State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 The Impacts of Intercity Competition and Intergovernmental Factors on Local Affordable Housing Expenditures Victoria Basolo 1999 Abstract Intercity competition reduces the likelihood of cities to spend local dollars on housing programs Intergovernmental factors positively influence cities to spend local dollars on housing programs Introduction Federal devolution and funding cutbacks put pressure on cities Cities cannot afford housing programs Redistributive policies may cause mid to upper income people to move away Cities use zoning regulations to exclude high density housing New Jersey - Mount Laurel case of exclusionary zoning Court mandated cities in the state provide their fair share of low and moderate income housing Most affordable housing programs originate from the federal government Federal and state governments often require cities to set aside revenue for affordable housing programs Intercity Competition Cities compete to maintain population base, fiscal health, and to attract new residents Tiebout the individual will choose the community with the best local services If the community fails, the individual moves However, Tiebout ignores other factors such as life cycle, distance to work, proximity to family and friends Peterson people consider costs and benefits of government services Reason cities will eschew redistributive policies Lower tax Federal government should be responsible for redistributive policies Schneider local market with businesses and residents on the demand side and the government on the supply side Synthesis of the public choice perspective Tiebout residents as buyers and city as sellers Niskanen budget maximization Peterson motives of city decision makers Schneider/Peterson – with redistributive policies, lower income people pay less taxes and receive housing while higher income pay more and gain little Downs city competition allows cities to maintain a reasonable tax rate in order to attract residents State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Inconsistent with redistributive policy The solution to city competition is state and regional allocation of resources Rusk states should facilitate annexation while the federal government should provide incentives for metropolitan organization Intergovernmental Influences Regulations are implemented through federal grant programs Shift in attitude toward government has resulted in a trend toward small central government and devolution of responsibilities Significant decline in federal budget authority for low income housing, but federal budget outlays for assisted housing have increased steadily. State policy regulations may direct local policy and require certain activities Localities are required to assess and meet community needs California law mandates redevelopment agencies set aside a percentage of earnings Federal devolution increased state involvement but state funding still remained low Research Questions and Methods Does interjurisdictional competition decrease spending on affordable housing? Intergovernmental (IG) funds stimulate cities to spend more local revenue Do cities spend more as IG increases? States have direct control over localities and can force localities to perform certain tasks Are housing plans or set aside mandates more likely to spend local dollars? Results 48% of cities cooperate with their neighbors to achieve balanced economic development 19% perceived cooperation between their city and neighboring jurisdictions 32% had no consideration of the neighboring cities activities Federal government is the largest source of funding and funds most affordable housing Local housing professionals queried Federal funding is very important State funding is less important State mandated planning is more prevalent than housing set aside requirements Cities rely on IG dollars (federal grants) but the effects on local expenditures are still unknown More than ½ of the respondent cities spent zero city funds on housing programs As intercity competition increases, cities are less likely to spend funds on affordable housing 2 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Conclusion Federal government has the greatest level of influence regarding local expenditures on affordable housing Competitive cities are less likely to spend local funds on affordable housing Federal funding encourages cities to spend more Inclusionary Housing in California and New Jersey: A Comparative Analysis Nico Calavita Kenneth Grimes Alan Mallach 1997 Summary IH should be part of the affordable housing strategy – but that is unlikely Introduction Intensified gap between upper and lower class due to: Residential segregation creates urban underclass Less manufacturing jobs Inner-city isolation from job market Higher living standards of suburbs HUD counteracts this with mobility programs For example: moving to Opportunity for Fair Housing Demonstration Help low income families move to healthier communities State level initiatives: “Anti-snob zoning” in Mass Public housing depends largely on public sector subsidies HUD residential mobility programs This dependence raises serious questions of the programs effectiveness IH is a different approach that is emerging Inclusionary Housing Describes techniques that link construction of low and moderate-income homes to construction of housing for the marketplace Includes lower income units in a market driven development IH objectives Increase supply of affordable housing Foster greater economic and racial residential integration Superior to section 236 and Section 8 which fostered integration at the macro scale Resulted in isolation within suburbia Uncertainties for IH Susceptible to pressure from both market and political conditions 3 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Politically appealing but market declines increase developer resistance New Jersey and California have the most experience with IH California IH programs are the result of the housing affordability crisis, growth control, and land use regulations Between 1970 and 1993 gross rent levels increased 436% Home prices increased 723% Median household income increased 316% Reasons for increase in CA housing costs High demand Development Impact Fees (DIFs) Growth controls Public policies can mitigate impact Building permit priority for development of affordable units “Cost offset” approach to IH initiated with the development of Irvine (voluntary inclusionary program): Rezoning impact on low and moderate income housing needs Resulted in a settlement that required the Irvine Company to produce 700 units of low and moderate income housing City provides offsets and financing off-site infrastructure 1979 lawsuit together with a requirement from the Air Resources Board mandated an inclusionary program in Orange County. Required provision of affordable housing in the vicinity of new jobs New Jersey Mount Laurel decision Found that zoning was being used to exclude low and moderate income households Court found that developing municipalities must provide fair share However, the court provided no specific guidance on how to do so Mount Laurel problems of inclusionary zoning led to the Mount Laurel II decision in January 1983 Decision cut through barriers to effective relief Established procedure for providing low and moderate income housing “Builders remedy” – lower courts were instructed to grant zoning relief and even building permits Legal Framework California No clear state mandate or fiscal incentives for inclusionary programs Most inclusionary programs are adopted locally and subject to local political and economic conditions New Jersey Council On Affordable Housing (COAH) - includes IH Encourages compliance with Mount Laurel mandate Regulation implementation is generally a one-size-fits-all approach 4 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Unresponsive to differences in environmental, social, economic, and political conditions However, it does offer an element of predictability Evolution of IH Programs California HCD prepared a “Model Inclusionary Ordinance” Diversity of IH programs early on due to housing crisis 1980s – HCD used a hands off approach toward IH Regulatory relief, costs offsets – counter costs incurred in providing inclusionary units New Jersey IH was rare in NJ before Mount Laurel II decision in 1983 Federal low-income housing tax credit significant cost offset In 1990 – reduction in density led to construction of single family subdivisions in order for developers to find relief in inclusionary requirements Conclusion Each locality should meet its fair share of the region’s affordable housing need Seek to lower the burden of the developer through the cost-offset approach Diminished IH support due to antiregulatory pressure and economic tends IH survival depends on affordability, home ownership preference, and cost offset compromises IH is an important too but not a sufficient strategy to fully address all needs Subsidizing Redevelopment in California Michael Dardia, 1998 Summary Redevelopment Agencies (RDAs) Developed in 1945 to combat urban blight Engage in variety of activities today Provide municipal infrastructure Assist in provision of affordable housing Renovation of commercial downtown areas Tax increment financing for RDAs causes strain for other local jurisdictions Purpose of study Estimate size of subsidies that RDAs receive Judge effect of RDA actions on the increase in property values Examine the degree of blight in project areas Results Project areas were worse off than the average area in most cities Fewer than ¼ of the projects came close to being responsible for the property tax revenues they received Total tax increment revenues was $78 million $40 million can be explained by actions of RDAs 5 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 $38 million in subsidy from other jurisdictions to the RDAs Continuing on the same pattern for the other 76 projects, total subsidy would be $170 million annually Recommendations 1. The legislature should formally clarify its goals for redevelopment. 2. Blight conditions need to be aligned with the goals for redevelopment and made more precise. 3. There should be a formal oversight authority to monitor RDA behavior. 4. If the legislature intends redevelopment to be self-financing rather than highly subsidized, the pass-through rate should be increased significantly. Introduction Controversy over RDAs 1994-1995 -- 351 RDA projects spent $3.3 billion to build 5,000 low-income housing and 6,000 others Also displaced 500 households Received $1.5 billon in property taxes Initiated several new projects that consisted of thousands of acres of vacant land Conflict revolves around tax increment financing Property tax increase in any RDA project area goes to the RDA RDA is not necessarily responsible for raise in real estate value What is Redevelopment and how is it financed? RDAs designate specific redevelopment projects and focus on blighted areas RDAs will purchase and assemble lots for use by developers and provide infrastructure and affordable housing The state gives RDAs special powers Can assemble properties for sale Can use eminent domain to acquire property to sell Receive city general funds, federal Community development Block Grants Financed through increases in property tax revenues Not shared among all jurisdictions Payments to RDAs last as long as there is outstanding debt Why is Redevelopment Financing Controversial? RDAs receive 97% of all tax increment revenues in the state When property taxes go to RDAs instead of school districts, the state must reimburse the school districts Tax increment financing can create financial incentives to declare blight AB 1290 (1993) tightened the definition of blight as well as changed the distribution of tax increment revenues Any new RDAs share 1/3 of their tax increment revenues with other local taxing jurisdictions The Redevelopment Process Redevelopment Agencies City council is usually the governing board of the RDA In larger city agencies, the city council appoints a governing board 6 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 RDAs can purchase and sell property, make loans or grants, enter into contracts, seize property by eminent domain and construct or rehabilitate structures Redevelopment Projects RDA identifies a project area which is a blighted area where redevelopment will take place Projects are equally divided among commercial, residential, and public uses RDA must complete a preliminary Report (as well as an EIR) Evidence of blighted conditions and plans to eliminate blight Financing structure Sets time limits Size of Redevelopment Activity Statewide, redevelopment agencies received total revenues of $1.2 billion in 1984-1985 and $2.2 billion in 1993-1994 Project improvement is the largest operating expense Real estate purchases were only 4% of total operating expenditures Policy Issues Critics of redevelopment Opposed to the use of governmental powers like eminent domain and view land write downs as gifts of public funds Tax increment financing is viewed as a diversion of property taxes Opposition of glaring abuses Designation of vacant land as blighted Attracting retail firms that generate sales tax revenues Reluctance to provide affordable housing How Blighted Are Project Areas? Legal definition is not precise enough Cities can benefit from 30 years of tax increment revenues AB 1290 – both physical and economic blight conditions are necessary to be classified as blighted Do RDAs Generate Enough of the Growth in Project Areas to Earn Their Tax Increment? Dependent on how much RDAs contribute to local growth Who “Loses” Under Tax Increment Financing? Tax increment financing causes conflict Subsidies can change the distribution of public expenditures Study Design and Methodology Measure property value—assessed value not market value Results How blighted are project areas? Average differences vary within each city Conclusions Difficult to quantify blight and as a result it is difficult to assess its extent Easier to assess the size of subsidies for redevelopment 7 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Match pair analysis yielded that redevelopment did have some positive effect on assessed values AB 1290 was a significant revision to redevelopment law New pass through laws increases the percentage of tax increment revenues the must be shared with other government Results in less subsidies for RDAs California’s Housing Element Law: The Issue of Local Noncompliance Paul G. Lewis, 2003 Housing element – often called fair-share housing law Housing element process Regional council which represents cities Assign a housing unit goal (allocation) to each city California’s housing element problem Broad notion of fair-share Long standing problem of housing affordability and underproduction Limits lower and middle class opportunities California law requires local governments to update their housing element periodically HCD reviews the update and certifies it if it is acceptable Failure to satisfy HCD or to update results in noncompliance Noncompliance limits eligibility for certain state and federal funds Testing Competing Explanations for Local Noncompliance Large majorities of jurisdictions in the state have been noncompliant at some point Lack of vacant land Aversion to new housing, overt antigrowth policies Lack of planning capacity or experience Older housing stock SB 910 would have required fines for noncompliant cities This study examines differences between cities able to attain housing element compliance and those who have not The Relationship between Compliance and Housing Production Housing element defenders argue that compliance enables more housing to be built Other factors influence why some cities experience rapid housing development and others do not Demographic characteristics Position in urban hierarchy Physical capacity to accommodate new buildings, etc. Housing element noncompliance is not a significant predictor of the rate of multifamily development Cities that were job centers and with fewer senior citizens experience faster rates of multifamily housing development 8 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Cities with noncompliant housing elements developed new housing that was weighted more toward single-family units Rethinking the Housing Element Approach Tensions between various policy goals: Increased housing production, an equitable distribution of housing responsibility, special attention to housing needs of low-income groups, local autonomy, environmental protection, etc. Production of affordable housing rests mainly with profit motives of private developers Necessary to seek a more workable approach to housing policy where success and failure have measurable results Fair-share planning approach to encourage overall housing production may place an unrealistic burden on housing policy Introduction Controversies over Local Government Noncompliance with the Law Local governments are not energetic in planning for housing and are trying to deflect their fair share onto other jurisdictions High land costs and lack of state and federal funding About 1/3 of all cities and more than 1/5 of all counties had their housing elements judged noncompliant by HCD Other localities are overdue in submitting their draft housing elements History Enacted in 1969 - requires detailed planning to meet housing needs 1970 – additional legislature required HCD prepare a statewide housing element Statewide housing planning became more active during the Brown administration (1975-1983) Developed guidelines for implementation and enforcement of the statute More aggressive approach toward fair-share goals By the 1980s, the concept of fair-share was fully enshrined in state law Reallocation process of housing needs became more fully developed Housing element revisions Emphasized performance over process of housing element planning Contentions Inconsistent levels of compliance with housing element law Fear of litigation motivates local governments to expend time and resources on housing elements Opposition from housing advocates, growth opponents and school districts Low and moderate-income housing needs are typically unmet Preparation of housing elements does not guarantee housing units will be built Regional allocations do not take into account many local factors such as planning and growth policies, habitat preservation, clean air and traffic congestion 9 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Housing element laws emerged from frustration with local exclusion of affordable housing or multifamily units Reasons for Noncompliant Housing Elements Four main factors: Community social status and exclusion Attempt of upper-income homeowners to insulate their cities Local land-use characteristics and vacant land Lack of sufficient land resources to accommodate new housing unit requirements Local governments often have vacant sites zoned for industrial or commercial use Resources of the local government Small cities may be fiscally strained, or may not have professional staff to prepare adequate housing elements Performance in producing housing depends on the availability of subsidized housing funds Local politics and residential growth policies Antigrowth and growth management policies Comparing compliant with noncompliant Noncompliant tend to be cities of slightly higher status Social exclusion Noncompliant tend to be older cities and lower population density Noncompliant has additional restrictive growth management policies Cities with larger populations are more likely to reach compliance, due to greater resources and less influence from homeowners and more from pro-growth business Relationship between compliance and production Housing market and demographic factors outweigh compliance status in contributing to variations in growth rates Analysis does not determine relationship of compliance to production of affordable units No measurable relationship between compliance and overall housing production Reforms Past attempts at reforms included penalties, self-certification and transfers of allocation Recommended shift would be to directly reward effective performance based on number and mix of new developments Experiences in other states regarding fair-share planning and state review of local housing policy may be beneficial for California, such as: Comprehensive permitting, state or regional boards of review or appeals, minimum zoning densities or the builders remedy Conclusion Concern with overall residential production and increase of housing supplies, particularly at low and moderate-income levels 10 State and Local Housing Policy November 13, 2003 Housing element process as a tool to ensure adequate housing production However, it is not clear that the fair-share process is the best too Maximizing housing production can conflict with allocating a regions needs as fair share to each municipality The goals and approaches of state housing law must be reconsidered and a more workable approach is necessary Discussion Questions 1. Which is more beneficial for housing programs, intercity competition or intergovernmental factors? Is there a way to maintain an element of intercity competition while still influencing cities to spend local revenues on housing programs? 2. What lessons can we learn from the Mount Laurel case in New Jersey? 3. Do people really behave the way Tiebout suggests? Do Peterson and Schneider have a more accurate description of public choice? 4. Is there an appropriate balance between housing production and growth control policies? Which is more reasonable? 5. What is the best way to promote compliance with housing elements? 6. Is the size of subsidy that RDAs receive justifiable? 7. Are RDAs responsible for growth that they benefit from, or are there other factors that influence growth? 8. What is Inclusionary Housing, and is it an affective affordable housing strategy? 9. Is Inclusionary Housing sufficient to address all moderate and low-income housing needs? 11