielding large profits to the banks, but is interfered with when it would yield large losses. The benefits to the elites in developing countries are far less obvious, but are often very substantial and are the reason that voices well-placed to argue against the current system are rarely raised against it. An example is in the restructuring of Indonesia’s indebtedness after the Asian crisis. When the assets of the insolvent local banks were sold, who was best placed to bid for those assets? Who knew everything about the assets and precisely what they were worth? The families that had owned them and were the principal shareholders of the banks. So, in effect, these families were able to regain control of the assets they had owned before the crisis with their foreign debts discharged by their government, all for an average cost of 28%. Who would speak out against such extraordinary largesse? Would you if, somehow, you could repay your home mortgage for onefourth of the debt owing? Our system of financial governance neatly transferred the real cost of the crisis, which should have been borne by borrowers and lenders that had engaged in imprudent borrowing and lending, onto the people of the debtor nations who had done nothing. As Professor Luis Carlos Bresser Pereria, former Finance Minister of Brazil, testified before a US House Committee in the aftermath of the debt crisis, the elites in the debtor nations often profited from that crisis (Pereira 1990). Periods of great volatility and forced asset sales offer huge opportunities to those with access to better information, power and financial resources. Overall, the system of global financial governance has displayed a quite remarkable degree of resilience. When one analyses whom it serves, this is unsurprising. Any system that rewards the powerful at the expense of the powerless is likely to prosper. Yet the system was not designed to do this. Its architects were Keynes and White at Bretton Woods in 1944. Their primary goal was the promotion of global trade. Fixed exchange rates were to facilitate that trade. The IMF was established to provide short-term Vol. 3 No. 53 May - June 2011 ERA Newsletter 32 ************************************************* loans and technical advice to nations to facilitate their management of these fixed rates. This fixed exchange-rate system ended in the 1970s as the US went off the gold standard and floated its currency and other developed nations followed suit. During the 1970s, the IMF’s core mission ended. Global institutions are, however, notoriously hard to kill. Witness the Bank for International Settlements, which Keynes and White had intended be closed but which lived on to become the most significant global banking regulatory institution. So the IMF continued on until the debt crisis of 1982 gave it a new role. The commercial banks needed to keep lending to the sovereign debtors so they could service their debts, but they didn’t want to advance more funds without changes to the policies that had led these nations to the brink of insolvency. Yet it was politically impossible for a Bank of America or J.P. Morgan to be dictating economic policy to a Brazil or Argentina. The IMF stepped in. As a supposedly independent international financial institution it was well-positioned to play the role of crisis manager of nations in trouble. It was well-positioned for the role but not staffed or equipped to discharge it. So the IMF performed poorly, with disastrous consequences for the human rights of poor people in poor nations. Yet it has continued to fulfil this function, with substantially unchanged policies, for over a quarter of a century – talk about negative resilience! Over time, as its litany of policy failures began to mount, the Fund attracted sustained, unrelenting criticism from both sides of politics in the US and from developing countries and it was allowed to shrink in size from a total staff approaching 3000 to about 1700 (Vines and Gilbert 2004, Meltzer 2000). Yet in 2009, another crisis rescued the Fund. The GFC meant the G20 needed an organisation through which it could channel most of its US$1.1 trillion funding package, a bill the IMF fitted. And so, today, the credibility of the IMF has been somewhat restored by having a new role and its staffing levels are again climbing. The IMF continues to exert control over the economic policies of developing countries in crisis some 35 years after the role for which it was established ended. It has proven to be a remarkably resilient institution, to the detriment of a substantial proportion of the people on the planet. ■ [To be concluded in next issue.] *************************************************