OF BRANDS AND GROWTH Interpreting the PIMS evidence on the contribution of branded consumer businesses to economic growth – policy implications Professor David Stout, Special Adviser N/e/r/a This report was commissioned by AIM. September 1998 Executive summary Particularly during the last decade it has become clear that non-price competition - the fight to win market share by establishing a quality edge, by product differentiation in established markets, and by innovation in new markets - has become the most important driver of value added and competitive success within the Single Market. The consequence is that competitive advantage - whether at the level of the firm, the Member State or the European Union as a whole - is not rigidly set by initial factor endowments, but is created by R&D, learning and strategic investments, supported by brand reputation in increasingly differentiated markets and selling to ever more demanding and knowledgeable distributors and final consumers. In this setting, horizontal product differentiation itself - that is to say greater product variety - is a competitive weapon, to be deployed alongside product quality in its several dimensions. Competitive actions are most effective when they are most difficult to copy quickly - as is the case with innovation. The incentive to innovate is further increased by the successful entry of outside producers into the Single Market, often with sophisticated versions of products already developed and sold in their own domestic markets. The distinction between the manufacturing function and the various simultaneous and downstream service functions involved in supply is nowadays fading. The service elements in the value chain - including the promotion of brands, the communication of product benefits and the provision of benefits to the distributor - have become at least as important in fast moving consumer goods (FMCG) markets as the production process itself. Furthermore, in the widened Single Market, scale economies persist in the “service” elements, after production scale economies in manufacturing have been largely exploited. Brand reputation is a necessary enabling condition of non-price competitive success, whether by innovation, product improvement or line extension. It is one of the main functions of advertising and promotion to reach - on the strength of pre-existing brand reputation - the early “critical mass” of demand that facilitates profitable volume and share growth, which in turn justifies the costs sunk during the development stages. The wave of inward investment by global competitors, the avalanche of information recently available to consumers and the further evolution of the relation between distributor and manufacturer have all increased the significance of brands, and the importance of reputation and intellectual property. Results set out in the PIMS Report, Of Brands and Growth, support these observations. It appears there that the competitive process flows from R&D, service investments, process and product innovation, promotion and advertising to higher perceived relative value expressed by means of the three main weapons - price competition, quality competition and new product offers. All three are mediated, and enabled, by high reputation - but particularly the last two. The dynamic system is continued, and the circle completed, by way of consequent market share gains by the winners, scale economies, value added increases augmented by the growth of the market, and the resulting profit gain for plough-back into renewed R&D, innovation and quality competition. Quality competition and innovation do not simply redistribute value added among competing firms: they raise it overall by raising domestic consumption standards. They also benefit overall wealth creation by their impact on industrial development. At a time when relatively low-value, labour-intensive tasks are increasingly being transferred to low-wage economies outside the EU, the development of higher value-added activities through innovation and branding helps the EU economies to concentrate on economic activities in which they retain a competitive advantage. The preservation of employment levels by creating such high value activity provides the most robust basis for sustainable employment policies and wealth creation. Several fields of European policy competence can enhance these processes: measures that help to free up commercial communications of all kinds; that protect intellectual property; that continue the support of collaborative precompetitive R&D; that simplify and unify product description rules and develop recognised quality standards that can be adopted by producers, without limiting product diversification; that facilitate start-ups by small enterprises; that encourage inward foreign direct investment, locating high value-added stages of the supply chain within Europe; and that put in place environment policies, industrial infrastructure policies and competition policies to stimulate new entry, and innovation and to allow for the increased importance of both knowledge and service in FMCG markets. 1. The importance of non-price competition 1.1 The Role of Non-Price Competition in the Single Market Ten years ago, in The European Challenge 19921 Paolo Cecchini and his team predicted that an increase in European economic welfare equal to 4.8% of GDP would result simply from the reductions in the price of given levels of output as a consequence of the Single European Act. This looked-for cost saving from cross-border scale economies and more intense competitive pressures driving out less efficient firms is what is chiefly remembered of the Cecchini Report - peak prices brought down to average in industries like dairy products, where competitive barriers were already low; and to the level of the two lowest price producers in such industries as railway rolling stock where cross-border entry barriers were high. For several reasons, nothing like this degree of price uniformity has yet occurred, but another set of welfare gains has been appearing in a way that was envisioned elsewhere in the Cecchini Report. In a short section near the end of the report, called “Market Dynamics and Technical Progress”, Cecchini wrote: “For companies, costs and prices are increasingly just two of the components of their competitive strategy for the 1990s indeed as of now. Today, more than ever before, is witness to the emergence of more telling competitive weaponry. Business’ capacity to develop new forms of organisation, to penetrate new geographical markets, to invent new products and processes - these are the stuff of which competitive edge is made. Comparative advantage is no longer seen as divine inheritance, nor are market structures set in tablets of stone. These ‘non-price’ factors, central to competitive business strategies, are dynamic and subject to continual change. And among these factors, the role of innovation is crucial.” Today, as a generalisation, this has become received wisdom. It is the purpose of the PIMS study to investigate the processes on the ground, at the level of the individual business. The study investigates the drivers of innovation and quality competition, and what kinds of business conduct wins and loses. By 1997, in the Commission’s Single Market Review, London Economics and the other researchers involved found the principal gains from the Single European Act to have appeared not from falls in cross-country disparities in price-cost margins, which had not yet appeared in many sectors, but from the consequences of company strategies in “product design”. “Product design” was used as a collective term to include product variety, R&D, innovations, advertising and promotion. Pro-competitive actions were 1 Cecchini, P., The European Challenge 1992 - the Benefits of a Single Market, Wildwood House, CEE, 1988. found to include a large measure of competition by service provision. The challenge of more intense competition and the opportunity of a larger and more open European market encourages and enables a faster pace of product innovation. It also increases quality and variety within established product markets. This 1997 finding corroborated an earlier observation by a European Commission working paper on industry policy, that: “at a time of rapid technological change associated with substantial economies of scale, differentiated products, more flexibility and globally operating firms, most sources of competitive advantage are created rather than endowed.... Producers must meet the competition first of all in terms of quality.... The ability to command a premium price constitutes the best indication of superior competitive performance”.2 1.2 How Quality Competition Operates The emphasis here is very different from the static welfare gains associated with the homogeneous product markets, negligible transport costs, perfect information and uniform tastes of old text-book models of competition. In place of that model, we have here a turbulent disequilibrium process of market evolution in the Schumpeterian tradition, in which bridgeheads are established by innovation, undermined by imitation and counter-innovation, and re-established. The process involves typically oligopolistic fights for market share, combining every dimension of the product that affects consumer choice. Among these non-price factors - collectively called quality - are appearance, appeal to other senses, image promoted by marketing effort, convenience, speed of action, running cost, reliability, servicing, consumer friendliness, environmental soundness, and how well the product performs the functions for which it is selected. Because consumers are different, diverse products co-exist. The theoretical difference between horizontal differentiation (variety) and vertical differentiation (superiority) is blurred by the variety of tastes. In customisation - the tailoring of a Dell computer or a cosmetics pack to the precise requirements of the consumer - horizontal differentiation in fact becomes a powerful quality discriminator (Stout & Swann, 1993)3. The key dynamic consideration is the difference in the response lags to different means of competing. In the very short run, with a fixed array of product offers in the market, there are no effective means to try to raise market share other than to lower price or to launch a sales promotion. With excess capacity, or at least important unachieved economies of scale, such actions will be undertaken, provided that they are not expected to be matched European Commission DG III Working Paper, “Industrial Policy in an Open and Competitive Environment: Guidelines for a Community Approach”, Brussels, 14 September 1990. 3 “Non-Price Competitiveness of British Firms”, in Hughes (ed) Future of UK Competitiveness and the Role of Industrial Policy, PSI, 1993). 2 by rivals before they have had the intended effect on sales and unit costs of players. However, since simple price competition is transparent and can be simply copied by equally efficient rivals, it will seldom generate the kind of breathing space that is necessary in order to win share and volume from rivals. In contrast, competing on difference based upon an aspect of added value that cannot be quickly copied is often the only reliable way to grow, faster than the market as a whole is growing. Response times to price changes are measured in days. First mover advantages to major innovators are measured in years.4 Several recent studies have supported this account of a more dynamic Single European Market economy, impelled by cross-border competition and enabled by information flows, a faster pace of technical change, inward investment, alliances and mergers. A notable feature has been powerful entry from firms based in other economies, introducing a strong dose of global oligopoly rivalry. European companies have lost ground, with a fall in the EU share of global exports by 7 percentage points since the early 1970s. This is largely due to the Tiger economies of South East Asia, rather than to the success of US and Japanese firms.5 1.3 The Weakened Distinction Between Manufacturing and Services Products are best seen today as “bundles of utilities”, and the distinction between manufacturing and services is becoming ill-defined. The “service” elements in product provision by the producer include customisation, product information, the many dimensions of product quality, design and packaging, and the confidence the consumer has in the brand. We can expect to see a continuation in the shift of added value downstream from raw material and manufacturing, towards the services of convenience, product trust, variety and shopping pleasure. This implies, for the manufacturer, a new and more collaborative relationship with the increasingly powerful and concentrated retail sector. The role of the manufacturer is to provide those contributions to value added which lie outside the retailer’s province - the strength of established brands and a stream of product improvements and innovations.6 1.4 Recent Developments in European Markets The relationship between manufacturers and retailers has changed radically in Europe, with the restructuring of distribution. The position has changed from a situation in which retailers were seen as simply a passive conduit through which goods had to flow to reach the consumer, to one in which retailers have become vital partners with manufacturers in the successful distribution of branded FMCGs. This has transformed the manufacturerretailer relationship from a zero-sum to a positive-sum game. It has also 4 See, for example, Panorama of European Industry 1997, Vol. 1 p. 93 UNICE, Benchmarking Europe’s Competitiveness from Analysis to Action, UNICE, 1997 See Hamel and Prahalad, Competing for the Future, HBS, Cambridge, Mass., Ch. 2, 1996, on the consequences of “disintermediation” for the manufacturing-services distinction 5 6 endowed retailers with substantial “gatekeeper” power. Increasingly, scale economies are realised more through the services associated with the product offer than at plant level, and those services are generated both by the manufacturer and by the retailer. Direct consumer advertising to the end consumer and in-store promotions and related services are both critical to success. On the supply side, the most obvious benefits of the Single European Market are the “lowered costs of space”, allowing scale economies and scope economies to be generated across national boundaries. Associated with this is a combination of production focus and wider consumer choice, which has changed FMCG markets dramatically over the past decade. Concentration in FMCG markets has generally been increasing. In their 1997 study for the Commission, the Economist Advisory Group found that at the pan-European level the 4-firm concentration ratio rose between 1983 and 1993 from 21.1% to 23.5% for highly advertised product markets and from 34.8% to 37.2% for highly advertised, high R&D markets. Since most available economies of scale in production are achieved at a plant size equivalent to less than ten per cent of the total European market, it might be supposed that concentration has gone further than is necessary to minimise costs. However in branded goods markets, this is not the case, for economies of scale in selling continue indefinitely for a global brand. Reputation is not reduced when it is spread over more consumers. On the contrary, it is increased. It is therefore not surprising to find that, over recent years, pan-European firms have, in general, sustained their profits, while businesses that have stayed regional have lost out. As the Economist Advisory Group concluded, in that review, “Fewer firms in larger markets may well start to compete more vigorously with each other”.7 High brand reputation is a consequence of success as well as a necessary condition of successful non-price competition. For innovation to be worth the investment cost and the risks, the product must be tried by a critical mass of consumers early enough for demand for the new product to take off before it can be imitated. Product differentiation, far from being a barrier to entry, opens up niche opportunities which would be absent or disregarded in a more homogeneous market (Caves, 1983).8 Consumer goods manufacturers typically employ advertising to enable product differentiation, often relying upon the accumulated reputation of an over-arching brand.9 Inter-firm rivalry is found to be at least as strong in advertising-intensive industries as elsewhere. Industry concentration tends to be higher, but the share of the leading firms is less stable.10 It is only when combined with high rates of innovation that high advertising protects rank.11 7 Single Market Review, Vol. 3, Sub-Series V, p. 61 Caves, R;, “Information Structures of Product Markets”, Harvard IER Paper 1002, 1983 9 Mueller, WF & Rogers RT, “Role of Advertising in Changing the Concentration of Manufacturing Industries”, Re of Ecs and Stats, Feb. 1980. 10 Eckard, “Advertising, Competition and Market Share Instability”, Journal of Business, 1987 11 Geroski & Toker, “Turnover of Market Leaders”, CBS Working Paper, LBS 1993. 8 New products, under an established brand, share the benefits of past reputation. Brands can last indefinitely, while individual products ride a life cycle up and then down. The investment in goodwill is vast and largely unaccounted for in corporate and national statistics. In competitive markets it is sustained by process and product innovation. Both advertising and intellectual property protection are involved. Many young, fast-growing markets (such as savoury snacks and yoghurt) exhibit high concentration together with high new entry. These sections are strongly contested and the leaders’ shares are constantly vulnerable to attack. Both brand support and intellectual property rights have become more important than ever as a result of the three major developments in European FMCG markets: the pace of inward investment; technical change and a tidal wave of accessible information to consumers and suppliers; and the restructuring and concentration of distribution. In short, the nature of FMCG industries is changing rapidly, and the way in which competition works has undergone a transformation. It is important that policy responses keep up with these changes. 1.5 Market Dynamics and the PIMS Report The PIMS Report, Of Brands and Growth, presents a wealth of statistical evidence on the contribution of branded consumer businesses to competitive growth. Many of the main connections between cause and effect, as FMCG markets change and grow, are highlighted in the Report. For the particular firm, growth depends upon the growth of the market as a whole and upon the strength of the particular drivers of competitive advantage, relative to its competitors both inside and outside the European market. As increases in the variables in this system work their way through, and feed back into profits ploughed into new investment in knowledge, R & D and brand reputation, so the firm prospers and grows. Conversely, if links are weakened or broken, the firm declines, as does its contribution to market growth and overall employment. For the European economy as a whole, an increase in perceived relative value enhances growth by two routes: first, by way of an increase in the average quality and unit value of domestically consumed products; and second, by way of the trade balance, as domestic value added is increasingly exported and substituted for imports. 1.6 PIMS Evidence on Competition by Raising Value The PIMS report has provided evidence that investment in knowledge and in brands is just as important to the sustaining and strengthening of market position as physical investment in plant, equipment and stocks. Without that market building, capacity expansion would be wasted. There is a link from R & D and marketing effort to the three main motors of competition - price, quality and new product launches An essential enabling condition is consumer interest and confidence, which can be summarised as reputation , raising consumers’ perception of increased relative value. This in turn benefits market share, value added, and the means and motive to complete a circle back to renewed physical, marketing, and R&D investment. For the purposes of this discussion, the three key results of the PIMS study are: the drivers of FMCG growth and performance are price, quality and innovation; relative value for money is a combination of quality and price. Quality change, which is harder to achieve, and takes longer to emulate, has more weight than price change; relative quality change is best reflected in perceived value change when the brand is highly regarded. If price competitiveness is increased, there need be no conflict between price and non-price competition. Successful innovation leads to gains in share, volume increases and the facilitation of efficiencies that pave the way for cost and price reductions. The case is different if price competition takes the form of a simple squeeze on manufacturers’ margins, for that threatens the link to value added, profits and the means to invest in R & D, know-how and innovation. 2. European Policy Implications The PIMS study has tested the dynamics of FMCG markets, particularly the nexus of branding, innovation and growth. Almost every aspect of European economic and social policy has some influence upon the competitive process in consumer markets. The five policy areas that the PIMS results have a direct bearing upon are innovation, intellectual property, consumer choice and standardisation, commercial communication and competition. 2.1 Innovation: PIMS result - innovation drives growth Critical mass is easier to reach, the larger is the total market open to the innovator wherever he is located within the EU. The larger is the total market, the greater the opportunity to specialise, customise and diversify, without forfeiting economies of scale. Furthermore, scale economies in the application of new knowledge and in the spreading of brand reputation are never exhausted, as are scale economies in production. Both the completion of the Single Market and the enlargement of the EU will tend to raise the rate of innovation and hence the rate of growth of domestic value added. 2.2 Intellectual Property: PIMS result - IP provides the means to gain by innovating The links through R&D, know-how and product innovation to competitive advantage are vulnerable to attack from “look-alike” products which free-ride on established brand reputations. The copying of a good new idea and the emulation of a process innovation is the means by which technology is transferred through and across industries. But there is a trade-off between making something easy to imitate and providing an incentive to invest in research and development in the first place, which depends on the appropriation of a temporary leadership advantage by the innovator. A balance has always to be struck by the policy-maker between ensuring rapid technology transfer and protecting intellectual property rights. Policies that open markets will always need to contain safeguards to prevent the possibility that incentives to innovate are undermined. It is important that intellectual property rights are enforced and “look-alikes” discouraged in developing markets. 2.3 Consumer Choice and Standardisation: PIMS result - brands give choice There are links - both ways - between value added growth and total European market growth. Quality competition and innovation do not simply redistribute value added among competing firms: they raise it overall by raising domestic consumption standards. They also benefit overall wealth creation by their impact on industrial development. At a time when relatively low-value, labourintensive tasks are increasingly being transferred to low-wage economies outside the EU, the development of higher value-added activities through innovation and branding helps the EU economies to concentrate on economic activities in which they retain a competitive advantage. The preservation of employment levels by creating such high value activity provides the most robust basis for sustainable employment policies and wealth creation. In other work12, quality standards, voluntarily adopted, have been found to be strongly associated both with domestic competitive advantage and with trade performance. The adoption of quality standards by a brand is part of its nonprice competitiveness. Horizontal product differentiation, by increasing “customisation”, is ipso facto an ingredient of quality. Quality standard setting, with European rather than American or Japanese leadership in the process, raise the competitive advantage of European nations, particularly in new and hi-tech product and service markets. The distinction is important between such open and voluntary adoption of standards on the one hand, and the imposition of rules and measures that enforce homogeneity by standardising output and thus diminishing the range of consumer choice. The EU has recognised that all regulations have a cost particularly for small new entrant firms who make an important contribution to the innovative performance of markets. These firms do not generally have the advantage of established brand reputation and it is usually harder for them to obtain finance. It is therefore important that other impediments to their entry like the task of understanding and responding to complex regulations are kept low. Policies, like SLIM - to simplify internal market legislation - and BEST - to lower entry barriers for small firms - are now appropriately being developed as European initiatives. The message to policy makers is not to insist upon narrow specifications of products, imposed from outside the market, or homogeneity simply for the sake of supposed economies of scale from uniformity. One of the main developments in manufacturing processes in recent years has been mass customisation - the ability to combine economies of scale with flexibility and product variety. This has increased the advantages of product differentiation as an expression of non-price competition. The reputation of a brand enables a variety of products that carry that brand name to share in the consumers’ confidence of its technical and safety standards. The brand acts as a flag under which a diversity of products can be sold without the consumer losing confidence in the safety specifications of any of them. This is a credible communication method because brand equity, and the reputation of all the products with that brand name, suffer from a lapse in the standards of any one of them. 2.4 Commercial Communication: communication is part of competition PIMS result - commercial Price cuts are apparent to the consumer of established products independently of actual purchase. By contrast, quality competition and the benefits afforded by a brand new product require that the product be tried. For this to happen, buyer inertia must be overcome. Every form of 12 Shurmer, Swann, Temple, Standards, Non-price Competition and Trade Performance, CBS Working Paper 1994, LBS. commercial communication is employed to encourage that trial. Media advertising, the Internet, package design, labelling, samples and retailer services are all involved. They support the reputation of the brand name carried by the innovation or by the product difference. A critical mass of consumers has to be won before demand for a new product can take off, justifying the investment in it. Brand reputation encourages that initial trial. The high importance of non-price competition has dissolved the old distinction between the physical function of manufacture and the provision of the range of services that inhere in the product, as described in the first part of this paper. Product design, packaging, advertisement and product information and convenient availability are all as much part of the bundle of utilities that makes up a product as the physical product itself. An increasing proportion of value added and employment is due to these service elements. Retailers have a natural immediate access to the consumer and therefore an important role in communication. But that is largely exercised to influence the location of the purchase, both by the provision of physical amenities and by psychological appeals - including smell and sound - that do not, for the most part, distinguish between particular products. As retailers become larger and more sophisticated, their ability to deliver on marketing and promotional plans developed in partnership with manufacturers increases. At the same time, however, the tendency for a few large retailers to act in effect as gatekeepers between the manufacturer and the consumer can become a threat to access to the market from the manufacturer’s perspective. It is important that the manufacturer continues to have a prominent role in the direct communication of product claims, through media advertising, the design of packaging, and the communication of product information; and that new products can gain access to the consumer. 2.5 Competition Policy: PIMS results - leadership is not anticompetitive; advertising is not a barrier to entry The PIMS study also indicates that a leading share position without exceptional brand reputation is easily eroded if it is not well defended. Conversely, the percentage point increase in share taken by a low share business with high reputation is strikingly large. This points to the importance - to the growth of these markets - of advertising and services to the retailer, which both support the image of the brand. Examples are the building of the close and automatic communication links between retailer and manufacturer that make possible effective in-store promotions to their mutual advantage; the provision of cast-iron guarantees of product safety; and, most importantly, a continuous stream of product improvements that justify the outlets’ support of the brand. A consideration for the framers of European competition policy is to allow such drivers of reputation to continue to work. A competition policy that placed price as the sole criterion would be missing out on crucial elements of the drivers of consumer welfare, and could mistakenly undermine beneficial partnerships between manufacturers and retailers. It is important that policy does not discourage collaboration among manufacturers and distributors to increase added value, as distinct from fighting over shares of a fixed added value. There are big potential welfare gains, both in efficiency terms and in consumer satisfaction, from manufacturer-retailer collaborations. Provided that there is competition between manufacturers, such collaborations are unlikely to imperil price competition. A manufacturer seeking to win share from a rival manufacturer will not overlook the importance of price competitiveness. Keeping the final consumers’ preferences in mind, he will seek to equate, at the margin, the market advantage of keener price with that of improved quality. This is an area in which the development of increasingly powerful retail groups can have ambiguous effects on welfare. Given their importance as controllers of access to the consumer, large retailers are well placed to use their leverage in negotiations with suppliers. This leverage is increased by the fact that, through their extensive involvement in private label sales, large retailers are at once the manufacturers’ most important customers and amongst their biggest competitors. One way in which retailers exert bargaining leverage is to lead branded goods manufacturers to supply private label products that incorporate the most recent innovations. This activity has become an established part of the competitive environment but one that carries with it the risk that returns to manufacturer innovation are diluted and innovation discouraged. The PIMS study has general implications for the conduct of competition policy in markets supplied by branded FMCG manufacturers. Two important lessons to be drawn from the PIMS study are these: first, leadership - in the sense of a preponderant share of a product market - is not per se anticompetitive. In the context of markets where innovation and branding are prominent, positions that might be thought “dominant” under a static share-ofmarket test, turn out to be very vulnerable to competitive erosion, particularly by new products. Leading firms have to run hard in order to stand still. Second, advertising and product differentiation - far from being barriers to entry - can make entry easier, by opening up opportunities to get close to more specific segments of the market and more distinctive sets of consumers.