© 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. Lecture 4 Chapter 4: Market Efficiency, Market Failure, and Government Intervention Markets and Efficiency A. Markets are efficient mechanisms for allocating resources Five Institutional Requirements for Workable Markets 1. Accurate information is widely available 2. Property rights are protected 3. Contract obligations are enforced 4. There are no external costs or benefits 5. Competitive markets prevail B. The Discipline of Markets Explain how high prices ensure that firms will supply highly valued products. Explain how firms that fail to innovate will be disciplined by the market. C. Consumer and Producer Surplus Graphically Remember that market efficiency is achieved when the sum of consumer and producer surplus is maximized Supply Demand Quantity 1. Show consumer surplus on this graph. 2. Show producer surplus on this graph. 3. Demonstrate that the sum of consumer and producer surplus will fall if a smaller quantity is traded. 4. Demonstrate that the sum of consumer and producer surplus will fall if a larger quantity is traded. © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. Market Failures 1. Asymmetric Information The problem where one side to a transaction has more information than the other side—leads to fewer than optimal trades Example: the used car market--Since buyers can’t distinguish quality differences, they will assume all cars are low quality. Sellers have no way to convince buyers that their car is not a lemon. Adverse selection Occurs before the market transaction. Adverse selection is the problem that the people or firms who are most eager to make a transaction are the least desirable to parties on the other side of the transaction (higher-risk individuals are more likely to buy insurance) Moral hazard Occurs after the market transaction. Moral hazard the problem that one party to a transaction changes their behavior in a way that harms the other party Example: Without insurance I won’t engage in risky behaviors because I know I’ll bear the entire cost if I have a problem. Then I buy insurance and promise the seller that I won’t engage in risky behaviors but then I do because I know he won’t be able to tell and also that he will bear most of the cost if I have a problem. Further example: Without health insurance I won’t go to the doctor very often because I know I’ll bear the entire cost if I do. Then I buy insurance and then I go to the doctor for every little thing since the insurer bears most of the cost. 2. Problems with Property Rights: Public Goods Exist Public goods are nonexcludable: you can’t keep someone who hasn’t paid for them from using them. See Lecture 1 3. Problems with Property Rights: Common Property Resources Exist The Tragedy of the commons: Common property resources (ocean fish, the atmosphere, common grazing lands) are owned by the community at large and tend to be overused © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. 4. Problems with Property Rights: Problematical Contract Enforcement The legal system for enforcing contracts may be nonexistent, corrupt, or inefficient 5. Third-Party Effects (Externalities) Exist See Lecture 1 for definitions Assuming that the external costs or benefits can be measured correctly, then we can find the efficient quantity: Supply after counting external costs Price Supply Demand Price Supply Demand after counting Demand external benefits 6. Monopoly Power Exists Efficiency depends upon competitive markets. Lack of competition can reduce efficiency. © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. Government-Controlled Prices Economists have figured out that freely operating markets will adjust so that there are no shortages or surpluses—the equilibrium price acts as a rationing device. However, sometimes certain groups don’t like the equilibrium price because, to them, it is “too high” or “too low.” These groups sometimes ask the government to control the price by choosing what they consider to be a “better” price. This sounds like a good idea until you remember that prices convey important and useful information, which we ignore at our peril. When the government controls the price of a good, this important and useful information is lost. This causes unintended problems. Economists know that price controls are intended to have certain effects. Economists have observed that price controls also, unfortunately, have unintended effects. These unintended effects occur because price controls prevent the price of a good to function as a rationing device. Sequence of events: ________________________________________________________________ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ The a shortage the price quantity supplied the shortage government occurs which of the good does not rise persists imposes a is a signal cannot legally and quantity price below for the price rise demanded does not equilibrium to rise fall ________________________________________________________________ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ ⌂ The a surplus the price quantity supplied the surplus government occurs which of the good does not fall persists imposes a is a signal cannot legally and quantity price above for the price fall demanded does not equilibrium to fall rise © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. A. Price Ceiling Sometimes people say the price of a good is “too high” and they ask the government to control the price by imposing a price ceiling designed to lower the price. Definition: A price ceiling is a legal maximum price that is lower than the equilibrium price. (A legal maximum price that is higher than the equilibrium price is not, by our definition, a price ceiling.) The intended effect of a price ceiling is to lower the price of a product, in order to help buyers. The unintended effects of a price ceiling include persistent shortages, fewer trades than at equilibrium, and creation of the need for nonprice rationing devices. The groups that lobby for price ceilings frequently ignore or fail to consider these unintended effects. Let’s look at the market for apartments: Supply of apartments of a particular quality Price ceiling Demand for apartments of a particular quality Let’s look at the market for kidneys: Supply Demand © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. B. Price Floor Sometimes people say the price of a good is “too low” and they ask the government to control the price by imposing a price floor designed to raise the price. Definition: A price floor is a legal minimum price that is higher than the equilibrium price. (A legal minimum price that is lower than the equilibrium price is not, by our definition, a price floor.) The intended effect of a price floor is to raise the price of a product, in order to help sellers. The unintended effects of a price floor include persistent surpluses, fewer trades than at equilibrium, and, sometimes, the desire/need for additional government action to dispose of the surplus. The groups that lobby for price floors frequently ignore or fail to consider these unintended effects. Let’s look at the market for workers: Supply of workers of a particular quality Demand for workers of a particular quality Let’s look at the market for milk: Supply of milk Demand for milk © 2010 Jane Himarios, Ph.D. Taxes and Deadweight Loss Tax policy affects efficiency. Supply with an excise tax Supply with no excise tax a e b Demand Q2 Qefficient 1. Show the tax revenue (redistribution from consumers and producers to the government. 2. Show consumer surplus after the tax is levied. 3. Show producer surplus after the tax is levied. 4. Show the deadweight loss of the tax. The deadweight loss is the loss in consumer and producer surplus due to inefficiency because some transactions do not occur and so their value to society is lost. What if the market quantity is not really the efficient quantity because of negative externalities? If this is the case can an excise tax help move the market to the true efficient quantity? Tariffs A tariff is a tax levied on an imported product. Tariffs drive up prices of imports and have all the effects shown above. They also invite retaliation. If you are interested, read “Obama to Impose Tariffs on Chinese Tires,” Yahoo! Finance, http://finance.yahoo.com/news/Obama-to-impose-tariffs-on-apf2199438691.html/print?x=0, Ian Johnson, “China Strikes Back on Trade,” Wall Street Journal, 9/14/2009 and Timothy Aeppel, “Tariff on Tires to Cost Consumers,” Wall Street Journal, 9/14/2009.