CARDIFF BUSINESS SCHOOL MACROECONOMICS (BS1652) Spring Semester 2005-06 Maths Macro Lecture 2 Simultaneous equation systems in macroeconomic analysis I. The ‘Keynesian Cross’ model In a model of the macro-economy, one will normally find both exogenous variables and endogenous variables. The ‘Keynesian Cross’ model is no exception. The model comprises two basic equations – a national income identity (or equilibrium condition) and a consumption function. The precise nature of the equations making up this model depends upon the number of sectors which the economy is considered to have – all economies must have a minimum of two sectors (households and firms), but an economy can also comprise a government sector (government expenditure and taxation) and a trade sector (exports and imports). Assuming that the economy is a closed one (i.e. no trade) and has no government sector (i.e. no government expenditure or taxation), then the model is as follows: (i) y = c + i (equilibrium condition) (ii) c = a + b. y (consumption function) where y represents national income, c is consumption and i is the exogenous level of investment expenditure, while a and b are constants of the consumption function ( a > 0 and 0 < b < 1 ). Since the level of investment expenditure is determined outside of the model (it must be since there is no equation within the model which explains its level), the variable i is said to be exogenous (or autonomous). [Similarly, the values of the constants in the consumption function, i.e. a and b , are also exogenous since they are determined ‘outside’ of the model.] The ‘Keynesian Cross’ model above comprises only two endogenous variables: y and c . Note that y depends on c (from the equilibrium condition) but also that c depends on y (from the consumption function). Hence, if either of c or y changes, then so too will the other variable (but this, of course, is not the case for the exogenous variable i , which remains at its pre-determined value – changes in the value of the endogenous variables can not cause changes in the values of the exogenous variables). Note, however, that if either the exogenous variable i , or the constant terms in the consumption function, were to experience a change in their value (due to an ‘outside’ or exogenous shock), then the values of both c and y will change, that is, changes in the exogenous values can induce changes in the equilibrium values of the endogenous variables. The ‘reduced form’ of a model The ‘reduced form’ of a model is a series of equations which express the equilibrium values of the endogenous variables in a model as functions simply of the exogenous variables/constants. The number of ‘reduced form’ equations will therefore correspond to the number of the endogenous variables in the model. In the ‘Keynesian Cross’ model depicted above, there will be two ‘reduced form’ equations, one for c and one for y . To obtain the ‘reduced form’ equation for y , substitute for c in equation (i) : y = a + b. y + i y - b. y = a + i y(1- b) = a + i y = (a + i)/(1- b) To obtain the ‘reduced form’ equation for c , substitute for y in equation (ii) : c = a + b. ( c + i ) c - b. c = a + b. i c ( 1 - b ) = a + b. i c = ( a + b. i ) / ( 1 - b ) How can we be sure that the equations we have determined are actually the ‘reduced form’ equations? Well, it can be seen from looking at the right hand sides of each equation that they only contain pre-determined values, that is, either the value of the exogenous variable i and/or the pre-determined constants ( a and b ) from the consumption function. Thus, if we knew the values of i , a and b , then by substituting these into the ‘reduced form’ equations, we would be able to determine the equilibrium solution values of c and y . For example, if i = 200 , and a and b are respectively 50 and 0.8, then the equilibrium values for c and y are: y = ( 50 + 200 ) / ( 1 - 0.8 ) = 250 / 0.2 = 1250 c = [ 50 + (0.8) (200) ] / ( 1 - 0.8 ) = 210 / 0.2 = 1050 2 [Note that, since i = 200 , c + i = 1050 + 200 = 1250 , which is the value of y. Hence the answers are consistent and you have an in-built check to see whether or not you have worked out the answer correctly.] Note, however, that we got definitive answers for the values of y and c because it was assumed that i was exogenous (and hence its level was known). But what if the level of i depended upon a variable such as the interest rate r ? In this situation the model becomes: (i) y = c + i (equilibrium condition) (ii) c = a + b. y (consumption function) (iii) i = i0 - h. r (investment function) where i0 is the exogenous component of investment expenditure, h > 0 , and r is determined exogenously. To obtain the ‘reduced form’ equation for y , substitute for c and i in equation (i) : y = a + b. y + i0 - h. r y - b. y = a + i0 - h. r y ( 1 - b ) = a + i0 - h. r y = ( a + i0 ) _ h_ .r (1- b) (1- b) (A) To obtain the ‘reduced form’ equation for c , substitute for y and i in equation (ii) : c = a + b. ( c + i ) c - b. c = a + b. i c ( 1 - b ) = a + b. ( i0 - h. r ) c = ( a + b. i0 ) _ bh . r (1- b) (1- b) Clearly the solution values for both y and c depend upon the value of r , the rate of interest. The other important thing to note is that equation (A) , which is derived from the equilibrium condition (i) , provides us with a relationship between y and r which describes equilibrium in the real sector of the economy. Equation (A) is also known as the IS curve, and forms a key part of the IS/LM model (see notes for Maths Macro Lecture 3). 3 Turning equation (A) around to express r as a function of y , we get: y = ( a + i0 ) _ h_ .r (1- b) (1- b) ( 1 – b ). Y = ( a + i0 ) - h. r h. r = ( a + i0 ) - ( 1 – b ). Y r = ( a + i0 ) - ( 1 – b ). Y h h The slope of the IS curve is therefore given by: dr/dy = - ( 1 – b ) / h Diagrammatically, then, we have the following: r Slope = - ( 1 – b ) / h IS y Given that the slope of the IS curve is - ( 1 – b ) / h , then, if b (the marginal propensity to consume) increases, or h (the interest sensitivity of investment) increases, then the slope of the IS curve will become flatter; if b or h should decrease, then the slope of the IS curve will become steeper. Having examined the IS curve, in Maths Macro Lecture 3 we will investigate the LM curve and the IS/LM model. 4