qwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwer tyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopa sdfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjkl Debt Levels and Share Price a Sensitivity Analysis on Vestas zxcvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbn Author: Lavinia Andrei MSc. Finance and International Business mqwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwert Advisor: Otto Friedrichsen yuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopas April 2011 Aarhus School of Business, Aarhus University dfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjklz xcvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnm qwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwerty uiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopasd fghjklzxcvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjklzx cvbnmqwertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmq wertyuiopasdfghjklzxcvbnmqwertyui Acknowledgements I would like to express my appreciation and thankfulness to my supervisor for his guidance and to my friends for their support. Abstract Capital structure is one of the areas of corporate finance which has long been under the scrutiny of theorists and researchers. This paper aims to take a hands-on approach and to look at how the level of debt affects share prices in the case of Vestas. Firstly, a plain vanilla valuation of the company is performed, yielding a share price of EUR 30.03. The company’s optimal capital structure is thereafter determined, by employing the two sub-frameworks of the trade-off theory: static and dynamic. The results point out that Vestas is currently either around optimum debt levels (in the dynamic trade-off case), or below them (in the static trade-off case). An extensive sensitivity analysis of share prices dependent upon debt levels is built into the valuation model, thus determining how the share price will fluctuate when the debt level changes. In addition to target debt levels, the sensitivity analysis further looks at the effects of other debt-related variables (cost of debt and marginal tax rate), as well as non-debtrelated ones (the risk free rate and the return on the market portfolio). Given the way the valuation model is designed, the larger the effect that a variable has on the weighted average cost of capital, the larger its impact on the company’s share price will be. Key words: capital structure, static trade-off, dynamic trade-off, valuation, sensitivity analysis, Vestas. Contents List of Figures ................................................................................................................... 5 List of Tables .................................................................................................................... 6 Chapter 1. Introduction ................................................................................................. 7 1.1. Problem Statement..................................................................................................... 8 1.2. Limitations ................................................................................................................. 9 1.3. Methodology............................................................................................................ 10 1.4. Structure of the Thesis ............................................................................................. 11 Chapter 2. Overview of Capital Structure Theories ................................................. 12 2.1. Does Capital Structure Matter? ............................................................................ 12 2.1.1. The M&M Theories ...................................................................................... 12 2.1.2. Subsequent Studies........................................................................................ 13 2.2. The Trade-Off Theory.......................................................................................... 15 2.2.1. Determinants of Capital Structure ................................................................. 17 2.2.2. The Static Trade-Off Model .......................................................................... 20 2.2.3. The Dynamic Trade-Off Model .................................................................... 21 2.3. The Pecking Order Theory .................................................................................. 25 2.3.1. Information Asymmetry Considerations ....................................................... 25 2.3.2 Agency Costs Considerations......................................................................... 26 2.4. Market Timing Theory......................................................................................... 26 Chapter 3. Business Strategy Analysis ....................................................................... 28 3.1. External Analysis ................................................................................................. 28 3.2. Porter’s 5 Forces Model ....................................................................................... 29 3.3. Competitor analysis ............................................................................................. 29 3.4. Internal Analysis .................................................................................................. 29 3.4.1. Strategy statements........................................................................................ 29 3.4.2. Product and Service Mix ............................................................................... 30 3.4.3. Business segments ......................................................................................... 30 3.5. SWOT Analysis ................................................................................................... 31 Chapter 4. Analysing Historical Performance .......................................................... 33 4.1. Reorganisation of Financial Statements .............................................................. 33 4.1.1. Treatment of Accounts, Assumptions and Estimations ................................ 33 1 4.1.2. Results of Reorganisation ............................................................................. 36 4.2. Credit Health ........................................................................................................ 37 4.3. Stock Market Performance .................................................................................. 37 Chapter 5. Base case scenario valuation..................................................................... 39 5.1. Scenario description ............................................................................................. 39 5.2. Forecasting performance ...................................................................................... 39 5.2.1. Revenue growth............................................................................................. 39 5.2.2. Cost of capital................................................................................................ 40 5.2.3. Other inputs ................................................................................................... 42 5.2.4. Continuing value ........................................................................................... 43 5.3. Valuation result .................................................................................................... 43 5.4. Critique ................................................................................................................ 44 Chapter 6. Sensitivity Analysis .................................................................................... 45 6.1. Target capital structure ........................................................................................ 45 6.1.1. The Static Trade-off Target Debt Level ........................................................ 46 6.1.2. The Dynamic Trade-off Target Debt Level and Adjustment Speed ............. 48 6.1.3. Simulation Assumptions and Method ........................................................... 49 6.1.4. Results ........................................................................................................... 51 6.1.5. Discussion and Critique ................................................................................ 54 6.1.6. Discussion on the Adjustment Speed ............................................................ 58 6.2. The Cost of Debt .................................................................................................. 59 6.2.1. Types of Debt - Discussion ........................................................................... 59 6.2.2. Sensitivity Analysis Assumptions and Method ............................................. 61 6.2.3. Results and Discussion .................................................................................. 62 6.3. Other Debt-Related and Non-debt-related Variables ........................................... 62 6.3.1. Simulation Assumptions and Method ........................................................... 63 6.3.2. Results ........................................................................................................... 64 6.3.3. Discussion and Critique ................................................................................ 64 6.4. Simulations of All Variables ................................................................................ 65 6.4.1. Simulation Assumptions and Method ........................................................... 65 6.4.2. Results ........................................................................................................... 66 6.4.3. Discussion and Critique ................................................................................ 67 Chapter 7. Conclusions ................................................................................................ 69 2 Bibliography ................................................................................................................... 72 Annexes .......................................................................................................................... 77 A1. Market Definition, Size and Growth .................................................................... 77 A1.1. Market Definition .......................................................................................... 77 A1.2. Market Size.................................................................................................... 78 A1.3. From Present to Future - Market Growth ...................................................... 79 A2. PESTEL Analysis ................................................................................................ 82 A2.1. Political and Legal Factors ............................................................................ 82 A2.2. Economic Factors .......................................................................................... 82 A2.3. Socio-cultural Factors.................................................................................... 84 A2.4. Technological Factors ................................................................................... 85 A2.5. Environmental Factors .................................................................................. 86 A2.6. General Degree of Turbulence in the Industry Environment ........................ 86 A3. Competitor Analysis ............................................................................................ 87 A3.1. The top 4 ........................................................................................................ 87 A3.2. Competition trends ........................................................................................ 88 A4. Porter’s 5 Forces Model ....................................................................................... 90 A4.1. Bargaining Power of Buyers ......................................................................... 90 A4.2. Bargaining Power of Suppliers...................................................................... 91 A4.3. Threat of New Entrants ................................................................................. 93 A4.4. Threat of Substitute Products ........................................................................ 94 A4.5. Competitive Rivalry within the Industry ....................................................... 96 A5. Internal Analysis .................................................................................................. 97 A5.1. Corporate Vision, Mission and Strategy ....................................................... 97 A5.2. Product and Service Mix ............................................................................... 98 A5.3. Geographic & Business Segments ................................................................ 99 A5.4. Business Model ........................................................................................... 100 A6. SWOT Analysis ................................................................................................. 103 A6.1. Strengths ...................................................................................................... 103 A6.2. Weaknesses ................................................................................................. 105 A6.3. Opportunities ............................................................................................... 105 A6.4. Threats ......................................................................................................... 107 A7. Reorganisation of Financial Statements ............................................................. 110 3 A7.1. Invested Capital ........................................................................................... 110 A7.2. NOPLAT ..................................................................................................... 111 A7.3. Free Cash Flow ............................................................................................ 112 A7.4. Return on Invested Capital .......................................................................... 112 A7.5. Revenue Growth .......................................................................................... 113 A8. Interest Coverage ............................................................................................... 113 A9. Historical Analysis Results ................................................................................ 114 A9.1. Income Statement ........................................................................................ 114 A9.2. Balance Sheet .............................................................................................. 115 A9.3. Cash Flow Statement ................................................................................... 116 A9.4. NOPLAT ..................................................................................................... 117 A9.5. Invested Capital ........................................................................................... 117 A9.6. Free Cash Flow ............................................................................................ 118 A9.7. Financial Ratios ........................................................................................... 119 A10. Base Case Scenario Valuation Inputs .............................................................. 120 A10.1. Detailed forecast ........................................................................................ 120 A10.2. Key Driver Forecast .................................................................................. 121 4 List of Figures Figure 1: The Static Trade-off Theory ........................................................................... 16 Figure 2: Degree of Turbulence in the Industry ..............................................................28 Figure 3: Porter’s 5 Forces ..............................................................................................29 Figure 4: Vestas’ Revenue .............................................................................................. 31 Figure 5: SWOT Analysis ..............................................................................................32 Figure 6: ROIC Tree ........................................................................................................36 Figure 7: Stock Market Performance...............................................................................37 Figure 8: Valuation result ................................................................................................43 Figure 9: The Static Trade-off Model..............................................................................47 Figure 10: Simulation #1 Share Price Histogram ............................................................53 Figure 11: Simulation #2 Share Price Histogram ............................................................53 Figure 12: Simulation #3 Share Price Histogram ............................................................53 Figure 13: Simulation #4 Share Price Histogram ............................................................53 Figure 14: Simulation #5 Share Price Histogram ............................................................54 Figure 15: Simulation #6 Share Price Histogram ............................................................54 Figure 16: Share Price Sensitivity in the Static Trade-off Case ......................................62 Figure 17: Share Price Sensitivity in the Dynamic Trade-off Case ................................62 5 List of Tables Table 1 – Determinants of Capital Structure .................................................................. 18 Table 2: Main Valuation Inputs .......................................................................................43 Table 3: Target Capital Structure Percentage Changes Results ......................................51 Table 4: Target Capital Structure Simulation Results .................................................... 52 Table 5: Simulation results of other debt and non-debt related variables .......................64 Table 6: Link between the target debt level and the cost of debt ....................................66 Table 7: Share-price sensitivity when all analysed variables are simulated....................66 6 Chapter 1. Introduction Companies constantly strive to maximise their share price, both through their investment choices and through their financing ones. This paper looks at the latter in an attempt to shed some light upon how the share price would be affected by changes in the capital structure of the firm. In their seminal work, Miller and Modigliani (1958) posit that in a perfect market, the capital structure of the company is irrelevant and therefore, has no influence on the value of the company. However, their theory was based on numerous and quite restrictive assumptions which make their conclusions work on paper more than off it. In the real world, markets are far from perfect, transaction costs exist, and there are agency costs of debt and equity. Those and other facts have somewhat cast a shadow on the capital structure irrelevance principle. If the capital structure actually does matter, then what would be the optimal debt-to-equity level? The static trade-off theory affirms that firms select their capital structure by systematically trading off the advantages of debt financing against its costs. The optimal capital structure is thus reached by choosing a debt level that maximises firm value. A cross-sectional study by Titman and Wessels, (1988) links debt levels to costs of financial distress and bankruptcy, but also acknowledges the influence of tax shields and the fact that debt reduces suboptimal investment. Overall, the results are found to be inconclusive. In a more recent paper, Chang et al., (2009) build on the research of Titman and Wessels, (1988) and, by improving the model, find statistically significant results for all the determinants. In spite of the aforementioned advantages, many large companies like Microsoft, Vestas, or a considerable number of pharmaceutical companies choose to keep their debt levels extremely low, a decision which is in conflict with the propositions of the static trade-off theory. The target adjustment model, a more dynamic one, posits that firms gradually adjust their capital structure towards a target level which shifts over time, being a function of various endogenous and exogenous factors. Clark et al., (2009) try to determine whether firms actually do adjust toward a target capital structure and, by studying 26,395 firms from 40 countries, they find evidence supporting the dynamic 7 trade-off theory for capital structure. They also study the speed of adjustment over their large sample of data and find differences between developed and developing countries. The company which is used to illustrate the effects of leverage on share price is Vestas. All throughout its history, Vestas has been known to have a low to very low debt-to-equity ratio. It might have been due to the desire to stay safe of default risks, which might have seemed high in this new „green” industry. Or it might have been due to the impossibility to access external funds at an acceptable cost for various reasons. However, the company has been growing steadily and is now looking to diversify its capital structure, slowly starting to take on more debt. On 15 March 2010, it announced the successful placing of a 600m Eurobond. The transaction was received very well by the European investors and the book was more than three times oversubscribed. How will adding more debt influence them? Does the type of debt which they chose to issue matter? 1.1. Problem Statement The present thesis takes a balance sheet approach to corporate valuation, studying how the share price is affected by changes in the structure of the statement of financial position. The aim of the paper is to analyse how changing the level of a company’s leverage from the current one to the optimal one might affect its overall share value. This paper will tackle the following issues: 1) Calculate the price of Vestas’ shares given the current level of debt (which includes the EUR 600 m Eurobond) by employing a plain vanilla valuation. 2) Determine the optimal capital structure under the static trade-off theory and calculate the new share price of Vestas under that capital structure. 3) Determine the optimal capital structure under the target adjustment model and calculate the new share price of Vestas under the hypothesised capital structure. A discussion of the adjustment speed from the viewpoint of the target adjustment model will also be undertaken. 8 4) Given that the optimal capital structure involves higher debt levels, discuss which type of debt would be most appropriate for Vestas by looking at possible advantages and disadvantages for Vestas and also by comparing the potential effects that the debt instruments might have on the cost of debt of the company. 5) Perform a sensitivity analysis of the share price. The main exogenous variable will be the level of debt. Simulation will be used to determine to which extent it affects the share price. Moreover, the sensitivity analysis will also look at different debt-related variables (cost of debt, marginal tax rate), as well as non debt-related variables that affect the cost of capital (the risk free rate and the return on the market portfolio). 1.2. Limitations Firstly, it should be mentioned that the valuation and the discussions in the paper are all undergone from the point of view of an external party that is not privy to inside information from Vestas. The analysis is solely based on public information from Vestas and various other external sources. The information taken into account is dated up until 1 September 2010. Therefore, any information – immaterial or material enough to possibly alter the valuation results - which was made public by the company or other sources after 1 September has not been considered. Moreover, in order to further limit the extent of the analysis, some issues which might otherwise affect the valuation or the effect of optimal capital structure on share prices have not been taken into consideration. These issues are as follows: personal taxes for debt and equity; the effect of inflation on tax gains from leverage; adjustment costs of changing the financing part of the balance sheet (changes are assumed to be costless); financial distress costs – the analysis does not look at what happens to the share price if the amount of leverage becomes higher than the optimum. 9 1.3. Methodology The valuation of Vestas is built upon information gathered from the company’s financial statements over the past 10 years, as well as various other sources, such as competitors’ financial statements, industry reports and reports on financial markets. A number of frameworks and models – both theoretical and empirical - have also been used in order to answer the issues at hand in this thesis. They are all briefly outlined below. Firstly, for the pre-valuation documentation, a strategic business analysis has been conducted by using frameworks such as PESTEL (Annex A2), competitor analysis (Annex A3) and Porter’s 5 forces (Annex A4). An internal analysis of the company is also performed (Annex A5). Thereafter, the most important facts have been summed up and presented as an overview in the SWOT analysis (Annex A6). Secondly, the valuation per-se employs two different methods that complement each other: the enterprise discounted cash flow method and the economic profit method. They provide the same result, but give different insights into the valuation. The reason for choosing these two frameworks is that they do not include the effects of the company’s capital structure in the valuation and focus solely on Vestas’ operating performance. Thirdly and lastly, the sensitivity of the share price to different debt levels will be analysed. To do this, the following steps will be undertaken: 1) Target debt levels will be calculated based on the insight provided by two capital structure theories: the static trade-off theory and the target adjustment or dynamic trade-off model. For the former theory, the model used is the one described by Chang et al., (2009), while for the latter, the model by Clark et al., (2009). 2) Given that the valuation is conducted from an outsider’s perspective, the target debt level is assumed to be a random variable with a normal distribution and a mean equal to the debt levels calculated in point 1. A simulation of possible debt target levels will be run. Because of the assumption that the company is a going concern, the simulation results will be limited to include only outcomes up to a certain level. Any higher outcome could potentially mean that the firm has entered financial distress, and therefore the going concern assumption would not be valid. Estimating 10 the results of financial distress is beyond the scope of this thesis, which is why simulation outcomes have been capped and are not allowed to be higher than a level considered adequate and beyond which financial distress costs seriously come into play. 3) The share price will be calculated. 4) After running an appropriate number of simulations and repeating steps 2-4, the mean and standard deviation of the share prices will be calculated. 1.4. Structure of the Thesis The thesis continues in the following manner: chapter 2 provides a literature review of capital structure theories and studies, chapter 3 tackles a business strategy analysis, the next section looks at Vestas’ historical performance, followed by the base case valuation in chapter 5 and the sensitivity analysis in chapter 6. Conclusions are presented in the last section – chapter 7. 11 Chapter 2. Overview of Capital Structure Theories Although vastly explored, the issue of capital structure is still largely not clarified. A plethora of studies have been trying to answer questions like „what influences the choice of capital structure and to which extent?”, but results have been either inconclusive or antithetical. Like in a Picasso painting, a multitude of shapes and colors seem to fit harmoniously with each other, but taken as a whole, they don’t make complete sense and the overall picture can be interpreted and re-interpreted in numerous ways. Different points of view representing different capital structure theories give birth to different interpretations of the Picasso painting and hence, different answers to the capital structure issues at hand. Modigliani and Miller, (1958) argue that capital structure is irrelevant under stringent conditions. However, reality cannot be bound within those conditions and therefore, with the acknowledgement of that fact, three major theories – trade-off theory, pecking order theory, market timing theory - have come to light, trying to explain the whats, whys and hows. This section starts off with an overview of studies trying to determine if capital structure does matter in real life and what effect it has on the valuation of a company. If capital structure does matter, how do we determine the optimal level of debt? Answers to this question are presented from the point of view of all three major theories, but the focus is cast on the trade-off theory, which is central to the sensitivity analysis part of the paper. 2.1. Does Capital Structure Matter? 2.1.1. The M&M Theories The first attempt to create a theory linking capital structure to firm value was undergone by Modigliani and Miller, (1958) and further reviewed and corrected in Modigliani and Miller, (1959) and Modigliani and Miller, (1963). Their Proposition I or „Irrelevance Proposition” states that „the average cost of capital to any firm is completely independent of its capital structure and is equal to a pure equity stream of its class”1. This proposition represents the cornerstone of modern corporate finance and also the basis for the static trade-off and the pecking order theories. 1 See Miller and Modigliani (1958), p. 268. 12 There are, in fact, two distinct kinds of irrelevance propositions. The first type is the result of market mechanisms acting against arbitrage opportunities, as developed by Stiglitz, (1969). He shows that the proposition holds true even under less stringent assumptions. The second type is connected to multiple equilibria, as primarily developed by Miller, (1977), who shows that the proposition holds even when assuming that interest payments are deductible in their entirety when calculating income taxes. Subsequent research has focused on dis-proving the theory by using arguments connected to tax advantages, financial distress costs, agency issues, transaction costs, adverse selection and other issues. Contrasting theories have been put forward. However, covering all the range of counter-arguments is not within the scope of the paper. A comprehensive overview of developments to the date of the study is provided by Harris and Raviv, (1991). 2.1.2. Subsequent Studies The conclusions drawn from later analyses on the effects of capital structure changes on firm value are somewhat diverging with respect to the irrelevance proposition. To this date, there is no generally-accepted black-or-white answer as to whether it does hold in real life or not. Pinegar and Lease, (1986) investigate the effect of corporate structure changes that do not have any tax-related impact, such as exchange from preferred to common stock. Their hypothesis is that these exchanges still have an impact on share value because of signaling or agency costs considerations. They find that the market value of equity increases after announcements of this kind. Therefore, the signaling hypothesis put forth by Leland and Pyle, (1977) is proven to influence the reaction of the market, even though the exchanges do not affect the tax status of the issuing company in any way. Eckbo, (1986) analyses 723 debt offerings and tries to determine what kind of effects they have on share prices. Theory predicts that increasing the level of debt would have a positive impact on the valuation of the company’s shares. However, his results do not support that affirmation. Regardless of whether straight or convertible debt is issued, no strong positive relation is found between the offerings and the returns on the market. Apart from a small subsample of public utility offerings, all other offerings analysed resulted in zero abnormal returns. However, a drawback in this type of study is that it does not account for whether the changes in capital structure are made on a short 13 or long term. Only the latter are postulated to have valuation effects, and thus, mixing the two categories might be the reason behind the inconclusive results. Similarly to Eckbo, (1986), Eldomiaty, (2002) categorises companies according to systematic risk levels, but only creates 3 groups: low, medium and high risk. His research presents two main findings: firstly, that firms seem to be exhibiting target capital behavior throughout all three risk groups and secondly, that long term – and not short term - debt and market value are positively related. He also analyses the effect of different other factors across the three groups and finds different outcomes within each group. The determinants that affect market values for all three risk groups are target debt ratio, liquidity position and interest rate. He concludes that capital structure has a more poignant effect if the risk level is higher. Muradoglu and Sivaprasad, (2006) take an investment approach to the issue and forecast abnormal returns for an investor on portfolios of debt for different classes of risk. They group 792 companies into 9 categories based on their 4-digit industry classification codes and further rank them according to how much debt they have outstanding. They then attempt to determine whether cumulative abnormal returns of the stock are related to the level of debt. The results from their analysis show that generally, abnormal returns decline when debt levels go down. They find that if leverage were used as a trading strategy and an investor were to invest in the lowest leverage firms with an average debt burden of 0.23%, the investor would be able to earn a cumulative abnormal return of 6.28% in one year’s time and a staggering 491% during the 24-year research period2. Carpentier, (2006) specifically looks at the long-run effects of changes in capital structure on firm value on the French market. Her paper is one of the first to actually suggest a direct test for the irrelevance proposition. She uses a sample of 243 French companies in a time period of 10 years between 1987 and 1996. She finds that both the increases and the decreases in debt levels are determining both positive and negative effects on firm value. Hence, she cannot reject Modigliani and Miller’s capital structure irrelevance proposition. Event study literature also touches upon the issue of market reactions to announcements of capital structure changes (i.e. announcements of equity or long-term debt). Spiess and Affleck-Graves, (1995), as well as Loughran and Ritter, (1995) find 2 See Muradoglu and Sivaprasad (2006), p. 17 14 negative reactions of 30% to 50% in the 5 years time-frame after the equity announcement. This is in line with the signaling argument stating that firms only issue equity if they know that their shares are overpriced. As a result of this fact, rational investors adjust their perceptions of the stock. By using more fine-tuned statistical tests for the 5-year time period following the announcement, Dichev and Piotroski, (1999) find that straight debt issues do not present mean abnormal returns. They also find that firms which issue convertible debt underperform the market by as much as 50% to 70% in the same time period, the percentage being proportional to the amount of debt issued. In several studies, Graham also finds that capital structure matters, by extensively researching marginal tax rates and the tax benefits of debt. In Graham, (1996a) and Graham, (1996b), he develops an innovative method of calculating marginal tax rates by using filed tax reports of companies. In Graham, (2000), he estimates the value that a company leaves on the table by being too conservative and not exercising the full benefits of debt and finds that the average firm could have as much as double the amount of debt before the marginal tax benefits begin to decline and they would be able to reap additional gross tax benefits of 15% of firm value. 2.2. The Trade-Off Theory The trade-off theory was born as a result of adding taxes to the irrelevance proposition in Modigliani and Miller, (1963). In this hypothetical instance of the world, where only taxes matter, there is a tax advantage that results from using debt, due to the fact that interest paid on debt is tax deductible. Therefore, firms have an incentive to use debt as a financing tool. But why don’t they use debt to entirely finance the company? In one of the classic articles of the trade-off literature - Kraus and Litzenberger, (1973) - the tax advantages of debt are offset by the costs of bankruptcy. In a statepreference framework, the firm either earns enough money to cover its debt obligations and thus, benefit from the tax advantages of debt, or cannot do so, therefore becoming insolvent and incurring bankruptcy penalties. The optimal capital structure is determined by finding the level of debt, such that the resulting division of states (i.e. those where the firm is solvent versus those where the firm is bankrupt) yields the maximum market value of the firm3. Furthermore, it is shown that the market value of a 3 See Kraus and Litzenberger (1973), p. 912. 15 levered firm is the unlevered market value, plus the corporate tax rate times the market value of the firm's debt, less the complement of the corporate tax rate multiplied by the present value of bankruptcy costs.4 The same trade-off is commented upon in the famous paper by Myers, (1984), “The Capital Structure Puzzle” and depicted in Figure 1. There are three elements brought into question by Myers, who focuses on issues that are often overlooked in literature. Firstly, he acknowledges Figure 1: The Static Trade-off Theory that the costs of adjustment might keep the company from being at the optimal level of debt. If these more than offset the advantages of using leverage, then the firms will postpone adjusting to optimal debt levels. However, these costs are rarely taken into consideration in models. Secondly, Myers discusses debt and taxes. He applauds the contribution of Miller Merton, (1977), who proves that personal income taxes play a role in determining the optimal debt level in a company. A taxable investor will not be interested in bonds if personal taxes on interest income from debt is under the rate of interest on bonds5. Myers brings forth the idea that Miller’s explanation hinges upon the marginal tax rate. Once one takes into account the fact that not all firms face the same marginal tax rate, the explanation crumbles. Lastly, Myers looks at the costs of financial distress, which include more than the classical bankruptcy costs. They include subtler issues such as agency, moral hazard, monitoring and contracting costs, which are more difficult to quantify – and usually are not quantified in models - , but still have an impact on capital structure.6 The trade-off theory can be divided into two strands of literature, one dealing with static trade-off models and the other with dynamic trade-off ones. The former postulates that firms cannot be anywhere but at the solution: the optimal level of debt. 4 See Kraus and Litzenberger (1973), p. 915. 5 See Miller (1977), p. 268. 6 See Myers (1984), p. 579-580. 16 The latter acknowledges that firms can move away from the target, because of disturbances, and they constantly adjust their debt levels to reach the optimal level. This last type of model allows for the possibility to calculate the speed of adjustment – how long it takes companies that have moved away from the target to get back to the optimal level. Thus, the model is also called the target-adjustment model. Frank and Goyal, (2007) provide two definitions pinpointing the two sub-types of theories7: „Definition 1. A firm is said to follow the static trade-off theory if the firm's leverage is determined by a single period trade-off between the tax benefits of debt and the deadweight costs of bankruptcy. Definition 2. A firm is said to exhibit target adjustment behavior if the firm has a target level of leverage and if deviations from that target are gradually removed over time.” 2.2.1. Determinants of Capital Structure Theoretical and empirical research has pointed out various factors that influence the optimal level of capital structure. A brief overview of studies is presented in the table on the next page, comprising both static and dynamic studies of capital structure. Determinants of capital structure are presented – along with the reasoning behind their influence -, in a non-exhaustive manner. Nor are the studies presented in the rightmost column the only ones which look at those specific determinants. The sign in between brackets documents how the determinant is supposed to affect capital structure (negatively or positively), based on theoretical reasoning. The results of the cross-sectional results are presented in the rightmost column. 7 See Frank and Goyal (2007), p. 7. 17 Table 1 – Determinants of Capital Structure Determinant (relation Reasoning Studies where it appears - refer to bibliography (relation to CS) found; model used: static (S) / dynamic (D)) Costs of financial High costs of financial distress (which might include bankruptcy costs and Bradley et al., (1984), (-; S). distress (-) Collateral agency costs of debt) are related to low debt levels. value of If assets can be used as collateral, the firm will prefer to issue debt secured with assets / Tangibility (+) Titman and Wessels, (1988), (insignificant; S); Rajan assets with known values, rather than to issue other types of securities that will and Zingales, (1995), (+; S); Flannery and Rangan, be undervalued because the market has less information. Costs of information (2006), (+; D); Chang et al., (2009), (-&+; S); Talberg asymmetry are thus avoided. et al., (2008), (+; S); Antoniou et al., (2008), (+; D); Byoun, (2008), (+; D); Clark et al., (2009), (insignificant, D). Non-debt tax shield (-) Firms with large non debt tax shields use less debt because the tax deductions Bradley et al., (1984), (-; S); Kim and Sorensen, (1986), that result from depreciation and investment tax credits replace the benefits of (-; S); Titman and Wessels, (1988), (insignificant; S); leverage. Flannery and Rangan, (2006), (insignificant; D); Antoniou et al., (2008), (+; D); Chang et al., (2009), (&+; S); Clark et al., (2009), (insignificant; D). Growth/Market-to- Growth opportunities are assets that cannot be collateralised and used to secure Myers, (1977), (-; S); Kim and Sorensen, (1986), (-; S); book ratio/ Investment debt. They are also connected to the suboptimal investment problem, because of opportunities (-) Titman and Wessels, (1988), (insignificant; S); Rajan the inclination of equity-controlled firms to expropriate wealth from and Zingales, (1995), (-; S); Flannery and Rangan, bondholders. The more growth opportunities the firm has, the more likely it is for (2006), (insignificant; D); Talberg et al., (2008), (-; S); it to engage in this behaviour, which poses an agency problem. Growth can be Antoniou et al., (2008), (-; D); Byoun, (2008), (-; D); measured by the market-to-book ratio. Firms tend to issue stocks if their market- Chang et al., (2009), (-&+; S); Clark et al., (2009), to-book ratio is high, so there will be less debt in that case. It is also considered a proxy for investment opportunities. 18 (insignificant; D). Uniqueness (-) If a company that sells a unique good or service goes bankrupt, its customers, Titman and Wessels, (1988), (-; S); Chang et al., (2009), employees and suppliers will suffer high costs. These firms would keep their (-; S). debt levels low in order to prevent liquidation. Industry classification Debt levels vary by industry. For example, debt levels are low for firms in Titman and Wessels, (1988), (significant; S); Bradley et (+/-) industries with products requiring customized spare parts and servicing (and for al., (1984), (significant; S); Flannery and Rangan, which liquidation is costly). (2006), (significant; D); Byoun, (2008), (+, D); Chang et al., (2009), (significant; S). Size / Diversification Large companies have a lower cost of debt and lower bankruptcy costs, so they Titman and Wessels, (1988), (-; S); Kim and Sorensen, (+) have an incentive to use more debt. Moreover, the more diversified a company is, (1986), (insignificant; S); Rajan and Zingales, (1995), the higher its debt capacity will be, since it can borrow at more favourable terms. (+; S); Talberg et al., (2008), (-; S); Clark et al., (2009), (+; D). Volatility / Operating If a company’s earnings are very volatile, it would be excessively risky for them Bradley et al., (1984), (-; S); Kim and Sorensen, (1986), risk (-) to hold a lot of debt. Operating risk might be one reason for high earnings (+; S); Titman and Wessels, (1988), (insignificant; S); volatility. A company that has a high level of operating risk may not be able to Antoniou et al., (2008), (insignificant; D); Chang et al., sustain high financial risk at the same time and will prefer to keep debt levels (2009), (-&+; S). low. Profitability (-) If a company can generate funds internally, it has a smaller financing deficit and Titman and Wessels, (1988), (insignificant; S); Rajan will use less debt. and Zingales, (1995), (-; S); Flannery and Rangan, (2006), (-; D); Talberg et al., (2008), (-; S); Antoniou et al., (2008), (-; D); Byoun, (2008), (-; D); Chang et al., (2009), (-&+; S); Clark et al., (2009), (insignificant; D). Tax rate: marginal or A high effective tax rate would prompt companies to use more debt, in order to Kim and Sorensen, (1986), (-; S); Antoniou et al., effective (+) (2008), (+; D); Byoun, (2008), (-; D). fully reap the advantages of the debt tax shields. 19 2.2.2. The Static Trade-Off Model A textbook static trade-off model is presented by Bradley et al., (1984), who use cross-sectional, firm specific data to test for the existence of an optimal level of debt. They find that debt ratios are inversely related to costs of financial distress, (which take into account bankruptcy and agency costs), to the level of non-debt tax shields, and to the variability of firm value (if the costs of financial distress are significant). They also find that industry dummy variables explain 54% of the variation in leverage ratios. Kim and Sorensen, (1986), test the effect of business risk, growth rate and the size of the firm on leverage ratios. Their findings show that high growth firms use less debt, high risk firms use more debt, and firm size is uncorrelated. Similarly to Myers, (1977), these effects are opposite to what theory might suggest. The study also examines the impact of agency costs by classifying the 168 firms in two equal groups: one of companies with a high and another with a low degree of inside ownership. Tests prove that a higher degree of ownership does in fact translate into a higher degree of debt, and therefore agency costs are important in determining the optimal capital structure. Several explanations based on agency costs are provided. The agency costs of equity explanation states that firms with heavy insider ownership would prefer to use debt in order to avoid the costs of equity that result from consuming perquisites. The agency costs of debt explanation states that firms with high inside ownership have a lower agency cost of debt, which is why lenders might prefer to lend to them. High inside ownership imposes closer control, and therefore, standard provisions and covenants are more effective. Moreover, creditors might regard high inside ownership firms as more likely to negotiate suboptimal investment issues8. Titman and Wessels, (1988), analyse the theoretical determinants of capital structure by employing different measures of long/short-term or convertible debt instead of a single aggregate one. They focus on 8 determinants: the collateral value of assets, non-debt tax shields, growth, uniqueness of the line of business, industry classification, size, volatility and profitability, but find overall inconclusive results. However, they do report some interesting findings which are in line with real life practices. They find that debt levels are inversely related to uniqueness because firms that can impose high costs 8 See Kim and Sorensen (1986), p. 141. 20 on their customers, employees and suppliers in case of liquidation have less leverage 9. They also find that short term ratios are negatively related to firm size, a result that stems from the practice of small companies of not issuing long term debt because of the high costs they would have to incur. All the other determinants have an insignificant effect on capital structure. In a more recent work, Chang et al., (2009) expand on Titman and Wessel’s model and find statistically significant results for all the determinants. However, they have excluded size from their model, invoking goodnessof-fit criteria. 2.2.3. The Dynamic Trade-Off Model 2.2.3.1. Development of the Theory This strand of theory presents multiple variations by focusing on various elements. Some dynamic trade off research develops partial adjustment models which include a large part of the determinants presented in Table 1 (Flannery and Rangan, (2006); Byoun, (2008); Clark et al., (2009) – the results are also presented in the table). Other papers have a more specific focus: Kane et al., (1984) on taxes; Harris and Raviv, (1990) on the informational role of debt; Zwiebel, (1996) on managerial entrenchment; Liu, (2009) on the historical market-to-book ratio; and Goldstein et al., (2010) on EBIT. The first models developed did not include transaction costs. Brennan and Schwartz, (1984) build an equilibrium variation model for a hypothetical firm for which both the investment policy and the financing policy are endogenously decided upon. The feasibility set for the decisions is determined by the investment opportunities, the capital market equilibrium, as well as the bond indentures that the company is restricted by. The analysis brings to light three main issues that impact upon the financing decision and the optimal amount of leverage. These are the design of the bond indenture, the initial capital structure, and the choice of capital structure given the current debt levels of the company. Kane et al., (1984) have a different approach and look at the traditional tax advantages-bankruptcy costs trade off in an options valuation model that incorporates bankruptcy costs and corporate, as well as personal taxes. Their simulation analysis points out that if the tax advantage is small, then the cost of being very far away from the optimum is small as well. This result is in line with the observed wide range of debt levels that companies have. Kane et al. also acknowledge that there 9 See Titman and Wessels (1988), p. 17. 21 might be other considerations driving debt levels (like agency costs or moral hazard) that they have not looked at. These models predict somewhat higher target debt levels because, since transaction costs are inexistent, there is nothing in the way of firms adjusting to the optimal debt levels and reaping the full advantages of debt. Fischer et al., (1989) develop the model of Kane et al., (1984) and include transaction costs in a dynamic model where capital structure depends on a set of firmspecific characteristics. Their model gives rise to a hypothesis about the type of firms that go through a wide range of debt levels. These firms have a low effective corporate tax rate, a high variance of underlying asset value, a small asset base (i.e. they are small companies) and low bankruptcy costs10. One of the more recent researches including transaction costs is the model of Hennessy and Whited, (2005). They attempt to shed some light on the facts that had remained unexplained to that date by the static trade-off models, for example the inverse relation between profitability and size on the one hand and debt levels on the other. Like in Brennan and Schwartz, (1984), their investment and financing decisions are endogenous, but in the current case, the decisions are joint. The model also comprises graduate income taxes, personal taxes on interest income and on dividends, financial distress costs, as well as equity flotation costs. They find that there is no target leverage. Furthermore, they prove that past debt levels affect current ones. Apart from path dependency, leverage also presents hysteresis (i.e. the effects of a current decision are made apparent with a certain delay in time). Another piece of research on path dependency which points out that historical market-to-book ratios affect current ones is by Liu, (2009). Results show that there is a partial adjustment model at work and there are strong relations between past market-to-book ratios and current debt levels. A strand of literature looks away from firm-specific characteristics and tries to provide explanations for the level of debt based on other factors. Harris and Raviv, (1990) propose a model based on the signaling and the disciplining role of debt. The signaling argument states that investors “read” the signals of the firm and eliminate uncertainty about the quality of the firm. The disciplining argument states that debt can be used as an instrument which exerts pressure on managers to perform efficiently and prevents them from empire building. This is accomplished through the fact that debt gives creditors the opportunity to compel the firm to go into liquidation. The trade-off 10 See Fischer et al. (1989), p. 33. 22 between these advantages and disadvantages leads to an optimal capital structure. However, if applied in practice, the model possesses some drawbacks related to difficulties in analysing the “signals” and learning from them. Zwiebel, (1996) analyses the dynamics of capital structure and takes an agency costs approach by looking at debt under managerial entrenchment. His model also plays upon the disciplining role of debt, like in Harris and Raviv, (1990). The difference is that here, the manager himself chooses to use debt as a commitment device to forgo value-decreasing investments and through that, preventing potential take-over’s. The cost that balances the aforementioned benefit is that too much debt makes its effects less stringent and managers might still chose to undertake empire-building projects. The authors outline numerous various implications of the model which are in line with the classical free cash flow models (for example, that growth opportunities and profitability are negatively related to debt levels), as well as some that differentiate their model from free cash flow models (for example, a strong point of this model is that the benefits and costs that are traded off have the same source: the use of debt as manager’s commitment to be efficient). Antoniou et al., (2008) analyse the determinants of capital structure in different settings: capital market - oriented economies (UK and US) and bank-oriented ones (Germany, France and Japan). The results related to firm characteristics and leverage based on the entire sample are presented in Table 1. Moreover, they conclude that the characteristics of the legal system and the market conditions affect leverage levels. A higher rule of law pushes firms to keep their debt levels at a low. In markets where bank – ownership is accustomed, debt levels are higher because the company can be rescued in case of bankruptcy by the shareholding bank. Of the most recent studies, Sabiwalsky, (2010) proposes a nonlinear model based on the classic tax shields - bankruptcy costs trade-off; here, the target debt level is not static, but changing and chosen such as to maximise the difference between the debt tax shield and the costs of insolvency. He finds that size is a major determinant of the explanatory power of the model (24%, 16% and respectively 11% of the variation of debt adjustments of medium, small and large samples). Thus, he concludes that the trade-off model explains the choices of medium sized firms best. 23 2.2.3.2. Results on the Adjustment Speed Jalilvand and Harris, (1984) analyse a sample of US firms and their financing decisions in order to determine what variables influence the firms’ adjustment speeds. They find that size, interest rate and stock price levels all have significant effects. Sjoo, (1996) finds that the most influencing macroeconomic variables on the Swedish market are adjustment processes of domestic price levels, interest rates and export prices. Drobetz and Wanzenried, (2006) use a sample of 90 Swiss firms and find that size is inversely related to adjustment speed, while the availability of economic prospects and term spread are positively related. With regard to the speed of adjustment itself, research has failed to come to a common conclusion. Earlier research, as well as conventional wisdom predicts adjustment speeds between 8% and 15%11. Later studies prognosticate somewhat higher speeds. Huang and Ritter, (2009) find speeds of 17% per year for book leverage (closing the gap in 3.7 years) and 23.2% for market leverage (closing the gap in 2.6 years). Flannery and Rangan, (2006) find that an average firm closes in to its target with around one third of the difference each year. Byoun, (2008) splits firms into 4 different categories, according to whether they have a financial deficit or surplus and if they are above or below target levels. The group with the highest adjustment speed is the financial surplus – above target (30%), followed by financial deficit – below target (20%), financial surplus – below target (5%) and finally financial deficit – above target (2%). Antoniou et al., (2008) investigate market-oriented versus bank-oriented economies. Their results point out that French firms are fastest to adjust, followed by firms in the US, UK, Germany and Japan. Clark et al., (2009) compare the adjustment speed between developed and developing countries and find that in the former, speed is independent of legal and institutional factors, while in the latter, it is the reverse, with tax variables being highly significant. As expected, firms adjust slower in developing countries. The mean around the world is 30.5%, and varies between 17% and 44.1%. Similarly, Cook and Tang, (2010) examine the relations between macroeconomic conditions and capital structure adjustment speed and find comparable results with Clark. Better macroeconomic conditions relate to higher speeds. 11 See Flannery and Rangan (2005), p. 481. 24 2.3. The Pecking Order Theory The pecking order theory was born out of the desire to answer some questions that the trade-off theory couldn’t, for example, why it is that in reality large firms use less debt than predicted. The basic reasoning behind the pecking order theory is summed up in either of the following terms, depending on which explanation of firm behavior we choose to buy: “information asymmetry”, developed by Myers and Majluf, (1984), or “agency costs”, developed by Jensen, (1986). When looking to finance projects, firms follow a pecking order: they prefer internal to external financing and debt to equity if they must use external sources. In a pre-pecking order article, Stiglitz, (1973) reaches the same conclusion of financing sources preference based on tax arguments. He takes into account corporate taxes and personal taxes on interest and dividends. Does the pecking order theory actually relate to what happens in the corporate world? Shyam-Sunder and Myers, (1999) tested the pecking order theory against a static trade-off model and found that the former has much more explanatory power of the time-series variation of debt ratios. Conversely, Frank and Goyal, (2003) pinpointed that, “net equity issues track the financing deficit more closely than do net debt issues”12; this contradicts the pecking order theory, indicating that it does not entirely explain corporate behavior. 2.3.1. Information Asymmetry Considerations The argument of Myers and Majluf, (1984) and Myers, (1984), states that firms have more information regarding their operations and worth than outside investors have. This is why, whenever firms are in need of funds, they exhibit a preference for internal funds, and when using external funds, they prefer to issue debt rather than equity, for fear that their shares will be underpriced by the less knowledgeable market. Sometimes, they might even prefer not to take positive-NPV investments, should these be financed with equity. Heaton, (2002) underpins the term “managerial optimism” as being the behavior of managers who believe their firm is undervalued. They use a simple model trading off the benefits of refraining from undertaking bad investments because of the high perceived cost of financing and the costs of passing up positive-NPV projects for 12 See Frank and Goyal (2003), p.217. 25 the same reason. They point out that managers who behave that way follow a pecking order. However, the difference between the benefits and costs tends to vary by firm. In order to overcome information asymmetry barriers, firms use signaling to let the investors know the true value of their shares (Leland and Pyle, (1977)). Cadsby et al., (1990) demonstrated with the use of game theory – a Nash equilibrium model – that good firms will always use signals when these are available, with the intention to distinguish themselves in the eyes of the investors. 2.3.2 Agency Costs Considerations Jensen, (1986), comments upon the fact that the use of debt minimizes agency costs related to managers. The managers are assumed to act in their own best interests, which may not coincide with those of the shareholders. If a company produces a substantial amount of free cash flow (cash flow over the amount required to fund the entire array of positive NPV projects), conflicts might arise between shareholders and managers as to the payout methods of the free cash flow. Shareholders will prefer dividends, but managers might want to use the funds for empire building or over-using perks. By using debt, managers commit to making periodic payouts, thus limiting squandering of company funds. Jensen also states that debt is better than announcing a permanent increase in dividends, because the latter is not binding and it can always be undone by managers. 2.4. Market Timing Theory Baker and Wurgler, (2002) document companies’ habit to time the market when attempting to raise funds. Firms decide whether to issue stocks or debt based on the market-to-book ratio. If the market-to-book ratio is high (i.e. shares are overvalued), companies will prefer to issue stock and thus, raise funds in a cheap way. Otherwise, they will use debt. Therefore, firms’ current capital structure is a result of past decisions and efforts to time the market. Baker and Wurgler’s main finding is that low leverage firms are those which issued shares when their market-to-book was high, while high leverage firms are those which issued debt when their market-to-book were low. Kayhan and Titman, (2007) also examine the relation between firms’ histories and their current capital structure and find that past returns on the stock market explain current debt levels. Their results show that firms reduce their leverage if they raise 26 capital in years when stock prices are high. Moreover, firms appear to be more likely to issue stock after an increase in prices on the equity capital market. 27 Chapter 3. Business Strategy Analysis 3.1. External Analysis Vestas is competing in the wind turbine manufacturing industry. One way to define this industry could be as the one “dealing with the research and development, manufacture, construction, sale, and maintenance of wind turbines for residential, commercial or industrial purposes”. The modern wind industry is only about 3 decades old. Over the years, it has grown considerably, with record double-digit growth rates sometimes going close to 50% per year, as was the case in 2008-2009. At the end of 2009, the cumulative market size had reached a total of 158,505 installed MW worldwide13. As for the future, industry growth rates are expected to increase in the next 5 years, but at a slower pace, as quantified by The Global Wind Energy Council (GWEC)14. The annual installed capacity growth for 2010 is only expected to amount to 6.6%, considerably less if compared to 41.3% in 2009. The annual installed capacity will slowly rise with each year, while the growth of cumulative installed capacity is characterized by a decreasing trend. GWEC has estimated the growth of the world’s cumulative installed wind power capacity under three different Figure 2: Degree of scenarios. In the most pessimistic Turbulence – scenario the reference one – in the Industry production of energy from the installed capacity will cover 4.9 – 5.6% of the world’s total energy demand by 2030. Under the two more optimistic scenarios – moderate and advanced – wind energy will cover 15 - 17.5% and 18.8 - 21.8%, respectively. Source: collected information 13 See 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council. p. 12. 14 See 34) Ibid., p. 17. 28 The PESTEL analysis provides a picture of the degree of turbulence in the industry, depicted in Figure 2 on the previous page. The political, legal and economic factors are the ones with the highest impact, while technological factors have a mediumstrength effect. Socio-cultural and environmental issues come last in terms of ramifications. For details, see Annex A1. Market Definition, Size and Growth, as well as Annex A2. PESTEL Analysis. Figure 3: Porter’s 5 Forces 3.2. Porter’s 5 Forces Model A more in depth analysis of the 5 forces affecting the industry, as well as a discussion of the general degree of turbulence in the industry is presented in Annex A4. 3.3. Competitor analysis At the moment, there are a total of 52 wind turbine manufacturers worldwide. Source: collected information Competition within the industry is quite fierce, with the top 10 companies having 78.7% market share and each being very close to the other in terms of market share. Vestas is the world’s leading manufacturer, with a 12.5% share, surpassing the second runner up - GE Wind Energy - by only 0.1%. The most considerable ascension of 2009 was the growth of the Chinese manufacturers, 3 of which made it in the top 10 for the first time. The two most notable trends in the market are the gradual shift from oligopolistic towards monopolistic competition and the rise of the Chinese manufacturing companies, detailed in Annex A3. Competitor Analysis. 3.4. Internal Analysis This section is a summary of the more extensive analysis in Annex A5. Internal Analysis. 3.4.1. Strategy statements Vestas’ strategy statements are as follows: 29 vision – “Wind, oil and gas”; mission – “Failure is not an option”; strategy – “Number 1 in modern energy”; values / principles – “Cost of energy”, “Business case certainty”, “Easy to work with”. Vestas has proven that they are sticking to their vision and mission. Throughout time, they have shown their resilience. Despite the financial crisis that brought despair to many industries, Vestas managed to achieve record revenue and EBIT (revenue was 9.96% higher than the previous year, while EBIT was 28.14% higher). Another example of their determination is the fact that they invested EUR 160m in building a tower plant in Colorado, US. They proved to be committed to the US market, even though they did not receive any order on the US market that year15. The strategy of the company explains how they aim to accomplish their vision. In this sense, Vestas wants to be “Number 1 in modern energy”, not only in terms of market share, but also in terms of safety standards, performance of power plants, customer satisfaction and green production. So far, they have managed to achieve that. 3.4.2. Product and Service Mix Vestas produces 9 types of onshore turbines ranging from 850 kW to 3 MW and 2 types of offshore ones, both with a nameplate capacity of 3 MW. The company is currently developing a 6MW offshore turbine As for the company’s service mix, Vestas has the following areas of focus: installation, maintenance and repair. The main support functions that enable it to serve customers are the Performance & Diagnostics Centre and the Vestas Spare Parts & Repair. Vestas expects the same growth for the demand of its services, as for its products. 3.4.3. Business segments Vestas is operating in 3 geographic segments covering the entire world (Europe, Americas and Asia/Pacific). The company has production plants, sales and 15 Information retrieved from Ditlev Engel interview: 77) Rose, C. 2010. Ditlev Engel on Charlie Rose. New York. 30 service units and R&D functions in all of them. As expected, Europe is the largest, both in Figure 4: Vestas’ Revenue terms of revenue, and in terms of number of people employed. Historically, Vestas has had a more than steady revenue stream, and has always managed to improve its yearly sales figures. It registered a record growth rate of 55% in 2004. At the other extreme was the growth 2006, which amounted to only 7.6%. Figure 4 depicts Source: data from financial reports revenue evolution from 2001 to 2009. 3.5. SWOT Analysis This section presents the SWOT analysis for Vestas, based on the previously presented information. Figure 5 depicted on the next page sums up the analysis, which is presented in full in Annex A6. SWOT Analysis. 31 Figure 5: SWOT Analysis Source: collected information 32 Chapter 4. Analysing Historical Performance 4.1. Reorganisation of Financial Statements Vestas’ historical financial statements from 2000 and up to 2009, inclusively, have been reorganized for valuation purposes and the effects of non-operating accounts have been singled out and separated from operating ones, since only the latter are useful in order to calculate the worth of the company through this valuation model. 4.1.1. Treatment of Accounts, Assumptions and Estimations There are some issues that are worth highlighting before going deeper into the historical analysis. Firstly, a mention of the changes in reporting of financial statements should be given attention to. In 2000, Vestas went through a share split. Hence, the valuation spreadsheet presents the figures adjusted for the split. What’s more, there was a transition from GAAP to IFRS which took place in 2005. This entailed changing the treatment of goodwill related to business combinations, which was previously amortised, changing income-recognition criteria and the treatment of prepaid service, reclassifying deferred tax assets as non-current assets, and lastly, recognising deferred tax liabilities, pensions and similar liabilities in current and non-current liabilities instead of provisions. Secondly, since holding large cash reserves does not bring the company high returns, operating cash was assumed to be no higher than 2% of operating revenues. The extra amount was deemed excess marketable securities. The amount was not considered in valuing the company operations and was added back after the operating value was calculated. Thirdly, taxes are an issue that was given consideration due to the international scope of the company. The marginal tax rate is not explicit and has to be calculated. In attempting to estimate the company’s marginal tax rate, certain assumptions had to be enforced due to insufficient information and the use of proxies has been resorted to. Graham, (1996b) looks at the most appropriate proxies for this rate. His research shows that the best proxy is a simulated tax rate that he develops. Unfortunately, it is beyond our ability to calculate it, because it uses information from tax filings, which we do not have access to. The second best would be a trichotomous 33 variable equal to the top statutory rate if both taxable income and net operating loss carryforwards are positive; half of the top statutory rate if either is positive and the other is 0 and 0 otherwise. We have chosen to start from there and make a few necessary adjustments. Previous to the group reorganization from 2004, Vestas had subsidiaries in 9 different countries, as well as minority interest of 49% in an Indian associate company. Thus, their revenues were taxed at different rates. Damodaran, (1994) states that the appropriate marginal tax rate for companies which operate in multiple tax locales is the average of the different marginal tax rates, weighted by the operating income of each locale. His suggestion was also taken into account. Given all the arguments presented above, the marginal tax rate for 2000 – 3003 was a trichotomous variable equal to: if both taxable income and net operating loss carryforwards - the average of the statutory tax rates of the countries where subsidiaries were set up, weighted by operating income of each; if either taxable income or net operating loss carryforwards are zero and the other is positive – half of the aforementioned average; 0, otherwise. In the event that the company had sales in a country where no subsidiary was established and no information regarding where the revenue was registered, an additional assumption was taken on. All sales in Europe (excluding the Nordic Region) were taxed in Germany, all those in the Americas was taxed in the US, all those in Asia/Pacific were taxed by the Indian associate company, and the rest in Denmark. Starting from 2004, the Vestas Group was reorganized in business units focusing on sales or production and therefore, all income is taxed in Denmark. With this in mind, the Danish statutory tax rate was used instead of the weighted average from above. The choices presented above are completely arbitrary and thus, to compensate for the assumptions taken on, the issue has been subjected to simulation in Section 6.3. in order to analyse the sensitivity of the share price to the marginal tax rate. Vestas disclosed that it had both defined benefit and defined contribution pension plans. Since only the former are relevant for valuation purposes, we looked into whether Vestas recorded any plan assets or liabilities. The company’s pension-related 34 liabilities were larger than plan assets, which is why Vestas recorded a retirement – related liability of EUR 2 mil. The amount was subtracted from the value of operations in order to find equity value. Vestas disclosed deferred tax assets of EUR 110 mil, which was treated as an equity equivalent, meaning that NOPLAT has been adjusted to account for the yearly change in the account and investor funds were also reconciliated by adding the same amount. Based on information from the footnotes in the annual reports, Vestas’ provisions have been split into income smoothing provisions and warranties provisions. The former fall into the category of equity equivalents and are treated similarly to deferred taxes, while the latter are treated as other non-interest-bearing liabilities. The amounts are subtracted from revenues to compute EBITA and the associated reserve is netted against operating assets. Operating leases were valued based on the rental expense, using the following formula: 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡 𝑣𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒𝑡−1 = 𝑅𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑎𝑙 𝑒𝑥𝑝𝑒𝑛𝑠𝑒𝑡 1 𝑘𝑑 + 𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡 𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒 Rental expense on operating leases is only disclosed starting from 2005, when Vestas adopted the IFRS. For the first 5 years of the historical analysis, rental expenses have been estimated using Prof. Damodaran’s spreadsheet (Damodaran, (2007)). Thus, operating leases totaled EUR 636 mil at the end of 2009. In the valuation spreadsheet, the value of leases is subtracted from net PPE and added back later on to determine Invested Capital. Finally, employee stock options were valued using Black – Scholes, but, given the very large difference between the high strike price and the current low spot price of the shares, the total value of the options does not have a great impact on the valuation end result. The inputs into the calculation are based on information presented in the 2009 annual report under share-based incentive programme for 2007 to 2009 and for 2010 to 201216. 16 See 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S., p. 34 35 4.1.2. Results of Reorganisation Invested Capital increased more than tenfold over the 10 year period, from EUR 416 mil to EUR 4,611 mil, as can be observed in Annex A6.1. Invested Capital. As suspected, the largest proportion is attributed to investments in property, plant and equipment materialized in production facilities, followed by goodwill and intangibles. The evolution of NOPLAT - total income generated from operations available to Vestas’ investors - is depicted in Annex A6.2. NOPLAT. The company had a negative NOPLAT in 2004 and 2005, when it recorded losses; yet, having gotten back on track, it managed to improve its NOPLAT considerably up to a total of EUR 767 mil in 2009, compared to EUR 188 mil from the beginning of the historical period. As Vestas is currently in the growth stage of its life-cycle, it reinvests its cash flow back into the company in order to fuel growth, which can be clearly observed in the results of the free cash flow calculation, shown in Annex A6.3. Free Cash Flow. With the exception of the year 2005, the company’s gross cash flow is always positive and mostly offset by the increases in working capital and operating leases, as well as capital expenditures. ROIC Figure 6: ROIC Tree 31.6% Pre-tax ROIC Cash tax rate 44% 28.2% Operating margin Average capital turns 16.1% 2.73 Gross margin Operating working capital/Revenue 23.6% 14% SGA expenses Fixed assets / Revenue -6.8% 18.8% Depreciation / Revenue Other assets / Revenue -2.4% 3.8% Other operating expenses / Revenue -0.6% Other adjustments / Revenue Source: author’s calculations 2.3% Return on Invested Capital is detailed in Annex A6.4. Return on Invested Capital. In order to put the figures into perspective and find out what the drivers of this return are, the ROIC tree depicted in Figure 6 was developed, with ratios computed for 36 the last year of the historical analysis period. The tree unveils the fact that the impetus for Vestas’ ROIC is primarily given by the level of optimization and capital efficiency, portrayed by the high average capital turns. A turnover of 2.71 means that with EUR 1 invested in working capital, the company managed to generate EUR 2.71 in revenue. Revenue growth is also an important input of the valuation. Historically, it has been fluctuating greatly from one year to the next, with no clear trend pointing in a certain direction. The largest change was in 2004, when Vestas had a 55% revenue growth, whereas 2 years later, the smallest growth rate was recorded, a modest 7.6%. The evolution over the historical period is shown in Annex A6.5. Revenue Growth. 4.2. Credit Health We have already posited that Vestas uses little debt. Just exactly how little is highlighted by calculating interest coverage. Interest coverage ratings were calculated relative to EBIT, EBITDA and EBITDAR, the last of which takes into account rental expenses for operating leases from the financial report footnotes. All ratios have reached a peak value in 2008 (16.7, 20.1, and 20.6 respectively) and fell briskly the following year mainly because of the growth in rental expenses which was at a much greater pace than the growth in EBIT. The results are portrayed in Annex A7. Interest Coverage. Vestas’ debt is not rated. However, with the help of Prof. Damodaran’s spreadsheet (Damodaran, (2007)), synthetic ratings estimations were performed. The results were situated between D (in 2003 and 2004, because of a red bottom line) and AAA (maintained over the past 3 years). 4.3. Stock Market Performance Since the hypothesis investigated in the Figure 7: Stock Market Performance thesis links debt levels with share prices, it might be insightful to look at historical share prices. Figure 5 depicts 3 different measures of Total Return to Shareholders. A comparison to the other 3 major competitors mentioned in Chapter 3. Competitor Analysis is not possible, since GE Wind Energy is part of the multinational conglomerate GE which makes Source: author’s calculations 37 available share prices irrelevant for comparison. As for Sinovel and Enercom, they are not traded on the stock market. However, 3 other listed competitors in the top 10 were included: REPower, Gamesa and Suzlon. Siemens was not taken into account because as a group, it is very diversified and the figures would be indicative of the entire group and not of Siemens Wind Power itself. Over the past 5 years, Vestas has greatly exceeded shareholder’s expectations. It performs best compared to the other companies, for the entire period. During the 5 years, the company’s book debt-to-value ratio decreased from 33% to 9.1%. It seems that, contrary to M&M’s theory, market value in this case was inversely proportional to debt levels. The only thing that could explain this relationship and still be in accordance with theory would be that Vestas’ target debt level is low and somewhere around the current levels. This shall be further investigated in Chapter 6 – Sensitivity Analysis. 38 Chapter 5. Base case scenario valuation 5.1. Scenario description The base case scenario represents the foundation of the valuation and of the simulation analysis, as this is the point from which the investigation will develop. In this scenario, the industry is assumed to grow at a moderate pace and there will be no shocks which might affect its development. Current regulations and policies will still be in place and will continue to propel the industry forward. Incumbents will continue to receive subsidies and tax credits. Imposed country-specific renewable energy targets are also assumed to be successfully implemented. In time, the industry’s characteristics will gradually start shifting towards those of a maturing trade. Increased competition will drive prices and market shares downwards. This is expected, given the current competition trends within the industry (Annex A3.2. Competition Trends). Vestas’ financial position will have a slight drop in 2010, but will stabilize thereafter. The reason for the drop is mostly represented by a decline in income, as detailed in the first and second quarter reports of 2010. Major expected orders from several countries did not materialize yet and will be recognized as income during 201117. 5.2. Forecasting performance 5.2.1. Revenue growth As we have seen when comparing the evolution of revenue growth in time with that of major macroeconomic factors in Annex A2.2. Economic Factors, there is a weak correlation between them. One reason behind that might be the fact that the industry is still in a growing stage and it is fuelled by numerous factors, like the global concern for a sustainable future and the political environment. Moreover, the fact that Vestas was one of the pioneers in the field gave the company a competitive advantage. Therefore, when forecasting future rates, we have chosen to base our assumptions on past performance of the company, more than on external factors. What’s more, Vestas’ own 17 See 95) Vestas 2010b. Interim Financial Report, Second Quarter 2010. Randers: Vestas., p. 1 39 expectations for 2010, as presented in the Management Report of the previous year18, as well as the first two interim financial reports of 2010 are also taken into account. The last annual report mentions a revenue of EUR 7 bil in 2010, but expectations have been adjusted downward due to sales which failed to materialise. As for 2011 revenues, these are expected to be of record amount, since the firm and unconditional order intake in the first half of 2010 totals 4289 MW19, almost as much as in 2009 as a whole (4759 MW). Thus, revenue growth rates start off at -9%, are expected to peak at 55% in 2011 and then start dwindling, finally reaching a level of 6% for the continuing value period. The reason for the decline can partly be attributed to the aforementioned industry changes and partly to the fact that Vestas does not rely mostly on serving its home country market, as major competitors are doing. Vestas sold only 57 MW in Denmark over the whole of 2009, compared to 3569 MW sold by GE Wind Energy in the US 20. Therefore, in time, Vestas will find itself in a slight disadvantageous position because of the fact that it’s playing an away game. 5.2.2. Cost of capital In order to estimate the cost of capital, the weighted average formula was used: Vestas’ debt is not traded, thus not rated. Without being able to rely on the market for information regarding yields to maturity, the cost of debt was approximated using Professor Damodaran’s estimation spreadsheet (Damodaran, (2007)). The inputs into the spreadsheet (level of debt, rental expense and interest expense) were the forecasts of 2014, the last year of the detailed forecast, and lead to a cost of debt of 3.65%. However, analysts opine that the yield-to-worst for Vestas Eurobonds is 4.37% (Andersen, (2010)). Since the 2009 debt level is of EUR 339 mil, and the debt levels have increased considerably after the bond issue, the estimated cost of debt was adjusted See the section „Outlook for 2010”, 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas 18 Wind Systems A/S., p. 27. 19 94) Vestas 2010a. Interim Financial Report, First Quarter 2010. Randers: Vestas.; 95) Vestas 2010b. Interim Financial Report, Second Quarter 2010. Randers: Vestas. 20 33) Glader, P. 2010. G.E. Leads U.S. Wind Market but Faces More Competition. Available: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303720604575170500339244626.html January 2011]. 40 [Accessed 27 upwards with 46 percentage points to 4.11%; this adjustment is the average of the yield to worst and the predicted cost of capital, weighted by the proportion of the Eurobond versus existing debt. The after-tax cost of debt was used in the valuation. A marginal tax rate of 25% was employed in the adjustment, as this is the expected statutory rate of Denmark for the foreseeable future (see Section 4.1.1. Treatment of Accounts, Assumptions and Estimations for the reasoning of this particular choice of rate). As for the cost of equity, the CAPM model was utilised: The proxy for the risk free rate was a 10 year government bond yield. Koller et al., (2005) suggest that the German Eurobond is the best choice when valuing European firms. Taking that suggestion into account, the risk free rate used equals 2.9%21. In order to estimate Vestas’ beta, a regression of the company’s stock returns on the S&P500 market index return was conducted: A period of 3 years of daily data was used, as recommended by Daves et al., (2000) and lead to a beta of 1.42, meaning that Vestas’ stock moves in the same direction as the market, but with more variation. This might explain the delayed effect of the financial crisis: in the midst of the crisis, revenues were growing steadily (as shown in Figure A8 – Capacity Growth and Macroeconomic Variables), while at present, when economies are recovering, the company is expecting low revenues. To account for the fact that betas are mean reverting, the Bloomberg Smoothing Mechanism was employed. The adjusted beta is: As for the return of the market portfolio, given that it cannot be estimated per se, a market index was used as a proxy. Koller et al., (2005) state that the most commonly used proxy is the S&P500. It is also the longest trading index. Since all the major indexes are highly correlated with each other, the S&P500 was deemed as an 21 6) Bloomberg. 2011. Government Bonds [Online]. http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/rates-bonds/government-bonds/germany/ 2011]. 41 Bloomberg. [Accessed Available: 6 January appropriate proxy. Monthly returns dating back to January 1950 were used. The arithmetic average was annualized and lead to an Rm of 8.47%. Therefore, the resulting market risk premium is of 5.57%, which is in line with Koller et al., (2005), who also perform some estimations and obtain a market risk premium of 5.5%. The company’s capital structure also influences its cost of capital. Koller et al., (2005) opine that target debt levels should be used in the forecast. Since historical debt levels have been fluctuating greatly, no inferences were based on previous debt levels. In order to determine the target, we have firstly taken into account the declaration of the company’s management: „The proportion of equity in relation to the Group's future capital structure is expected to continue to be high”22. After including the EUR 600 mil Eurobond, the debt levels increased to 24.52%. This is considered to be the target level of debt. Book levels were employed in calculations, since the debt is not traded and since the company does not find itself in a position of financial distress. However, it should be acknowledged that the current level of interest rates might cause differences between the market and book values of debt. After factoring in off-balance sheet debt – the value of operating leases – the debt target decreases to 17.05%. After plugging in all the estimations, the resulting cost of capital for the forecast period equals 8.3%. 5.2.3. Other inputs As far as the other rates and inputs are concerned, the reasoning behind them starts off by taking into account company expectations for 2010, which are rather unflattering for Vestas. Their evolution in time loosely follows a curved shape, where they improve, stagnate shortly and thereafter slightly worsen. The guidelines provided by annual reports for the year 2010 include: - an EBIT margin of 5-6%; - a NWC of 15% of annual revenue at year-end; - investments in net property, plant and equipment of EUR 250 mil; - investments in intangible assets of EUR 350 mil; - a fall in warranty provisions of 3%. To sum up, the major inputs are shown in Table 2 below. All other figures are presented in Annex A9. Base case scenario valuation inputs. 22 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S., p. 87, 42 Table 2: Main Valuation Inputs Detailed Forecast Key driver forecast CV 2020- Year 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Revenue Growth -9% 60% 12% 10% 10% 9% 8% 8% 7% 7% 6% 6% COGS/Rev 84% 84% 84% 84% 84% 6.4% 6.8% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% 7.2% ROIC 8.3% 13.6% 13.8% 13.9% 14% 14% 14% 14% 13.9% 13.9% 13.8% 13.8% WACC 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% 8.3% Adj EBITA margin 2024 5.2.4. Continuing value The inputs that dictate the continuing value amount were chosen based on the fact that Vestas is a growing company in a young industry, and therefore, the continuing value should represent a considerable portion of the valuation amount. A ROIC of 9% and a growth in NOPLAT of 6% were forecasted, both slightly below the rates in the last year of the key driver forecast. Moreover, the ROIC value is also based on a piece of research conducted by Koller et al., (2005), in which they found that median ROICs across several industries from 1963 to 2003 was 9%. They also found that although these differ by industry (industries that rely on patents and brands have ROICs above median, while utilities – below), they gradually regress towards the median. As a result of these inputs, continuing value amounts to 79.9% of total operating value. Figure 8: Valuation result 5.3. Valuation result Value of Equity The results of the valuation are presented in the table to the right. The end result of EUR 30.03 is slightly higher than the current market valuation, more exactly by 18.41%23. The reason behind the difference is the belief that considerable negative media coverage has affected share prices. The fact that Vestas decided to relocate production facilities to cheaper regions might Operating Value Excess Mkt Securities Financial Investments Excess Pension Assets Enterprise Value Debt Capitalized Operating Leases Retirement Related Liability Preferred Stock Minority Interest Long-Term Operating Provision Restructuring Provision Future Stock Options Stock options have been a sound business decision, but the reports of Equity Value closing down facilities on the Isle of Wight in the UK, as No. shares (thousands) Value per Share Source: valuation spreadsheet 23 Given the price of EUR 25.36 on 31 January 2011. 43 7.099 355 12 0 7.466 (351) (980) (2) 0 0 0 0 (16) (0,022) 6.117 204 30,03 well as in Scandinavia has taken its toll on the share price on the market. However, to account for the effects of various variables on the valuation, investigations were conducted in Chapter 6 – Sensitivity analysis. 5.4. Critique Vestas’ historical evolution over the decade between 2000 and 2009 is fluctuating considerably. The valuation assumes that the company stabilises by the end of the key driver forecast, but, since we are dealing with a very volatile industry, this might not be the case. At this point in time, it is hard to predict at what level the rates will stabilise and because of the sensitivity of the valuation model, even slight differences have a considerable impact on the valuation. 44 Chapter 6. Sensitivity Analysis This chapter represents an attempt to translate hypotheses and expectations into numbers. More precisely, it represents an attempt to quantify how sensitive Vestas’ share price is in respect to various factors. Firstly, the effects of different target capital structures will be measured, followed by a section looking at the cost of debt and finally, a few debt-related and non-debt-related variables that affect the cost of capital: the marginal tax rate, the risk-free rate and the return on the market portfolio. The concluding section of the chapter presents an overview of all the simulation results. 6.1. Target capital structure In their 2009 annual report, Vestas mention that they plan to keep debt levels low, but do not give any indications as to how low. The company’s 2010 Eurobond brings debt to book value up to 24.52%, based on the 2010 company forecast evolution. Myers and Majluf, (1984) only posited the existence of the target debt levels, but did not indicate how one could calculate them. They name what the costs and benefits of debt are, but they do not attempt to measure them precisely. From all of those, subsequent literature that tries to quantify costs or benefits mainly deals with tax advantages (Graham and Lemmon, (1998), Graham, (2003) and Graham, (2003)), and bankruptcy costs (Warner, (1977)). All the other types of costs and benefits largely remain elusive. In research, particularly empirical studies, the most popular method employed is the usage of proxies as independent variables utilised to regress target levels on. In an attempt to quantify Vestas’ target debt level, various estimations were performed. An inverse approach to that described above was used, namely that the coefficients resulting from statistical regressions were used to calculate Vestas’ target capital structure. Hence, as with the majority of trade-off literature, costs and benefits were not calculated directly, but the use of proxies and regression models lead to the uncovering of target leverage levels. Two different models were used, one representative for the static trade-off theory, and the other for the dynamic trade-off theory, respectively that of Chang et al., (2009) and of Clark et al., (2009). 45 6.1.1. The Static Trade-off Target Debt Level The most important reasons behind deciding to use this particular model were the following: the model is based on the seminal work of Titman and Wessels, (1988). In addition, the more recent model presents improvements (refined indicators, the use of the MIMIC24 model instead of the SEM25) which bring about greater accuracy and result significance; unlike a regular regression model, this type of model highlights the exact relationship between the unobservable attributes (meaning the immeasurable determinants of capital structure) and the observable variables (meaning the proxies used to replace the determinants); the comprehensiveness of the model is another advantage. It includes proxies for growth, profitability, collateral value of assets, non-debt tax shields, uniqueness, volatility, and industry; the large sample size is a sign that results obtained through this model could be representative for Vestas as well (13,887 firm-year observations stretching over 16 years and covering 351 industries). with the exception of size – which, compared to the older model, was not taken into account because of goodness of fit criteria – all other determinants of capital structure were statistically significant. The precursor of this model is the structural equation model of Titman and Wessels, (1988) comprising of 15 determinants of capital structure: 24 Multiple Indicators and Multiple Causes Model, a reduced form of SEM. 25 Structural Equation Modeling. 46 Chang et al., (2009) use a MIMIC model in their analysis. The restricted formula for the model is: where Y is a vector of indicators of the latent variable η (target capital structure) and X is a vector of causes of η. ξ denotes disturbance. The diagram below shows the relationship between the different vectors, which is explanatory for both the model of Titman and Wessels, (1988) and also that of Chang et al., (2009). Figure 9: The Static Trade-off Model X1 y1 ε1 y2 ε2 y3 ε3 η X2 X3 ξ Source: Chang et al., (2009) The representation shows that the latent variable, namely capital structure (η) is dictated by a series of causes (X1, X2, X3), which are in fact the determinants of capital structure. These are then measured by corresponding y variables. By using the vector of causes, X, two different equations were set up and the target debt levels for both long term and short term debt were calculated, as presented below: 47 *The independent variables in the two equations respectively stand for: RD/S: R&D/Sales; CE/TA: Capital Expenditure/Total Assets; GTA: Percentage Change in Total Assets; MBA: Market-to-Book Assets; MBE: Market-to-Book Equity; RD/TA: R&D/Total Assets; NDT/TA: Non-Debt Tax Shields/Total Assets; ITC/TA: Investment Tax Credits/Total Assets; Dep/TA: Depreciation Expense/ Total Assets; IGP/TA: Investments & Gross Property, Plant and Equipment/Total Assets; OI/TA: Operating Income/Total Assets; OI/S: Operating Income/Sales; STDGOI: Standard Deviation of Percentage Change in Operating Income; CV(ROI): Coefficient of Variation of ROI; CV(ROE): Coefficient of Variation of ROE; CV(OITA): Coefficient of Variation of Operating Income/Total Assets; IND: industry – two-category dummy variable. The overall debt-to-book value is 39.73%, where book value is adjusted to include off balance sheet items (reserve for income smoothing provisions and leased assets). Compared to the base case scenario, which only includes the Eurobond, this target level is 1521 percentage points higher. By using the base case scenario valuation and plugging in this debt level into the WACC, the new share price equals EUR 63.47 – more than the double of the previous EUR 30.03 or a change of 111.36%. 6.1.2. The Dynamic Trade-off Target Debt Level and Adjustment Speed The reasons for which the model by Clark et al., (2009) was thought to be appropriate were the following: this model, too, presents highly significant results from a statistical point of view; the authors also perform regressions on subsamples based on country considerations. Therefore, the regression which was used for Vestas is based on the results that Clark et al., (2009) present for Denmark. This is thought to yield results that are more insightful and closer to the actual truth. Clark et al., (2009) use a partial adjustment model to test whether firms move towards a target and, if yes, at which adjustment speed they do so. Their model is presented below: where MDR is the market-to-debt ratio and λ is the adjustment speed. In order to estimate the future market-to-debt ratio, the following model is used: where Xi,t is the vector of firm characteristics used to predict the debt levels of next period and Fi is the vector of firm fixed effects. 48 Vestas’ target capital structure was calculated based on its own firm specific characteristics and using the regression below: *The independent variables in the regression respectively stand for: MDR1: Market-to-Debt ratio equal to (Long-Term Debt + Current Liabilities)/(Total Assets - Book Equity + Market Equity; EBIT/TA: EBIT/Total Assets; MB: Market-to-Book Ratio; ln(TA): natural logarithm of Total Assets; RDDUM: dummy variable equal to 1 if there was an R&D expense and 0 otherwise; RD/TA: R&D/Total Assets; DEP/TA: Depreciation Expense/Total Assets. The “L” stands for one-period lagged variables. From this model, the resulting debt-to-book value ratio is of 22.73%, which yields a share value of EUR 28.01, lower that the EUR 30.03 by 6.73%. The difference is much smaller than the previous case due to the fact that the debt ratio change which has an impact on WACC is also smaller than before. It should be noted that the level of debt estimated using this model is very close to the target debt level used in the forecast period, which includes the Eurobond. The former is only 1.79% lower than the latter. A natural conclusion would be that perhaps there is some reason for issuing a Eurobond of EUR 600 million. A suspicion that Vestas is already close to target levels was already raised in Section 4.3. Stock Market Performance. Even though it might seem that the target debt level is somewhat low, we must bear in mind that certain traits which are characteristic to Vestas and are documented in literature are connected to low debt levels. Kim and Sorensen, (1986) document the fact that high growth firms use less debt. Uniqueness is also a determinant negatively related to leverage, which Titman and Wessels, (1988), as well as Chang et al., (2009), determine with the use of R&D expenditures. Vestas does not report its R&D expenses, but it does boast having the largest R&D department in the industry, employing 2,980 people at the end of 2009. This might be indicative of a high degree of uniqueness. 6.1.3. Simulation Assumptions and Method In order to find how sensitive the share price is, the first step was to analyse the change in equity price that would be produced if the target debt level is increased and decreased. Changes in increments of 1% are induced, up to +/- 10% compared to the 49 forecasted target debt level of the base case. The percentage changes in share price compared to the base case are portrayed in the next section. The next step involves a total of 6 main simulations. These were adjusted during further simulations, to provide feasible results. Each simulation was run 5000 times and all the outcomes are presented in the next section. The first simulation assumes that the target capital structure of Vestas is the one calculated using the static trade-off model of Chang et al., (2009). However, since in real life, the target capital structure is not an unflinching number, but the realization of a random variable, a distribution was set up as the basis for the simulation. The target capital structure was assumed to have a normal distribution, the mean of which was the previously calculated target value (39.73%), while the standard deviation was calculated using the formula: which yielded a deviation of 86.08%. Since the deviation is that large, in some instances, the simulation can return a negative value or a value above 100%, both of which are economically impossible. We have thus restricted the simulation in two ways. Firstly, to only take into account positive figures. If the simulated value is negative, we assumed that the company will pay off all of its debt. Secondly, the target level has been capped at 65%. All the simulation results that are above will revert to 65%26, which is considered a reasonable approximation of the level beyond which financial distress costs might start to come into play. It should be acknowledged that these assumptions regarding standard deviation and the financial distress threshold are largely arbitrary, due to lack of data. Moreover, they are restrictive and influence the results to a considerable extent. By simulating target cap structure it is possible to get a WACC lower than the growth rate for continuing value, which leads to value destruction because continuing value is negative. It is also possible to get a WACC higher than ROIC, which also leads to value destruction. Vestas however stands on solid ground, and therefore, WACC should be in between the two rates. Thus, a conditional simulation is performed and the 26 All other listed top 10 manufacturers (Gamesa, Suzlon, Siemens as a whole, REPower) have debt levels between 56% and 72%. 50 cost of capital’s variation was restricted to the interval defined by the growth rate at the lower limit and the ROIC at the upper one. This is considered in line with reality because Vestas is a young company in a growing industry, and therefore, most of the enterprise value should be in the continuing value. This was the second simulation. The third simulation is similar to the first, but uses the results of the dynamic trade-off model as the mean for the target debt level simulation. The rest of the assumptions and methodology are identical. To calculate the standard deviation, a similar formula was used as in the previous case, yielding a deviation of 9.1%. The conditional simulation – the fourth simulation - is also performed, but the results do not differ much. The fifth simulation connects the static and dynamic trade-off model results and assumes that the target level lies in between the two. A uniform distribution where the lower and upper limits of the range are the debt levels calculated through the dynamic and respectively static trade-off model is set up. A secondary conditional simulation is run in this case as well, being the sixth simulation and the last of the capital structure simulations. 6.1.4. Results Table 3: Target Capital Structure Percentage Changes Results Debt Level Change -5% Table 3 presents the results Share Price (EUR) 24,85 % Change from Best Case -17,25% -4% 25,78 -14,17% analysis. A percentage change of -3% 26,75 -10,92% +1% has a slightly bigger impact -2% 27,78 -7,48% -1% 28,87 -3,85% Base Case 1% 30,03 31,26 0,00% 4,09% 2% 32,57 8,44% results suggest that as the debt moves 3% 33,96 13,08% further away from the base case 4% 35,45 18,04% 5% 37,04 23,35% of the preliminary simulation than a change of -1%, but in the same direction predicted by theory: less debt leads to a lower share price. The target, the impact becomes smaller and smaller, meaning that it is not directly proportional with the debt level percentage change. The table below, Table 4, lists the results of the base case scenario and of all the debt target level simulations, which are further commented upon in this section. 51 Table 4: Target Capital Structure Simulation Results Simulation Reference Base Case #1 #2 #3 #4 #5 #6 Target Capital Structure* WACC Share Price 24.52% 34.8% (29%) 34.3% (28.9%) 22.8% (9.1%) 22.7% (9%) 31.2% (4.9%) 31.3% (4.9%) 8.3% 7.6% (2.2%) 7.5% (1.4%) 8.4% (0.6%) 8.4% (0.5%) 7.8% (0.3%) 7.8% (0.3%) EUR 30.03 EUR 42.50 (EUR 469) EUR 63.61 (EUR 597) EUR 31.06 (EUR 14.53) EUR 31.72 (EUR 20.56) EUR 41.10 (EUR 9.57) EUR 41.24 (EUR 9.61) * Target capital structure is measured as debt to total book value, where the latter is adjusted to include off balance sheet items. () The numbers in between parentheses represent standard deviations. The first simulation (#1) results in a mean share value of EUR 42.5. However, in 2081 instances, the share was worthless due to the fact that the cost of capital was either larger that the ROIC of the continuing value, or less than the growth. The first simulation was upgraded and the conditional simulation (#2) run next restricted the cost of capital in between the two other rates. This time, the mean share value was EUR 63.61 - much higher due to the fact that the share price was never allowed to be worthless. The price didn’t fall below EUR 4.56 (the result of simulations where the cost of capital is the lowest and is equal to the growth rate in NOPLAT). Given that the highest historical price ever recorded for Vestas was of EUR 92.79, this result – even though very far from the current economic reality - is not completely impossible. The histograms in Figures 10 and 11 depict the share price resulted from the first two simulations. In both histograms, most of the results are clustered around the lower values, with fewer and fewer results scattered towards the higher prices. In Figure 10, the leftmost column portrays the results when the share was worthless, and the next one, the results when all the debt was paid off (the target capital structure was all equity). In the latter case, share value is EUR 13.20. Instead of allowing share value to be 0 due to an inappropriate cost of capital, a condition was set so that the WACC is in between the ROIC and growth rate of the continuing value. Thus, the minimum share value is EUR 4.65. In Figure 11, the leftmost column represents all the instances when the share price was EUR 4.65. The next column portrays 1946 cases out of which 1905 correspond to a no debt capital structure and a cost of WACC of 9%. The resulting share price in those 1905 cases was EUR 20.5. 52 Figure 10: Simulation #1 Share Price Histogram Source: based on simulation results Figure 11: Simulation #2 Share Price Histogram Source: based on simulation results The results of the third simulation (#3) imply a share value of EUR 31.06. This is much closer to the EUR 30.03 from the forecasted base case due to the fact that the target debt levels and the standard deviation are much lower in this case than in the former. In this case, there are no instances of the share having the null value. Next, the conditional simulation (#4) where the variation of the cost of capital is limited between ROIC and growth is also performed, but the results do not differ much. This time, the mean value of the share price is EUR 31.72. The smaller difference between the two results can also be attributed to the more restricted variation of the target capital structure. The following histograms (Figures 12 and 13) portray the share price results for simulations #3 and #4. The shape resembles the bell shape of a skewed distribution more than in the previous two cases due to the fact that the standard deviation of the target capital structure is much smaller and therefore, there are no abnormal results and no restrictions that would distort the shape of the results’ distribution too much. In the third simulation, the maximum debt level is 52.2%, while in the fourth, it is 58.2%. Figure 12: Simulation #3 Histogram of Results Source: based on simulation results Figure 13: Simulation #4 Histogram of Results Source: based on simulation results 53 As for the last unconditional simulation (#5), which entails a uniform distribution, the results were – as expected – in between those found above: the average share price was EUR 41.26. The fact that the variation interval is quite small (from 22.74% to 39.73%) and that the share price was always positive (the minimum recorded value was EUR 27.78) are the causes for such a high result. In the last conditional simulation (#6), the result is almost identical: EUR 41.24. As expected, the histograms showing the share prices (Figure 14 and 15 below) are much more even in shape, compared to all the previous cases. This is naturally due to the type of distribution chosen for the target capital simulation. Figure 14: Simulation #5 Histogram of Results Figure 15: Simulation #6 Histogram of Results Source: based on simulation results Source: based on simulation results In conclusion, the results show that the higher the debt level, the lower the cost of capital, and the higher the equity value; these findings are in line with theory and with expectations, given the conditioned debt target levels to be less than a potential financial distress threshold. However, it is important to note the sensitivity of the model, as can be seen from the very high share price particularly in simulation #2, but also in simulation #1. Hence, the variation in results might only be particular to how the model is built, and not necessarily solely to company and market characteristics. 6.1.5. Discussion and Critique Oddly enough, a brief historical walk-through of debt levels and stock value shows figures that are contrary to theoretical predictions (and also to the results of the simulation): Vestas’ share price and its degree of indebtedness seem to be inversely related. The maximum share price of Vestas over the 12 years when it has been listed is EUR 92.79. The price was registered in August 2008, the same year in which the company also had the lowest ever debt levels, the debt to book total cap ratio being as 54 little as 5.8%. Perhaps at that point in time, there were other, more potent factors driving share prices. Or perhaps it was a sort of pre-financial crisis bubble (share prices fell as low as EUR 32.23 in November the same year). At the opposite spectrum, the share price was lowest from 2002 to 2005, when leverage levels were historically the highest (varying between 26.7% and 33.4% book debt to value). In the latter case, the equity value was influenced considerably by not meeting market expectations over the 4 year period. Vestas continually failed to meet beginning-of-the-year forecasted targets during that time frame. Moreover, the NEG Micon combination in 2004 also led to a downward adjustment of prices. Given the facts portrayed above, why is it that the calculated target levels could be reasonable estimations? The following results are sample means extracted from cross sectional studies that aim to test whether the target capital structure exists. Bradley et al., (1984) find that, depending on the industry, debt levels can be between 9.1% (drugs and cosmetics industry) and 58.3% (airline industry). Kim and Sorensen, (1986) find that the mean debt ratio for firms with a low degree of inside ownership27 is 32%, coupled with a standard deviation of 16%. Clark et al., (2009) document an average debt-to-value of 42.8% for their Danish sub-sample, with a corresponding standard deviation of 20%. Liu, (2009) analyse a sample with a mean book debt to value of 47.5% (standard deviation of 21.5%) and a market debt to value of 39.5% (standard deviation 24.8%). Therefore, the estimated target levels for Vestas fall within the reported interval or within maximum one standard deviation from the mean of each of the results presented above. However, the values calculated for Vestas fall towards the lower end of the debt intervals from previous studies. This can be explained by a few company characteristics which are documented in literature as to have a negative impact on debt levels. One of these characteristics is company size. Brennan and Schwartz, (1984), as well as Hennessy and Whited, (2005) and Graham, (2000) document the inverse relationship between size and the level of debt. A second characteristic is growth opportunities, documented by Myers, (1977), Kim and Sorensen, (1986), Rajan and Zingales, (1995), Talberg et al., (2008), Antoniou et al., (2008) and Byoun, (2008). A 27 In 2009, Vestas’ board of directors and executive management owned a total of 0.07% of overall number of shares. 55 third factor that leads to lower debt levels is that the model disregards transaction costs. Kane et al., (1984) make this observation with regard to the effects of transactions costs. Another observation which should be noted concerns the current debt levels of listed industry competitors in the top 10: Gamesa, Suzlon, and REPower. Siemens has not been considered because the debt levels in their annual report refer to the group and not Siemens Wind Power. Koller et al., (2005) state that in order to calculate target debt levels, it is important to also look at peers. The observed capital structures range from 56% to 72%, without taking into account off balance-sheet items. Why, then, would Vestas’ target be so much lower? One answer would be that the industry is now in the growing stage and all the incumbents are trying to get a foothold in the market and accumulate as much share of it as possible. That means investing heavily, which requires rising considerable funding in very little time – a strategy employed by all competitors. It is likely that companies will revert to their target levels – which are much lower – as the industry matures. Vestas might have lower debt levels because of being ahead in the adjustment towards optimum. Another argument would be that Vestas has been one of the pioneers in the market and thus, has had time to grow in the past – which Vestas did mostly using internally generated funds, but also debt. The high-leverage period is a thing of the past for Vestas and took place from 2002-2005, as the historical analysis shows. For a debt-conservative company such as Vestas, their debt levels peaked at 33.4% in 2005. An additional issue which might raise question marks is the high standard deviation in the static trade-off case. The reasons why this result came about are the fact that the number of observations used to calculate the deviation was quite small (10 in total) and that the difference between the target and actual debt levels was high in all of the cases. Looking at where peers stand might point towards a conclusion with regards to the plausibility of the standard deviation. The book debt-to assets ratio was calculated for the other listed peers in the top 10 (Gamesa, Suzlon, and REPower). It turns out that they all have lower standard deviations28 compared to Vestas, due to the fact that their debt levels are higher and thus, closer to the optimum. Gamesa comes quite close to Vestas’ standard deviation (80.24% for the former, compared to 86.08% for the latter), but in the Spanish competitor’s case, the high standard deviation is a result of very high 28 Gamesa has a standard deviation of 80.24%, Suzlon of 41.62% and REPower of 55.94%. 56 debt levels, contrary to Vestas’ financing position. Due to the discrepancies between industry incumbents it is difficult to draw a conclusion solely based on comparisons. However, if we look at the literature, the high standard deviation is in line with previous research. In Chang et al., (2009) the study on which the estimation of the static trade-off target debt level is based, the sample analysed has a mean long term debt to market value ratio of 44% and a standard deviation of 194%. The results for Vestas are much lower. Therefore, the standard deviation reported by Chang et al., (2009) sheds a more favourable light on Vestas’ 86.08% result. The next issue of concern is the actual valuation model which the simulation has been built into. The two frameworks used in the model (discounted cash flows and economic value) focus mostly on Vestas’ operating performance, and therefore, they only include the effects of the company’s capital structure to a very limited extent. And since the simulations make use of the valuation model, the sensitivity analysis is bound and connected to how the model is built. The spreadsheet doesn’t account for factors and market forces outside the company: bubbles, fads and trends (like the IT bubble, for example) – it is a plain vanilla valuation sheet that – if used to make economic decisions - should only be regarded as a point of view in a more complex analysis. It presents a very simplified view compared to reality. Apart from the feature that market and industry forces – which clearly affect prices – are not built in, other - more technical - drawbacks include for example the fact that the model is completely insensitive to changes in the balance sheet structure, and particularly important for the present issue, to the debt-equity mix. The only link between debt levels and share prices is through the debt to value ratio in the WACC, and not through the cost of debt. The latter is computed separately, and is an invariable input into the model. Therefore, it can be argued that the effect of debt levels is only superficial. Section 6.4. tries to reconcile this drawback by modifying the spreadsheet so that the amount of leverage has an effect on the cost of debt. An additional and final comment to the structure of the valuation model is that it works with accounting statements and does not actually try to compute the specific costs and benefits of debt, which are so vastly talked about (Kraus and Litzenberger, (1973); Miller, (1977); Myers, (1984); Frank and Goyal, (2007)). Even though they 57 might have given a more panoramic view upon the link with stock prices, an exact estimation of these costs and benefits remains elusive in this model. 6.1.6. Discussion on the Adjustment Speed As for the adjustment speed, it would be difficult to accurately calculate how fast Vestas would reach target optimal debt levels. Previous studies fail to reach a generally accepted conclusion related to the adjustment speed, which ranges from 8% (Flannery and Rangan, (2006)) to 23.2% (Huang and Ritter, (2009)). Clark et al., (2009) report adjustment speeds for numerous developed or developing countries around the world. In order to be consistent with the model chosen for the dynamic trade-off target level calculation, an adjustment speed can be deducted from the study’s results with respect to Denmark, yielding a much higher level than the previously mentioned 23.2%. Vestas should have a speed of 57.2%, meaning that the company should reach its target level in less than 2 years. We will assume that this is an appropriate estimation, for the sake of consistency with the model used to calculate the optimal amount of leverage. In Vestas’ case, the historical evolution of debt levels is not linear, thus not growing year by year, but fluctuating considerably: if the dynamic trade-off estimation of 22.7% is considered to be the target, then the observation of historical fluctuations is puzzling. Debt levels can be as high as 33% one year (as was the case in 2005) and as low as 12% the next. The company has managed to come close to the projected target level only in 2010, after issuing the Eurobond, when the company reached a debt-tovalue ratio of 24.52%. Why, then, was the company so slow to reach its optimal target level? Possibly because the company has been slowed down by the turmoil in the global economy, which acted as a disturbance and determined the firm to substantially deviate from the optimum. This hypothesis is supported by the company’s historical debt-to-value ratios, which were quite high before the financial crisis and decreased considerably as the crisis unfolded, thus reaching a level below optimum, instead of leveling off at 22.7%. Another explanation could be connected to industry risk. The wind industry is generally viewed as a risky one. If Vestas’ management considers this to be accurate and is risk averse, then the slow adjustment speed might be a conscious decision made by management and aiming to keep the company at bay from too many debt-related 58 costs. This explanation might also be linked to why debt levels fell so abruptly during the financial crisis, which might have been a measure to reduce exposure to risk. 6.2. The Cost of Debt Based on the results of the previous section, the conclusion to be drawn is that it increasing debt levels would be beneficial for Vestas’ share price. In the introduction, one question posed was whether the type of debt which Vestas would chose to issue matters. The answer is yes, because each debt instrument has different characteristics and therefore, influences the cost of debt in a particular way. What, then, would be the appropriate types of debt for the company? This section does not aim to be an exhaustive presentation of all debt instruments, but slightly touches upon the advantages and disadvantages of some of the most popular debt financing methods, especially in relation to the previous discussion. What’s more, no attempt has been made to quantify these advantages and disadvantages. 6.2.1. Types of Debt - Discussion A good option would be securitisation – the issue of secured debt like mortgage bonds. Vestas holds numerous fixed assets that could easily be used as collateral. In fact, studies show that the higher the proportion of property plant and equipment, the more debt a company should have (Rajan and Zingales, (1995); Flannery and Rangan, (2006); Talberg et al., (2008); Antoniou et al., (2008); Byoun, (2008)). In 2009, the ratio of fixed to total assets (measured in book values) held by Vestas was 22.7%. Peers’ ratios range between 16.69% for REPower, to 26.06% for Gamesa, to 58.32% for Suzlon. Gamesa comes closest to Vestas, but unlike the Danish turbine manufacturer, the Spanish one has a debt to assets ratio of 60.58%, much higher than Vestas’ 24.52%29. It might be, therefore, that Gamesa is truly putting their assets to use as collateral. Advantages of the mortgage bond include lower costs for borrowing, an effect of smaller yields. Due to the fact that the bond is secured by assets, investors require a smaller interest that matches the lower bond risk. Another advantage is that the cost of debt will not soar after issuing this type of debt, due to the low yield and implied risk. This has a beneficial effect on the share 29 Vestas’ ratio includes the Eurobond and also takes into account lased assets, unlike Gamesa’s ratio, which is calculated with “on balance sheet” items. 59 capital, because it will not trigger a large increase in the cost of capital, thus reducing the value of stock. Moreover, mortgage bonds allow the company to make use of otherwise illiquid assets – property, plant and equipment – and turn them into a very liquid means of raising funds. Effects on the cost of debt are also an incentive to use this instrument: it implies less chances for the cost of debt to increase very much, since the yield is smaller than in other cases, which means that the cost of capital would not increase very much either and the share price would not decrease by a considerable amount However, there are disadvantages as well. The fact that these instruments require lower interest payments compared to other types of debt – or even none at all – is one of them. A consequence of this is that the company does not benefit from tax shields as much as they would with straight debt, for example. Another potential option for Vestas could be to issue convertible bonds hybrid instruments between debt and equity. Advantages include lower fixed cost for borrowing due to the lower yield. The option to convert the instrument into stock at the time of maturity is valuable in itself and compensates the investor for the lower interest. The effects on the cost of debt are similar to the mortgage bonds presented above and thus represent an advantage for using convertible bonds as well. A third advantage would be incurred if Vestas includes a call protection option. This feature would entitle the issuer with the right to call the bond before term and therefore, compel the holder to convert the bond into stock at a date prior to maturity. It is a useful feature if company earnings, along with share prices, are forecasted to rise considerably, rendering the conversion to stock at maturity unprofitable for the company. However, calling the bond would mean giving up the tax advantages of the bond, so the trade-off between current tax shields and future profitability should be considered when deciding to call the bond before maturity. And finally, just as in the previous case, these types of instruments can be called before maturity, if the company pays off the entire mortgage in advance. One of the main disadvantages would be that the company benefits from less tax shields, as in the case of mortgage bonds. 60 Another disadvantage would be dilution of EPS, which takes place at the time of conversion and is certainly undesired by current shareholders. In addition to that, there is also the threat of diluting control, in the event that a large part of the debt issued is bought by one single investor. A third debt instrument that Vestas could use is the zero-coupon bonds or strips. Much as in the cases of the previous instruments, advantages include less monthly costs, since the bond pays no coupons, and they can be called before maturity. Moreover, even though the company doesn’t pay coupons, it still records interest expense, which will be paid back in one lump sum at maturity or when the bond is called. Therefore, Vestas would benefit from tax advantages in this case as well. The effect on the cost of debt would also not be of considerable impact, if the company does not cross the financial distress threshold. Disadvantages would include the fact that these are the most volatile instruments and their swings are closely related to fluctuations in interest rates. At present times, interest rates have been known to change dramatically which would prompt investors to be reluctant to buy these bonds because of possible future fluctuations. Attractiveness of the instrument should thus carefully be considered before the issue. In conclusion, each debt instrument has its advantages and disadvantages for Vestas. A black and white decision cannot be made and the pluses and minuses of each have to be traded off and analysed from the viewpoint of the company’s financial strategy in order to decide which would be appropriate. What’s more, the decision of whether to subordinate new debt to the current Eurobond or to issue it at the same seniority will also take its toll on the cost of debt and the share price. 6.2.2. Sensitivity Analysis Assumptions and Method Since assumptions regarding the inputs in a potential simulation of the cost of capital would be very much like tossing a coin, the sensitivity analysis in this section aims to portray the effects of changes of the base case scenario cost of debt in increments of 0.1% up to a difference of +/-0.5% from the previously forecasted figure of 4.1%. In order to calculate the cost of capital, the assumption that the company will increase the amount of debt to the target level is applied to the calculation. Thus, two 61 sets of results for sensitivity analyses will be presented. The first assumes that the target debt level is of 39.73%, as the static trade-off model predicted. The other assumes 22.7%, based on the dynamic trade-off model. 6.2.3. Results and Discussion The two graphs below (Figures 16 and 17) depict the results of the simulation. As the cost of debt increases, so does the cost of capital. The results for the static tradeoff framework show that a change of +/-0.1% in the cost of debt triggers a change of +/0.03% in the cost of capital, leading to a difference of -/+2.7% in share prices compared to the base case. As for the case where the dynamic trade-off target level was used, a change of +/-0.1% in the cost of debt causes the cost of capital to modify by +/0.02% and the share price by -/+0.9%. Figure 16: Share Price Sensitivity in the Static Figure 17: Share Price Sensitivity in the Trade-off Case Dynamic Trade-off Case Source: author’s calculations Source: author’s calculations As would be expected, the share price drops when the cost of capital increases. The decrease is in smaller and smaller increments each time. The graphs also point out that the change is more dramatic in the static trade-off model due to the fact that the higher percentage of debt makes the cost of debt have a larger impact on the cost of capital. 6.3. Other Debt-Related and Non-debt-related Variables This section will focus on the effects of both debt related variables (marginal tax rate), as well as non-debt related variables that affect the cost of capital (the risk free rate and the return on the market portfolio). 62 6.3.1. Simulation Assumptions and Method Four different simulations are performed in this last section of the sensitivity analysis. In the first three only one of the three variables is allowed to fluctuate, while in the last one, all three are simulated. Results are presented in the following section. Antoniou et al., (2008) documents a positive relationship between the tax rate and amount of debt the company uses, with the intention to make the most of tax shields. The marginal tax rate in the base case scenario is assumed to be the Danish statutory tax rate, 25%. However, it is very difficult to calculate the marginal tax rate precisely with the limited information at hand. Graham develops a method of calculating marginal tax rates from company tax files (Graham, (1996a); Graham, (1996b); Graham, (2000); Graham, (2003); Graham and Lemmon, (1998)). He recalculates the amount of debt owed by changing the amount of interest deductions and hence tax shields, from which he derives the marginal tax rate. To put results into perspective and not let the base case 25% estimation constrain the results, a simulation was performed under the assumption that the variable has a normal distribution, with values clustering closer to the assumed mean of 25%. The standard deviation is 10.8%. The latter is based on the results of Plesko, (2003). He uses the same trichotomous variable as we have used to estimate the marginal tax rate and reports the 10.8% as the standard deviation of his sample. In the second simulation, the variable under the microscope is the risk free rate. We have also assumed this variable to have a normal distribution, with a mean of 2.9% (the estimation for the forecast period) and a standard deviation of 1.26%. The latter was estimated from historical yields of the German Eurobond with a 10 year maturity from January 1993 to January 2011, as extracted from the ECB database. The third variable, the return on the market portfolio, is evaluated in the next simulation. The assumptions in this case are that it has a normal distribution with a mean of 8.5%, as in the base case forecast period, and a standard deviation of 4.2%. The deviation was calculated as the standard deviation of the S&P500 returns from 1950 to 2010. Because of the high standard deviation, it is possible for the return on the market to be lower than the risk free rate, which, in some cases, could result in a negative cost of debt. Therefore, the return on the market is not allowed to fall below the risk free rate. Another effect of the high standard deviation is that the resulting cost 63 of capital could be so high that the value of operations is below the claims on the company’s cash flow (debt, leases, stock options and retirement related liabilities), which makes the share worthless. The last simulation allows all three variables to fluctuate based on the assumptions outlined above. 6.3.2. Results The table below presents the mean and standard deviation assumptions, alongside the results of all three simulations. For each of the variables, the simulation was run 5000 times. Table 5: Simulation results of other debt and non-debt related variables Variable Base Case Tm Rf Rm All Mean St. Dev. 25% 2.9% 8.5% 10.8% 1.26% 4.2% WACC 8.3% 8.3% (0.1%) 8.3% (0.3%) 8.4% (3.7%) 8.3% (3.7%) Share price EUR 30.03 EUR 30.13 (EUR 1.87) EUR 30.64 (EUR 4.71) EUR 48.51 (EUR 422.63) EUR 81.86 (EUR 1115) The numbers in between parentheses represent standard deviations. Results show that the marginal tax rate and the risk free rate do not influence the cost of capital and share price to a very large extent. The results of the simulation are quite close to those of the base case scenario. However, the return on the market portfolio has a much greater impact. The mean WACC is only 0.01% higher than the base case, but the standard deviation of 3.7% yields a much higher average share price and standard deviation. The valuation model that the simulation is built into is very sensitive to changes in the cost of capital, which is why the third simulation yields these results. The last simulation is the one with the highest resulting share price, due to the fact that all variables are allowed to fluctuate. Hence, there is a great variation of results from the base case, resulting in a EUR 81.86 share price and a corresponding standard deviation of EUR 1115. 6.3.3. Discussion and Critique Graham, (1996a) states that the fact that marginal tax rates are never explicitly calculated, and instead always replaced by various proxies is in fact the reason why most research fails to find tax as an important consideration in the choice of capital 64 structure. The fact that this analysis was grounded on no explicit calculation, but only on simulation, might bias the results. We find that the marginal tax rate does not have a material impact on the valuation, just as Graham had posited. In addition to the above, it can be argued that the standard deviation used for the simulation might not be representative in the case of Vestas, since it was extracted from previous research and is based on the sample used in that research. However, the restriction needed to be imposed due to the inexistence of more suitable options to be used in the estimation. The valuation seems to be slightly more sensitive to the risk free rate, perhaps due to the fact that the standard deviation of the simulated variable is much higher than in for the other variables. The return on the market portfolio seems to have the highest impact on the valuation. Because of the restrictions imposed on the simulation, 1654 cases of a share price of EUR 0 were recorded. In all of these cases, the cost of capital was very high, and by discounting the company’s cash flows, their present value was below that of the claims on the cash flows. 6.4. Simulations of All Variables The main purpose of the previous simulations was to try to isolate the effect a certain variable had on the share price and then attempt to analyse it. This final section takes a different approach and performs all-encompassing simulations, which allow all the variables previously studied in this section to fluctuate. 6.4.1. Simulation Assumptions and Method Two final simulations are performed in an attempt to link all the previous simulations together and determine what the cumulative effect on the share price might be. These last two simulations differ from each other in that the first uses the static trade-off target level and standard deviation, while the second uses the dynamic-tradeoff results. In both cases, the debt target level fluctuation is restricted to the interval [0%; 65%], based on the same reasoning as in Section 6.1.3. 65 Moreover, based on the target level simulated in each case, the valuation spreadsheet has been modified to link the debt level to the cost of debt, a link which was previously inexistent. Therefore, a higher debt level now gives rise to a higher cost of debt. Since the exact relationship between the two variables is dependent on many factors which are outside the scope of this study (like determining the exact mix of debt instruments issued or their seniority), an arbitrary variation in the cost of capital of 1% for each 10% points of debt level Table 6: Link between the target debt level and the cost of debt Target Debt Level* Between... 0% 5% 15% 25% 35% 45% 55% 65% And... 4,99% 14,99% 24,99% 34,99% 44,99% 54,99% 64,99% 65% Cost of debt 0,00% 2,20% 3,20% 4,20% 5,20% 6,20% 7,20% 8,20% * Target debt level is measured as debt to total book value, where the latter is adjusted to include off balance sheet items. variation, compared to the forecasted debt level in the base case scenario and in the same direction as the leverage variation is considered a reasonable assumption. Starting from the base case scenario inputs, a debt level of 25% corresponds to a cost of debt of 4.2%. Table 6 illustrates exactly how the two variables are tied together. A Vlookup Excel function was used to operate the simulation. The risk free rate, the return on the market portfolio and the marginal tax rate all fluctuate independently, based on the same assumptions as in Section 6.3. 6.4.2. Results Table 7 below compares the results of these last two simulations with those of conditional simulations #2 and #4 from Section 6.1. Table 7: Share-price sensitivity when all analysed variables are simulated Variable Static Trade-off Case Simulation #2 New simulation (#2’) 34% (29.2%) Debt 34.3% (28.9%) Target Level* Cost Of Debt WACC Share Price 4.2% 4.3% (3.6%) 7.5% (1.4%) 7.7% (1.3%) EUR 63.61 EUR 76.30 (EUR 543) (EUR 597) Dynamic Trade-off Case Simulation #4 New simulation (#4’) 22.7% (9%) 23% (4.9%) 4.2% 3.3% (0.6%) 8.4% (0.5%) 7.1% (0.8%) EUR 31.72 EUR 80.34 (EUR 166.61) (EUR 20.56) * Target debt level is measured as debt to total book value, where the latter is adjusted to include off balance sheet items. () The numbers in between parentheses represent standard deviations. 66 Given the fact that the target debt levels were simulated based on the same requirements, it was expected to obtain similar results, as has in fact happened in both the static and the dynamic trade-off case. As in Section 6.1.4., the lower result in the dynamic trade-off case is attributed to a lower distribution mean and a lower variance than the static trade-off case. With regards to the cost of debt, it was also lower in the dynamic trade-off case. This is a result of linking the cost of debt to the target debt level and more specifically, of the assumptions taken on for the type of distribution that the target debt level variable fits into. For simulation #4’, 68.2% of the results are within one standard deviation from the mean target debt level, or specifically within the interval [18.1%; 27.9%], which translates into a cost of debt of 3.2%; 4.2% or 5.2% as leverage increases. For simulation #2’, the statistical interval would be [-46.35%; 125.81%], which is restricted to [0%; 65%] for a more reasonable result, from an economical point of view. This means that the cost of debt in the latter case can take on any value from 0% to 8.2%, which might result in a higher average value, as well as a higher standard deviation. Results for the cost of capital pull together the effects of all the simulated variables. Since the risk free rate, marginal tax rate and return on the market portfolio exercise the same influence on the WACC, it is safe to conclude that the lower value in simulation #4’ also stems from the lower mean value and standard deviation of the dynamic trade-off target capital structure. The model was proven to be quite sensitive to changes in WACC, which is why the very large difference between equity prices in simulation #4 and #4’ can also be attributed to the 1.3% difference in WACC. As we have seen in Section 6.2., the higher the cost of debt, the lower the share price. The same relation between variables can be observed in Table 7: simulation #2’ has a higher average cost of capital and a lower average share price than simulation #4’. 6.4.3. Discussion and Critique Since the main difference compared to the previous simulations is related to debt level and cost, the main critique is to the same issues. Even though these last simulations seek to mirror economic reality and simulate all the variables at the same time, they still have some drawbacks. In an attempt to make the actual state of things easier to grasp, the cost of debt is only assumed to be influenced by the level of debt. 67 Since leverage is below the financial distress threshold, the relation between debt and its cost is assumed to be direct and proportional. It might be, however, that in the real world, the relation would be an exponential one and would most likely also be influenced by other factors like the types of debt issued, their maturity, new debt seniority and whether or not debt is subject to any covenants. An endeavour to scratch the surface of the enumerated factors has been attempted in Section 6.2.1. Types of debt, but, because of the complexity of information needed, the valuation model was not modified to include these factors. 68 Chapter 7. Conclusions The aim of this thesis was to present a sensitivity analysis of the share price of Vestas with regards to the optimal debt level, as well as various other variables, some debt-related (cost of debt and marginal tax rate), and others non-debt-related (risk free rate and return on the market portfolio). The starting point of the analysis was a base case scenario valuation which yielded a share price of EUR 30.03. The financing side of the balance sheet comprised of 24.52% debt – which included the EUR 600 mil Eurobond - with a cost estimated at 4.1%. The marginal tax rate was 25%, the risk free rate – 2.9%, and the return on the market portfolio – 8.3%. The optimal capital structure was then determined. Two different models were employed in this respect. The first is the static trade-off model which was derived from the research of Chang et al., (2009) and yielded a target of 39.73%. By plugging in this result in the base case scenario, the share price would be EUR 63.47, more than double than before. The second model is representative of the dynamic trade-off theory and was extracted from Clark et al., (2009). This model yielded a target debt level of 22.73% and a share price of EUR 28.01, both slightly below the base case. Judging by these figures, Vestas is almost at optimum leverage, but it took the company a long time to reach its optimum. Clark et al., (2009) posit that the adjustment speed to target leverage for Danish companies is less than 2 years. Vestas’ more gradual adjustment was probably caused by the turbulence in the global economy and an attempt to limit default risk exposure, as the company is an incumbent in a new and somewhat risky industry. If the optimal debt level is the one calculated through the static trade-off model, then Vestas needs to further increase debt levels. A brief discussion of appropriate debt instruments pointed out that appropriate choices would be the less risky instruments which would not prompt the cost of debt to increase considerably and thus, affect share prices in a negative way. Such instruments could be secured debt (mortgage bonds), convertible debt or zero-coupon bonds. The sensitivity analysis follows and 5 simulation variables were scrutinized. With regards to the target debt levels, a change of +1% has a slightly bigger impact than a change of -1%, but in the same direction predicted by theory: less debt leads to a 69 lower share price. Share prices range from EUR 31.06 to EUR 63.61, given the assumptions characterising each simulation and whether the static or the dynamic tradeoff target was used. Results point out that, as the cost of debt increases, so does the cost of capital and that the share price drops when the cost of capital increases. The decrease is in smaller and smaller increments each time. The results from the static trade-off framework show that a change of +/-0.1% in the cost of debt leads to a +/-0.03% change in the cost of capital, and further on to a difference of -/+2.7% in share prices compared to the base case. In the dynamic trade-off case, a change of +/-0.1% in the cost of debt causes the cost of capital to modify by +/-0.02% and the share price by approximately /+0.9%. The next variables analysed were the marginal tax rate, the risk free rate and the return on the market portfolio, which were simulated within the base case scenario. The respective average results were EUR 30.13, EUR 30.64 and EUR 48.51. The very high standard deviation of the return on the market portfolio leads to the largest difference from the base case result. If all the variables are simulated simultaneously, the resulting share price is as high as EUR 81.86. In combination, the effects of all the variables on the equity value build up considerably. The last two simulations integrate all the variables and also link the debt levels with the cost of debt. Within the static trade-off framework, the cost of debt was higher than in the dynamic trade-off state, and the resulting share prices were of EUR 76.30, and EUR 80.34, respectively. Even though all these results are higher than the current share price of Vestas, they are still below the maximum share price in the company history: EUR 92.79. Assumptions are one of the factors that affect the results to a large extent. Another factor is the valuation model. Since the analysis was performed within the valuation spreadsheet, the way it is built greatly impacts on the sensitivity analysis results. Valuation focuses on how much company operations are worth, and hence, the only way the simulation variables affect share prices is through the cost of capital. The valuation model is in fact extremely sensitive to changes in the cost of capital and therefore, the larger the impact on the cost of capital, the larger the effect on share price. Therefore, given the constraints outlined above, the conclusion is that debt levels do influence share prices and that Vestas is either close to, or below the optimum 70 amount of leverage, depending on the framework considered. By managing the financing of its operations in a way that would keep the cost of capital as low as possible, the company can increase its share price considerably. However, there are also factors outside the grasp of the company, which affect the final outcome to a very large extent: the highest result of the individual one-variable simulations was the effect of the return on the market portfolio. Therefore, external variables should not be neglected in the determination of the optimal capital structure. 71 Bibliography 1) Acher, J. 2010. China Became Top Wind Power Market in 2009 [Online]. Copenhagen: Reuters. Available: http://www.reuters.com/article/idUSTRE62S12620100329 [Accessed 19 November 2010 2010]. 2) Andersen, A. H. 2010. Significant Downgrade by Vestas. Silkeborg: Jyske Bank. 3) Antoniou, A., Guney, Y. & Paudyal, K. 2008. The Determinants of Capital Structure: Capital Market-Oriented Versus Bank-Oriented Institutions. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 43, 59-59. 4) Archer, C. L. & Jacobson, M. Z. 2005. Evaluation of Global Wind Power. Journal of Geophysical Research, 110. 5) Baker, M. & Wurgler, J. 2002. Market Timing and Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 57, 1-32. 6) Bloomberg. 2011. Government Bonds [Online]. Bloomberg. Available: http://www.bloomberg.com/markets/rates-bonds/government-bonds/germany/ [Accessed 6 January 2011]. 7) Bradley, M., Jarrell, G. A. & Kim, E. H. 1984. On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence/Discussion. The Journal of Finance, 39, 857-878. 8) Brennan, M. J. & Schwartz, E. S. 1984. Optimal Financial Policy and Firm Valuation/Discussion. The Journal of Finance, 39, 593-607. 9) Byoun, S. 2008. How and When Do Firms Adjust Their Capital Structures toward Targets? The Journal of Finance, 63, 3069-3096. 10) Cadsby, C. B., Frank, M. & Maksimovic, V. 1990. Pooling, Separating, and Semiseparating Equilibria in Financial Markets: Some Experimental Evidence. The Review of Financial Studies, 3, 315-342. 11) Carpentier, C. 2006. The Valuation Effects of Long-Term Changes in Capital Structure. International Journal of Managerial Finance, 2, 4-18. 12) Chang, C., Lee, A. C. & Lee, C. F. 2009. Determinants of Capital Structure Choice: A Structural Equation Modeling Approach. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 49, 197-213. 13) Clark, B. J., Francis, B. B. & Iftekhar, H. 2009. Do Firms Adjust toward Target Capital Structures? Some International Evidence. SSRN eLibrary. SSRN. 14) Cook, D. O. & Tang, T. 2010. Macroeconomic Conditions and Capital Structure Adjustment Speed. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16, 73-87. 15) Damodaran, A. 1994. Damodaran on Valuation : Security Analysis for Investment and Corporate Finance, New York, Wiley. 16) Damodaran, A. 2007. Ratings.Xls. 17) Daves, P. R., Ehrhardt, M. C. & Kunkel, R. A. 2000. Estimating Systematic Risk: The Choice of Return Interval and Estimation Period Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions 13, 7 - 13. 18) Dichev, I. D. & Piotroski, J. D. 1999. The Performance of Long-Run Stock Returns Following Issues of Public and Private Debt. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 26, 1103-1132. 19) Drobetz, W. & Wanzenried, G. 2006. What Determines the Speed of Adjustment to the Target Capital Structure? Applied Financial Economics, 16, 941-941. 72 20) Eckbo, B. E. 1986. Valuation Effects of Corporate Debt Offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 15, 119-151. 21) Efiong, A. & Crispin, A. 2007. Wind Turbine Manufacturers; Here Comes Pricing Power. Merrill Lynch. 22) Eldomiaty, T. I. 2002. Dynamics of Firm’s Market Value, Capital Structure and Risk. New Zealand Finance Colloquium Archives. 23) Emerging Energy Research 2009. Global Wind Turbine Markets and Strategies 2009 - 2020. Emerging Energy Research. 24) Emerging Energy Research 2010. Wind Turbine Component Supply Chain Strategies: 2010 - 2025. Cambridge, MA, USA: Emerging Energy Research. 25) European Wind Energy Association 2009. Wind Energy, the Facts. Brussels: European Wind Energy Association. 26) European Wind Energy Association 2010. Wind Energy Factsheets. Brussels: European Wind Energy Association. 27) Financial Times and Harris Interactive 2010. Energy Sources Poll. New York: Financial Times/Harris Interactive. 28) First Solar 2010. First Solar Corporate Overview 2010. First Solar, Inc. 29) Fischer, E. O., Heinkel, R. & Zechner, J. 1989. Dynamic Capital Structure Choice: Theory and Tests. The Journal of Finance, 44, 19-40. 30) Flannery, M. J. & Rangan, K. P. 2006. Partial Adjustment toward Target Capital Structures. Journal of Financial Economics, 79, 469-506. 31) Frank, M. Z. & Goyal, V. K. 2003. Testing the Pecking Order Theory of Capital Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 67, 217-248. 32) Frank, M. Z. & Goyal, V. K. 2007. Trade-Off and Pecking Order Theories of Debt. SSRN eLibrary. SSRN. 33) Glader, P. 2010. G.E. Leads U.S. Wind Market but Faces More Competition. Available: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB100014240527023037206045751705003392446 26.html [Accessed 27 January 2011]. 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council. 35) Global Wind Energy Council 2010. Global Wind Energy Outlook 2010. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council. 36) Goldstein, R., Ju, N. & Leland, H. 2010. An Ebit-Based Model of Dynamic Capital Structure, Forthcoming. 37) Graham, J. R. 1996a. Debt and the Marginal Tax Rate. Journal of Financial Economics, 41, 41-74. 38) Graham, J. R. 1996b. Proxies for the Corporate Marginal Tax Rate. Journal of Financial Economics, 42, 187-222. 39) Graham, J. R. 2000. How Big Are the Tax Benefits of Debt? Journal of Finance, 55, 1901-1941. 40) Graham, J. R. 2003. Taxes and Corporate Finance: A Review. The Review of Financial Studies, 16, 1075-1129. 41) Graham, J. R. & Lemmon, M. L. 1998. Measuring Corporate Tax Rates and Tax Incentives: A New Approach. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 11, 54-65. 42) Harris, M. & Raviv, A. 1990. Capital Structure and the Informational Role of Debt. The Journal of Finance, 45, 321-349. 43) Harris, M. & Raviv, A. 1991. The Theory of Capital Structure. The Journal of Finance, 46, 297-356. 73 44) Heaton, J. B. 2002. Managerial Optimism and Corporate Finance. Financial Management, 31, 33-45. 45) Hennessy, C. A. & Whited, T. M. 2005. Debt Dynamics. The Journal of Finance, 60, 1129-1165. 46) Huang, R. & Ritter, J. R. 2009. Testing Theories of Capital Structure and Estimating the Speed of Adjustment. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44, 237-271. 47) Jalilvand, A. & Harris, R. S. 1984. Corporate Behavior in Adjusting to Capital Structure and Dividend Targets: An Econometric Study. THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 39, 127-146. 48) Jensen, M. C. 1986. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review, 76, 323-329. 49) Junfeng, L., Pengfei, S. & Hu, G. 2010. China Wind Power Outlook 2010. Chinese Renewable Energy Association and Global Wind Energy Council. 50) Kane, A., Marcus, A. J. & Mcdonald, R. L. 1984. How Big Is the Tax Advantage to Debt? The Journal of Finance, 39, 841-853. 51) Kayhan, A. & Titman, S. 2007. Firms' Histories and Their Capital Structures. Journal of Financial Economics, 83, 1-32. 52) Kenitzer, S. 2007. The Power of Multiples: Connecting Wind Farms Can Make a More Reliable - and Cheaper - Power Source [Online]. American Meteorological Society. Available: http://www.eurekalert.org/pub_releases/2007-11/ams-tpo112107.php [Accessed 19 November 2010 2010]. 53) Kim, W. S. & Sorensen, E. H. 1986. Evidence on the Impact of the Agency Costs of Debt on Corporate Debt Policy. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 21, 131-144. 54) Koller, T., Goedhart, M. & Wessels, D. 2005. Valuation, John Wiley & Sons. 55) Kraus, A. & Litzenberger, R. H. 1973. A State-Preference Model of Optimal Financial Leverage. The Journal of Finance, 28, 911-922. 56) Leland, H. E. & Pyle, D. H. 1977. Informational Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Financial Intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32, 371-388. 57) Liu, L. X. 2009. Historical Market-to-Book in a Partial Adjustment Model of Leverage. Journal of Corporate Finance, 15, 602-612. 58) Lopez, M. R. 2009. Global Market Share in Wind Turbine Manufacturers Unveiled [Online]. Available: http://www.ecoseed.org/en/wind-energy/article/8-windenergy/833-global-market-share-in-wind-turbine-manufacturers-unveiled [Accessed 19 November 2010]. 59) Loughran, T. & Ritter, J. R. 1995. The New Issues Puzzle. Journal of Finance, 50, 23-51. 60) Miller Merton, H. 1977. Debt and Taxes. THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 32, 261261. 61) Miller, M. H. 1977. Debt and Taxes. The Journal of Finance, 32, 261-275. 62) Modigliani, F. & Miller, M. H. 1958. The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment. American Economic Review, 48, 261-298. 63) Modigliani, F. & Miller, M. H. 1959. The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment: Reply. American Economic Review, 49, 655-670. 64) Modigliani, F. & Miller, M. H. 1963. Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction. American Economic Review, 53, 433-444. 65) Muradoglu, G. & Sivaprasad, S. 2006. Capital Structure and Firm Value: An Empirical Analysis of Abnormal Returns. DocStoc eLibrary. 74 66) Myers, S. C. 1977. Determinants of Corporate Borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5, 147-175. 67) Myers, S. C. 1984. The Capital Structure Puzzle. The Journal of Finance, 39, 575. 68) Myers, S. C. & Majluf, N. S. 1984. Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have. Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 187-221. 69) Office for National Statistics. 2010. Domestic Energy Consumption Per Household: By Final Use [Online]. Available: http://www.statistics.gov.uk/STATBASE/ssdataset.asp?vlnk=7287 [Accessed 19 November 2010]. 70) Pinegar, M. J. & Lease, R. C. 1986. The Impact of Preferred-for-Common Exchange Offers on Firm Value. THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE, 41, 795-815. 71) Plesko, G. A. 2003. An Evaluation of Alternative Measures of Corporate Tax Rates. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 35, 201-226. 72) Quilter, J. 2010a. Horns Rev I Offshore Wind Farm Is Shut Down. Available: http://www.windpowermonthly.com/news/1007703/Horns-Rev-I-offshore-windfarm-shut-down/ [Accessed 6 December 2010]. 73) Quilter, J. 2010b. Investigators Still Reviewing Horns Rev I Shutdown. Wind Power Monthly [Online]. Available: http://www.windpowermonthly.com/news/1010108/Investigators-reviewingHorns-Rev-I-shutdown/ [Accessed 6 December 2010]. 74) Rajan, R. G. & Zingales, L. 1995. What Do We Know About Capital Structure? Some Evidence from International Data. The Journal of Finance, 50, 14211460. 75) Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century 2010. Renewables 2010 Global Status Report. Paris: Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21st Century. 76) Renewable Uk 2010. Wind Energy Generation Costs. London: Renewable UK. 77) Rose, C. 2010. Ditlev Engel on Charlie Rose. New York. 78) Sabiwalsky, R. 2010. Nonlinear Modelling of Target Leverage with Latent Determinant Variables - New Evidence on the Trade-Off Theory. Review of Financial Economics, 19, 137-150. 79) Schmitz, S. 2010. Wind Turbine Supply: Comparing Us & Eu Markets. Infrastructure Journal. 80) Shyam-Sunder, L. & Myers, S. C. 1999. Testing Static Tradeoff against Pecking Order Models of Capital Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 51, 219244. 81) Sjoo, B. 1996. Dynamic Adjustment and Long-Run Economic Stability. Economic Modelling, 13, 427-463. 82) Sovacool, B. K. 2009. Contextualizing Avian Mortality: A Preliminary Appraisal of Bird and Bat Fatalities from Wind, Fossil-Fuel, and Nuclear Electricity. Energy Policy, 37, 2241-2248. 83) Spiess, D. K. & Affleck-Graves, J. 1995. Underperformance in Long-Run Stock Returns Following Seasoned Equity Offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 38, 243-268. 84) Stiglitz, J. E. 1969. A Re-Examination of the Modigliani-Miller Theorem. American Economic Review, 59, 784-794. 85) Stiglitz, J. E. 1973. Taxation, Corporate Financial Policy, and the Cost of Capital. Journal of Public Economics, 2, 1-34. 75 86) Talberg, M., Winge, C., Frydenberg, S. & Westgaard, S. 2008. Capital Structure across Industries. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 15, 181200. 87) The Financial Forecast Centre 2010a. Crude Oil Price Forecast. In: Crude Oil Prices - Past Trend, P. V. F. P. (ed.). 88) The Financial Forecast Centre 2010b. Usd to Eur Forecast. In: Us Dollar to Euro Currency Exchange Rate - Past Trend, P. V. F. P. (ed.). 89) The Wind Power 2010. Offshore Wind Farms. www.thewindpower.net. 90) Titman, S. & Wessels, R. 1988. The Determinants of Capital Structure Choice. The Journal of Finance, 43, 1-19. 91) United Nations Environment Programme & Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2010. Global Trends in Sustainable Energy Investment 2010. Paris: United Nations Environment Programme. 92) Vestas. 2007. It All Starts with a Loyal Supplier. Available: http://www.vestas.com/en/media/article-display.aspx?action=3&NewsID=1706 [Accessed 5 December 2010]. 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S. 94) Vestas 2010a. Interim Financial Report, First Quarter 2010. Randers: Vestas. 95) Vestas 2010b. Interim Financial Report, Second Quarter 2010. Randers: Vestas. 96) Vestas Company Announcement. 2008. V90-3.0 Mw Offshore Wind Turbine Back on the Market Again [Online]. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S Available: http://www.vestas.com/files//Filer/EN/Investor/Company_announcements/2008/ 080218-MFKUK-11.pdf [Accessed 6 December 2010]. 97) Warner, J. B. 1977. Bankruptcy Costs: Some Evidence. Journal of Finance, 32, 337-347. 98) Windfacts Table 3.1: Design Choices of Leading Manufacturers. 99) Wiser, R. & Bolinger, M. 2010. 2009 Wind Technologies Market Report. US Department of Energy. 100) World Wind Energy Association 2009. World Wind Energy Report 2009. 101) Zwiebel, J. 1996. Dynamic Capital Structure under Managerial Entrenchment. The American Economic Review, 86, 1197-1215. 76 Annexes A1. Market Definition, Size and Growth A1.1. Market Definition Vestas sums up its company vision in three words: “Wind, oil and gas”. They see themselves on a par with all other energy producers, and thus, they see themselves as part of the global energy industry. However, that is a vision for the future. On a general level, Vestas is part of the energy industry. However, at present, the wind power industry itself is still in its infancy and therefore exhibits completely different characteristics, when compared to the other, more mature energy industries, like coal and gas energy or nuclear power. The set-up costs for producing energy from wind are quite high. Therefore, a characteristic of the wind energy market is that it is highly subsidized. This way, industry incumbents are provided with an incentive to invest in and develop wind energy parks. Moreover, subsidies allow them to compete in terms of prices charged for the energy produced with producers that use fossil fuels. In time, however, after breaking even with the setting up costs, wind energy is cheap. Therefore, cost efficiency considerations related to the fact that using wind is free, should also be taken into account. Another characteristic is industry growth at an incredible pace, in contrast to conventional energy industries, which show only slightly increasing growth rates, at best. Finally, environmental considerations are probably the most obvious characteristics separating the wind industry from the established energy industries, since wind is a clean energy source. Given the differences between the industries, it would be inappropriate to place Vestas in the big picture they see themselves in, mainly because they are not competing with the large, established energy producers at the moment. Therefore, we can infer that they are operating in the wind energy industry and not the larger and all-encompassing energy industry. Moreover, they are not in the business of producing energy themselves, but producing the tools used for making energy and then selling them. Hence, the industry Vestas is directly competing in can be further limited to the wind turbine manufacturing industry. 77 One way to define the wind turbine manufacturing industry could be as “the industry dealing with the research and development, manufacture, construction, sale, and maintenance of wind turbines for residential, commercial or industrial purposes”. A1.2. Market Size The first large scale, electricity-producing windmill was built in 1888 in Cleveland, Ohio, but the wind turbine industry started off almost one century later, in the 70s. The main motivation for the boom was most likely to have been the oil crises which resulted from the Arab Oil Embargo in 1973 and the drop in Iran’s oil production in 1979. Both made oil prices soar and hence, increased focus was targeted towards finding alternative energy solutions. Danish manufacturers pioneered the industry. In terms of the market size, it will not be restricted to a certain country or region, since Vestas competes neither nationally, nor within a certain geographic area, but worldwide. It ships its products mainly in Europe, but also exports in America and Asia. Its three greatest competitors (based on market shares) are from the US, China and Germany. Over the years, the industry has grown considerably, with record double-digit growth rates sometimes going close to 50% per year, as was the case in 2008-2009. The evolution over the past years is portrayed in figures 1 and 2 presented below. The graphs depict the annual and respectively cumulative installed capacity, both worldwide and for Vestas. At the end of 2009, cumulative market size had reached a total of 158,505 installed MW worldwide30. Figure A2 Figure A1 Source: Data from Global Wind Energy Council, (2009) 30 Source: Data from Global Wind Energy Council, (2009) See 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council. p. 12. 78 Current industry size can be expressed in a series of key figures, as presented in Table A1 below. The measurements are all from the end of 2009. Table A1: Industry size indicators Market Size Indicator Installed capacity Energy production from installed capacity World consumption covered by wind power Market worth for turbine installations Number of employees worldwide Estimate 158,505 MW 163 TWh31 2%32 EUR 45 bn33 627,92734 A1.3. From Present to Future - Market Growth 2009 was a record year, with cumulative worldwide capacity growing more than ever, by as much as 32%. The global concern for a sustainable future fuelled growth in the industry. As Figure A3 shows, growth trends and strategies were specific to geographic areas. In the more established geographical markets (i.e. Europe), the tendency was towards relocating to cheaper production sites, in order to meet the production demands of an industry on its way to globalisation. The younger markets like Asia and USA started ramping up harder to close the gap between them and Europe. There were also major markets with huge potential (i.e. Canada, Brazil) entering the initial build-up stage in full swing. Figure A3 Source: Emerging Energy Research, (2009) 31 See 34) Ibid., p. 13. 32 See 100) World Wind Energy Association 2009. World Wind Energy Report 2009., p. 5. 33 See 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council., p. 8. 34 See 35) Global Wind Energy Council 2010. Global Wind Energy Outlook 2010. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council., p. 11. 79 At the end of 2009, the financial crisis struck the wind energy industry as well, having a delayed effect. Even though the same overall increasing trends in Figure A3 apply, growth has slowed down. The crisis brought about lower prices for coal and gas, which made wind too expensive and too risky in comparison. Moreover, difficulties in raising finance and the considerable increase in equity requirements for starting wind farm projects seriously affected industry growth. The failure of the 2009 Copenhagen Climate Conference participants to come to an agreement regarding CO2 prices and target requirements that would act as successors to the Kyoto Protocol further decayed the chances that growth rates would remain at the same level as the high historical ones. GWEC estimated the level of annual installed capacity at the end of the year to be only 6.41% higher than 2009, incomparable to the 47.31% registered growth from 2008 to 2009. The market is currently facing difficult times. 2010 has also been a challenging year, with the crisis still taking its toll. GWEC (Global Wind Energy Council, (2010)) estimates that the growth in installed capacity in 2010 will range from 26,753 MW in the most pessimistic but most likely scenario, to 43,152 MW in the most optimistic and least likely one. If we compare the figure to the 38,343 MW growth registered in 2009 we realize how sensitive the industry is to changes in the economy. As for the future, industry growth rates are expected to increase in the next 5 years, but at a slower pace, as quantified by GWEC35. The evolution is depicted in the figure to the right. We can clearly see that market trends are ascending. However, growth rates are below the record levels of before the financial crisis. Annual installed Figure A4 capacity growth for 2010 is only expected to amount to 6.6%, considerably less if compared to 41.3% in 2009. Annual installed capacity will slowly rise with each year, while the growth of cumulative installed capacity is characterized by a decreasing trend. Comparisons between Source: Global Wind Energy Council, (2009) 35 See 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council., p. 17. 80 Figure A5 Figure A6 Source: Data from Global Wind Energy Council, (2009) Source: Data from Global Wind Energy Council, (2009) the trends and growth rate trends are portrayed in Figures A5 and A6. Even though the market seems to be slowing down at present, market potential is enormous and there would be room for meteoric growth. Archer and Jacobson, (2005) estimate that even if only approx. 20% of the world’s wind power would be captured, it could satisfy 100% of the world’s energy demand for all purposes (6995–10177 MTOE) and over seven times the world’s electricity needs (1.6–1.8 TW). The question is whether industry and economic factors will allow producers to tap into this enormous potential for development. Figure A7 GWEC has estimated the growth of the world’s cumulative installed wind power capacity under three different scenarios. The time span is as far out into the future as 2030 (see Figure A7). In the most pessimistic scenario – the reference one – production of energy from the installed capacity will cover 4.9 – 5.6% Source: Global Wind Energy Council, (2010) of the world’s total energy demand by 2030. Under the two more optimistic scenarios – moderate and advanced – wind energy will cover 15 - 17.5% and 18.8 - 21.8%, respectively. Production of windmills will not only cover installation of new windmills, but also replacement of older and less efficient turbines that become obsolete. 81 A2. PESTEL Analysis A2.1. Political and Legal Factors Political issues have a high impact on the wind turbine industry. Governments that adhered to the Kyoto Protocol have committed themselves to lowering greenhouse gasses (GHG). As part of the package of measures that they have taken to achieve this, they set mandatory renewable energy targets (RETs) for electricity retailers, who must comply with the requirement of producing part of the supplied electricity from renewable energy sources. Hence, RETs might be considered a driving force for the turbine manufacturing industry because the higher the targets, the higher the demand for turbines and the larger the wind industry - as a whole - becomes. At the beginning of 2010, 85 countries – out of which all 27 EU countries - have RETs. The target average for EU is 20% by 202036. Currently, in the US and Canada, there are no national RETs, but some of the states have imposed local targets. 83 countries worldwide37 also have power generation promotion policies, such as feed-in tariffs, renewable portfolio standards, capital subsidies or grants, investment tax credits, sales tax or VAT exemptions etc., which provide incentives for the use of renewable energy sources. Figure A8 A2.2. Economic Factors When comparing the growth in installed capacity (both annual and cumulative) with macroeconomic variables, we notice that the evolution of the wind industry is not highly correlated to the state of the economy. By examining the graph to the right, we could conclude that there is a weak correlation to the macroeconomic indicators presented in Table A2 on the next page. It seems that the effects of the financial crisis have been combated by political efforts and financial Source: Data from World Bank 36 st See 75) Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21 Century 2010. Renewables 2010 - Global Status Report. Paris: Renewable Energy Policy Network for the 21 st Century., p.35. 37 See 75) Ibid., p. 37. 82 back-up that governments provided and by the fact that the worldwide green trend makes the industry very attractive. In fact, the real story is somewhat different. There was a rather delayed effect of the crisis. The protective regulatory measures were efficient enough to minimize the effects of the economic slump, but not to eradicate them. Growth rates have slowed down, but they are still extremely high compared to the other indices. . Table A2: Capacity Growth and Macroeconomic Variables Year Annual installed capacity growth Cumulative capacity growth Inflation, GDP deflator USA real interest rate UK real interest rate GDP growth 2005 40,50% 24,09% 4,70% 2,80% 2,60% 3,60% 2006 32,21% 25,32% 5,50% 4,60% 1,80% 4% 2007 30,31% 26,72% 5,70% 5,10% 2,60% 3,90% 2008 31,03% 28,20% 8,40% 2,90% 1,60% 1,70% 2009 47,31% 31,76% 2,70% 1,50% -0,70% -1,90% Source: Data from World Bank In the beginning of 2009, at the height of the financial crisis, the wind turbine industry was still registering record growth rates. However, things took a different turn and, by the end of 2010, it became clear that the industry would not reach projections for the year. Apart from the classical effects which were affecting all industries (low credit availability, high interest rates, collapse of equity markets), the crisis impacted on the industry in more specific ways as well. The average debt versus equity mix changed from 10% required equity to 25-30%38. Coupled with the impossibility to access funds via equity markets, it made matters worse. Moreover, in USA, the number of investors shrank to almost none. The loss of “tax equity” investors – usually large companies who were investing in renewable energy projects for the sake of tax advantages – had considerable impact on the industry across the Atlantic Ocean. Because of the crisis, a large number of investing companies recorded losses and hence, tax shields became useless. With the loss of tax advantages, investment in the wind industry rapidly declined. Combating measures were taken to insure that investment in the industry will not come to a halt. Governments worldwide committed a total of EUR 139 billion as 38 See 25) European Wind Energy Association 2009. Wind Energy, the Facts. Brussels: European Wind Energy Association., „Project Financing – Traditional Methods” section 83 ‘green stimulus’39, consisting of grants, cash for research and development, contribution to grid developments and financial assistance for projects. More and better support policies were taken on. Institutional investors and companies with strong balance sheets which had available funds continued to invest in the industry, breaching the financing gap. As a result, by the end of 2009, the industry had bounced back. Overall, the drop in total investments was only 6% less than the previous year40. Another economic factor that influences the industry is the price of other energy sources. The economic crisis brought about even lower prices for oil and fossil fuels, which made electricity producers continue to use traditional energy plants and think twice before investing in more expensive and riskier wind power projects. A2.3. Socio-cultural Factors The green tend is in full swing. Concepts like “sustainability”, “environmental awareness” and “eco-friendly” are on everyone’s lips, from average citizens, to companies, to governments. And this socio-cultural trend has seeped into every area of life. The mundane is changing and examples of that fact are abundant. People are driving more hybrid cars and living in eco-friendly houses. As a result of signing the Kyoto Protocol, companies started trading their CO2 emissions. The Dow Jones Sustainability Indexes were launched in 1999 to track the most sustainable companies worldwide. And that is not even the tip of the iceberg. The bottom line is that everyone is involved. People are concerned about the future of the planet and there is a general appeal for action to be taken. Wind energy is reaping a lot of benefits from this “green trend” because it has a lot to offer in return. That is precisely why it has become widely popular throughout society, and its popularity ratings are on the rise. To give just a few examples, a poll conducted by the Financial Times and Harris Interactive, (2010) in USA and 5 other European countries find an overwhelmingly large number of respondents favoring wind energy. In the US, 87% of respondents favour a large increase in the number of wind farms (with 50% being strongly in favour of the matter). The results for the other 39 See 91) United Nations Environment Programme & Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2010. Global Trends in Sustainable Energy Investment 2010. Paris: United Nations Environment Programme., p. 5. 40 See 34) Global Wind Energy Council 2009. Global Wind 2009 Report. Brussels: Global Wind Energy Council., p. 6. 84 countries are: Great Britain – 82% (38%), France – 77% (33%), Italy – 87% (49%), Spain - 90% (53%), and Germany – 82% (40%). A2.4. Technological Factors Competition within the industry is a driving force of turbine technology improvements and product development. Companies have kept the established threeblade, gear-driven Danish design, but the size of the turbines and their capacity has increased considerably. The industry standard is now the 1.5 MW turbine, but the race for bigger and more powerful turbines is fierce. In 2007, Enercon installed the world’s largest turbine – E112 - which totaled 6 MW. In 2008, the company broke its own record and erected the E126 model. The latter had a nameplate capacity of 6 MW, but technical revisions showed it can produce more than 7 MW. In the beginning of 2010, the Norwegian company Enova announced they are developing an offshore 10 MW turbine, which will be able to produce enough electricity to supply 3845 average UK homes41. In order to cope with the increase in capacity and furthermore, to permit the large-scale integration of wind energy sources, an improvement in transmission capacity needs to take place. The US is investing heavily in the development of a smart grid, which makes use of digital technology and involves a two-way communication between the retailer and the end user. This way, the retailer can better control energy savings. Another development is the super grid, which refers either to large international electrical grids, or grids of superior performance. Kenitzer, (2007) argues that if wind farms are connected to each other and to the main international transmission grid, differences in wind speed at various locations can be smoothed out and there will be a more or less constant supply from wind power to the electrical network. Unfortunately, access to electrical grids is one of the threats the industry is fighting against. There are numerous remote areas that have good wind but are too far from the electrical grids to merit investment at the moment. According to a factsheet of the European Wind Energy Association, (2010), electricity infrastructure is ageing rapidly and the EU needs to build 43% of the total capacity it currently has, just to 41 Domestic Data valid for 2001 consumption, retreived from 69) Office for National Statistics. 2010. Energy Consumption Per Household: By Final Use [Online]. Available: http://www.statistics.gov.uk/STATBASE/ssdataset.asp?vlnk=7287 [Accessed 19 November 2010]. 85 replace the old plants and keep pace with the increasing demand. A need for a transEuropean power grid is becoming clearer and clearer. Onshore and offshore electrical parks should be connected to national networks in order to prevent future power supply shortages. In order to do that, power lines that are decades old need to be replaced by new “electricity highways” that can cope with the increase in transmission capacity and can connect new power sources to the upgraded European grid. A2.5. Environmental Factors Apart from issues such as visual intrusion and noise, which can be solved by building more offshore than onshore farms, it has also been argued that wind parks cause damage to the ecosystems they are built in. Onshore parks cause damage to birds and bats while offshore ones, to fish and other marine wildlife. However, Sovacool, (2009) has looked into the matter of avian mortality and has found that wind farms are responsible for only 0.3 – 0.4 fatalities per GWh. Fossil fuels, on the other hand are found to be much more harmful, causing as much as 5.2 fatalities per GWh. To put the mind of those who uphold such arguments at ease, park developers such as Dong Energy for example, have complied to undergoing environmental monitoring programs to make sure no damage is done to wildlife. A2.6. General Degree of Turbulence in the Industry Environment Figure A9 depicts the relative power of each of the Figure A9: Degree of Turbulence factors mentioned in the in the Industry PESTEL analysis. As it points out, the industry is shaped by two primary factors with opposite effects: political and legal on the one hand and economic on the other. Positive measures imposed by political rule are employed in order to compensate for the mostly negative effects of the Source: collected information economic crisis. 86 The imprint of socio-cultural factors is less visible. These factors might be the underlying explanation as to why the industry took off in the first place, but in the present state, they are of less significance and no major shifts which might affect the industry are expected to stem from these factors. Therefore, they will cause little disturbance to the current state of things. The technological factors represent a threat that the industry is currently dealing with, mainly in terms of grid connectivity. These factors cause medium disturbances in the industry because they pose a menace to the development of wind parks. The last category – environmental factors - mainly comprises criticism towards the industry. Fear of damage to the environment has been alleviated by recent research, while solutions for the other environmental threats – noise and visual intrusion – can be minimized through building offshore wind parks. Therefore, the category in discussion only imposes a minor print on the shape of the industry, as skeptics will always exist. A3. Competitor Analysis At the moment, there are a Figure A10 total of 52 wind turbine manufacturers worldwide. Competition within the industry is quite fierce, with the top 10 companies having 78.7% market share and each being very close to the other in terms of market share, as the figure to the right depicts, in rounded figures. Vestas is the world’s leading Source: Data from Acher, (2010) manufacturer, with a 12.5% share, surpassing the second runner up - GE Wind Energy by only 0.1%. The most considerable ascension of 2009 was the growth of the Chinese manufacturers, 3 of which made it in the top 10 for the first time. A3.1. The top 4 The Danish manufacturer Vestas is at the helm of the industry and has been the long-standing leader. However, Vestas has seen its market share decay over the past years because of increased competitiveness. Vestas, unlike all the other manufacturers, is not relying on its home market to fuel company growth and is exporting almost all of 87 its products. In 2009, Vestas delivered 57 MW in Denmark, compared to a total of 4,707 outside of their home country. With 98.85% out of total delivered MW exported worldwide, Vestas is facing local competition on all of the markets it is shipping its turbines to. The second runner-up is the US-based GE Wind Energy, with a total share of 12.4%. The company started off under the name of “Zond” in 1980 and was subsequently acquired by Enron and then by GE during Enron’s bankruptcy proceedings. It is currently the market leader in the US, which is the country with the highest cumulative amount of wind production in the world, as of the end of 200942. Therefore, it represents a serious threat for Vestas in the race for industry leadership. The Chinese company Sinovel comes in third, with 9.2% of the market. The boom of the Chinese suppliers – lead by Sinovel - is truly impressive, China being the country with the highest amount of capacity installed in 200912. The major part of it was manufactured and erected by Sinovel (3,510 MW43 out of 26,010 MW12). The fourth-largest market share worldwide is held by the German Enercon. The company also holds the largest market share of their home market – currently third in the world based on cumulative installed capacity12. Enercon, set up in 1984, differentiates itself through the use of a more efficient direct drive or gearless wind turbine, combined with an annular generator. Most other wind turbines use a gearbox. The advantages of Enercon’s technology include improved controllability. A3.2. Competition trends Table A3 on the following page shows the two competition trends which are currently shaping the industry: the shift from oligopolistic towards monopolistic competition and the increasing importance of the Chinese manufacturers. 42 See 100) World Wind Energy Association 2009. World Wind Energy Report 2009., p. 16. 43 According to the company website: http://www.sinovel.com/Companyoverview2.html. 88 Table A3: Competition Company Vestas (Denmark) GE Wind Energy (United States) Sinovel (China) Enercon (Germany) Goldwind (China) Gamesa (Spain) Dongfang (China) Suzlon (India) Siemens Wind Power (Denmark/Germany) Repower (Germany) Acciona Windpower (Spain) Nordex 2009 12.5% 12.4% 9.2% 8.5% 7.2% 6.7% 6.5% 6.4% 5.9% 3.4% - 200844 19% 18% 5% 9% 4% 11% 4% 7% 7% 3% 4% 4% 200745 22.8% 16.6% 3.4% 14% 4.2% 15.4% 10.5% 7.1% 4.4% 3.4% 2009 rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 - 2008 rank15 1 2 9 4 8 3 11 5 6 12 7 10 2007 rank16 1 2 10 4 8 3 5 6 7 9 A3.2.1. The trend towards monopolistic competition The four-firm concentration ratio for the year 2009 totals 42.6% and shows that the industry is at the border between oligopolistic and monopolistic. In comparison, the ratios for 2008 and 2007 are 57% and 68.8%, respectively. Vestas, who had the lion’s share in 2007, decreased by as much as 10.3% in just 2 years and is seriously threatened by GE. Clearly, the industry structure is shifting because of competition forces at play. As the number of players on the market will continue to increase, competition will evolve into a monopolistic one. An effect of this shift is the fact that the market has transformed from a seller’s to a buyer’s market. Prices are now starting to follow the law of demand and the industry is becoming more and more globalised. The target of governments worldwide is to turn wind power into a commodity, and not a resource out of the reach of less developed countries. A3.2.2. The Chinese Wave As we can observe from Table A3, in 2007, there were only 2 Chinese companies in the top 10, and both of them are in the last quarter of the classification. One of the companies was Sinovel, who was on the last position of the list with 3.4% and the other was Goldwind, at number 8. In just two year’s time, Sinovel surpassed its co-national rival and entered the top 3, taking the bronze medal with 9.2% market share. 44 See 58) Lopez, M. R. 2009. Global Market Share in Wind Turbine Manufacturers Unveiled [Online]. Available: http://www.ecoseed.org/en/wind-energy/article/8-wind-energy/833-global-marketshare-in-wind-turbine-manufacturers-unveiled [Accessed 19 November 2010]. 45 See 98) Windfacts Table 3.1: Design Choices of Leading Manufacturers. 89 By 2009, Goldwind also dropped to number 5 and, interestingly enough, one additional company made its way into the top: Dongfang, currently on the 7th position. Overall, China is the country with the highest market share (22.9%), followed by Germany (17.8%, if the sales of multi-national Siemens are included). In 2009, China has increased its cumulative capacity by more than 100% 46. Junfeng et al., (2010) found that domestic turbine manufacturers now cover 70% of the market in China and are beginning to look more and more towards export markets. The underlying boost for this growth was given by the commitment made at the Copenhagen Climate Conference by the Chinese government to supply as much as 15% of the country’s electricity demand through renewable energy. This requires an unparalleled addition of capacity. Junfeng et al., (2010) produce three scenarios stating that wind energy capacity will reach 150 GW, 200 GW or 230 GW by 2020. Given that China has a total of 25.8 GW currently installed, the increase to the projected levels would truly be unprecedented, even in the case that the pessimistic scenario comes true. A4. Porter’s 5 Forces Model A4.1. Bargaining Power of Buyers The main buyers in the industry are large independent power providers (IPPs) and utilities companies, according to a Merrill Lynch report (Efiong and Crispin, (2007)). The number of turbine buyers is still relatively small and purchases are in large quantities. However, given the growing interest in wind energy, the number of buyers is increasing rapidly worldwide. Therefore, one of the shifts that the industry is currently going through is the transformation from a seller’s to a buyer’s market. As a result, individual buyers have increasingly less power, but taken together, buyers can exert more pressure for lowering prices. On the whole, their bargaining power is low to medium. It is worth mentioning that the trend is actually driven by political will, rather than an actual interest in supplying energy from wind. The enlargement of the buyer base is dictated by the degree of government support. For example, there is a higher demand of turbines in Germany than in Russia, Argentina or South Africa (Global Wind 46 See 49) Junfeng, L., Pengfei, S. & Hu, G. 2010. China Wind Power Outlook 2010. Chinese Renewable Energy Association and Global Wind Energy Council. 90 Energy Council, (2010)), even though the latter countries have better wind resources. The determining factor for higher demand is a favourable political climate. As mentioned before, an increasing number of countries is setting targets and promoting support policies. A beneficial policy landscape determines an increase in the bargaining power of buyers. The bargaining power is also influenced by the high switching costs involved. These include installation, maintenance and later on, decommissioning and replacing older turbines. Once a turbine manufacturer made a sale, the high switching costs lock buyers down, therefore determining a low bargaining power. The threat of backward integration should also be considered. From this perspective, bargaining power is low. Most of the customers in the industry are electric utilities companies and independent power producers. Integrating backwards and acquiring turbine manufacturers is not a trend because it would involve very high amounts of funds. The only case in the industry where backward integration took place was GE, who acquired Zond in 1980 from Enron, during bankruptcy proceedings. Therefore, the price of acquisition was under market value. Over the subsequent three decades, there were no other cases of backward integration. Developing an in-house turbine manufacturer is also not very plausible because of the major knowledge requirements mainly in terms of design, and engineering. On the whole, buyers presently have a low to medium bargaining power, which is, however, expected to strengthen in the future. A4.2. Bargaining Power of Suppliers As Figure A11 on the next page shows, the supply chain is highly fragmented because of the complex technical structure of the turbine. The first three supply chain categories represent bottlenecks in the supply chain, depicted in the figure by key pinch points. These are the suppliers with the highest bargaining power, due to the high concentration of the supply of important parts to a few companies. 91 Figure A11: Supply chain Source: Emerging Energy Research, (2010) However, the industry trend is towards vertical integration. Pressure is exerted on the turbine manufacturers to simultaneously lower costs and develop better turbines, which in turn exerts the same pressure on the suppliers. Hence, turbine manufacturers find themselves dependent upon their key suppliers. In 2006 and 2007, the industry was facing shortages in various components, such as blades, generators and bearings (Wiser and Bolinger, (2010)). The industry was severely affected because of this lack of production capacity. However, due to an increasing demand, it is expected that the number of suppliers will steadily increase. Integration trends are depicted in Figure A12 on the next page. Blades and towers are being produced in-house more and more. For example, Vestas, Suzlon, Nordex and Gamesa all have their own blade manufacturing facilities in China. As for towers, any company located in countries with an existing steel industry will find it convenient and cost-effective to produce domestically. Generators and gearboxes are moving closer to the turbine manufacturers by setting up regional manufacturing facilities, in order to reduce costs and time-todelivery. Wiser and Bolinger, (2010) find the same results for the American market, where a higher number of equipment pieces are being produced domestically in recent years. 92 Figure A12: Component suppliers’ strategy overview Source:Emerging Energy Research, (2010) Given the characteristics of the supply chain, we can infer than suppliers have a moderate to high bargaining power, but, given the vertical integration trends and the expectation that there will be more suppliers in the future, their bargaining power is expected to diminish. A4.3. Threat of New Entrants The threat of new entrants is dependent upon industry entry and exit barriers. The most important barriers to entry in the wind turbine industry include capital requirements, patents, know-how and economies of scale. As one might suspect, capital requirements for Figure A13: Cost breakdown of a 2 MW turbine establishing a manufacturing plant are huge, in the millions of EUR and in double and even triple digit numbers. The requirements for building wind farms are large as well. The cost of a 2MW wind turbine installed in Europe in 2006 was as much as to EUR 1,227. 76% of that cost is represented by the turbine itself (see Figure A13). According to the European Wind Energy Association, (2009), typical deal financing for a wind farm project is 70-75% loan and 25-30% equity. In all, it amounts to a high investment, making the industry less accessible to new entrants. 93 Source: European Wind Energy Association, (2009) If acquiring financing is deemed possible, the next barriers to overcome are to acquire know how (since the industry is highly technical) and more importantly, to make sure there are no infringements to existing patents. The best known case was Enercon’s denial to export products to the US because of a patent that Kenetech registered before Enercon could do so. Thus, Kenetech prohibited the German company’s access to the market until 2010 (Schmitz, (2010)). If a company manages to surpass the obstacles outlined above, it will still have major difficulties competing with the more established producers, who benefit from high economies of scale. Barriers to exit are determined by the high costs involved and the relatively long payback period. This might demotivate companies to enter the industry. Despite numerous and generally high barriers, governments extensively use policies in order to encourage investments in the industry. High demand for wind power also attracts investors in the industry. In conclusion, the fact that the industry is considered attractive, there is a medium to high threat of new entrants, despite the medium to high entry and exit barriers. It is expected to intensify. A4.4. Threat of Substitute Products Substitutes for wind power might Figure A14: Carbon footprint of energy sources include power from fossil fuels (gas, oil, coal), nuclear fusion, as well as other renewable sources (solar photo-voltaic cells (PV), waves and rivers, biomass). The question to address is whether they are true substitutes. By analyzing the economics of Source: First Solar, (2010) wind and comparing it with other sources, we can find some answers to the question posed. Out of all energy sources, wind is the least harmful to the environment. Its carbon footprint is exactly 75 times smaller than that of coal (see Figure A14). It is also the most cost-effective. Onshore wind is the second least expensive power source, after gas, in terms of capital outlay. Their slightly higher operating and maintenance costs are offset by the fact that wind is free, unlike other fuels (see Table A4). 94 Table A4: Costs used to derive energy Technology Gas Coal Nuclear Onshore wind Offshore wind Capital cost (EUR/kW) 770 1,955 2,370-3,555 1,540-1,896 2,963-4,266 O&M cost (EUR/kW/yr) O&M cost (EUR/MWh) 4.7 8.3 10.6-13 Fuel cost (2009 avg, EUR/MWh) 16.6 8.9 7.7 63 93 Source: figures in GBP from Renewable UK, (2010), converted to EUR at GBP 1.185/EUR The cost curve has a downward slope with the speed of the wind, as shown in Figure A15. The graph depicts two types of wind turbines: a GBP 1,300/kW or EUR 1,540 and a GBP 1,600/kW or EUR 1,893. If set up in areas with sufficient wind (moderate to fresh breeze on the Beaufort scale), turbines can generate cheaper electricity than coal and nuclear energy. Naturally, the bigger the turbine, the cheaper the electricity becomes (Figure A16). Figure A15: Generation costs of onshore wind and other power sources Figure A16: Generation costs of offshore wind sources Source: Renewable UK, (2010) Source: Renewable UK, (2010) However, the future evolution of prices is entirely another matter. Wiser and Bolinger, (2010) reports that 2009 saw a sharp drop in the price of wholesale electricity, largely driven by natural gas prices. The discovery of gas deposits lowered expectations of an increase in the price of natural gas. On the wind turbine market, prices are starting to ease, but they remain overall high by historical standards. Therefore, it is safe to say that fossil fuels remain a very attractive substitute, cost-wise. Governments have a decisive word to say with regards to the future. Pressure is exerted on governments to further pave the way for renewables. Whether they will, and to what extent, is going to determine how high the threat of substitute energy sources will be. In conclusion, the threat of substitute products is medium-to-high, but given the advantages of wind power, it is expected to slowly decrease. 95 A4.5. Competitive Rivalry within the Industry As discussed in Annex A3 – Competitor Analysis, rivalry within the industry is quite strong. Hence, we can label this force as having a high impact. The fact that the industry is quite concentrated is an effect of the medium to high entry barriers. What’s more, the industry is becoming more and more consolidated. The big fish are eating the small fish in an attempt to improve market share. In the US alone, 11 acquisitions were announced in 2007, 5 transactions in 2008 and 6 in 2009, according to Wiser and Bolinger, (2010). Companies’ market share is determined more by how much they can produce, rather than issues such as product or brand differentiation, product positioning or company strategy. All the producers are continuously striving for technological improvements that would allow them to erect higher and more powerful turbines. Moreover, they are all relocating production facilities in cheaper counties (China, US and Spain) in an attempt to keep costs as low as possible. Another thing they have in common is that they mostly focus on their home markets (all except for Vestas, who is exporting throughout the world). The fact that they are all following the same pattern makes rivalry more intense. In business strategy terms, industry competition is turning the ocean red. Added pressure from increasing prices of raw materials (e.g. steel) and components’ shortages (such as in 2008) intensifies rivalry. Moreover, the large, established producers, such as Vestas and GE are watching their market shares shrink because of fast growing companies, such as the Chinese ones, which have newly entered in the top 10. However, apart from Vestas, all the other companies are largely relying on their home market and exporting very little. So far, very few direct conflicts have been registered (for example, the Kenetech Enercon patent dispute in the US which ended with preventing Enercon from entering the American market). Given all the issues briefly outlined above, competitive rivalry within the industry is medium and the trend is towards intensifying. 96 A5. Internal Analysis A5.1. Corporate Vision, Mission and Strategy Vestas’ strategy statements are as follows: vision – “Wind, oil and gas”; mission – “Failure is not an option”; strategy – “Number 1 in modern energy”; values / principles – “Cost of energy”, “Business case certainty”, “Easy to work with”. The company vision provides the target and long term focus of development. Vestas strives to create a world in which wind is as important a power source as oil and gas. They expect that by 2020, a total of 10% of the world’s energy supply will come from wind47. In a strategic management sense, the mission puts into words a shorter term perspective. For Vestas - “Failure is not an option”, meaning that they will pave the way for wind generated electricity, while improving company efficiency. They are committed to a Triple15 target (an EBIT margin of 15% on a revenue of EUR 15bn by 2015), to which failure does not apply. If they grow, wind grows as well, so they aim to see wind on the same level with the traditional energy sources, because they have not only a business to defend, but a planet. Vestas has proven that they are sticking to their vision and mission. Throughout time, they have shown their resilience. Despite the financial crisis that brought despair to many industries, Vestas managed to achieve record revenue and EBIT (revenue was 9.96% higher than the previous year, while EBIT was 28.14% higher). Another example of their determination is the fact that they invested EUR 160m in building a tower plant in Colorado, US. They proved to be committed to the US market, even though they did not receive any order on the US market that year48. The strategy of the company explains how they aim to accomplish their vision. In this sense, Vestas wants to be “Number 1 in modern energy”, not only in terms of market share, but also in terms of safety standards, performance of power plants, 47 48 See 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S., p. 15. Information retrieved from Ditlev Engel interview: 77) Rose, C. 2010. Ditlev Engel on Charlie Rose. New York. 97 customer satisfaction and green production. So far, they have managed to achieve that. At the moment, they have the lion’s share of the worldwide market: 12.5%. In terms of safety, the number of accidents in 2009 is 42.6% smaller than in 2008 and is at a record low. When it comes to performance, Vestas is constantly undertaking measures of prevention for power plant optimization through maintenance and monitoring of their turbines. Customer satisfaction is measured yearly by Vestas through the customer loyalty index, which went up to 64 in 2009 from 52 in the previous year. As for green production, 49% of the energy they used in 2009 was renewable and 85% of their electricity consumption was also from renewable sources, the latter being a record achievement. In conclusion, Vestas’ strategy statements are not just a marketing trick and the company truly lives up to them and by them. A5.2. Product and Service Mix Vestas produces 9 types of onshore turbines ranging from 850 kW to 3 MW and 2 types of offshore ones, both with a nameplate capacity of 3 MW. The company is currently developing a 6MW offshore turbine, which will determine the cost of energy to plummet, compared to any other energy sources. The company wants to increase the share of offshore turbines it installed, which is currently only at 2%. Throughout the year 2009, Vestas produced and shipped 3,320 wind turbines totaling 6,131 MW in aggregate capacity, compared to 6,160 MW and 3,250 wind turbines in 2008. As for the company’s service mix, Vestas has the following areas of focus: installation, maintenance and repair. The main support functions that enable it to serve customers are the Performance & Diagnostics Centre and the Vestas Spare Parts & Repair. The former is responsible for monitoring more that 15,500 turbines worldwide, accounting for 26,600 MW, or 69% of Vestas’ total installed capacity. The latter supports the company’s service units and is responsible for supplying spare parts and repairs of key components worldwide. Vestas expects the same growth for the demand of its services, as for its products. 98 A5.3. Geographic & Business Segments Vestas is operating in 3 geographic Figure A17: Distribution of employees at the end segments covering the entire world (Europe, of 2009 by geographic and business segments Americas and Asia/Pacific). The company has production plants, sales and service units and R&D functions in all of them. As expected, Europe is the largest, both in terms of revenue, and in terms of number of people employed (see Figures A17 and A18). It accounts for 68% of both its number of employees and its revenue. The Americas hold 11% of the number of employees and 21% of revenue, while Asia/Pacific Source: Vestas, (2009) Figure A18: Distribution of 2009 revenue by geographic segments (mEUR) 21% and 11%, respectively. Compared to the previous year, Vestas had 0.5% less employees and there was a shift from Europe to the Americas and Asia/Pacific, most notably in the production units. As for revenue, the distribution was 60% from Europe, 26% from the Source: Vestas, (2009) Americas and 14% from Asia/Pacific. This clearly points out once again that at the moment, Europe is the driving force in the industry, as well as the most powerful market, since it is also the oldest one. Figure A19: Segment financials 2009 Figure A20: Segment financials 2008 Source: Vestas, (2009) Source: Vestas, (2009) The same conclusion is also drawn by looking at each segment’s financials (Figures A19 and A20). Global revenues grew by 15%, Europe’s sales units accounting for exactly 10% out of the 15% increase (two thirds). Americas and Asia/Pacific sales units decreased, and the rest was contributed by the production facilities. 99 Historically, Vestas has had more than a steady Figure A21 revenue stream, and has always managed to improve its yearly sales figures. It has had record growth in 2004, registering a growth of 55%. At the other extreme is the growth was from 2006 when they recorded a 7.6% rate. Figure A21 depicts revenue evolution from 2002 to 2009. A5.4. Business Model Source: data from financial reports Figure A22: The business model Source: StrategyLab A5.4.1. Infrastructure Vestas’ core capabilities lie in the technology they use, their green production process and their corporate culture, which is committed to the concept of “green”. Their partner network includes suppliers, with which the company works very closely, to the point that some of the employees are even located with the suppliers and assist them in developing customised parts specific to the needs of Vestas. To some extent, governments worldwide are also in the partner network, since politics are fueling growth in the industry. The value configuration of the company is a traditional, self-owned value chain with more than 1,000 partners worldwide. The company is not outsourcing any of their primary or support activities. They are only buying components from their suppliers and are producing their own blades, nacelles and towers in their dedicated production facilities. Distribution is also made through their own channels, serving each of the main geographic segments. 100 A5.4.2. Offer What Vestas offers is a mix of one particular product and a bundle of support services. The product is represented by an entire green energy system: the turbine. The company does not separate the three main components (blades, nacelle and tower), but sees them as a unitary system. The additional services offered are installation, maintenance and repair. A5.4.3. Customers The target customers of Vestas are energy park developers or independent power providers, therefore, large companies such as Dong. However, Vestas is also servicing smaller companies with its more petite, but versatile 850 kW turbines: V52 and V60. Vestas reports that their revenue of 2009 came from 201 customers, 27 less than the previous year49. The company also aims for larger customers in the future, as mentioned in their last annual report. The relationship with customers is characterized by direct contact. It is a close, long-term relationship. Because of the fact that sales are made directly by Vestas, who also provides service and support for the windmills, the company is always in touch with its clients. Vestas is continually improving its customers’ satisfaction, measured by the customer loyalty index. In 2009, it reached a record of 64. In order to reach its customers, Vestas uses its own direct distribution channels. It has set up sales departments in all three geographic segments in which it operates. Europe brings in the largest amount of revenue, followed by the Americas and Asia/Pacific. A5.4.4. Finance Cost structure is divided between raw materials and consumables, direct labour, indirect expenses such as salaries, depreciation of production facilities, rental and lease expenses, as well as provisions for losses. The total cost of sales for 2009 amounted to EUR 5,195m, but the cost breakdown is not reported by the company. Revenue streams, as depicted in Figures A18 – A20 in Section A5.3., come from three major geographical segments that span the world and in each, from production and sales of turbines, as well as from services rendered to customers. 49 See 93) Vestas 2009. Annual Report 2009. Randers: Vestas Wind Systems A/S., p. 16. 101 Historically, the company has managed to increase its revenues yearly, as depicted in Figure A21 in Section A5.3. In conclusion, Vestas has a sound business model, which was tried and tested for almost a quarter of a century and has overcome even the most difficult developments, such as the financial crisis of recent years. 102 A6. SWOT Analysis The present SWOT analysis represents an overview of all the issues presented in Annexes A1-A5. A6.1. Strengths Vestas’ strengths mainly fall within 3 large categories: company strategy, finance and lastly, product and production. A6.1.1. Company strategy Vestas was the first major turbine manufacturer. Later on, Vestas became the first turbine manufacturer to ever set up wind turbines offshore. The company installed its first turbines off the shores of Sweden in 1990. The company has thus benefitted from a first mover advantage. Vestas is still the company with the highest amount of installed and operating MW, both worldwide and also offshore (1313.2 MW, rated by nameplate capacity, compared to 1083.1 MW installed by Siemens, according to The Wind Power, (2010)). Vestas has also supplied turbines for the largest offshore park in the world – Thanet in Great Britain, a sign that they want to make the most of the benefits of being a first mover. The fact that Vestas is currently the world market leader is thus a result of the first mover advantage. Clearly, this is one of the company’s biggest strengths, but that does not protect them from the threat of competition. Even though their market shares have been decreasing because of competition and other factors, they are committed to remaining “No.1 in modern energy”, as they mention in their strategy statements. In keeping with the trend of making wind energy more mainstream, another opportunity might be the fact that Vestas is positioning itself as a „modern energy producer”, not a „wind energy producer”. It shifted to another much larger and much more profitable industry. A6.1.2. Finance The fact that they have always given customers a reliable product translated into a steady financial growth over the years and continuously improved earnings. 103 A6.1.3. Product and Production Process The strong relationship with suppliers is another strength of the company. Vestas realized the importance of a strong connection with the suppliers during the supplies shortage, when the company’s bottom line turned red. Therefore, the company has taken some measures to prevent repercussions like these from re-occurring in the future. In autumn 2007, it has rolled out a Supplier Loyalty programme in which 110 of Vestas’ biggest suppliers are part of (Press Release Vestas, (2007)). In recent years, it has relocated some of its employees at its suppliers. Moreover, some key suppliers have become more closely involved in the development process at Vestas, with the intention to reduce costs and improve overall quality (Vestas, (2009)). Their in-house manufacturing helps them keep costs under control, while still delivering leading products. One of the strengths of Vestas is the fact that it is in the forefront of technological advances. Vestas has the largest R&D department, with offices in all of their market segments (Europe, America and Asia). The R&D department is continually making innovating improvements to existing products and bringing to market bigger better windmills. At the moment, they are working on the 6 MW offshore turbine, which is currently one of the segments where companies are competing fiercely in. No other company has put a 6MW model on the market, but several companies have announced coming models (Siemens, Gamesa and Enercom). Enercom is currently testing the 6 MW E-126 onshore in Germany. Diversity of employees might also be an advantage because it brings together a lot of different ways of thinking. Innovation might be easier in a diverse environment. They employ Lean in their production processes and are also aiming to reach 6sigma by the end of 2010. The company has a great deal of production flexibility. It operates manufacturing plants in Denmark, Germany, India, Italy, Britain, Spain, Sweden, Norway, Australia, China, and the United States. 104 A6.2. Weaknesses A6.2.1. Production process On the weaknesses side, it is fair to mention the overall high costs of supply parts and manufacturing that lead to a high price of the windmill. To these, even higher grid connection and maintenance costs are added, especially for offshore parks. A6.2.2. Company image The pressure to reduce the overall high costs lead the company to close down some of its production facilities and relocate to cheaper sights. They have closed down operations in the UK (Isle of Wight) in July 2009, laying off a total of 624 people on Isle of Wight and in Southampton. Protests from a group of ex-employees followed soon after the announcement. A6.2.3. Product weaknesses Vestas has experienced various operational problems with its turbines, which might shed unfavourable light on the quality of the turbines. For example, the V90 offshore turbine of 3 MW was withdrawn from the market for over one year due to problems with its gearbox. It was re-released for offshore use on 1 May 2008 (Vestas Company Announcement, (2008)). In June 2010, part of the largest offshore park in Denmark, Horns Rev 1 was shut down due to a malfunction in its transformer station (Quilter, (2010a)). Previously, the same park was affected by a design fault in the towers, causing the turbines to slide (Quilter, (2010b)). A6.3. Opportunities A6.3.1. The Regulatory Environment Opportunities encompass first of all the environmental trend, which is supported through regulations, agreements and treaties. The Kyoto Protocol is an international treaty signed in 1997, and which entered into force in 2005. It currently binds a number of countries worldwide to targets set for the reduction of greenhouse gasses. The Protocol was open for signing between 16 March 1998 and 15 March 1999 and totaled 84 signatory states that also ratified the Protocol. Currently, the number is 194 (193 states and one regional economic integration organization – the EU). Wind energy is one of the most vastly employed 105 solutions to help countries reach those targets, due to its advantages, discussed in Annex 3.4. Threat of Substitute Products. Either in the attempt to reach targets they have committed to, or for other reasons, governments are trying to boost this industry by employing many different types of “green stimulus” etc. In the USA – currently the number one country by installed capacity50 - the industry boom of 2009 was largely due to the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA), enacted by the Congress in February 2009. The bill provides production or investment tax credits, as well as tax credits for new manufacturing facilities. It also provides the framework for a USD 6 billion loan guarantee program, which was particularly beneficial during the economic downturn. In the second largest country by installed capacity20, China, a wind feed-in tariff system helps increase the profitability of both offshore and onshore wind farms. The tariff encourages developing larger wind parks by linking wind park size directly to the tariff rate: the bigger the park, the more generous the rate. Other countries, currently not in the top 10 of World Wind Energy Association, (2009), are ramping up and trying to reach higher green energy levels. Australia passed a “20% by 2020” law in August 2009 and Japan set a national target to reduce greenhouse gasses by 25% until 2020. Moreover, there are other political measures that are not directly connected to the wind industry, but that might positively affect the industry. For example, in July 2008, the EU Parliament voted for extending the Emissions Trading Scheme to the Aviation Industry after 2012. After 2012, countries might start investing more in wind energy because they are aware that they have to balance the greenhouse gasses emissions from aircrafts with using more renewable energy, to avoid buying extra carbon credits. A6.3.2. Recent industry evolutions Backward integration might be a way to consolidate the business in the more distant future. A number of competitors are already backward integrated, so there is a trend in the industry towards larger, more diversified companies. Siemens, Suzlon, GE Energy and Gamesa have all incorporated gearbox producers. Vestas already produces nacelles and blades and towers and might want to integrate some of its key suppliers as well, in order to secure a steady flow of parts. At the moment, Vestas’ strategy is only 50 See 100) World Wind Energy Association 2009. World Wind Energy Report 2009., p. 8 106 to fortify the relationship with suppliers through loyalty programmes and other measures, but shifts in competition structure might affect Vestas’ future strategy. Rising oil prices are advantageous for wind energy, because they make wind and other renewable energy sources more appealing. 2009 was an all-time-low record year because of the financial crisis. 2010 saw crude oil prices peak in May and then plummet and stay low until September. However, they’ve started to go up again and the current quotes are around EUR 66.72 per barrel51. The Financial Forecast Centre, (2010a) estimated the future rising trend, forecasting prices to rise to around EUR 75 per barrel as early as April 2011. A6.4. Threats A6.4.1. Government Regulations Firstly, the industry’s dependence on government regulations might turn out to be a two edged sword. First of all, there is the threat that government aid will be reduced, which will affect all renewables, not only wind. Moreover, Vestas faces a lot of uncertainty about the future of the US market. The USA lacks a binding national target for the share of renewables in electricity production, since it has not ratified the Kyoto Protocol. There are a number of states that have self-imposed targets, but many voices have called for a national renewable energy standard (RES). Lastly, “green stimulus” does not target wind energy in particular, but renewable energy in general. The reason why wind energy took off compared to the other green energy sources is that the installation and maintenance costs to energy output ratio is the most advantageous. If some other technology is developed that would have a better cost-output ratio, there will be a massive shift within the renewable energy industry towards that new technology, to the detriment of turbine manufacturers. Therefore, wind energy might be “number one”, but its pedestal is somewhat frail. A6.4.2. International Agreements The Kyoto Protocol provided stimulus for the industry by setting 2012 renewable energy targets. However, there have been no agreements regarding targets after 2012. Negotiations of country representatives participating in COP14 in Poznan, 51 Yahoo Finance quote from 9 December 2010. 107 Poland and COP15 in Copenhagen, Denmark, have failed to result in renewed targets. In December 2010, all eyes fall on the COP16 Summit in Cancun, Mexico. A6.4.3. High Pressure to Keep Costs Low Costs are a major issue because these are an important factor determining competitiveness. Turbine manufacturers are under a twofold pressure when it comes to costs. They need to keep their own costs low, while producing better turbines which minimise the costs of generating electricity. Keeping costs low is also starting to be dictated by market forces. There is a transition from a seller’s to a buyer’s market. Therefore, it will no longer be the producers who are setting the prices, but the customers, which implies that producers must become more cost effective and perhaps even try to differentiate their products in the future. Dependence on government regulations is also a threat from the cost perspective, because it might prevent companies from becoming more cost efficient, knowing that subsidies will work for them, for example. With the increasing pressure to keep prices low, less subsidies will mean that Vestas has to become more efficient in its production in order to match the offers of its new competitors. A6.4.4. Economic environment risks The low dollar is negatively affecting Vestas’ bottom line, especially since the Americas are the second largest geographical segment. The Financial Forecast Centre, (2010b) estimates that the USD to EUR exchange rate will fall to as little as 1.25 by March 2011, from a current average rate for December of 1.406. A6.4.5. Industry risks There is an intense competition among turbine producers to secure suppliers. Demand for wind turbines increased much rapidly than forecasted by suppliers, who have lagged behind and are trying to ramp up capacity to reach demand from turbine manufacturers, especially on the generator front. Vestas’ competitors are trying to secure the supply of parts and raw materials, which induced a trend toward vertical integration in the industry. Therefore, turbine manufacturers scramble to acquire some of their key suppliers or to get them to enter exclusive arrangements. 108 Another threat is the fact that there are numerous substitute products, contrasted in Annex A3.4. Threat of Substitute Products. Yet another factor with a negative impact is the fact that there is limited access to electricity grids around the world. Current grids are close to maximum transmission capacity and an improved super-grid structure connecting “electricity highways” is being called for. 109 A7. Reorganisation of Financial Statements A7.1. Invested Capital EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- Invested Capital Operating Working Capital 226 534 659 627 900 538 181 548 1.316 Net Property Plant and Equipment 115 164 281 321 469 466 490 638 1.030 1.461 Other Assets Net of Other Liabs 8 5 5 4 9 5 11 13 25 16 Less: Short Term Warranties Provision 0 (42) (51) (58) (104) (138) (139) (154) (128) (111) Less: Long Term Warranties Provision (43) (21) (35) (39) (64) (83) (66) (107) (85) (82) 69 71 52 159 53 57 185 126 235 636 Value of Operating Leases Op. Invested Capital (excl.Goodwill) (9) 375 710 912 1.014 1.264 845 662 508 1.625 3.236 Goodwill & Intangibles 6 5 35 59 449 477 478 507 644 812 Cumulative Written Off & Amortized 1 2 3 5 22 52 85 114 146 206 382 717 951 1.078 1.735 1.375 1.225 1.129 2.415 4.254 Excess Marketable Securities 11 0 0 0 141 55 368 667 41 355 Investments 22 1 1 1 3 12 12 1 1 1 Non-operating Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total Investor Funds 416 718 951 1.078 1.880 1.442 1.604 1.797 2.457 4.611 Total Common Equity & Pref. Stock 3.364 Op. Invested Capital (incl.Goodwill) 215 528 596 613 1.251 962 1.262 1.516 1.955 Cum Goodwill Written Off & Amortized 1 2 3 5 22 52 85 114 146 206 Deferred Income Taxes 0 (11) (10) (15) (75) (140) (162) (154) (63) (110) 14 21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 6 7 8 21 39 50 40 Dividends Payable Short Term Income Smotthing Provision Long Term Income Smoothing Provision 11 26 44 61 38 9 36 3 9 121 241 566 634 670 1.243 891 1.242 1.518 2.097 3.621 Minority Interest 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Restructuring Provisions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement-Related Liabilities 0 0 0 1 1 2 3 2 2 2 106 81 266 248 582 492 174 150 123 351 Adjusted Equity Interest Bearing Debt Value of Operating Leases Total Investor Funds 69 71 52 159 53 57 185 126 235 636 416 718 951 1.078 1.880 1.442 1.604 1.797 2.457 4.611 110 A7.2. NOPLAT EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- NOPLAT Reported EBITA 134 75 76 8 (85) 218 472 700 916 Adj for Operating Leases 3 2 5 2 2 9 8 14 50 Adj for Non-operating component of pension expense 0 0 0 0 (0) 1 1 (1) 0 Add: Interest associated with Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Add: Increase in Short Term Income Smoothing Provision 0 0 6 1 0 13 18 11 (10) Add: Increase in Long Term Income Smoothing Provision Adjusted EBITA 15 19 17 (23) (29) 28 (33) 6 112 152 95 103 (12) (113) 268 466 730 1.068 (154) (195) Taxes on EBITA 47 (21) (30) 5 (39) (59) Change in Deferred Taxes (11) 1 (5) (60) (65) (22) NOPLAT 188 75 68 (66) (217) (254) 8 91 (47) 187 319 626 767 Taxes on EBIT Prov for Inc Taxes 50 15 18 (12) 33 50 152 203 230 Tax Shield on Interest Exp 6 7 11 8 7 14 5 5 16 Tax Shield on Operating Lease Interest 1 1 2 0 0 3 2 4 13 Tax Shield on Non-operating component of pension expense 0 0 0 0 (0) 0 0 (0) 0 Tax Shield on Interest associated with Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (2) (1) (1) (2) (1) (3) (5) (17) (4) Tax on Interest Income Tax on Non-operating Income (102) 0 (1) 0 0 (4) 0 0 (47) 21 30 (5) 39 59 154 195 254 Net Income 322 45 36 (39) (192) 111 291 511 616 Add: Increase in Deferred Taxes (11) 1 (5) (60) (65) (22) 8 91 (47) Add: Increase in Short Term Income Smoothing Provision 0 0 6 1 0 13 18 11 (10) Add: Increase in Long Term Income Smoothing Provision 15 19 17 (23) (29) 28 (33) 6 112 Add: Goodwill Amortization 1 1 2 17 30 33 29 32 60 Add: Extraordinary Items 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (37) 0 Taxes on EBIT (0) Reconciliation to Net Income Add: Special Items After Tax 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 184 65 55 (102) (255) 162 313 651 694 Add: Interest Exp. After Tax 9 10 13 43 42 36 14 15 47 Add: Interest Exp. On Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Add: Interest Exp. on Op. Leases 2 1 3 1 2 7 6 11 38 Add: Minority Interest Adjusted Net Income Add: Interest Exp. on Non-operating component of pension expense Income Available to Investors Add: Restructuring Charges Less: Interest Income After-Tax Less: Non-operating Income After Tax NOPLAT (143) 0 0 0 0 194 76 71 (58) (0) 1 1 (212) 205 334 (1) 676 0 778 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (2) (2) (1) (9) (5) (8) (14) (50) (11) (4) 188 0 (1) 0 75 68 (66) 111 0 (217) (11) 187 0 0 319 626 (1) 767 A7.3. Free Cash Flow EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- Free Cash Flow NOPLAT 188 75 68 (66) (217) 187 319 626 767 35 57 74 128 93 91 109 103 158 223 131 142 62 (124) 277 428 729 925 (308) (125) 33 (273) 362 357 190 (556) (768) (72) (118) (86) (90) (107) (160) (265) (521) (606) Incr in other operating assets/liabilities (8) (56) (27) (190) 20 39 6 14 26 Incr in Short Term Warranties Provisions 42 8 8 45 35 1 15 (26) (17) Incr in Long Term Warranties Provisions (21) 14 25 19 (17) 41 (22) (3) (2) 19 (107) 106 (3) (128) 58 (109) (401) Depreciation Gross Cash Flow Increase in Working Capital Capital Expenditures Inv in Operating Leases 4 Gross Investment (370) (259) (175) (378) 326 92 46 (1.220) (1.769) Free Cash Flow Excl. Goodwill (147) (127) (34) (316) 202 369 474 (491) (844) (32) (25) (407) (58) (33) (59) (169) (228) (159) (59) (724) 143 336 416 (660) (1.072) Investment in Goodwill and Intangibles 0 Free Cash Flow Incl. Goodwill (147) AT Interest Income 2 2 1 11 (0) 0 Foreign Exchange Translation 0 (4) (Incr)/Decr Retirement Related Assets 0 0 169 Restructuring Cash Flow Extraordinary items (Incr)/Decr Excess Mkt Sec Non-operating Cash Flow Cash Flow Available to Investors 14 50 11 (141) 9 87 5 (313) 8 (299) 625 (314) (5) (2) 4 (2) (10) (43) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 (3) (9) 12 11 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 37 36 (161) (61) (861) 231 41 131 (28) (1.338) AT Interest Expense 9 10 13 43 42 36 14 15 47 Interest on Operating Leases 2 1 3 1 2 7 6 11 38 Interest on Nonoperating Component of Pension Expense 0 0 0 0 (0) 1 1 (1) 0 Interest on Long-term Operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Financing Flow 0 Decr/(Incr) in Debt 25 (185) 18 (334) 90 318 24 27 (228) Decr/(Incr) in Operating Leases (109) (401) (2) 19 (107) 106 (3) (128) 58 Decr/(Incr) in Retirement Rel. Liab 0 0 (1) 0 (1) (1) 1 0 0 Decr/(Incr) in Long-term Operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Payments to Minorities 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 Common Dividends 7 42 11 0 0 0 0 0 0 Preferred Dividends 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Decr/(Incr) in Preferred 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Decr/(Incr) in Share Capital (5) (48) 3 (678) 102 (191) 27 29 Total Financing Flow 36 (161) (61) (861) 231 41 131 (28) 0 (793) (1.338) A7.4. Return on Invested Capital EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- Return on Invested Capital (BY) Net PPE / Revenues 9,0% 11,7% 17,0% 12,5% 13,1% 12,1% 10,1% 10,6% 15,5% Working Capital / Revenues 17,6% 38,3% 39,9% 24,5% 25,1% 14,0% 3,7% -0,1% 8,3% Net Other Assets / Revenues 2,7% 0,8% -1,7% 2,6% -2,9% -4,1% -0,2% -2,0% 0,7% 3,4 2,0 1,8 2,5 2,8 4,6 7,3 11,9 Rev. / Inv. Capital (pre-Goodwill) Pre-Tax ROIC 40,4% 13,4% 11,3% -1,1% -8,9% 31,8% 70,3% Cash Tax Rate -24,0% 21,5% 33,7% -472,4% -91,9% 30,5% 50,1% 10,6% 7,5% -6,5% -17,2% 22,1% 1,7 2,4 After-Tax ROIC (pre-Goodwill) Rev. / Inv. Capital (incl. Goodwill) After-Tax ROIC (incl. Goodwill) 3,3 1,9 2,1 2,8 4,1 143,8% 65,7% 31,4% 14,2% 28,2% 48,2% 123,4% 47,2% 4,0 5,3 2,7 49,2% 10,4% 7,2% -6,2% -12,5% 13,6% 26,1% 55,5% 31,8% Net PPE / Revenues 10,9% 16,0% 18,2% 15,4% 13,1% 12,4% 11,6% 13,8% 18,8% Working Capital / Revenues 29,7% 42,8% 38,9% 29,8% 20,1% 9,3% 1,8% 4,5% 14,0% Net Other Assets / Revenues 1,8% -0,6% 1,1% -0,8% -3,7% -2,2% -1,3% -0,6% 3,8% 2,4 1,7 1,7 2,2 3,4 5,1 8,3 5,7 Return on Invested Cap (Avg) Rev. / Inv. Capital (pre-Goodwill) 2,7 Pre-Tax ROIC 28,0% 11,8% 10,7% -1,0% -10,7% 35,6% 79,6% 68,5% 44,0% After-Tax ROIC (pre-Goodwill) 34,7% 9,2% 7,1% -5,8% -20,6% 24,7% 54,6% 58,7% 31,6% After-Tax ROIC (incl. Goodwill) 34,2% 9,0% 6,8% -4,7% -14,0% 14,3% 27,1% 35,3% 23,0% Average ROE 86,6% 8,0% 5,9% -4,2% -17,3% 10,0% 21,0% 29,4% 23,2% 112 A7.5. Revenue Growth EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- Growth Rates Revenue Growth Rate 47,6% 8,9% 18,5% 55,0% 39,9% 7,6% 26,1% 24,2% 10,0% Adjusted EBITA Growth Rate NA -37,1% 8,3% -111,2% 875,5% -337,4% 73,5% 56,8% 46,3% NOPLAT Growth Rate NA -60,1% -8,5% -196,8% 227,1% -186,0% 71,3% 96,1% 22,5% 87,5% 32,6% 13,4% 61,0% -20,8% -10,9% -7,9% 114,0% 76,1% 320,5% -86,0% -21,1% -210,1% 388,5% -157,9% 162,4% 75,6% 20,5% Invested Capital Growth Rate Net Income Growth Rate A8. Interest Coverage Year EBIT EBITDA EBITDAR Interest Rental Expense Interest & Rental Expense EBIT/Interest & Rental Expense EBITDA/Interest & Rental Expense EBITDAR/Interest & Rental Expense 2000 93,1 115,8 122,7 2001 132,6 168,6 175,5 2002 73,7 131,3 136,8 2003 74,2 149,2 168,9 2004 -9,1 136 148,3 2005 -115,7 7,5 20,2 2006 184,9 308,3 330,1 2007 443 581 592,0 2008 668 803 823,0 2009 856 1074 1123,0 7,2 6,9 14,1 15 6,9 21,9 16,6 5,5 22,1 24,2 19,7 43,9 50,9 12,3 63,2 48,4 12,7 61,1 50,1 21,8 71,9 19 11 30,0 20 20 40,0 62 49 111,0 6,6 8,2 8,7 6,1 7,7 8,0 3,3 5,9 6,2 1,7 3,4 3,9 -0,1 2,2 2,3 -1,9 0,1 0,3 2,6 4,3 4,6 14,8 19,4 19,7 16,7 20,1 20,6 7,7 9,7 10,1 113 A9. Historical Analysis Results A9.1. Income Statement EUR 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Income Statement Revenues Other Operating Revenues 868 1.281 1.395 1.653 2.561 3.583 3.854 4.861 6.035 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 6.636 0 (717) (1.065) (1.200) (1.432) (2.317) (3.375) (3.325) (3.974) (4.767) (5.073) Selling, Gen & Admin Expenses (35) (47) (64) (71) (108) (128) (165) (240) (375) (449) Depreciation Expense (22) (35) (57) (74) (128) (93) (91) (109) (103) (158) 0 0 0 0 0 (73) (56) (66) (90) (40) Reported EBITA 94 134 75 76 8 (85) 218 472 700 916 Amortization of Goodwill (1) (1) (1) (2) (17) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (30) (33) (29) (32) (60) Reported EBIT 93 133 74 74 (9) (116) 185 443 668 856 Non-Oper Income 25 19 0 1 (0) (0) 16 0 0 1 3 4 3 3 10 6 11 19 66 14 Cost of Goods Sold Other Oper Expense Intangibles Amort. (Excl. Goodwill) Interest Income (7) (15) (17) (24) (51) (48) (50) (19) (20) (62) Restructuring Charges 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Special Items 3 246 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Earnings Before Taxes 117 386 60 54 (50) (158) 161 443 714 809 Income Taxes (40) (50) (15) (18) 12 (33) (50) (152) (203) (230) 0 0 0 0 (1) 0 0 0 0 0 77 337 45 36 (39) 111 291 511 579 Interest Expense Minority Interest Income Before Extraordinary Items Extraordinary Items (After Tax) Net Income Preference dividends Earnings for common shareholders 0 0 0 0 0 77 337 45 36 (39) 0 0 0 0 0 77 337 45 36 (39) (192) 0 (192) 0 (192) 0 0 0 37 111 291 511 616 0 0 0 0 111 291 511 616 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 77 337 45 36 (39) (192) 111 291 511 616 Earnings per share (EUR) 730,86 3.211,46 430,42 339,40 (280,08) (1.094,84) 606,93 1.571,24 2.759,12 3.115,47 Earnings per share - fully diluted (EUR) 730,86 3.211,46 430,42 339,40 (280,08) (1.094,84) 606,93 1.571,24 2.759,12 3.115,47 Common dividends Retained profit 114 0 A9.2. Balance Sheet EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Balance Sheet Operating Cash 17 21 21 20 51 72 77 97 121 133 Excess Marketable Securities 11 0 0 0 141 55 368 667 41 355 Accounts Receivable 163 338 692 777 1.290 621 711 660 938 525 Inventories 247 402 223 193 436 698 881 1.107 1.612 1.663 Other Current Assets 0 0 0 0 0 540 466 452 833 1.359 Total Current Assets 439 760 937 990 1.918 1.985 2.502 2.983 3.545 4.035 Net Property Plant and Equipment 115 164 281 321 469 466 490 638 1.030 1.461 Goodwill 3 2 1 11 308 322 320 320 320 320 Other Intangible Assets 3 3 34 48 141 156 158 187 324 492 Other Operating Assets 8 5 5 4 9 5 11 13 25 16 22 1 1 1 3 12 12 1 1 1 Deferred tax asset 0 11 10 15 75 140 162 154 63 110 Other Non-operating Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 591 945 1.269 1.390 2.924 3.085 3.654 4.296 5.308 6.435 65 38 153 142 110 51 11 25 109 12 106 123 148 212 404 520 808 889 1.030 1.062 145 Investments Total Assets Short term debt Accounts Payable Tax payable Dividends payable Short Term Income Smoothing Provisions Short Term Warranties Provisions 1 8 6 5 17 50 33 73 42 14 21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 6 7 8 21 39 50 40 0 42 51 58 104 138 139 154 128 111 Other Current Liabilities 96 95 124 146 456 822 1.114 1.363 1.884 1.157 Total Current Liabilities 281 327 481 570 1.098 1.589 2.125 2.543 3.243 2.527 Balancing Debt 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Long Term Debt 41 43 113 106 472 441 163 125 14 339 Deferred Income Taxes 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Other Operating Liabilities 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Restructuring Provisions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Long Term Income Smoothing Provisions 11 26 44 61 38 9 36 3 9 121 Long Term Warranties Provisions 43 21 35 39 64 83 66 107 85 82 Long-term operating Provisions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Liabilities 0 0 0 1 1 2 3 2 2 2 Minority Interest 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Preferred Stock 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total Common Equity 215 528 596 613 1.251 962 1.262 1.516 1.955 3.364 Total Liabs and Equity 591 945 1.269 1.390 2.924 3.085 3.654 4.296 5.308 6.435 115 A9.3. Cash Flow Statement EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Traditional Cash flow Reported EBITA Depreciation EBITDA Less investment in working capital Foreign exchange translation effects Operating cashflow Less tax paid 134 75 76 8 (85) 218 472 700 35 57 74 128 93 91 109 103 158 169 131 149 136 7 308 581 803 1.074 (316) (123) 33 (286) 329 375 149 (525) (2) 4 (10) (43) 0 (4) (5) (2) 916 (871) 0 (147) 5 178 (151) 341 681 720 235 203 (53) (17) (24) (36) (65) (90) (104) (143) (174) (72) (118) (160) (265) (521) (606) Capital investments Less capex Less investment Less goodwill & intangibles acquired Short Term Warranties Provision Long Term Warranties Provision Less other operating assets/liabilities Total capital investments (86) (90) (107) 22 0 0 (3) (9) 1 11 0 (32) (25) (407) (58) (33) (59) (169) (228) 42 (21) 8 14 8 4 45 25 35 19 1 (17) 15 41 (26) (22) (17) (3) (8) (56) (27) (190) 20 39 (38) (184) (126) (621) (100) (169) 6 (250) 0 0 14 26 (724) (828) Finance Interest Income 4 3 3 10 6 11 19 66 14 Interest Expense (15) (17) (24) (51) (48) (50) (19) (20) (62) Debt raised/repaid (25) 185 (18) 334 (90) (318) (24) (27) 228 Total finance payments (36) 171 (39) 294 (133) (357) (24) 19 180 1 Plus non-operating income &expense Non-Oper Income 19 0 1 (0) (0) 16 0 0 246 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Extraordinary items 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 37 Investment in non-operating assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 265 0 1 (0) (0) 16 0 0 38 Restructuring charges 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Short Term Income smoothing Provision 0 0 6 1 0 13 18 11 (10) Long Term Income Smoothing Provision Special items Total non-operating items Less payments from reserves and to minorities 15 19 17 (23) (29) 28 (33) 6 112 Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Liabilities 0 0 1 0 1 1 (1) 0 0 Minority interest 0 0 0 (1) 0 0 0 0 0 15 19 24 (23) (28) 42 (16) 17 102 Less pref dividends paid 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Prefs issued/(redeemed) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Less dividends paid 7 (21) 0 0 0 0 0 0 Equity raised/repaid (24) 27 (14) 678 (102) 191 (27) (29) 793 Total equity cash payments (17) 6 (14) 678 (102) 191 (27) (29) 793 Net Cashflow (11) 0 (0) 141 (87) 313 299 (625) 314 Total payments to reserves/minorities Equity 116 0 A9.4. NOPLAT EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ NOPLAT Reported EBITA 134 75 76 8 (85) 218 472 700 916 Adj for Operating Leases 3 2 5 2 2 9 8 14 50 Adj for Non-operating component of pension expense 0 0 0 0 (0) 1 1 (1) 0 Add: Interest associated with Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Add: Increase in Short Term Income Smoothing Provision 0 0 6 1 0 13 18 11 (10) Add: Increase in Long Term Income Smoothing Provision Adjusted EBITA Taxes on EBITA 15 19 17 (23) (29) 28 (33) 6 112 152 95 103 (12) (113) 268 466 730 1.068 (154) (195) 53 (21) (30) 5 (39) (59) Change in Deferred Taxes (11) 1 (5) (60) (65) (22) NOPLAT 194 75 68 (66) (217) 187 (254) 8 91 (47) 319 626 767 A9.5. Invested Capital EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Invested Capital Operating Working Capital 226 534 659 627 900 538 181 548 1.316 Net Property Plant and Equipment 115 164 281 321 469 466 490 638 1.030 1.461 Other Assets Net of Other Liabs 8 5 5 4 9 5 11 13 25 16 Less: Short Term Warranties Provision 0 (42) (51) (58) (104) (138) (139) (154) (128) (111) Less: Long Term Warranties Provision (43) (21) (35) (39) (64) (83) (66) (107) (85) (82) 69 71 52 159 53 57 185 126 235 636 375 710 912 1.014 1.264 845 662 508 1.625 3.236 Goodwill & Intangibles 6 5 35 59 449 477 478 507 644 812 Cumulative Written Off & Amortized 1 2 3 5 22 52 85 114 146 206 382 717 951 1.078 1.735 1.375 1.225 1.129 2.415 4.254 Excess Marketable Securities 11 0 0 0 141 55 368 667 41 355 Investments 22 1 1 1 3 12 12 1 1 1 Non-operating Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement Related Assets 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Total Investor Funds 416 718 951 1.078 1.880 1.442 1.604 1.797 2.457 4.611 Total Common Equity & Pref. Stock 3.364 Value of Operating Leases Op. Invested Capital (excl.Goodwill) Op. Invested Capital (incl.Goodwill) (9) 215 528 596 613 1.251 962 1.262 1.516 1.955 Cum Goodwill Written Off & Amortized 1 2 3 5 22 52 85 114 146 206 Deferred Income Taxes 0 (11) (10) (15) (75) (140) (162) (154) (63) (110) 14 21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 6 7 8 21 39 50 40 Dividends Payable Short Term Income Smotthing Provision Long Term Income Smoothing Provision 11 26 44 61 38 9 36 3 9 121 241 566 634 670 1.243 891 1.242 1.518 2.097 3.621 Minority Interest 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Restructuring Provisions 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Long-term operating Provision 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Retirement-Related Liabilities 0 0 0 1 1 2 3 2 2 2 106 81 266 248 582 492 174 150 123 351 Adjusted Equity Interest Bearing Debt Value of Operating Leases Total Investor Funds 69 71 52 159 53 57 185 126 235 636 416 718 951 1.078 1.880 1.442 1.604 1.797 2.457 4.611 117 A9.6. Free Cash Flow EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Free Cash Flow NOPLAT 194 75 68 (66) (217) 187 319 626 767 35 57 74 128 93 91 109 103 158 229 131 142 62 (124) 277 428 729 925 (308) (125) 33 (273) 362 357 190 (556) (768) (72) (118) (86) (90) (107) (160) (265) (521) (606) Incr in other operating assets/liabilities (8) (56) (27) (190) 20 39 6 14 26 Incr in Short Term Warranties Provisions 42 8 8 45 35 1 15 (26) (17) Incr in Long Term Warranties Provisions (21) 14 25 19 (17) 41 (22) (3) (2) 19 (107) 106 (3) (128) 58 (109) (401) Depreciation Gross Cash Flow Increase in Working Capital Capital Expenditures Inv in Operating Leases 4 Gross Investment (370) (259) (175) (378) 326 92 46 (1.220) (1.769) Free Cash Flow Excl. Goodwill (141) (127) (34) (316) 202 369 474 (491) (844) (32) (25) (407) (58) (33) (59) (169) (228) (159) (59) (724) 143 336 416 (660) (1.072) Investment in Goodwill and Intangibles Free Cash Flow Incl. Goodwill AT Interest Income 0 (141) 2 2 1 11 (0) 0 Foreign Exchange Translation 0 (4) (Incr)/Decr Retirement Related Assets 0 0 178 Restructuring Cash Flow Extraordinary items (Incr)/Decr Excess Mkt Sec Non-operating Cash Flow Cash Flow Available to Investors 14 50 11 (141) 87 (313) (299) 625 (314) (5) (2) 4 (2) (10) (43) 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 (3) (9) 12 11 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 37 231 41 131 51 (161) (61) 118 9 (861) 5 8 (28) (1.338) A9.7. Financial Ratios EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ----------------- ------------------ Ratios Adjusted EBITA / Revenues Cost of Goods Sold / Revenues SGA costs / Revenue EBITDA / Revenue Depreciation / Revenues Reported EBITA / Revenues 82,6% 83,2% 86,0% 86,7% 90,5% 94,2% 86,3% 81,8% 79,0% 4,0% 3,7% 4,6% 4,3% 4,2% 3,6% 4,3% 4,9% 6,2% 6,8% 13,3% 13,2% 9,4% 9,0% 5,3% 2,2% 9,5% 13,3% 14,8% 16,8% 2,5% 2,7% 4,1% 4,4% 5,0% 2,6% 2,4% 2,2% 1,7% 2,4% 10,9% 10,4% 5,4% 4,6% 0,3% -2,4% 5,6% 9,7% 11,6% 13,8% Adjustments to EBITA / Revenues Adjusted EBITA / Revenues 76,4% 1,4% 1,5% 1,7% -0,8% -0,8% 1,3% -0,1% 0,5% 2,3% 11,8% 6,8% 6,3% -0,5% -3,2% 7,0% 9,6% 12,1% 16,1% Return on Invested Capital (BY) Net PPE / Revenues 9,0% 11,7% 17,0% 12,5% 13,1% 12,1% 10,1% 10,6% 15,5% Working Capital / Revenues 17,6% 38,3% 39,9% 24,5% 25,1% 14,0% 3,7% -0,1% 8,3% Net Other Assets / Revenues 2,7% 0,8% -1,7% 2,6% -2,9% -4,1% -0,2% -2,0% 0,7% 3,4 2,0 1,8 2,5 2,8 4,6 7,3 11,9 Rev. / Inv. Capital (pre-Goodwill) Pre-Tax ROIC 40,4% 13,4% 11,3% -1,1% -8,9% 31,8% 70,3% Cash Tax Rate -28,0% 21,5% 33,7% -472,4% -91,9% 30,5% 51,7% 10,6% 7,5% -6,5% -17,2% 22,1% 1,7 2,4 After-Tax ROIC (pre-Goodwill) Rev. / Inv. Capital (incl. Goodwill) 3,3 After-Tax ROIC (incl. Goodwill) 1,9 2,1 2,8 4,1 143,8% 65,7% 31,4% 14,2% 28,2% 48,2% 123,4% 47,2% 4,0 5,3 2,7 50,7% 10,4% 7,2% -6,2% -12,5% 13,6% 26,1% 55,5% 31,8% Net PPE / Revenues 10,9% 16,0% 18,2% 15,4% 13,1% 12,4% 11,6% 13,8% 18,8% Working Capital / Revenues 29,7% 42,8% 38,9% 29,8% 20,1% 9,3% 1,8% 4,5% 14,0% Net Other Assets / Revenues 1,8% -0,6% 1,1% -0,8% -3,7% -2,2% -1,3% -0,6% 3,8% 2,4 1,7 1,7 2,2 3,4 5,1 8,3 5,7 Return on Invested Cap (Avg) Rev. / Inv. Capital (pre-Goodwill) 2,7 Pre-Tax ROIC 28,0% 11,8% 10,7% -1,0% -10,7% 35,6% 79,6% 68,5% 44,0% After-Tax ROIC (pre-Goodwill) 35,8% 9,2% 7,1% -5,8% -20,6% 24,7% 54,6% 58,7% 31,6% After-Tax ROIC (incl. Goodwill) 35,3% 9,0% 6,8% -4,7% -14,0% 14,3% 27,1% 35,3% 23,0% Average ROE 90,6% 8,0% 5,9% -4,2% -17,3% 10,0% 21,0% 29,4% 23,2% Growth Rates Revenue Growth Rate 47,6% 8,9% 18,5% 55,0% 39,9% 7,6% 26,1% 24,2% 10,0% Adjusted EBITA Growth Rate NA -37,1% 8,3% -111,2% 875,5% -337,4% 73,5% 56,8% 46,3% NOPLAT Growth Rate NA -61,4% -8,5% -196,8% 227,1% -186,0% 71,3% 96,1% 22,5% 87,5% 32,6% 13,4% 61,0% -20,8% -10,9% -7,9% 114,0% 76,1% 339,9% -86,6% -21,1% -210,1% 388,5% -157,9% 162,4% 75,6% 20,5% Gross Investment Rate 161,5% 197,0% 123,6% 613,8% 262,5% -33,2% -10,7% 167,3% 191,3% Net Investment / NOPLAT 172,6% 270,2% 148,9% -376,9% 193,0% -98,0% -48,5% 178,4% 210,1% Invested Capital Growth Rate Net Income Growth Rate Investment Rates (excl. Goodwill) Financing EBIT/Interest Payable 8,8 4,4 3,1 (0,2) (2,4) 3,7 23,3 33,4 13,8 Adjusted EBITA/Interest payable 10,1 5,7 4,3 (0,2) (2,3) 5,4 24,5 36,5 17,2 Cash Coverage (Gross CF / Interest) 15,3 7,9 5,9 1,2 (2,6) 5,5 22,5 36,5 14,9 Debt / Total Cap (Book) Debt / Total Cap (Market) 31,9% 12,7% 29,3% 26,7% 31,0% 33,4% 11,7% 8,8% 5,8% 9,1% 1,7% 2,4% 20,5% 14,7% 26,9% 16,7% 2,8% 1,1% 1,6% 3,8% Valuation indicators Mkt Val Op Inv Cap/ BV Op Inv Cap 4,8 1,4 1,7 1,2 2,8 8,1 25,0 4,3 2,6 Market / Book (incl. Cum Goodwill) 4,7 1,4 1,7 1,2 2,1 4,8 11,8 3,3 2,2 22,3 13,2 16,6 (134,6) (21,1) 19,9 27,3 9,7 7,8 Mkt val Op Inv Cap / Adj EBITA Enterprise value / EBITA 67,3 25,0 17,0 21,9 (217,6) (24,8) 31,0 29,8 11,4 10,1 Price Earnings Ratio 80,7 9,6 21,8 38,6 (39,3) (12,7) 53,4 47,1 14,8 14,1 119 A10. Base Case Scenario Valuation Inputs A10.1. Detailed forecast EUR 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- Operations P&L Operating Revenue: % Growth Operating revenues 868 47,6% 1.281 8,9% 1.395 18,5% 1.653 55,0% 2.561 39,9% 3.583 7,6% 3.854 26,1% 4.861 24,2% 6.035 10,0% 6.636 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 NA 0 83% (717) 83,2% (1.065) 86,0% (1.200) 86,7% (1.432) 90,5% (2.317) 94,2% (3.375) 86,3% (3.325) 81,8% (3.974) 79,0% (4.767) 76,4% (5.073) 84,0% (5.073) 84,0% (8.116) 84,0% (8.928) 84,0% (9.820) 84,0% (10.803) 4% (35) 3,7% (47) 4,6% (64) 4,3% (71) 4,2% (108) 3,6% (128) 4,3% (165) 4,9% (240) 6,2% (375) 6,8% (449) 6,0% (362) 6,0% (580) 6,0% (638) 6,0% (701) 6,0% (772) 0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 2,0% (73) 1,5% (56) 1,4% (66) 1,5% (90) 0,6% (40) 1,0% (60) 1,0% (97) 1,0% (106) 1,0% (117) 1,0% (129) 2% 17 1,6% 21 1,5% 21 1,2% 20 2,0% 51 2,0% 72 2,0% 77 2,0% 97 2,0% 121 2,0% 133 2,0% 121 2,0% 193 2,0% 213 2,0% 234 2,0% 257 Inventories: % Revenue Inventories 29% 247 31,4% 402 16,0% 223 11,7% 193 17,0% 436 19,5% 698 22,8% 881 22,8% 1.107 26,7% 1.612 25,1% 1.663 22,0% 1.329 22,0% 2.126 22,0% 2.338 22,0% 2.572 22,0% 2.829 Acc Rec: % Revenues Accounts receivable 19% 163 26,4% 338 49,6% 692 47,0% 777 50,4% 1.290 17,3% 621 18,4% 711 13,6% 660 15,5% 938 7,9% 525 8,0% 483 8,0% 773 8,0% 850 8,0% 935 8,0% 1.029 Acc. Pay: % Revenues Accounts payable 12% 106 9,6% 123 10,6% 148 12,9% 212 15,8% 404 14,5% 520 21,0% 808 18,3% 889 17,1% 1.030 16,0% 1.062 16,0% 966 16,0% 1.546 16,0% 1.701 16,0% 1.871 16,0% 2.058 0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 0,0% 0 15,1% 540 12,1% 466 9,3% 452 13,8% 833 20,5% 1.359 15,0% 906 15,0% 1.449 15,0% 1.594 15,0% 1.754 15,0% 1.929 OCL: % Revenues Other current liabilities 11% 96 7,4% 95 8,9% 124 8,8% 146 17,8% 456 23,0% 822 28,9% 1.114 28,0% 1.363 31,2% 1.884 17,4% 1.157 16,0% 966 16,0% 1.546 16,0% 1.701 16,0% 1.871 16,0% 2.058 Total operating working capital WC increase/(decrease) WC: % Revenues 227 542 316 42,4% 665 123 47,7% 632 (33) 38,2% 917 286 35,8% 588 (329) 16,4% 213 (375) 5,5% 64 (149) 1,3% 590 525 9,8% 1.461 871 22,0% 906 (555) 15,0% 1.449 543 15,0% 1.594 145 15,0% 1.753 159 15,0% 1.929 175 15,0% Other Revenue: % Growth Other revenues COGS: % Revenue Cost of Goods Sold SGA: % Revenue SGA Other Op Exp: % Revenue Other Operating Expense -9,0% 6.039 0 60,0% 9.662 0 10,0% 10.628 0 10,0% 11.691 0 10,0% 12.860 0 Working capital Op Cash: % Revenue Operating cash OCA: % Revenues Other current assets 26,1% 120 A10.2. Key Driver Forecast EUR Revenue growth Revenue 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 20 --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- --------------- ----------9,0% 8,0% 8,0% 7,0% 7,0% 7,0% 6,0% 6,0% 6,0% 6,0% 6,0 14.018 15.139 16.350 17.495 18.719 20.030 21.231 22.505 23.856 25.287 26.80 Adjusted EBITA margin Adjusted EBITA 7,2% 1.007 7,2% 1.088 7,2% 1.175 7,2% 1.257 7,2% 1.345 7,2% 1.439 7,2% 1.525 7,2% 1.617 7,2% 1.714 7,2% 1.817 7,2 1.92 Cash tax rate NOPLAT 29,6% 709 29,6% 766 29,6% 827 29,6% 885 29,6% 947 29,6% 1.013 29,6% 1.074 29,6% 1.138 29,6% 1.207 29,6% 1.279 29,6 1.35 Closing Net PPE as % Revenues Net PPE 13,7% 1.920 13,7% 2.074 13,7% 2.240 13,7% 2.397 13,7% 2.565 13,7% 2.744 13,7% 2.909 13,7% 3.083 13,7% 3.268 13,7% 3.464 13,7 3.67 Other Invested Capital as % Revenues Other Invested Capital Invested Capital (pre-Goodwill) 23,9% 3.355 5.275 23,9% 3.623 5.697 23,9% 3.913 6.153 23,9% 4.187 6.583 23,9% 4.480 7.044 23,9% 4.793 7.537 23,9% 5.081 7.990 23,9% 5.386 8.469 23,9% 5.709 8.977 23,9% 6.052 9.516 23,9 6.41 10.08 Cumulative Goodwill Invested Capital Net Investment 2.768 8.043 436 2.768 8.465 422 2.768 8.921 456 2.768 9.352 431 2.768 9.813 461 121 2.768 10.306 493 2.768 10.758 452 2.768 11.237 479 2.768 11.745 508 2.768 12.284 539 2.76 12.85 57