COUNTRY NOTE 8: NATURAL RESOURCES: WHEN BLESSINGS BECOME CURSES Since at least the time of Adam Smith and David Ricardo there has been a belief that natural resources are a blessing: that countries richly endowed with natural resources have an advantage over countries that are not. For centuries, people moved to where natural resources were abundant: to the Americas, to Australia, to oil-rich countries in the Middle East. Natural resource endowments have helped many countries, including Australia, Canada, Finland, and Norway, to grow and diversify, in part by providing a basis for developing associated technologies and capital goods industries (World Bank 2001). Figure C8.1: Natural resources and growth, 1970-89 Source: Sachs and Warner (1997). Since the end of World War II, however, and particularly since the 1960s, evidence has accumulated that natural resources are less often a blessing than a curse.1 This finding is statistically robust, invariant to changes in specification, variable definitions, or inclusion of additional explanatory variables—including those commonly used in empirical growth studies, such as geography and climate. After controlling for all possible influences and interactions, the evidence is that countries rich in natural resources grow more slowly. Not only economic growth is affected negatively (Gelb 1988). Controlling for country income level, countries that are rich in natural resources have more unequal income 1 Sachs and Warner (1995, 1997, and 2001); Lane and Tornell (1999); Auty and Mikesell (1998); Gylfason (2001); Leite and Weidmann (1999); Dalmazzo and Blasio (2001). While there are many ways to define natural resource abundance—for example as the share of natural resources in GDP or exports (as in Figure C8.1), with further breakdown for fuel, ores and metals; or oil producing vs. other developing countries—they all suggest that countries rich in resources grow more slowly. 1 distribution and a larger share of their population in poverty, they exhibit greater corruption, have more authoritarian regimes, spend more on the military, and face a higher probability of an armed conflict (Palley 2003). The probability of a civil conflict is 0.5 percent in a country with limited natural resources, but 23 percent in a country where natural resources account for 26 percent of GDP (Collier and Hoeffler 1998, 2001). In far too many countries, including Iraq, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, Venezuela, former Zaire, Zambia, and many others, enormous oil or mineral wealth has not translated into economic and social well being for the majority of the population. Those natural resources that depress countries’ long-run growth are those whose rents are technically easy to appropriate: so-called point-source natural resources such as diamonds, gold, oil, and minerals. Other resources, such as land or human resources, have more diffuse rents and do not seem to have such an effect. Two lines of explanation have emerged to explain the “natural resource curse”. The first focuses on how natural resources affect the economy, and the second on how they affect institutions (Eifert, Gelb, and Tallroth 2003). Economic effects The so-called Dutch disease is perhaps the most well known effect of natural resource rents on the real economy. High exports of natural resources cause an appreciation of a country’s real exchange rate, which moves its productive resources away from tradables such as manufactured goods. If manufacturing produces significant positive externalities that are crucial for long-term development, such as learning-by-doing, the country’s economic growth rate will suffer (Sachs and Warner 1997). Another well-known problem of resource-rich economies is volatility, with cycles of boom and bust. For example, the high resource prices of the 1970s led resource-rich countries to borrow heavily, and the collapse of prices that ensued in the early 1980s left them with large debts and little capacity to service them (Manzano and Rigobon 2001). The countries affected ranged from Bolivia to Venezuela to Ivory Coast and Nigeria; many resource-rich countries have not yet recovered. Equally serious, unless a resource-rich economy has a large non-resource-based tradable sector to begin with, the uncertainty associated with cycles of boom and bust can reinforce a downward cycle. The smaller the non-resource tradable sector, the fewer opportunities workers have to find new jobs when resource prices decline; as a result, a price decline can cause the whole economy to contract. Interest rates will reflect the risks associated with this volatility: the greater the volatility, the higher is the interest rate, and, in turn, the smaller are investments in non-resource tradables. These two effects combine to cause the economy to specialize away from production of non-resource tradables. In turn, the less the economy produces non-resource tradables, “… the greater the volatility of relative prices, the higher the interest rate the sector faces, causing it to shrink even further, until it disappears” (Hausmann and Rigobon 2002). 2 Saving rates in oil-exporting countries are much higher than in other developing countries. But even so, these relationships mean that without corrective policies, volatility causes oilexporting economies to specialize inefficiently in the production of non-tradables, retarding their long-term growth. Thus, it has been argued that Venezuela’s growth implosion in the early 1980s was the result of the high real interest rates facing the non-resource tradable sector, and of uncompetitive and volatile exchange rates, which caused Venezuela to specialize almost exclusively in resource extraction and non-tradables (Hausmann and Rigobon 2002). Institutional effects These economic explanations do not answer questions about the differences in performance across resource-rich countries, such as why diamonds have been a curse for Sierra Leone but a blessing for Botswana, or why oil has been a blessing for Indonesia. Neither can they explain why point-source natural resources affect growth differently from natural resources with more diffuse rents. Such differences in performance have given rise to a large literature offering political and institutional explanations of the resource curse. Large and concentrated rents, easier to appropriate than the more diffuse rents associated with land or human resources, make societies less entrepreneurial by increasing the private returns to unproductive rent-seeking. Several studies focus on the “voracity effect,” or common pool problems, that move an economy into a low-growth equilibrium because of political fights over resource rents (Lane and Tornell 1999; Mehlum, Moene, and Torvik 2003). In Nigeria, for example, governance institutions were weak and large oil resources were wasted. Large windfall oil profits corrupted Nigeria’s institutions and changed its politics, which came to be shaped by the incessant fight over resource revenues. Public spending turned into outright patronage, crippling the civil service. Starting with the Biafra war in the late 1960, successive military dictators plundered Nigeria’s oil wealth, wasting resources on an enormous scale; the country’s total factor productivity has declined by 1.2 percent a year over the last few decades (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003). Numerous econometric studies confirm that countries rich in natural resources have weaker institutions, measured in terms of checks and balances on the executive, rule of law, and corruption (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003; Isham, Woolcock, Pritchett, and Busby 2003; Sala-i-Martin, Doppelhoffer, and Miller 2003; Robinson, Torvik, and Verdier 2002; Mehlum, Moene, and Torvik 2002). These studies also show that, controlling for institutions, natural resources have no effect on long-term growth. That is, institutions are not just the principal but the only channel through which resources influence the course of the economy. While natural resources were a curse for Nigeria, the discovery of diamonds became a blessing for development in Botswana, as did oil in Indonesia. Botswana has effectively maintained law and order, limited state predation, and enforced hard budget constraints on its parastatal organizations (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2003). The government has invested heavily in the expansion of infrastructure and efficient delivery of education and health services. While AIDS has reversed some of the health gains, 3 and led to a sharp decline in life expectancy, Botswana’s other social indicators are among the better in Africa and in the developing world. The bureaucracy is largely meritocratic, relatively non-corrupt, and efficient. Fiscal revenues from resource rents have used to smooth revenue over commodity price cycles, rather than financing consumption booms; indeed, Botswana was one of the first countries to establish a stabilization fund, which it managed well. One of the reasons behind Botswana’s success is believed to be its benign neglect by colonial powers: Botswana was on the periphery of the British empire, not known to have valuable resources, and hence of little interest. Thus, unlike in most other African countries, colonialism had a negligible effect on traditional social and political institutions. Botswana’s pastoral traditions traditionally encouraged broad-based participation and constraints on political leaders; rural interests, chiefs, and cattle owners retained their political power throughout the colonial period. They have been the source of checks on the executive, and explain why diamond rents have been exceptionally well managed. Indonesia did not have democratic and participatory institutions, at least until very recently. But although corruption and governance problems were widespread, Soeharto’s regime focused on economic and social development. On the one hand, it provided checks on state and individual predation and, on the other, it provided predictability and consistency in policy making (Temple 2003). Internal accountability mechanisms enabled the bureaucracy to deliver a wide array of social and infrastructure services, and poverty programs. Growth in Indonesia was not only rapid but quite widely shared, through programs such as the Instruction of the President (INPRES), a rural development program that was started at the time of the first rise in oil prices in 1973 and subsequently expanded. INPRES included village support grants, rural infrastructure, and a massive expansion of schooling (World Bank 1994). One reason for Indonesia’s success was that the Soeharto regime shielded technocrats from political pressures: the group of high-level technocrats responsible for policy making (the “Berkeley mafia”) was empowered to make economic policy decisions with long-term growth and development objectives in mind. Thus, the response to a fall in oil prices in the early 1980s was a text-book adjustment that triggered comprehensive microeconomic reforms—from competition policy to exchange rate adjustments and trade liberalization (see also Country Note 2, Lessons from Countries That Sustained Their Growth). Economic and political explanations are difficult to disentangle. In the course of development, economic institutions are shaped by economic incentives and opportunities, and political dynamics respond to underlying economic forces (Engermann and Sokoloff 2003). Political and other institutions may be the main explanatory forces, but economic forces also play a role in explaining why the institutions are the way they are. Conclusion Simply copying or adopting policies that have been effective elsewhere rarely succeeds. Many resource-rich developing countries have experimented with oil funds or stabilization programs but with disappointing results. Successful management of a natural resource curse calls for a combination of policies and institutions. On the economic policy front, countercyclical stabilization policies have a critical role to play, as do policies that maintain the 4 competitiveness of the real exchange rate for the non-resource tradable sector, and financial policies that encourage investments in that sector. On the institutional front, institutions such as transparency, and checks and balances on the use of rents, that increase the costs of nonproductive activities can help countries to move away from rent-seeking equilibria to more dynamic, diversified, and growing economies. East Timor’s oil stabilization fund illustrates this approach. While it is too early to conclude how the fund will work in practice, the intent of the fund is to rely on institutional improvements that ensure resource rents are effectively used for long-term development. It emphasizes transparency and public awareness of the issues that concern the good use of oil revenues, thus developing constituencies in support of prudent policies. References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson (2003), “An African Success Story: Botswana”. In Dani Rodrik, ed., In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.1369-1401. Auty, R., and R. Mikesell (1998), Sustainable Development in Mineral Economies. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Buiter, W., Akram Esanov, and Martin Raiser (2001), “Nature’s Blessing or Nature’s Curse? The Political Economy of Transition in Resource-based Economies”. EBRD Working Paper No. 65. London, UK: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler (1998), “On the Economic Causes of Civil War”, Oxford Economic Papers 50. Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler (2001), “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Washington, DC: World Bank. Dalmazzo, A., and G. de Blasio (2001), “Resources and Incentives to Reform: A Model and Some Evidence on Sub-Saharan African Countries”. IMF Working Paper No. 86. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Eifert, Benn, Alan Gelb, and Nils Borje Tallroth (2003), “The Political Economy of Fiscal Policy and Economic Management in Oil-exporting Countries”. In J. M. Davis, R. Ossowski, and A. Fedelino, eds., Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (2002), “Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development among New World Economies”. NBER Working Paper No. 9259. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Gelb, Alan, (ed.) (1988), Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? New York: Oxford University Press. Gylfason, T. (2001), “Nature, Power, and Growth”. CESinfo Working Paper No. 413. Hausmann, Ricardo, and Barry Eichengreen (2002), “Original Sin: The Pain, the Mystery, and the Road to Redemption”. Working Paper, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Online at http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~.rhausma.cid.ksg/publication.htm Hausmann, Ricardo, and Roberto Rigobon (2002), “An Alternative Interpretation of the ‘Resource Curse: Theory and Policy Implications.” NBER Working Paper No. 9424. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. 5 Isham, Jonathan, Michael Woolcock, Lant Pritchett, and Gwen Busby (2003), “The Varieties of Resource Experience: How Natural Resource Export Structures Affect the Political Economy of Economic Growth.” Middlebury College Working Paper Series 0308. Middlebury College, Department of Economics. Lane, Phillip R., and Aaron Tornell (1999), “Voracity and Growth in Discrete Time”, Economic Letters 62 (1): 139-145. Leite, C., and J. Weidmann (1999), “Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth”. IMF Working Paper No. 85. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Manzano, Osmel, and Roberto Rigobon (2001), “Resource Curse or Debt Overhang?” NBER Working Paper No. 8390. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Mehlum, Halvor, Karl-Ove Moene, and Ragnar Torvik (2003), “Institutions and the Resource Curse,”. Mimeo 29/2002. Oslo University, Department of Economics. Economics Working Paper Archive at WUSTL. Palley, Thomas I. (2003), “Lifting the Natural Resource Curse”, Foreign Service Journal 80 (12): 5461. Robinson, James A, Torvik, Ragnar and Verdier, Thierry, 2002. "Political Foundations of the Resource Curse," CEPR Discussion Papers 3422, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers. June 2002 Rodriguez, F., and D. Rodrik (2000), “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-national Evidence”. In Macroeconomics Annual 2000. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Online at: http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~.drodrik.academic.ksg/papers.html Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner (1995), “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. Paper No. 517a, Harvard Institute for International Development. Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner (1997), “Sources of Slow Growth in African Economies”, Journal of African Economies 6 (3): 335-376. Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner (2001), “The Curse of Natural Resources”, European Economic Review 45 (4):827-838. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, Gernot Doppelhofer, and Ronald Miller (2003), “Determinants of Long-term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE) Approach”. University of Cambridge Faculty of Economics and Politics; Columbia University Department of Economics; and Columbia University Department of Economics. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, and Arvind Subramanian (2003), “Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: An Illustration from Nigeria”. IMF Working Paper 03/139. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Temple, Jonathan (2003), “Growing into Trouble: Indonesia after 1966”. In Dani Rodrik (ed.): In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. World Bank (1994), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. World Bank (2001), “From Natural Resources to Knowledge Economy: Trade and Job Quality”. LAC Research Report. Washington, DC: World Bank. 6