Revolutionary Industrial Change in Air Transport: Research and Strategic Application Robert N. McGrath, Ph.D. College of Business Embry-Riddle Aeronautical University 600 S. Clyde Morris Blvd. Daytona Beach, Florida 32114-3900 (386) 226-6703, fax -6696 (mcgrathm@erau.edu) This first revision submitted to International Journal of Innovation and Technology Management July, 2004 1 ABSTRACT This paper summarizes and interprets several years of research that considered the National Aeronautics and Space Administration’s assertion that the Small Aircraft Transportation System (SATS) will become an economical alternative to automobile and airline travel -- a radical paradigmatic shift. However, the literature suggests that revolutionary changes to major techno-economic paradigms should not always be made in singular radical disruptions, but rather, through the commercialization of technologies in series of market niches chosen wisely. Therefore, hypothetical SATS aircraft cost and technical performance characteristics were computer-modeled to simulate SATS in the corporate aviation environment, and in the air taxi industry. Results of exploratory research based on these models are reviewed. From the standpoint of traditional Strategic Management theory, implications are offered regarding the successful incubation of this emerging industry. 2 The National Aeronautics and Space Administration (NASA,) leading several coalitions of public, private, and educational institutions, is investing millions of dollars to research and demonstrate the feasibility of the Small Aircraft Transportation System (SATS) concept. “The envisioned outcome is to improve travel between remote communities and transportation centers in urban areas by utilizing a new generation of single-pilot light airplanes for personal and business transportation between [sic] the nation’s 5,400 public use general aviation airports” (“NASA Small,” 2000) ... “Burgeoning transportation demand will be dominated by the increasing value of time during the information age, when human/intellectual capital replaces physical capital as the basis for the creation of wealth. The new value of time makes doorstepto-destination speed the premium commodity during this new era” (Holmes, 1999.) But scholarly research in Strategic Management and related fields suggests that the successful development of a SATS mass-market should most likely be preceded by the development of industrial and institutional markets (Utterback, 1994; Christensen, 1997; Afuah, 1998.) So, in a series of funded and independent exploratory studies conducted by the author, NASA’s “hypothesis” was examined in the context of (a) corporate/business aviation and (b) the air taxi industry. NASA itself has speculated that these will be likely early markets (“Southeast SATSLab,” 2000; “NASA-led,” 2001.) This paper summarizes and interprets overall findings. First, a theoretical interpretation of the situation is outlined. Second, results of research are summarized. Third, the research is interpreted in light of theory, and the paper concludes. SATS AND THEORIES OF EMERGING TECHNOLOGY-BASED INDUSTRIES Most industries experience complex market, economic, and technological forces, and as a result, the world does not always beat a path to a new technology (Porter, 1980, Foster, 1986, 3 Tushman & Anderson, 1986.) Some major evolutionary forces are fairly predictable, though, which help us generalize certain patterns that are likely to repeat in the SATS scenario. On the whole it is correct to view SATS as a substitute technological paradigm (Porter, 1980.) The consumer benefits that SATS will deliver are already being delivered by other transportation technologies - of course, with so much alleged room for improvement in speed that a discontinuity, or revolution, is implied (Foster, 1986.) NASA’s use of door-to-door travel time as a main metric of SATS’ viability illustrates this point. Before proceeding, terms such as “revolutionary” (Foster, 1986,) “discontinuous” (Tushman & Anderson, 1986,) and “radical” (Utterback, 1994) should be addressed. In the literature, there is no universally applicable definition of these terms as they apply to technological change or the paradigmatic change implied in the SATS vision. Loosely speaking, a revolution, discontinuity, or radical change may occur in any or all of a technology, a firm, a market, an industry, an economy, and so forth. Also, while the terms are very much related, they are not synonymous. Their main use is to communicate degrees and foci of change in a relative (though sometimes simplistic) sense, almost dichotomously in contrast with terms like “evolutionary,” “continuous,” or “incremental,” respectively. This is how these terms are applied in this paper. Also, it must be admitted that long-term revolutionary change can be accomplished through a series of accumulated steps that seem individually incremental. Indeed, noting this dynamic is part of the argument presented below. In terms of the likelihood of widespread substitution of SATS for other technologies, then, the issue is not whether SATS will be able to provide faster transportation - it is whether SATS will deliver superior value. The value of a product or service can be measured as the performance delivered per the cost incurred (Porter, 1980.) The substitutability of one (new, 4 emerging, commercially unproven) technology for another (familiar, mature, widely accepted) technology, can be assessed by comparing their relative values, or performance/price ratios. The performance/price ratios of mature technologies are, almost by definition, very good. First, due to phenomena such as economies of scale and scope, amortization of sunk costs over long production runs, high asset utilization rates, and learning effects, years of commercialization have made them economical, at least on a per-unit basis. Over time, as technologies stabilize and designs standardize, firms gravitate to "rational" pricing strategies, such as unit-cost-plus-margin. Second, mature technologies are normally high-performing in ways that are valued by consumers. And in sophisticated mass-markets, overall “performance” usually means a multidimensional bundle of attributes. In transportation, for example, speed is bundled with safety, reliability, comfort, etc. But maturity precludes much room for improvement in technical performance. When the demand exists for radically improved performance, logic compels a transition to new technology (Foster, 1986.) Overall, potential substitute technologies typically do not unambiguously outperform their mature rivals in their early stages of development, but contain the inherent potential to outperform the mature technologies by wide margins in the long run. Here it is important to note that “development” includes pre-commercialization stages, sometimes overlooked in generic models of product life cycles (introduction-growth-maturity-decline.) In other words the technology life cycle begins earlier than the classical marketing product life cycle. Any complex technology has a gestation stage prior to commercialization, sometimes a very long one. 5 In addition to being under-performing, new technologies are also typically costprohibitive, especially on a per-unit basis. This is partly because much R&D and other kinds of costs have been sunk without generating any revenues in return. Early in the development of new technologies, then, they usually do not present very good mass-market value. If rationally priced (cost-based,) they are expensive and relatively under-performing. But again, unit costs of new technologies can not ordinarily come down to levels that would make them competitive in mass markets, until production volumes become large enough to reap ostensible scale/scope economies, learning effects, etc. At this point the reader should note the “Catch-22” being presented. A technology might experience only the early part of its potential technology cycle (i.e., stopping prior to actual commercialization,) if the price/performance “business case” never develops. To successfully commercialize a truly revolutionary technology that faces a substitutability problem, and break free of the Catch-22, it is often true that pricing decisions must be made independent of production costs. Firms must price their products below unit production costs in order to achieve key imperatives such as the development of crucial target niches. In addition to early cost and performance problems, truly innovative technologies face psychological barriers to acceptance by the mass-market (Tushman & Anderson, 1986; McGrath, 1996.) Before the mass-market can be really developed, lead users, who essentially constitute big market experiments, typically need to be nurtured just to prove the viability of the product concept, to experience and help resolve growing pains, and to suffer economic externalities with which the mass-market has little patience (lower-than-acceptable reliability, difficulty getting support services, etc.) Such niches include individuals who just like being the "first kid on the 6 block" with a new technology, industrial customers which might value the new technology as helping control costs or generate revenues, the military, and/or governments which might subsidize a new technology for a variety of political, social and economic reasons. Such pioneers are needed sometimes for decades, simply to provide the time, learning, production volumes, and consumer feedback needed to make strides in improving the performance/price ratio of the new technology. SOME EXPLORATORY RESEARCH To examine the related part of the NASA vision, studies were conducted from 1999 to 2003. While several were funded and responsive to contractual goals (McGrath & Prayudi, 2000; McGrath & Bonney, 2003,) others (McGrath, 2002) were conducted independently as logical follow-on studies, of interest to the author because of their relevance to theory. This section briefly summarizes the results, all of which have been peer-reviewed elsewhere. SATS Baseline. In January of 2000 the author delivered to NASA a baseline study of the Life Cycle Costs (LCC) of SATS aircraft (McGrath & Prayudi, 2000.) Life Cycle Costing is a rigorous analytical technique adapted from systems engineering (Fabrycky & Blanchard, 1991.) One version is a hybrid engineering-economic technique that models costs as dependent variables, the independent variables being defined by characteristics of a technology. For example, the nominal weight of any type of aircraft is known to be correlated with, and a parametric predictor of, operating cost. Parametric modeling is often used early in the development of a new technology. In the SATS study, Life Cycle Costs were all costs incurred throughout a defined period of aircraft acquisition, ownership and operation. The SATS LCC model envisaged aircraft to be 7 evolutionary derivatives of commonplace General Aviation and Business Aviation aircraft, but advanced enough to achieve important NASA goals such as improvements in fuel and maintenance costs. Hypothetical aircraft were modeled as being governed by seven basic parameters: most notably, the number of engines, the type of engines, and seating capacity. Results and Implications. One basic observation was that the prices of SATS aircraft will be major factors that determine the economic viability of the vision. It will cost millions of dollars to operate even a “low-end” (low price, modest/poor relative performance) aircraft over a normal period of ownership. Achieving unprecedented advancements will still fall short of achieving cost and performance goals that would suggest large-scale substitution of aircraft for autos in the mass market for personal transportation. It is more likely and perhaps essential for SATS to first incubate in industrial or government niches. While disappointing to some aviation enthusiasts, this conclusion was unsurprising in light of the literature. Two clear questions emerged. First, since airplanes are so expensive relative to autos, how will considering the value of personal time affect the SATS vision? Second, which niches are viable as SATS incubators, theoretically necessary to develop the latent mass market? SATS in the Corporate Aviation Industry. The author and several research assistants conducted several literature reviews as to the economic valuation of personal time; absolutely no results emerged. However, the value of employee time has long been a matter of accepted Human Resources practices. For example, corporate aviation (organizations using “business jets” etc.) and the National Business Aviation Association (NBAA) have long argued that one of the advantages of a corporate flight department is its impact on employee time and productivity (Castro, 1985.) This premise is related to NASA’s assertion that time will become the critical 8 commodity in the “new economy.” Since the value of employee time can be respectably evaluated, and since corporate aviation was already speculated as being a likely SATS incubator, this scenario was opportune for study. In the next series of studies, then, NBAA-sponsored software was used to calculate and contrast the costs of traveling on SATS aircraft, airlines, and autos among various samples of origin-destination city pairs. Stratified samples were taken on national and regional bases, according to different versions of the SATS scenario. In addition to comparing trip costs on an ordinary accounting basis, the software calculated the economic value of the amount of time consumed by each corporate employee during a trip, using an estimation algorithm common in Human Resource Management (“Travel$ense,” 1999.) Results. In all studies the consideration of the value of time proved critical. To illustrate, Figures 1 and 2 provide results of examining a random sample of trips in the United States, (1) before and (2) after considering the value of time, given the choice of traveling by auto, airline, or an advanced SATS-like, twin-engine turboprop aircraft (McGrath, 2002.) The metric depicted on the vertical axis represents a ratio of door-to-door trip speed to trip cost, such that the higher the ratio, the better. In Figure 2, then, the cost of employee time is included in the denominator. One can easily see the importance of the value of time by comparing the two figures. They imply that while time always costs money, it costs far less more money in the faster modes of travel, helping the argument for corporate aviation and SATS. This appeared in all studies. -------------------------------------------------Place Figures 1 and 2 about here. -------------------------------------------------9 Another pattern that emerged in these studies is not shown in these figures. Advanced versions of low-end aircraft generally appeared to be cost-competitive when time was considered, because even they were much faster than any auto. High-end aircraft were much more costly to buy than low-end aircraft (sometimes by a factor of ten) and therefore, were nowhere near competitive in ordinary accounting terms. But after considering the value of time, even high price-and-performance configurations often appeared to be good alternatives because their superior airspeeds saved more time than all the other alternatives. Assumptions about trip distances made a large difference, though, suggesting that SATS’ viability lies within a range of trips from about 200 to 500 miles. Within that range auto effectiveness plummeted with distance, while SATS’ effectiveness gradually improved. Airline fares were mostly determined by factors other than distance, as any experienced traveler knows (note the scatter patterns in Figure 2.) Implications. Overall, while these studies were exploratory and non-empirical, NASA’s assertion about the economic viability of SATS received qualified support. Corporate aviation may be a viable testing and maturation ground for SATS technologies and operational concepts. Of course, more than one niche may be viable as a SATS incubator, so the next research question was to address another, already articulated in NASA’s vision. There was one basic research question, with many derivative questions. To this point in all studies, both by the author and other researchers elsewhere, the unit of analysis was almost always either a technology (such as an engine,) the airplane, or SATS as an entire infrastructure. This time, the viability of an air taxi enterprise was questioned. 10 SATS in the Air Taxi Industry. As studies progressed, they provided learning that allowed greater focus. In coordination with other NASA studies, the next series examined a specific but hypothetical private enterprise operating an air taxi business in a likely market (McGrath & Bonney, 2003.) (Here “air taxi” is a loose term that describes on-demand service as opposed to scheduled airline service, but because of the nature of this market, the air taxi industry is highly fragmented and operators mostly employ small aircraft.) The enterprise could easily fit into any of the regional settings being researched as likely future markets for SATS (“North Carolina,” 2000.) An enterprise was envisaged with two strategic objectives: one, enough capacity to exploit possible economies of scale; two, a “bare bones” level of investment in sunk and fixed costs. The general strategy was one of unit cost minimization. Three aircraft were modeled: a Beech Bonanza 33 (single piston engine, 4-seats), a Beech King Air 200 (twin-engine turboprop, 8-seats,) and an Eclipse 500 (twin engine turbofan, 6seats.) The former two aircraft types had been available in general aviation for a decade or two, and were aviation legacies with established cost and performance histories. As such, they were chosen not because they were expected to be, or to evolve into, SATS aircraft, but because (in addition to the availability of historical data) they represented aircraft configurations (size, seating capacity, engine number and type, etc.) envisaged as likely SATS configurations. The Eclipse, in contrast, was still in the developmental stage but was widely lauded as being revolutionary in terms that befitted SATS scenarios (Lewison, 2002.) At the time of writing, it was clear that advancements in small jet engines, lightweight construction materials, avionics technologies adopted from the military and airline industries, computer aided design technologies, manufacturing technologies, etc. were advancing individually and would converge 11 to, at least, very much rejuvenate general and business aviation through technology (Holmes, Durham & Tarry, 2004.) The downside, in contrast to studying the Bonanza and Beech aircraft, was that there was no established cost and performance baseline. Altogether, the former two aircraft could be thought of as evolutionary and the latter, revolutionary. Simple cost predictions distanced aircraft one from the other, as their levels of technological sophistication would suggest. The Bonanza (low end) was by far the least costly, and the Eclipse (high end) was the most costly. More interesting were their relative cost effectiveness figures under different sets of assumptions. In aviation, proven measures of cost effectiveness include cost per mile, cost per seat mile, and cost per hour. Note that these measures are analogous to ratios of performance and price, and are proxies for value. Table 1 presents data at two levels of analysis, total Life Cycle Cost (LCC,) and Direct Operating Cost (DOC). Total DOC is the same as total variable costs and is commonly (but sometimes sub-optimally) used in aviation as the sole cost criterion in decision-making. -------------------------------------------------Place Table 1 about here. -------------------------------------------------On an LCC per mile and per hour basis, the Bonanza was always clearly superior, followed by the Eclipse and the King Air. Margins were wider at the DOC level of analysis. On a cost per seat mile basis, however, the margins between the Bonanza and the Eclipse evaporated, while King Air improved relative to them both. In sum, high technology was costly but sometimes, cost effective. Note that the value of passenger time was not even considered. 12 But the above assumed perfect asset utilization. A critical metric in commercial aviation is “load factor,” a measure of utilization generally determined as the percentage of available seats filled by fare-paying passengers. When considering load factors progressively less than 100% (Table 2,) the Eclipse emerged as clearly superior, and the Bonanza emerged as clearly inferior, even to the much more costly King Air. -------------------------------------------------Place Table 2 about here. -------------------------------------------------However, these observations are somewhat hypothetical to the reality that the entrepreneur will not be able to dictate market share, fully utilizing any aircraft chosen regardless of its seating capacity. In other words, regardless (for the most part) of which aircraft is employed, the same number of passengers per flight (on average) can be assumed to seek the service. For example, if the business served an average of exactly three passengers per flight (not counting one pilot,) the relevant DOC figures from Table 2 would be .22 for the Bonanza, .45 for the Eclipse, and the (horrible) figure for the King Air does not even appear in the Table. So while a fully utilized Eclipse was measured to be as cost-effective as a fully utilized Bonanza, under-utilization can be economically catastrophic to the entrepreneur’s business case. Another view of asset utilization was obtained through sensitivity analysis, by varying the amount of trips, given the overall scale of the operation assumed at the outset. Figure 3 illustrates the results, showing the important impact of aircraft utilization (trip distance) on unit costs (cost per mile.) 13 -------------------------------------------------Place Figure 3 about here. -------------------------------------------------Implications. These results implied that it will be crucial to the operating margins of a SATS-like air taxi enterprise to align its overall capacity with market demand. Establishing an enterprise of an economical scale will be as important as maintaining high asset utilization at that scale. If the starting assumptions had been different, they may have determined an operation of a different scale. The question is whether at the establishment of the operation, which scale would be more economical on a unit-cost basis. If a large operation showed lower unit costs than a small operation, then an economy of scale would be said to exist. One problem is that this phenomenon is too often assumed to be automatic, but it is not. The crushing overhead suffered by many large airlines, for example, suggests that there are some diseconomies of scale at work. Furthermore, economies in some unit costs can co-exist with diseconomies in others. This is basic economics but implications for SATS are less obvious. Assuming the presence of an extensive and efficient infrastructure of SATS-like services and facilities, it is possible that greater economies may be found in larger enterprises than the one modeled. But without adequate infrastructure, the firm would have to invest in some services itself, perhaps ruining the overall cost structure of the firm. Widespread availability of maintenance services is an example. These points are important to the business case of any SATS-based enterprise but pursuing them was outside the scope of the air taxi studies. Overall Research Implications. Altogether, these studies implied that if historical industry/technology patterns repeat themselves, strategies can be envisioned to guide progress in 14 SATS. The examples from the research illustrate the kind of inefficiencies (e.g., aircraft seating capacity or overall fleet capacity mismatched to demand, lack of infrastructure, poor combinations of performance and price) that institutional market niches can help rationalize, illuminating and then reducing technological and related economic uncertainties en route to the development of a mass market. It should be noted that the line of research described above was accomplished somewhat independently of the research of others, which were investigating issues related to airports and airport systems, the impact on the airline industry, the impact on the capacity of the national airspace in general, specific technologies, regional and national macroeconomic impacts, and so forth. Many questions were still open at the time of writing. Results of other studies would clarify the research questions that would guide the continuation of the line of research being discussed here. STRATEGIC INTERPRETATIONS AND IMPLICATIONS Substitute technologies like SATS do not create new industries as much as they restructure existing industries. Door-to-door transportation is already the consumer function delivered by several technology paradigms. Theoretically, transportation can even be substituted by something more fundamental, like communication. Regardless, industry/technology history suggests that paradigmatic change should be attempted carefully and sequentially, identifying and attacking the most opportune market niches first, in ways that lend themselves to progressive substitution in subsequent niches. Again, determinants of substitution include relative performance and relative price, together determining relative value. The studies captured the same idea in the calculation of 15 cost-effectiveness metrics such as cost per passenger. In the SATS scenario, it would seem that improvements should be pursued in both areas. However, appreciating the full breadth of these terms includes some important subtleties that “go beyond the numbers,” and some are counterintuitive. The following discussion provides a few illustrations. Performance. At the time of writing SATS-related technologies truly were advancing rapidly. If their progression were to be managed in a coordinated fashion, their collective performance would probably synergize in ways that would create a new era in aviation transportation. This paper, of course, is more focused on the SATS vision than on aviation in general. The signals being sent that SATS aircraft would take some time to develop and mature, were being coupled with signals that the performance of subsequent generations of aircraft would be significantly better. The mass-market often acts on such signals by adopting a “wait and see” posture, pending results of trials (such as consumer experiences with air taxi services.) If a trial fails in the eyes of the mass market, this can “poison the well.” Thus progress in technological performance can have multifaceted implications. Performance Signals. The management of signals becomes important. For example, the mass market is interested in which organizations will endure the test of time; i.e., which organizations will still be around when the mass market engages with gusto. Proactive signaling can help improve perceptions regarding risks. Means include disseminating information lauding technological advances, plant openings and expanded production capacities, public and private resource investments, interfirm collaborations, etc. The long-term availability of a product is inversely related to the perception of the likelihood of consumer abandonment; so through 16 intentional or inadvertent signals, mass markets generally become wise as to which organizations are committed, and which are not. Buyer Orientations. As implied, buyers' technological orientations matter, and these orientations can differ from one niche to another. Some types of buyers simply enjoy being technologically adventurous and are both capable and willing to perform, or at least participate in, new product introduction and de-bugging. Adventure can, in itself, be a “performance” attribute to such buyers. To buyers who have an optimistic sense of technological evolution, attempts to develop SATS might seem like a string of necessary experiments, and that success is not only inevitable, but that it is imminent. Aviation enthusiasts may even be irrationally biased in favor of SATS. In this category one might include some potential air taxi entrepreneurs. In contrast, practically by definition mass market consumers do not view themselves as willing participants in grand social experiments that may balk at their expense. In particular, the mass market is sensitive to the risk of choosing technologies that will lose “standards wars” (Grant, 2003.) In the studies, for example, each of the numerous possible permutations of engine types, number of engines, and passenger capacity represents a potential design standard, or “dominant design” (Tushman & Anderson, 1986.) It is common for newly developing markets to experience periods of rapid growth once such uncertainties become settled. This is especially true in transitions from institutional and industrial markets to mass markets, such as the hypothetical transition from corporate aviation and air taxi to the mass market. But though the establishment of any particular technological standard will be to the benefit of manufacturers prepared to deliver that standard, it will be equally to the detriment of proprietors of noncomplementary technologies. This can result in a desperate “winner take all” situation. To put it 17 mildly, conflicts of interest will make it difficult for all SATS players to maintain one voice on all issues. While signals should be interpreted according to the vested interests of the signalers, however, the mass market is sometimes malleable (McGrath, 1996.) To be blunt, the best technologies do not always win; sometimes the most persuasive argument wins. Infrastructure. On a grander scale, it would not be part of a wise national industrial policy to expect society to make more than one significant technological transition, so the optimal (standards-based) technological trajectory should be carefully identified as soon as possible, and developed in a coordinated but legal way. Perhaps it is naive to expect practicing managers to strategize so cooperatively and so far in advance, or to suggest that even the experts (including academics!) can identify the optimal trajectory in so complex a scenario. Regardless, all must realize that standardization signals are some of the most powerful that will ever be sent. Alternative Technologies. Also, the world will not hold still for SATS. The markets in question will evaluate the SATS paradigm as a substitute for developments in automobile, regional airline, rail, and even communication infrastructures. So it seems imperative that SATS technologies not only evolve convincingly, but that they evolve faster than alternative technologies in their abilities to deliver the valued performance. The studies did not consider this. Price. “Price” includes more than the simple purchase price – it includes, for example, all monetary flows reflective of changes in comparable products over a relevant time frame, the effects of discounts, rebates, free ancillary products and services, and so forth (Porter, 1980.) In a broader sense it can also include switching costs, especially if switching costs are unavoidable results of a decision to purchase. In this regard, the total LCC view was appropriate in the 18 studies reviewed. More intriguing, of course, is the effective price discount hypothesized by the offsetting value of time. But first and foremost, the studies did indicate that the basic “sticker prices” of aircraft will be formidable barriers to substitution in the mass market. Price Signals. In free enterprise economies, price is a powerful signal. In a world of “perfect” information (where all relevant decision-making information is available and information search is costless,) prices should equilibrate where they accurately reflect economic value. But the world is not characterized by perfect information - economic rationality is bounded, and information search is not free. Potential consumers must incur costs of discovering the “right” price of SATS technology, and/or interpret the signals. It is widely assumed that SATS costs and hence, prices will drop over time because of such dynamics as experience effects and learning curves. Similar to the effect noted above about performance improvements, such “information” has the potential to delay (or at least confuse) development of the mass-market. Rapidly changing prices - even, ironically, falling prices convey present economic risk. The mass-market is generally averse to buying items that may become obsolete. It prefers to wait for other, smaller market niches (e.g., air taxi, business aviation) to rationalize market inefficiencies, and then buy-in (literally and figuratively) once prices stabilize. Even if large opportunities for scale, learning and experience effects exist, unit production costs are likely to be so high in the short term that industry profitability will be negative for years. This will impose severe strains on investment communities, so only patient capital should be pursued. SATS is presently a scenario structured for organizations with significant willpower, stay power, market power, and financial power. 19 Value. Again turning to the value of time (as an offset to price,) the obvious implication for SATS is that the more dramatic the immediate time savings of traveling it provides, the more likely substitution will occur – but more problematically, that the time saved must be consciously and economically valued. This is relatively straightforward in industrial markets where time has a dramatic impact on traditional accounting reports – i.e., where there is a tradition of valuing employee time. The SATS movement should work to make this idea part of the popular psychological calculus, not just a “rationalization.” Everyone knows that “time is money,” but what is the economic value of someone’s personal time? The author has twice searched for, and found virtually no literature on this subject. Much more research is needed. Something that also looms important to product value is discretionary v. nondiscretionary income. Rich people have lots of discretionary income; poor people have very little. The real value of a dollar – and the real price of a product -- varies to a consumer as a function of its discretionary nature. Most mass-market consumers have some discretionary income, but research is still needed that would confidently suggest that very many of them have enough to allow the purchase of aircraft for any reason, let alone personal transportation. Furthermore, this hypothetical segment must be so large that it can also accommodate the reality that only a fraction of it will actually buy aircraft. It is the author’s opinion that the SATS vision is often interpreted myopically as a broadening of the existing market for general aviation goods and services, not the broader and more latent mass market for personal transportation over distances of a few hundred miles. In other words what is often assumed to be the mass market for SATS – general aviation enthusiasts – may be better thought of as an intermediary niche that 20 must be nurtured en route to the development of the true mass market for personal and family transportation. Research in price elasticities in all niches seems warranted. Switching Costs. Next, switching costs are the one-time costs to a buyer of purchasing a substitute rather than maintaining or replacing an original product. They do not represent a price differential. Again, the LCC view implicitly includes switching costs, such as pilot training. Switching costs of product substitution (autos to aircraft) are greater than the switching costs of changing from one rival product (aircraft to aircraft) to another. This is because substitutes provide similar kinds of consumer functionality but in technologically different ways. Subsidies can lower switching costs. Ancillary equipment can be supplied, skills training can be freely given, and sophisticated business planning assistance can be offered aimed at bringing overall firm-level economic value out of SATS ownership. Guarantees, warranties, and confidence in trade-in (or trade-up) values can be contractually established. Industry Advocacy. On the whole, other advisable efforts include total-industry promotion. Without being too specific and especially without making unsupportable promises, the overall awareness of milestone accomplishments as well as general progress should be continuously elevated in target segments and across society as a whole, crafted to describe how SATS enhances overall lifestyles or improves overall business positions. More to the point, members of the new industry will need to police their population for members who are fraudulent or unduly opportunistic (as opposed to waiting for the free market and/or legal system to cull them out,) because the overall reputation of the movement is fragile and politically dependent. In a similar vein, some collaborative research and product development will likely be essential for some time to come. It is clear that SATS requires truly synergistic combinations of 21 advanced technologies, so inter-and intra-industry spillovers will continue to be of immense value. Summary. To summarize, the SATS mass-market is assumed to be largely latent, here meaning that consumers are not already aviators or especially aviation-minded. Information search about the value of SATS within this segment is not as efficient as within the segment of aviation enthusiasts. Risk has an immediate economic impact, regardless of whether or not the feared phenomenon ever actually happens. The very risk that pessimists might be right, that political resolve might collapse, and/or that technologies might not evolve and synergize in expected ways, injects a risk that has a real economic impact on the present viability of the SATS vision. Managing these risks can be partly accomplished through the strategic development of successive market niches chosen based on performance/price substitution characteristics. The studies reviewed here offer a glimpse into the learning that will continue to be necessary from the strategic management perspective. CONCLUSION Much of the research described above was accomplished independently by the author, guided by, but not wholly integrated with, other research which was investigating SATS’ macroeconomic impacts, regional and community impacts, emerging technologies to include structures, aerodynamics, engines, avionics, and air traffic control concepts, airport infrastructures, impacts on the natural environment, impacts on other industries such as the airlines, and so forth. Overall learning about the future of SATS will thus probably develop recursively, not linearly, as one “piece of the puzzle” is continuously added, informed by the work of others and hopefully contributing in turn. 22 It should also be noted that at the time of writing, SATS was mostly a US concept, but hypothetically, similar opportunities exist wherever it seems more viable to establish air-based personal transportation than to expand a ground-based infrastructure. As a comparison, note that nations with historically poor communications infrastructures are modernizing by establishing cutting-edge wireless infrastructures. The general implication to all industries globally is that the emergence of new and converging technologies presents both threats and opportunities relative to existing paradigms. NASA’s hypothesis that the economic value of an individual’s time will increase is intuitively appealing. As such, the extant understanding of information-age economics deserves expansion. The present studies were hamstrung by a lack of empirical research addressing the value of time in transportation economics. The design of the studies were accordingly exploratory and non-empirical. However, they do suggest that advanced general aviation and corporate aviation technologies have feasible applications in near-term aviation transportation niches. Whether successful commercialization in niches can be parlayed into realization of the ultimate SATS vision is problematic but not impossible. This paper has merely suggested that even when in a conceptual/visionary stage, it is not too early to begin mapping out firm-level business strategies in a new industry, by using lessons learned from industrial history. 23 REFERENCES Afuah, A.D. 1998. Innovation Management: Strategies, Implementation, and Profits. New York: Oxford University Press, Ch 7, pp. 135-158. Castro, R. 1985. Corporate Aviation Management. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press, Ch 1, pp. 3-20. Christensen, C.M. 1997. The Innovator’s Dilemma. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, Ch 8, pp.165-186. Fabrycky, W.J. & B. S. Blanchard. 1991. Life-Cycle Cost and Economic Analysis. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Ch 8, 122-143. Foster, R.N. 1986. Innovation: The Attacker's Advantage. New York: Summit, Ch 5, pp.113136. Grant, R.M. 2002. Contemporary Strategy Analysis, 4th ed. Malden, Mass: Blackwell, Ch 11, pp. 330-365. Holmes, B.J. 1999. The Small Aircraft Transportation System concept for the 21st century transportation. NASA General Aviation Program Office, Langley Research Center, Hampton, Virginia (white paper.) Homes, B.J., M.H. Durham, & S.E. Tarry. 2004. Small aircraft transportation system concepts and technologies. Journal of Aircraft, 41(1), pp. 26-35. Lewison, G.L. 2003. The Eclipse 500. Avionics News, February, p.32. NASA-led technology development aimed at increasing mobility, access for smaller communities. NASA Document FS-2001-03-59-LaRC. NASA Small Aircraft Transportation System (SATS) Southeast SATSLab Consortium. Southeast SATSLab (white paper.) 2000. North Carolina fourth-tier air transportation market analysis. 2000. RTI International and the Kenan Institute of Private Enterprise, RTI Project No. 08339.000, November. McGrath, R.N. 1996. Discontinuous Technological Change and Institutional Legitimacy: A Morphological Perspective. Ann Arbor: UMI Dissertation Services. McGrath, R.N. 1993. Economic viability of NASA’s next-generation aviation paradigm: A summary of research findings. Journal of Aerospace, annual transactions. 24 McGrath, R.N. & A.W. Bonney. 2003. SATS life cycle costs in an air taxi environment. Society of automotive engineers aerospace division world aviation conference technical paper and proceedings, Montreal, Canada, September. McGrath, R.N. & H. Prayudi. 2000. SATS precursor study report: Task 1, SATS user affordability: Life cycle costs / total cost of ownership. Report delivered to the NASA Langley Research Center, Hampton, Virginia, January. Porter, M.E. 1980. Competitive Strategy. New York: Free Press, Ch 8, 156-183. Southeast SATSLab Consortium overview of master plan, general information & program plan. (White Paper.) 2000. Southeast SATSLab Consortium. Travel$ense Business Travel Productivity Tracking Software (user’s manual.) 1999. Washington, DC: National Business Aviation Association. Tushman, M.L. & P.A. Anderson. 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational environments. Administrative Science Quarterly, 31, pp. 439-465. Utterback, J.M. 1994. Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, Ch 4, pp. 79-102. 25 Table 1. Cost-Effectiveness Measures ($.) Bonanza 33 Eclipse 500 King Air 200 LCC per Mile Seat Mile Hour DOC per Mile Seat Mile Hour 1.21 .30 227 1.87 .31 778 4.46 .56 1,412 .86 .22 161 1.34 .22 558 2.81 .35 889 26 Table 2. Cost ($) per Passenger Seat Mile Comparisons. Bonanza Eclipse King Air Life Cycle Cost per Total seats Total seats less crew Total seats less crew less one empty seat Total seats less crew less two empty seats Direct Operating Cost per Total seats Total seats less crew Total seats less crew less one empty seat Total seats less crew less two empty seats 27 .30 .40 .60 1.21 .31 .37 .47 .62 .56 .64 .74 .89 .22 .29 .43 .86 .22 .27 .34 .45 .35 .40 .47 .56 2.00 1.80 1.60 Auto Speed / Cost 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 SATS 0.60 0.40 Airline 0.20 52 8 54 9 56 9 59 0 60 0 51 0 50 0 46 8 45 5 44 9 41 3 37 4 37 1 36 8 36 1 35 3 30 8 29 9 28 7 27 8 25 7 23 2 20 9 18 7 18 0 16 8 11 8 0.00 8 52 9 54 9 56 0 59 0 60 Trip Distance Figure 1. Trip Cost-Effectivness Without Considerng the Value of Traveler Time. 0.35 0.30 SATS Speed / Cost 0.25 0.20 Airline 0.15 0.10 Auto 0.05 0.00 8 11 8 16 0 18 7 18 9 20 2 23 7 25 8 27 7 28 9 29 8 30 3 35 1 8 1 4 36 36 37 37 Trip Distance 3 41 9 44 5 45 8 46 0 50 Figure 2. Trip Cost-Effectiveness Considering the Value of Traveler Time. 28 0 51 Sensitivity of LCC per Mile to Trip Distance 7.00 6.34 6.00 5.09 Dollars per Mile 5.00 4.46 4.09 4.00 3.84 3.00 2.60 2.11 2.00 1.87 1.66 1.36 1.21 1.00 1.73 1.63 1.12 1.06 50 75 100 125 Percentage of Baseline Assumption Bonanza King Air Eclipse Figure 3. Sensitivity of Life Cycle Cost to Trip Distance. 29 150