Local and Community-Driven Development Historical Roots and the Evolution of World Bank Programs Hans P. Binswanger Steen Lau Jorgensen Jacomina de Regt March 11, 2006 1 Table of Contents Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 3 Box 1: Linking Community Empowerment, Decentralized Governance, and Sector Approaches to Local Development ............................................................................. 5 Part 1: A sampling of historical experiences ...................................................................... 6 1.1 Sector-specific approaches........................................................................................ 6 Box 2: From Specialized Agricultural Credit Institutions to Micro-Finance ............. 8 1.2 Community Development in India............................................................................ 9 Box 3: The Comilla Model of Rural Development .................................................. 10 1.3 Technology-led production programs ..................................................................... 10 1.3 Technology-led production programs ..................................................................... 11 1.4 Programs for special areas and special target groups ............................................. 12 Box 4: Slow progress in Decentralization ................................................................ 12 1.5 Integrated Rural Development and Area Development Programs ......................... 13 Box 5: Participatory appraisal and planning ............................................................. 14 1.6 Non-governmental approaches ............................................................................... 15 1.6 Key Lessons of History........................................................................................... 16 Part 2: Local and Community-Driven Development in the World Bank since 1990 ....... 17 2.1. Towards the synthesis ............................................................................................ 17 2.2 How well are the vision and the tools being implemented? ................................... 20 Box 7: Table ES1 of the OED report here ................................................................ 21 2. 3 How did the separate approaches evolve ............................................................... 22 2.3.1 Participation and de-concentration in sectoral programs ................................. 22 Water supply ......................................................................................................... 23 Urban development ............................................................................................... 23 Natural resource management............................................................................... 23 Nutrition ................................................................................................................ 23 2.3.2 Breaking out of the sectors: Social Funds and AGETIPs ................................ 23 Social Funds .......................................................................................................... 24 AGETIPS .............................................................................................................. 24 2.3.3 Fostering Participation: The Sourcebook......................................................... 24 2.3.4 Decentralization approaches to local development.......................................... 24 2.3.4 Community-driven Development in a Decentralization Context .................... 26 Mexico .................................................................................................................. 26 Brazil ..................................................................................................................... 29 Indonesia ............................................................................................................... 31 Subsaharan Africa ................................................................................................. 31 2.3.5 The development of community-based disbursement and procurement mechanisms ............................................................................................................... 31 2.4 The future agenda for LCDD .................................................................................. 32 From Messy Boutiques to Scaled up LCCD ............................................................. 32 Applying the guiding principles................................................................................ 33 Scaling up.................................................................................................................. 33 References ..................................................................................................................... 33 2 Introduction The idea of poverty-reducing rural development, and of involving communities in their own development, has deep historic roots. Mahathma Ghandi considered rural uplifting and reconstruction an essential feature of his program. He advocated communal harmony, economic equity, social equality, abstinence from alcohol and narcotics, promotion of 'khadi' (hand spun and hand woven cloth) and village industries, sanitation, health care, education and empowerment of women. In the last sixty years developing countries and their development partners have struggled to implement this vision. In particular many ways have evolved in which governments and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) support local communities. While it is difficult to do justice to the many different approaches, they can broadly be grouped into three broad models, that we will use in the later discussion of different development programs: 1. Under the “Service Delivery model,” government agencies or NGOs consult communities, but operate as direct service providers via their own staffs. This model is particularly widespread in the provision of health and education services, but is sometimes also used where it may be less appropriate. This was the model which was most often used in agricultural extension services and to deliver investments and services in many early community development programs and the area development programs which will be discussed later. In order to produce the services and infrastructure, a dedicated permanent staff is needed, with the associated management, incentives, and sustainability problems this implies. 2. Under the “Intermediary model”, government agencies or NGOs work directly with communities, but take a strong management role in community efforts, including in project design and choice of technology, the contracting of service providers, and in the management of funds for the community projects. While this approach has the potential of gradually building community capacities, in practice it often tends to limit community empowerment. Because government organization or NGO take on management functions, they need significant staff resources and managerial overhead to manage this approach. While NGOs can use flexible contracting and financial management procedures, government agencies have to operate under government accountability rules, making the contracting and disbursement processes unwieldy. 3. Under the “Empowerment model” the government agencies or NGOs operate primarily as facilitators and trainers to enable communities to identify their own priorities and carry them out. Communities are heavily involved in the design and choice of technology for their project. For small projects they usually manage the project money and directly contract for goods and services to implement them. 3 The successful Aga Khan Foundation programs in Pakistan and India, and the Onchocerciasis eradication program in Africa utilize this approach. Communitydriven development, as defined today by the World Bank, also uses the empowerment model. Community-development does not exist in a vacuum, but instead is a component of broader local and national development. An International Conference on Local Development held in Washington in June 2004 was the culmination of a long process by which various approaches to local and community development and service delivery were synthesized into a coherent framework. Box 1 provides excerpts from the Local Development Framework Paper written for this conference (World Bank 2005b). 4 Box 1: Linking Community Empowerment, Decentralized Governance, and Sector Approaches to Local Development Three alternative approaches to local development—decentralized sector approaches, local government approaches, and community support approaches—emphasize many of the same principles: empowerment of the poor and other marginalized groups, responsiveness to beneficiary demand, autonomy of local institutions, associated with greater downward accountability, and enhancement of local capacities. Although the three approaches all aim to provide public facilities and services at the local level, they organize their efforts differently. While sector approaches organize according to the functions to be performed or the services to be provided, local government approaches organize based upon the territorial jurisdiction under a legally autonomous authority. The basis of community support approaches is the social unit through which people organize, either traditionally or voluntarily, to make and act upon collective decisions. As a result of these fundamental differences, each approach has generated a distinct body of theory and practice relevant to supporting local development. To complement the services provided by sectoral agencies and local governments, programs using highly decentralized, participatory and demand-based methods such as community driven development (CDD) have demonstrated considerable success in getting resources to their intended beneficiaries and in achieving rapid impacts. Community Support Approaches Local Government Approaches Linked Approaches Decentralized Sectoral Approaches A decentralized and integrated approach involves organizing interventions around local territorial units such as districts, municipalities, or communes. Community-based organizations (CBOs), local governments, and deconcentrated sectoral agencies, as well as private organizations such as NGOs and firms, should be linked more coherently in order to support improved empowerment, governance, service provision, and private sector growth. A spatially framed approach, which links such local organizations through their respective roles and relationships at local government and community levels [emphasis added], promises to improve coordination, synergy, efficiency, and responsiveness in local development processes. Source: World Bank, Local Development Framework Paper, 2005 5 To achieve an integrated local development outcome, the new consensus makes community-driven development and integral part of local development, and involves the support of sector agencies and programs. What was emerging in this process could no longer be captured by the term “Community-Driven Development” but instead had become a framework for Local Development. Therefore we will are now consistently using the term “Local and Community-Driven Development (LCCD),” a terminology which clearly states who is supposed to be in empowered and be in charge. In part 1 the paper will provide a sample of historical examples of agricultural and rural development which have been tried and scaled up until about the 1990s. The concepts and vocabulary just discussed will be used to make this section more understandable. As we shall see, the development of the recent consensus was far from linear, and instead characterized by brilliant blueprints and pilots, by significant successes and large scale failures, and by protracted intellectual battles among the advocates of alternative approaches. Most strikingly we will see that the key ideas of combining empowerment, decentralization, and sector-specific expertise have long historical roots. This section closes with a set of conclusions and lessons. Part 2 of paper then deals with the Evolution of Local and Community-Driven Development over the past decade and a half, the slow emergence of the consensus just discussed, and the progress in implementing the new consensus. Of course the World Bank effort built on the global experience and its failures and successes. Part 1: A sampling of historical experiences 1.1 Sector-specific approaches Historically, systematic government support to agricultural development started with sector-specific approaches and programs which were usually focused on increasing agricultural production rather than poverty reduction, and tended to take advantage of the best agricultural opportunities. Today’s enormous canal irrigation systems in South Asia, China, Egypt, Mexico, Brazil are the legacy of sector-specific irrigation bureaucracies. From 1965 to 1986 irrigation projects were about 25 percent of the total agricultural and rural development lending of the World Bank (World Bank, 1987). Other sector-specific approaches involve agricultural research and extension, roads and water supply, health and education, forestry, land administration, and targeted agricultural credit (Box 2). They all used the service delivery model of community involvement, and almost never involve local governments. As discussed in the World Development Report of 2003a on Service Delivery, many of the sector-specific central bureaucracies have failed their users, and in particular the poor. Many of these agencies were and are still far too centralized and, not accountable to the users. Some are engaged in rent seeking, if not in outright corruption. They spend a disproportionate share of their resources on staff and offices in the capitals, and have rarely been capable of delivering services to the rural poor. In many countries efforts are underway to make these agencies more accountable to users, de-concentrate their staffs 6 and services, or devolve their part or all of their direct service delivery functions to local governments or communities, such as irrigation associations. 7 Box 2: From Specialized Agricultural Credit Institutions to MicroFinance Specialized agricultural credit institutions were one of the most important sector specific programs set up all over the World. India, for example, developed a comprehensive system of cooperative land development banks for investment credit and of agricultural credit societies for seasonal input credits. These systems built cooperative savings and loan associations, which they then federated into the larger systems. From 1965 to 1973 about a quarter of World Bank agricultural lending was for agricultural credit, with the largest financial support to India, Pakistan, Brazil, Mexico, and Morocco. These credit institutions were used by the other programs which are discussed in this chapter, including integrated rural development programs. Almost no selfsufficient institutions emerged out of this approach, and most systems ended up with a large number of dysfunctional and bankrupt primary credit societies. Moreover, most of the benefits from credit subsidies provided by these systems were captured by the rural elites, the better-off and well connected farmers. These failures led the World Bank to stop supporting specialized agricultural credit institutions. (World Bank, 1987). In the 1990s the focus shifted to micro-finance institutions, which emphasized savings as much as credit, and which had poverty reduction as a main objective. Spectacular example of scaling up are the micro-finance institutions in Bangladesh, such as the Grameen Bank, or the Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC). The high population density helped reduce transactions costs, and the high agricultural intensity, often with three crops during the year, increased economic opportunities year round. In other areas of the World where population densities are lower and agriculture usually depends on rainfall in a single season, the micro-finance institutions have not been able to scale up to the same extent. Further scaling up of micro-finance is one of the major objectives of declaring 2005 the Year of Micro-Finance. 8 1.2 Community Development in India In 1948, pilot community development projects were set up in India under the leadership of S. K. Dev, the first minister of community development. The pilots were clearly intended to empower local communities to undertake their own development. The pilots were scaled up into a national community development program which by the end of the First Five Year Plan (1952-57) included 1114 blocks covering 163,000 villages, and by the 1960s the entire country was covered. (Hedge, 2000). The program aimed at upliftment of the rural poor, covered agriculture, animal husbandry, roads, health, education, housing, employment, social and cultural activities. Efforts were made to improve literacy, health, sanitation, housing, transport and communication. A de-concentrated service delivery model was used to implement and scale up the approach. An extension organization, headed by a Block Development Officer (BDO) was established at each block or sub-district, with a team of subject specialists and village level workers (VLW). The village level worker brought knowledge to the villagers. Each VLW covered 5-10 villages and assisted with the implementation of various development programs launched by different departments. From 1950s till mid 1970s, there were few achievements. Contrary to the intentions of the pilot projects, community empowerment and democratic decentralization were minimal. During the initial phase of community development, government officials prepared the plans. These plans were to be implemented by the sector-specific agencies, which, as discussed above, suffered from many weaknesses. Communities at best were consulted, rather than in charge of resources and implementation. In addition the resources allotted for community development during 1952-67 were so low that it worked out to hardly to 8 rupees (between one and two dollars at the then prevailing exchange rates) per capita over this period (ibid). In Box 3 the Comilla Model of Rural development is discussed, whose early intentions were also subverted in the scaling up process 9 Box 3: The Comilla Model of Rural Development The Comilla model emerged in the mid 1960s, engineered by the Bangladesh Academy for Rural Development (BARD), which was led by Akhter Hameed Khan. The assumptions behind the Comilla Model are that (i) the problems of rural development should be approached from the villagers' point of view, because they have the best understanding of their problems; (ii) they are capable of bringing about changes in their conditions if they have been provided with the means for development; (iii) agricultural development should be made an essential step in initiating a broader rural development process; (iv) training, research and demonstration are essential in promoting rural development. The most important element of the Comilla approach was the creation of an institutional base in rural society, and then integrate around it certain basic development programs. The institutional base consisted first of a two-tiered system of agricultural cooperative to encourage farmers to generate capital by thrift deposits, help them to get supervised credit, and to encourage farmers to adopt the technological innovations jointly. Other salient features of the institutional framework include (i) involvement of both public and private sectors in the process of rural development; (ii) development of a cadre of institutional leaders in every village, such as the manager, model farmers, women organizers, youth leaders, village accountants; (iii) priority on decentralized and coordinated rural administration with due coordination between officials of various government departments and the representatives of people's organisations. The Thana Training and Development Centre (TTDC) was designed to be the locus of the coordination. The program placed heavy emphasis on economic and technological components of development. The Thana Irrigation Programme was to provide irrigation facilities to farmers through their participation in planning and implementation of irrigation schemes. The Rural Works Programme (RWP), which was the function of the local government institution. In 1972, the government put in place the Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) to replicate and expand the Comilla Model in other parts of the country. Later the programme was transformed into an institution called Bangladesh Rural Development Board (BRDB). The BRDB eventually became the largest government organisation involved in production oriented schemes, expansion of the two-tier cooperatives, a large number of target group oriented projects such as the rural women projects and projects for the rural poor. By never transferring financial resources and implementation responsibility to communities the scaled up program drifted back towards the service delivery approach. While the government introduced elected local governments, it never gave them full autonomy, and also starved them of funds. The BRDB programs therefore lost many of the decentralized and empowerment features of the Comilla model. Source: (Banglapedia 2005b) 10 1.3 Technology-led production programs As a consequence of the failure of the Community Development program, and the growing dependency of India on imported food grains, priorities in the 1960s shifted to agricultural production and a distinct technological orientation was given to the programs. The Intensive Agricultural District Programme (IADP) supported by the Ford Foundation, concentrate money, expert staff and agricultural inputs in a few wellendowed agricultural districts (Staples 1992). Production was the goal: equity was not a major consideration, which caused consternation among those Indians who believed this violated the tenets of Indian social democracy. The IADP program produced limited and mixed results. (ibid) One of the problems of the IADP programs was the lack of technology which provided sufficient returns to farmers. This constraint was overcome in the mid 1960s with the advent of the “Green Revolution” varieties of wheat and rice, which emerged from international centers supported by the Rockefeller and Ford Foundations. The new varieties spread rapidly in many areas of the developing world. The new short, stiffstrawed varieties raised the returns to improved seeds, fertilizer and irrigation, and spawned a boom in private irrigation investment based on wells. The benefits of the new varieties not only helped the incomes of the farmers who grew them. Landless laborers and small farmers benefited from reduced food grain prices, and from the increases in labor demand associated with the higher production levels, which reflected themselves in higher rural wages. These successes led to the creation of the Consultative Group of International Agricultural Research to support research in all major tropical food crops via a string of international centers. It soon became apparent, however, that only nations which invested into their own adaptive research capacities could take full advantage of the technologies becoming available internationally, by developing varieties which were fully adapted to their local conditions. At the national level the Green Revolution therefore led to increased investment in national research system all over the world, including the creation of EMBRAPPA in Brazil, often supported via donor funding, especially from World Bank loans. While the Green Revolution was the key event which eventually enabled Mexico, China, India, and most other Asian countries to become self-sufficient in food grains, it became quickly apparent that the new technology was initially only adapted to agricultural systems characterized by good irrigation and water control, and was unable to spread to areas where irrigation was either not available or did not afford good water control, and for dryland crops and areas and crops. It took a long time for varieties to emerge which provided a clear advantage in terms of yields and risks in areas of poor water control and in dryland areas. And up to today, the responsiveness of many dryland crops to fertilizers remains insufficient, or too risky, and therefore does not entice farmers to invest in fertilizers, especially where fertilizer distribution systems are poorly developed and fertilizers are still expensive, as in many parts of Africa. 11 1.4 Programs for special areas and special target groups As a consequence of the inability of the Green Revolution to solve the poverty issues outside of the most agriculturally suitable areas, the need for programs with a special poverty focus reemerged. In the 1970s, India’s central government introduced independent administrative hierarchies to carry out special programs to reach the rural poor, and poor areas, bypassing the Panchayati Raj system (Box 4). The targeting mechanisms in these programs were intended to avoid elite capture of the benefit. They included the Small Farmers' Development Agency, Tribal Development Agency, Marginal, Small Farmers and Agricultural Labourers Development Agency. Area development programs for Command Area Development, Drought Prone Areas, and Hill Areas were financed and operated directly by the Central Government (Hedge 2005). Most of these programs used targeted and subsidized agricultural credit as one of their main instruments to achieve their objectives (see Box 2). Implementation experience was mixed. Similar programs emerged all over the world. Box 4: Slow progress in Decentralization As early as 1957 the Indian government appointed the Balwantrai Mehta Committee to evaluate the Community Development Program. It found that the program failed to evoke popular initiatives. The Committee recommended the formation of a three-tiersystem of rural local Government, to be called 'Panchayati Raj' (Rule by Local Councils), with counsels at the village, the block and the district level. The aim was to decentralize decision making closer to the people, encourage their participation, and place the bureaucracy under the local people's control. The Panchayati Raj was initially not able to fulfill these expectations. Few financial resources were devolved to the system, which set it up for failure. By the end of the middle of the 1960s priorities and programs shifted back to centralized modes, and especially to food production. Almost all the development programs were implemented by the responsible government departments, and there was little or no scope for participation by the villagers. Not surprisingly this did not work well and created a dependency syndrome. By the late 1980s the limitations of the central agency model to empower and involve the poor communities became apparent. In India, therefore, movements to revitalize the Panchayaty Raj system started, culminating in the 73d constitutional amendment of 1992. These empowered the PR institutions to shoulder the responsibility of development and decentralized planning. Under this constitutional amendment, 29 items of development were transferred to PRIs, and States were required to allocate fiscal resources to the system. The central government too started to devolve implementation for its Centrally Sponsored Schemes to the PR institutions. Presently over 3.3 million elected leaders have assumed positions in the Panchayati Raj administration covering 227,678 village Panchayats, 5906 Panchayat Samitis and 474 Zilla Parishads. The reservation of 33 percent of the elected posts for women and Scheduled casts and tribes has resulted in more active participation of these groups. Implementation of the constitutional amendment and devolution of fiscal resources to them still varies widely among Indian States. Source, Hedge 2000 12 1.5 Integrated Rural Development and Area Development Programs By the early 1970s, the initial successes of the Comilla Model, and the failure of the Green Revolution to reduce poverty in all but the most agriculturally suitable areas, provided inspiration for the creation of many Integrated Rural Development Programs, or area Development Programs. Following the famous “Nairobi Speech” of Mr. McNamara in 1973 the World Bank sharply increased its lending to agricultural and rural development. The new strategy advocated a continued involvement in sector-specific programs such as irrigation or agricultural credit, but also introduced a new focus on integrated rural development via area development project, which strongly emphasized smallholder agricultural productivity. The ADPs were rural investment programs, often to serve the rural poor in previously neglected and degraded rural areas. They included agriculture and other sectors, such as rural infrastructure, health, education, water supply, and small scale rural industry. Up to 1992 the World Bank assisted nearly 300 such projects, 45 percent of which were in Africa. The Rural Development Policy of 1975 emphasized that rural development should be participatory, decentralized, embedded in a favorable agricultural policy regime, and based on good available technology. In Mexico, the three PIDER projects implemented from 1975 to 1988 were considered to be at the cutting edge of a ‘social engineering’ approach to participation (Box 5). However most of the area development projects financed by the World Bank did not follow the Bank’s own policy guidance. The participatory planning process followed in Zacatecas in box 5 was a rare exception. Instead most projects were prepared in a hurry by teams of agricultural professionals, with little involvement of the beneficiaries. Project preparation teams, not the beneficiaries and those to be involved in implementation, prepared the development plans for the areas. Implementation of the different program components was entrusted to the central or regional government agencies in charge, such as the extension service, the irrigation department, or the ministry of education. These inevitably used the service delivery approach. Even in the PIDER projects in Mexico decentralization did not go beyond the level of the state. This was in clear contradiction to the policy which recommended a decentralized approach and strong local institutional development. The central agencies often had priorities which were not necessarily those of the project designers, or the affected populations. In the PIDER project in Zacatecas, for example, what was delivered at the community level by each agency was rarely in line with the priorities of the community identified at the elaborate planning stage. Implementation by central agencies gave rise to a major coordination problem, which the World Bank tried to solve by strengthening of the project units, often staffed by expatriate advisors. 13 Box 5: Participatory appraisal and planning During the preparation of the second phase of the PIDER project, the Zacatecas State Development Plan became the first instance when in 1979 the plan of an entire state was prepared through a participatory methodology. The programming exercise included diagnostic studies in all communities with populations of between 250 and 3,000; in addition, communities of more than 3,000 inhabitants were contacted through their authorities. The survey work itself had two foci--locality studies and sectoral studies. For the former, sixty field teams using a total of 120 technical experts carried out the diagnostic work; in the sectoral studies, eight groups including over 100 technicians were responsible for the analysis. About 80% of the total population of Zacatecas state was contacted by the field teams. A total of 4,029 investment proposals were received as a result of direct consultations with communities, and an additional 2,209 projects were proposed by government departments. After analysis of the survey data, the planners proceeded with the definition of priority objectives, strategies, specific investments for various communities, and sector plans. [Cernea, Michael “A Social Methodology for Community Participation in Local Investments: The Experience of Mexico’s PIDER program”, 1983]. The lighter Rapid Rural Apprasal (RRA) techniques also developed in the 1970s and 1980s. RRA developed its own assessment tools which enabled the outside planners to gain a better understanding of the development realities of communities than would be possible by expert visits, and in less time than large scale survey research, or the process used in Zacatecas. The RRA techniques were soon transformed into Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA), which transfers the role of analyzing and planning to the community itself. It is a structured process to help communities understand their constraints and opportunities, and develop their own sets of development priorities. Facilitators help communities to develop, present and analyze information. Techniques involve (i) diagrams, maps or quantification are created and presented physically by rural people in a manner they readily understand. (ii) walking transects across the village to gain a shared understanding of the environment, (iii) household listings and wealth ranking, (iv) reporting and analzing the findings in different discussion groups, such as men, women and youth, (v) ranking and scoring of constraints, options, opportunities and priorities. Visualization of the results for all to see and understand is a major element of these techniques. Source: The World Bank’s Participation Sourcebook (2003b). Participatory appraisal and planning techniques techniques have become an essential tool for systematic planning and priority setting in community development programs all over the world, in both rural and urban settings. The results of participatory rural assessments are often used as an input into participatory planning at the local level. Participatory appraisal approaches have also been applied widely to participatory planning at the level of local governments. For example they are widely used in the pilot local development fund programs initiated by the United Nations Capital Development Fund in over 15 developing countries (UNCDF, 2005). 14 OED reviewed these programs in 1987 and 1990, and again summarized the lessons in 1993. Performance of the ARD portfolio was significantly worse than that of other agricultural projects financed by the World Bank, or of projects in other sectors, and was especially poor in Africa. Overall half of area development programs failed, and in Africa it was two thirds. Projects were more successful where government commitment was strong and where the agricultural policy environment was better. Project benefits were rarely sustainable, and projects attained little institutional development impact, especially where project management units were used, and even more so where they were staffed by expatriate advisors. Central coordination of the sector agencies never worked. Locally proven technologies were often not available, and project-specific technology development components set up to remedy the situation usually failed. Monitoring and evaluation was often poor or non-existent. All in all, the projects did not follow the institutional development approach of the Comilla model, or the core strategic elements of the World Bank’s own rural development strategy. In the early 1990s the area development project approach was abandoned by the World Bank, along with lending for large scale irrigation construction and rural credit institutions. As a consequence, the rural agricultural and rural development portfolio of the World Bank shrank significantly, and the remaining programs focused on agricultural policy reforms, agricultural research and extension, and irrigation rehabilitation. Natural resource management projects became more important focusing on forestry and watershed management. 1.6 Non-governmental approaches Under the pressure from the failure of many state led efforts, governments in South Asia and elsewhere started during the 1970s to recognize the role of voluntary organizations or NGOs in supplementing government efforts in rural development. NGOs typically support the initiatives of local communities. They cover a wide range of rural development activities including relief and rehabilitation, family planning, mother and childcare, health and sanitation, income and employment generation, etc . In India, the Ministry of Agriculture created the 'Freedom from Hunger Campaign' to support voluntary organizations involved in rural development, which eventually became the Council for Advancement of People's Action and Rural Technology (CAPART). Success of these initiatives have now encouraged many state governments to launch schemes to promote people's participation and several centrally sponsored schemes have stipulated the development of community based organizations to plan and implement the program (Hedge, 2000). In many cases, the NGOs act as contractors for government financed programs. In many countries contracting NGOs has led to the proliferation of intermediary NGOs servicing pre-formulated schemes, and to an explosion of self help groups, with little connection to decentralized local or village government. And opportunities to set up intermediary NGOs have sometimes drawn valuable staff resources from government services. 15 1.6 Key Lessons of History The sample of historical experiences brings out a number of major features: 1. All reviewed large scale programs for community development and poverty reducing rural development started out with strong ideals of community participation and empowerment, coordination of development efforts at the local level, flexible and responsive local planning and implementation mechanisms, and decentralization of decision making and financial responsibilities. Many also viewed all or parts of the institutional, social, and agricultural policy environment for rural development as hostile. The sad lesson from this review is that most of the programs rushed into scaling up long before the institutional, social and policy environment could have been reformed. As a consequence many efforts ended up as programs of centralized bureaucracies, which stifled participation and empowerment, were unable to coordinate implementation of various sectors effectively, and choked in their own bureaucratic procedures. 2. The large scale programs paid little attention to reforming the institutional environment, and devolution of functions and financial resources to local governments or communities, that would have been in a better position to help coordinate and supervise the development actors on the ground. While India created elected local governments as early as the late 1950s, it only started supporting them in earnest in the 1990s. Similar experiences of creating elected governments, but then not devolving authority and fiscal resources to them occurred in Ghana, Tanzania, Mexico and other developing countries. 3. When the central sector agencies failed to implement the programs on the ground, many governments turned to NGOs to help with implementation. Particularly striking is that most NGOs used the “Intermediary model” and the “Service Delivery model”, rather than the “Empowerment Model” for supporting communities. Therefore they often substituted their own staff for the latent or actual management and implementation capacities of communities and service users, and failed to seize an important opportunity to reduce overhead costs and to overcome their own internal bureaucratic hurdles. 4. The early thinkers and leaders fully recognized the dangers of elite capture in their environments, and tried to build programs which would mitigate these dangers. Many governments created special targeted programs for the weaker groups and poorer areas which were managed from the center, or started to involve nongovernmental organizations in the program administration. These programs had very mixed results in reaching the poor. It was only in the 1990s that communities and local governments were starting to be used to target their own poor members. 16 Part 2: Local and Community-Driven Development in the World Bank since 1990 During the 1980s the World Bank changed its main focus from targeted poverty reduction to the management of the debt crisis, via macro-economic and sector policy reforms. However, by the late 19802 it became clear that the expected positive results of the adjustment programs for growth and poverty reduction were coming much slower than hoped for, and in many cases failed to appear altogether. At the same time the stabilization and structural reform programs had imposed significant losses on poor groups and social safety nets were urgently required. Fortunately, the World Development report on Poverty of 1990 moved poverty reduction back to center stage in the World Bank priorities. The strategy rested on a dual approach of accelerating growth, complemented by targeted programs for those bypassed by growth. But, as the historical examples of Part 1 show, the World Bank was in a poor position to respond to targeted poverty reduction. Central sector agencies had a poor record in delivering services to the poor, and were often costly and corrupt. Declining international cereals prices undermined the rate of returns to large scale irrigation programs, and they came under increasing attacks from environmental and social groups. The large scale agricultural credit programs had created costly institutions, and had failed to reach the poor (Box 2). Technology-led approaches proved of limited applicability in resourcepoor areas. The area development programs had proven a failure. It was therefore not obvious how to deliver the targeted development and safety net programs which were called for under the 1990 poverty reduction strategy. In this environment, staff of different sectors experimented on their own, and a number of parallel approaches emerged which often competed with each other. All these approaches selectively built on the international experienced reviewed in Part 1. But they did not systematically use the international experience to develop a unified framework. Therefore, as discussed in the introduction, it was only recently that the various different approaches have been brought together into a unified framework of local and communitydriven development (World Bank, 2005b). 2.1. Towards the synthesis In the World Bank, the process which led to this synthesis started in 1999 (?) with the creation of a cross-sectoral Working Group on Community-Driven Development (CDD Group) by President James Wolfensohn. 1 In his many country visits he had seen first Mr. Wolfensohn’s decision to call for the formation of this working group resulted from a meeting between him and the following staff from the Africa Region, Daniel Benor, Senior Advisor, Callisto Madavo, Vice President, Jean-Louis Sarbib, Vice President, and Hans Binswanger, ESSD sector director. The group presented Mr. Wolfensohn with an initial version of the Africa CDD vision discussed below (World Bank, 1990), and proposed that it become a major operational thrust in the Africa Region. 1 17 hand what the different community development approaches which were being pursued could achieve. But he was also bewildered by the many approaches to community empowerment which were being used. The terms of reference of this group, anchored in the Social Development Department, were to ……[Steen to fill out]. For the first time the CDD Group brought together all practitioners of community empowerment and decentralization approaches to jointly review the many programs and approaches applied in the World Bank. The CDD group became the instrument for consensus building and integration of approaches, as well as a key driver in moving the agenda forwards. On its comprehensive website it currently celebrates its five years existence and accomplishment. The first full articulation of the vision of an integrated program along the lines discussed in box 1 was produced by the CDD working group in the Africa Region (World Bank 2000).2 The vision states “The five main dimensions of CDD are: empowering communities, empowering local governments, re-aligning the center, improving accountability, and building capacity”. (ibid, p. 9). Realigning the center was understood as a reform effort of the centralized sector agencies so that they would devolve responsibility for delivery of most services to local governments and community levels.3 One of the first tasks of the CDD working group was to define Community-Driven Development, and various similar approaches, so that it became possible to define more clearly what was happening in the different Regions of the Bank. The definitions used for tracking the World Bank’s support to CDD are given in Figure 1. CDD clearly is built on the “empowerment model” of supporting communities discussed earlier, as CDD is now defined as programs in which the communities had control over their own projects and resources. Consultation and participation in maintenance of community projects was no longer sufficient to classify as Community-Driven Development, but is defined as ……….. Another feature which comes out clearly in the classifications is that efforts to reform the institutional environment, including decentralization and capacity building for local governments, were also tracked and given full credit as activities in support of CDD. Show the classification here 2 The members of this working group were Hans Binswanger, Jacomina de Regt. Laura Frigenti, Brian Levy, and Catherine…… The statement was written by Swaminathan Aiyer. In 2001 the Africa Region followed with a “Sourcebook on Community-Driven Development for Africa” (World Bank 2001e). Shortly thereafter a similarly comprehensive vision was presented in chapter 9 on CDD on the PRSP sourcebook, (Dongier et al, 2003). “Traditionally, central governments in Africa have followed the “blue collar” approach of operating all services. After decentralization, they will need to shift to a “white collar” approach. Instead of running services directly, they should focus on facilitating local government activities, setting standards, monitoring outcomes, providing training to lower levels, and providing rewards and penalties to improve local government performance.” (ibid, p. 11). 3 18 The classification was used to track progress in CDD, and growth in lending and nonlending support. Provide data on this growth from 2000 to 2005. Steen or Jacomina to discuss the trends A second major task for the World Bank’s CDD group was to develop guidance on how to implement CDD. The group therefore ten key design principles, that are reproduced in Box 6. At the same time the CDD Group started developing a number of implementation tools: for Economic and Social Analysis; Community Mobilization and Capacity Building; Information and Communications; Monitoring and Evaluation; Targeting and Selection; Direct Financing and Contracting; Institutional Options, Safeguards, and Social and Gender Inclusion. It has assembled the existing experience of CDD in post conflict settings, and in urban development. The World Bank Participation Sourcebook (2003b) provides a comprehensive overview of methods to enlist the participation of stakeholders at various levels from the community to local and national level. The Online Sourcebook on Decentralization provides a comprehensive overview and practical guidance on how to move forward in this area. CDD has also been adapted and used for combating HIV/AIDS, managing natural resources, water supply and many more. 19 Box 6: World Bank guidance on key design principles for CDD 1. Establish and enabling environment through relevant institutional and policy reform. 2. Make investment responsive to informed demand, by providing knowledge about options and requiring community contributions to investment and recurrent costs. 3. Build participatory mechanisms for community control and stakeholder involvement, by providing community groups with knowledge, control and authority over decisions, and resources.. 4. Ensure social and gender inclusion. 5. Invest in capacity building for Community-based Organizations (CBOs) 6. Facilitate community access to information. 7. Develop simple rules and strong incentives, supported by monitoring and evaluation. 8. Maintain flexibility in design of arrangements. 9. Design for scaling up. 10. Invest in an exit strategy, including permanent institutional and financing arrangements at an affordable fiscal costs. 2.2 How well are the vision and the tools being implemented? While perhaps inevitable, the separate development of different approaches, and the slow process of integration into a coherent framework had a number of adverse consequences. It led to the application of widely different approaches in projects of different sectors. They confused country teams, the borrowers and other development partners. The problem was compounded since other development partners similarly experimented with new approaches, and rarely coordinated them with World Bank supported projects. Since the approaches were driven by sector-specialists, these separate projects were not able to approach the underlying issues of the institutional, social and economic policy environment. As a consequence they reduced the impact and sustainability of the projects, as amply demonstrated in the recent OED review of Community-driven development. It is therefore not surprising that transforming the vision into sweeping reform and integration programs within countries has lagged significantly behind the consensus and intellectual guidance which was being developed. At the level of each country program, it has proven very difficult to merge the various approaches which were being pursued by different sectors in the Bank, as well as build the necessary consensus with the central and sector-specfic government entities, as with programs financed by other donors. Countries differ vastly in the configuration of approaches which they are using to support rural development. Some have strengths in their programs at community level, but lag in decentralization and alignment of the central agencies. Others have made more progress 20 on decentralization, but lag in the area of community empowerment. It is therefore essential that reform and integration of approaches be designed and pursued incrementally, starting from where a country actually is. In a recent review of projects with community participation components which were approved in by the World Bank between 1989 and 2003, the independent Operations Evaluation Department distinguished between Community Based Development (CBD) and Community-Driven Development (CDD).4 The latter support the empowerment of the poor by giving communities control over subproject resources and decisions, while CBD gives communities less responsibility and emphasizes collaboration, consultation, or sharing of information with them on project activities. (World Bank 2005c). Since 1989 the share of projects that include CBD/CDD components grew from 2 percent in fiscal year 1989 to 25 percent in 2003, and within that portfolio there was a progressive shift from CBD to CDD. From 1994 to 2003 the outcome ratings of CBD/CDD projects have been better than for non-CBD/CDD projects, and sustainability ratings have improved over time. But the interventions have often failed to provide consistent and long term support and institutional changes needed to achieve long term sustainability. The projects have done better on quantitative goals such as construction of infrastructure than on qualitative goals such as capacity enhancement. Those projects that have supported indigenously matured participatory efforts or when the Bank has provided long term support to communities beyond the length of a single subproject have done better on capacity enhancement. The increased access to service delivery infrastructure such as schools and health centers does not always translate into effective service delivery. Further the poorest may not always have benefited from these projects. (ibid). OED provides a very useful overview of CBD/CDD strengths and weaknesses, which is reproduced in Box 7. Box 7: Table ES1 of the OED report here A major failing has been the near absence of rigorous impact evaluation studies and there is therefore little hard evidence on the impact of the projects on poverty reduction and community capacity. The projects have enhanced the capacity of government institutions to implement participatory interventions, but few governments have yet adopted the approach more widely in their development program. A key recommendation of the OED report is that CBD/CDD projects still need to be better integrated into an overall country’s assistance strategy (ibid). Clearly by 2003 the project portfolio fell still short of implementing the design principles discussed in Box 7. With the exception of a few OED could not apply the four way classification developed by the CDD group and presented in table …., because prior to 2000 the classification did not exist, and could not been applied to projects prior to then. 4 21 projects and programs, the most glaring shortcomings were the area of institutional reform, full empowerment of communities, monitoring and evaluation, failure to truly scale up, and development of exit strategies. Describe the integration and unification efforts which are ongoing in Senegal, Nigeria, and other countries. Include a reference to the toolkit which Jacomina has produced. Suggested bottom line: Much has been achieved to spread participatory approaches, but the rigorous application of the CDD guidelines of the anchor on institutional reform and development is still not fully implemented. There are still too many sector-specific boutiques which are not effectively contribution to broader policy and institutional changes. Of course you can add your own take on the effort. 2. 3 How did the separate approaches evolve We have already discussed how poorly placed the World Bank was in the late 1980s and early 1990s to help countries design and implement targeted poverty reduction interventions. On the other hand the historical section shows that there was available inside and outside the Bank considerable experience in how to improve participation, empower communities, make sector agencies more responsive, and build decentralized government institutions. We will now review how the World Bank progressively incorporated these approaches into its programs and developed the different strands which eventually came together in LCCD. Note that the term “Community-Driven Development” did not exist at the time. It was coined by Deepa Narayan and Hans Binswanger in 1995 to denote the integration of participatory approaches with decentralization and direct community empowerment.5 2.3.1 Participation and de-concentration in sectoral programs World Bank staff in different sectors began to experiment with participatory approaches in a wide range of sector-specific projects, as well as in area development projects. For example, from the late 1970s Michael Cernea developed a bottom-up participatory planning model from the community to the municipal and state level for the PIDER integrated rural development programs which was widely applied in Mexico. Give more names and examples. Below we review a few of the sector-specific efforts The term “Community Development” was rejected because it was too closely identified with the failed community development program in India, or the Community development programs in the United States, which mostly use the “service delivery” or “intermediary” models for working with communities, rather than the “empowerment” model. 5 22 Water supply The water supply sector, both outside and inside the World Bank, started early to introduce a variety of participatory mechanisms in its projects. Jacomina or Steen to find some early examples By 1995 Deepa Narayan was able to analyze a sample of 121 completed water supply projects in forty-nine countries which included various participatory mechanisms. Most of these projects were completed during the 1980s and involved 18 different bilateral, multilateral and NGO financing agencies. The study was able to define and measure participation, overall and at the various project stages. The methods and degree of participation varied widely among these projects, from representative user committees as part of service delivery approaches to direct involvement in construction and supervision of contractors as part of full empowerment approaches. Seventy-nine percent of the projects were rated low or medium in overall participation and only 21 percent received high ratings. Multiple regression analysis was used to measure the impact of participation and other factors. “The results are clear: beneficiary participation contributed significantly to project effectiveness, even after statistically controlling for the effects of seventeen other factors…..The proportion of water systems in good condition, overall economic benefits, percentages of the target population reached, and environmental benefits rose significantly with participation…..Effective participation did not result when agencies retained control over implementation details-that is the what, when, how and where of implementation. At the beneficiarly lever, the two key characteristics determining participation were commitment before construction, or demand, and the degree of organization of the beneficiaries [emphasis in the original].” (Narayan, 1995, pp. 1,2). Many of the projects analyzed in the above study where small scale, but in the meantime the water supply sector has done a lot of work to scale up participatory and communitydriven approaches, and in some instances to link it to decentralization efforts to local governments. Chapter ….in this volume analyzes the early scaling up phase of such a program in Kerala, India. Urban development Kampung Improvement Program in Indonesia Natural resource management Jacomina Nutrition Steen 2.3.2 Breaking out of the sectors: Social Funds and AGETIPs While the above examples show that there is significant potential to improve infrastructure and service delivery in sector-specific programs, the reforms of many sectors one by one to achieve these improvements was a very slow and hard approach to 23 achieve this, especially since most sector bureaucracies resist such changes. A sector-bysector approach was also not fast enough to deal with adverse employment and welfare consequences of adjustment programs. Many World Bank staff were therefore looking for ways to reach communities directly with a broad menu of interventions or assist municipalities with the implementation of broader infrastructure investment programs which sector agencies were unable to deliver. Social Funds and AGETIPS (give full name) emerged from these efforts. Social Funds Steen: Boliva, Zambia, Malawi. The shift from intermediary and service delivery approaches to empowerment approaches. The progressive linking to decentralization and local government capacity development. The merging of Social Funds and the CDD agendas. AGETIPS Steen 2.3.3 Fostering Participation: The Sourcebook Jacomina: The first version of the Sourcebook came out in 1995, and was based on a bank-wide “Participation working group” which originally had been created by Aubrey Williams, now retired, but still available at awilliams@earthwave.net. He could perhaps write a paragraph or two on the origins of this effort and the contents of the first source book 2.3.4 Decentralization approaches to local development Latin America, Tim Campbell, Anwar Shah, and others. And how it was operationalized primarily in urban development project. How it evolved, including for example the procect support to the decentralization in Bolivia, Colombia, and elsewhere. The section should also include a reference to UNCDF pilot programs for Local Development Funds, which, for example in Mozambique, became the basis for a recent project. Steen: Can you find someone, such as Tim Cambpell, to write a brief section on this? Between 1992 to 1996 the World Bank conducted a global study of 14 countries and five provinces in large countries on “Decentralization, Fiscal Systems, and Rural Development.”6 The study was designed to complement the work of the participation task force discussed above, and to focus particularly on the financing of rural development at the level of local government. 6 The study was headed by Hans Binswanger and the team at various times included Keith McLean, Graham Kerr, Andrew Parker, Suzanne Piriou-Sall, Johan van Zyl, and Melissa Williams. Outputs are summarized in McLean et al, 1998, Piriou-Sall ????, and Aiyer et al, eds. 1995,1996. 24 The study examined the level of decentralization in delivering services for six key rural sectors: primary education, primary healthcare, agricultural extension, rural roads maintenance, rural water supply, and forestry management. It looked at the powers of local institutions over delivering crucial services to rural populations.7 The results in the chart below show that, in terms of aggregate sector decentralization, countries with high agricultural and rural development performance tend to be much more decentralized than countries with low performance. Jiangxi (China) was the most decentralized in our sample of nineteen countries/states/provinces. Colombia, Philippines, and Poland respectively completed the top fifth of countries, and only these countries scored over 50% in sector decentralization. Imo State in Nigeria received the lowest score, followed by Cote d’Ivoire, Burkina Faso, and Senegal. Five of the African countries ranked in the lowest quarter of the sample; Zambia is the only exception. The high score of Jiangxi reflects views of those who have been working on China over the past two decades; China is more decentralized than most other countries. This decentralization is strongly fiscal and administrative and there is considerable devolution of related powers. In villages and township communities, and there are local non-party elections to the lowest level elected bodies, Township Peoples Congress and Village Committees. 7 The study constructed a decentralization index ranging from 0 to 10 based on data collected from World Bank sector specialists who had worked intensively in the respective countries/states/provinces. It was based on answers to the following question: Where is the smallest management unit for rural sector service delivery physically located? Which level of government responsible for conditions of service of civil servants in the smallest management unit? How important are elected bodies in (a) service delivery, (b) policy formulation, and (c) funding of each sector? Which level of government pays the salaries of staff in smallest administrative unit? What proportion of sector expenditures of smallest administrative unit is derived from the budgets of local governments? What proportion of sector expenditures of smallest administrative unit which is derived from user charges, in-kind contributions, and other beneficiary cost-recovery schemes? Who determines the budget of the smallest sector management unit? 25 2.3.4 Community-driven Development in a Decentralization Context The previous section suggests that more decentralized countries/provinces do better than more centralized ones in agricultural and rural development. However, as discussed in Boxes two and three, the notion that decentralization must be an important institutional pillar of rural development goes back to at least the 1950s. Furthermore the Comilla model explicitly linked decentralized coordination and decision making, local government and community development. But in scaling up these associations were lost. It took until the 1990s to until large scale development programs were developed, which made these links a reality. Mexico The Decentralization and Regional Development Projects financed by the World Bank (DRD I and II) were implemented between 1990 and 2002.8 (Chapter ….in this volume, on which this section draws, provides much more details on these programs). They followed on three integrated rural development projects (PIDER I to III) implemented from 1975 to 1988, and the DRD project was designed to address weaknesses in the PIDER projects.9 The DRD I project was designed to address each of these. Mexico 8 The leaders of the teams which designed DRD I and II were, respectively, Abel Mateus and Andrea Silverman. The division chiefs for the two projects were, respectively, Hans Binswanger and Michael Baxter. 9 The Project Completion Report for PIDER III (1981-88) indicated that, while that project generally met its objectives, it suffered from several problems. These included, inter alia: (i) low levels of total public investment in poor regions in spite of the project; (ii) inadequate participation of primary stakeholders; (iii) 26 remains one of the most unequal countries in Latin America, (Gini coefficient of 0.54). Forty-five percent of the population is still poor, and in rural areas half the population remains extremely poor. At the time of the introduction of the program, Mexico was emerging from the debt crisis which hit in the early 1980s, and had led to a massive increase in poverty, and a sharp reduction of development expenditures. The DRD 1 project was a small component of the broader “Solidaridad” program introduced by President Salinas to deal with these issues. The program was introduced at a time when the Partido Revolutionario Institutional (PRI) had already ruled for sixty years, and was just starting to experience its first real challenges to its rule. Corruption was widespread, and rural areas were dominated by local strongmen, the so called “Caciques.” In spite of having a decentralization law and elected state and municipal councils and chief executives, Mexico remained a highly centralized country in which over 90 percent of fiscal revenues were collected by the state. Under the DRD I project a Municipal Funds component10 was piloted in four Southern States of Mexico, and quickly became its most successful components, eventually using up 154 of the project loan’s 350 million dollars. As a consequence DRD II, implemented from 1994 to 2002 was expanded to 8 states with a total of 1437 municipalities. The Municipal Funds used up over 90 percent of the 500 Million dollars of the project loan. The project introduced a large number of innovations in World Bank practices some of which were specifically designed to counter the perceived weaknesses at the municipal and community level: The Municipal Funds program worked directly with rural municipalities as the coordinators and implementers, and provided fungible grants to them. A formula based on a municipal development index was used to allocate money to the municipalities. This allowed targeting of the program toward the poorest municipalities, and overcame the problems of political manipulation associated (Diaz-Cayeros et al, 2004). In order to ensure that rural localities receive a fair amount of money, the amount of money going to municipal cabeceras was restricted, again using a formula. A Municipal Development Council (MDC) was formed to coordinate and supervise the program, and functioned under the guidance of the elected municipal council, the Cabildo. The MDC was headed by the elected mayor, and included the heads of localities within the municipalities, the representatives of existing committees, and the Cabildo’s budget officer. lack of technical quality in the preparation and appraisal of projects; and (iv) inadequate project monitoring. 10 Municipal Funds is the generic term used to denote the DRD I & II component implemented initially as part of Fondos Municipales de Solidaridad, which evolved in successive stages into: Fondo de Solidaridad Munciipal (1995); Fondo de Desarrollo Social Municipal (1996-7); and, Fondo para la Infraestrictura Social Municipal - FISM (since 1998 to present). 27 Projects emerged from community priorities and followed a clear project cycle up to the approval at the MDC level. The MDC and the community then signed a contract, and a technical implementation plan was prepared. The municipalities then put the implementation responsibility and the money into the hands of communities, i.e. using the empowerment model from the start. New disbursement, procurement, and accountability procedures had to be developed which were simple, yet provided safeguards for the proper use and accounting of the resources transferred to the communities.11 Most community projects were small in size, and usually less than the maximum of $50,000. Communities made their contributions in cash or in kind, ranging from 20% to 40%, and fast completion of the works. Due to its innovative nature, Municipal Funds activities used a learning-by-doing approach across all levels of operation — federal, state, municipal and community levels. Between 1995 and 1997 DRD II implemented around 106,000 projects in building or rehabilitating classrooms and schools, potable water, rural roads, support to production, electrification, sewage systems, pavement, urbanization, and others. In addition, Mexico used its own funds to scale up the approach all over Mexico. Between 1990 and 2000 over half a million community projects were executed in this way. Poverty targeting to municipalities was much better than under previous approaches. Projects were in line with community priorities, generally of good quality, and about thirty percent cheaper than projects implemented via state agencies. Sustainability of the subprojects remained a problem, partly because the communities were not yet legal entities capable of charging for services. Municipal performance varied widely, depending on management capacity, which remains a major constraint for the successful implementation of the now much enhanced municipal development budgets. Participatory monitoring and evaluation remains weak and there exists no rigorous impact evaluation of the program. The relationship between the Mexican Government and the World Bank during the design and execution of these programs were highly interactive, incorporated learning by doing, as well as repeated disagreements and consensus building efforts. Mexico was not dependent on World Bank lending to finance its poverty reduction program, but it used the World Bank strategically to try new approaches and introduce many innovations into its own programs. The program benefited from the existence of a legal framework for Municipalities which needed activation, rather than creation. It also benefited from the experience of many earlier rural development programs, and from the cadre of rural development professionals these had formed and allowed to gain experience. Despite the small size of the DRD program within Mexico’s overall poverty reduction programs, many of the innovations introduced in the Municipal Fund approach were 11 Jean Claude Sallier and his Mexican colleagues invented and designed the original community-driven disbursement, procurement, and financial accountability procedures without which the entire program could never have been implemented. 28 incorporated into legislation supporting Ramo 33 and the corresponding Fiscal Coordination Law of 1998 (for details see chapter….). Brazil In 1993 the World Bank supported rural development in ten North Eastern Brazilian States via integrated rural development projects called “Programas de Apoio aos Pequenos Produtores Rurais do Nordeste (PAPP).” These projects were supported by loans to the Government of Brazil, which passed the resources to the Northeast Development Agency (SUDENE), and from there to the states, which used their sector agencies to implement the programs. There was no involvement of local governments. The program was in crisis, suffering from many of the problems of area development programs. Most components used either the service delivery or the intermediary model for supporting rural communities, and by design about 55 percent of the project resources were being used for the management of the projects at the federal, SUDENE, State, and State agency levels. A significant proportion of the project resources were to be provided as credit at close to market interest rates. Because Brazil was implementing the Plan Real to overcome a major macro-economic crisis, real interest rates were at extremely high real levels and therefore there was little demand for agricultural credit. The projects, however, contained a successful pilot component, which provided matching grants to small rural communities, the “Apoio às Pequenas Comunidades Rurais” (APCR).12 These projects functioned very much like the community projects under the Mexican Municipal Funds. In order to avoid the cancellation of the rural development projects, it was decided to eliminate the credit component for which there was no demand, reduce the number of intermediaries in the management of the project to just the existing state technical units, and put all the project resources to support the APCR approach, redesigned and adjusted to incorporate lessons from the Mexico Municipal Funds.13 The intermediary model of community support was replaced by the empowerment model. The redesigned projects became one of the largest and most successful CDD programs in the World Bank at a total cost of 1.43 billion dollars, and benefiting 37,592 communities comprising 2,540,733 benficiary families over the past 12 years. (Barboza et al 2006). 12 The component was designed by a team led by Hubertus von Pogrell, and incorporated lessons from implementation experience in projects managed by Jean Claude Sallier, who invented the Community-base disbursement and procurement procedures which made the Mexican DRD projects into a success. 13 The proposal for this very radical redesign was worked out in consultation with the locally recruited staff of the Recife office of the World Bank by Hans Binswanger, at that time Senior Advisor for the Latin America Region, Tia Duer, Division Chief for the Agricultural Division for Braizil, and Antonio Maghalaes, undersecretary of Planning for Brazil. Luis Coirolo then led the team primarily from the Recife office, which generated the buy in from the governors of the Northeastern States and the state level technical units, produced the details of the redesign, including operational manuals and all other tools, and brought it for approval to the Regional Management of the Latin America Region and the World Bank Board. The buy-in from the Governors of the Northeastern States and Central Government officials was secured by inviting them to visit the Municipal Funds Program in Mexico, which at that time was in its third year of highly successful implementation. 29 Brazil had been under a military dictatorship until 1986, and had approved a new democratic constitution in 1987 which introduced a radical program of decentralization to States and Municipalities. Under the new constitutions, municipalities were to receive twenty two percent of the public fiscal resources. The new dispensation also enabled community and civil society participation in development. Nevertheless, at the time of the redesign, municipalities and communities were still considered to be dominated by small, self-serving elites, and most observers expected a high level of elite capture if they were empowered with responsibility and fiscal resources. Because of the fear of elite capture, the Brazil program took a more cautious approach to the devolution of functions and funds to the municipalities. The state technical units still functioned like social funds. However, the redesigned project introduced Municipal Development Councils similar to those in Mexico in about 15 percent of the municipalities, the so called FUMAC approach. These councils focused on identification, sub-project approval and supervision, and did not manage money, which was directly transferred from the State level to the communities. Attempts to devolve the funds to the municipal level and have them allocated on a formula basis as in Mexico have so far been resisted by the technical units of the states. As of this writing, the FUMAC model has been generalized across almost all municipalities, and the Municipal Councils have become involved in coordinating implementation of other federally financed programs. The Northeast Rural development Program as a whole now has progressively been improved by systematically addressing criticisms and concerns. Its enviable record of success owes much to a high level of continuity in the Word Bank staff involved, and the supervision and adaptation of the program from the Recife office of the World Bank. A recent synthesis of evaluations conducted (Barboza et al 2006 a, b). 1. The loan resources actually reaching the communities have risen from around 45 percent to over 90 percent. At the same time the costs per sub-project have fallen by around 30 percent. This means that for every dollar of total program costs, about two and a half times as much project work can be implemented at the community level than before the redesign. 2. The program has created significant social capital, at both the community and local level. 3. As in Mexico, the program is well targeted to poor municipalities and to poor communities, although it does not generally reach the poorest of the poor. 4. Project quality and sustainability is high. 5. The program has significantly impact in improving water supply and electricity in poor communities of the Northeast, and has reduced child mortality and the incidence of a number of diseases. 6. While rates of return to productive projects are high, they tend to have a higher failure rate and lower sustainability than social and infrastructure projects. 7. The program has not had a significant impact on the net wealth of the beneficiaries. 30 Brazil implemented what was to become called as Community-Driven Development more cautiously than Mexico, and provided less fiscal resources to the municipal level. It did not generalize the approach across the entire country by mainstreaming it into the intergovernmental fiscal system. As a consequence the number of projects implemented under the program remains much smaller than in Mexico. The challenge for Brazil and the Bank is to take advantage of this experience by institutionalizing it more fully at all levels: community, municipality, state, and the federation. Indonesia Steen: The Kacematan Development Program Subsaharan Africa Jacomina: Guinea, Burkina Faso, Uganda: The development of fully fungible local and community development funds using norm-based allocations of resources, and directly linking these funds to progress in decentralization. 2.3.5 The development of community-based disbursement and procurement mechanisms The progressive shift in large scale sectoral or multi-sectoral programs from intermediary and service delivery approaches to an empowerment approach, in which communities have full control over implementation and the finances associated with it, would not have been possible using the classical disbursement and procurement mechanisms of the World Bank and of other donors. As discussed before, Jean-Claude Sallier, together with his Mexican counterparts, and supported by the procurement and disbursement specialists of the Latin America Region of the World Bank, pioneered these systems. Six innovations made this shift possible: 1. Legal ownership of the funds: Funds transferred to communities were considered matching grants, and therefore became the property of the communities, rather than the executing agency of the program or the World Bank. Just like credit provided by a bank, the proper spending of these resources now becomes the responsibility of the owner of the funds, the community 2. Replacing detailed accounting for the funds by a contract with the community: The “expediente technico” for a small community project specifies what will be done with the money, and how it will be used, as well as the technical details of the sub-project to be financed. It is a four to six page document with a cover page, which is in the form of a contract between the executing agency, the community, and sometimes a facilitator or technical agent. At the end of the implementation, the community signs a certificate of completion or handover of the project to the community, in which the latter certifies that the project has been properly executed and the funds accounted for. Rather than having to produce receipts for each individual expense, it is this completion certificate which serves as the “receipt” for accounting purposes of the executing agency and the World Bank. Verification of the proper use of the funds by the implementing agency of the 31 3. 4. 5. 6. program or by outside auditors then can consist of verifying that a road or a classroom has actually been constructed and is in operation. Direct transfer of the matching grants into the accounts of the community. This is usually done in tranches, the first of which followed the signature of the contract, and the second or third of which depend on demonstrating certain progress benchmarks in the execution of the project. Purchase technical support by the community. The community can select any capable supplier and use a portion of the matching grant, usually of the order of 8 percent, to pay for the technical services. Local shopping for both goods and services: This implies the suppression of the traditional distinction between services and goods in the community procurement rules. Local shopping is the main procurement system of communities for small contracts and quantities of supplies. (Competitive bidding is still required if the community entered into larger contracts where this method is justified). Local shopping rules mean that community obtains offers from three suppliers, and that its finance or management committee chooses from these three offers. Transparency at the community level: Communities elect finance committees which are in charge of day to day spending. Checks must be signed by at least two members of the finance committee. The committee has to present all accounts to the general assembly, which often also elects an audit committee to audit accounts, purchases, stocks, and their uses. Proper application of the rules means a radical shift in the direction of accountability in project finance: From upwards accountability to the executing agency of the program and the World Bank, to horizontal and downwards accountability to the members. Of course upwards accountability remains, but in sharply simplified form. The idea of transferring funds directly to communities met with widespread resistance at first, inside the Bank, among borrowing countries, and among executing agencies and NGOs who were used to intermediary and service delivery models of assisting communities. Therefore it took over ten years form the initial development of these new procedures in Mexico to full acceptance and widespread use in Social Funds, sector-specific and multi-sector CDD programs it took nearly ten years. The final formulation of these rules in the World Bank system occurred in ………. Jacomina, please find the date and the document which sanctify these rules. 2.4 The future agenda for LCDD From Messy Boutiques to Scaled up LCCD Steen Three strands evolved in parallel and led to much confusion within (three ways of financing schools in Malawi) and across sectors (AG versus HD versus INF versus Decentralization gurus) – Madagascar example. Little scaling up because of turf and battles 32 What you need to discuss here is how the different approaches gradually incorporated design elements from their rivals and therefore became more and more similar, most strikingly as far as Social Funds, CDD, and Decentralization approaches are concerned. Applying the guiding principles Steen and Jacomina Scaling up Steen and Jacomina References Aiyar, Swaminathan, ed. August 1995. Decentralization: A New Strategy for Rural Development. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 1. Aiyar, Swaminathan, ed. August 1995. How Well Has Decentralization Worked for Rural Development. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 2. Aiyar, Swaminathan, ed. August 1995. Decentralization Can Work: Experience from Colombia. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 3. Aiyar, Swaminathan, Keith McLean, and Suzanne Piriou-Sall, eds. September 1996. The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 9. Aiyar, Swaminathan, and Suzanne Piriou-Sall, eds. September 1996. How Rules And Incentives Can Improve The Working Of Demand-Driven Rural Investment Funds. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 10. Aiyar, Swaminathan, ed. September 1996. Has Decentralization Aided Biodiversity Conservation? AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 11. Banglapedia, 2005a?, Rural Development, Dhaka, Bangladesh Banglapedia, 2005 b? The Comilla Model, Dhaka, Bangladesh Barboza, Tulio, Hans Binswanger, Alberto Costa, and Claudia Romano 2006: Hans to provide title Campfens, Hubert, ed., Community Development Around the World, University of Toronto Press, Toronto Diaz Cayeros, Alberto and Beatrice Magaloni, 2004, The Politics of public spending, part II, Background paper for the World Development Report, World Bank, Washington DC Dongier, Philippe, Julie van Domelen, Elinor Ostrom, Andrea Ryan, Wendy Wakeman, Anthony Bebbington, Sabine Alkire, Talib Esmail, and Margret Polsky, 2003, 33 “Community Driven Development,” Chapter 9 of PRSP Sourcebook, Washington DC Hegde, N.G. 2000, Community Development in India : An Overview, Proc. of the Asian Productivity Organization, Tokyo, Japan seminar on Comparative Study on Planning Process of Community Development, Ulaanbaatar, Mongolia. Aug. 21-26 Khwaja, A.I. 2000. “Can Good projects Succeed in Bad Communities?” Harvard University. Paper Presented at the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics. May 2 Krishna Anirudh 2004. Partnership Between Elected Local Governments and Community-Based Organizations: Exploring the Scope for Synergy. Social Development Papers Community Driven Development Number 52/February. Kumar, N. (2002), The challenges of community participation in forest development in Nepal, OED Working Paper Series, World Bank, Washington D.C. Lin, Justin and Funning Zhong. 1997. Fiscal Decentralization and Rural Development in China. Forthcoming. Manor, J. 1999. The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization. Directions in Development. Washington D.C., The World Bank. Mansuri, G. and V. Rao (2004), ‘Community-Based and Driven Development: a critical review’, The World Bank Research Observer 19 (1): 1-39. McLean, Keith, Graham Kerr, Suzanne Piriou-Sall and Melissa Williams, 1998 Decentralization and Rural Development: Characterizing Efforts In 19 Countries, Washington DC, World Bank working paper Narayan Deepa 1995. The Contribution of People’s Participation: Evidence from 121 Rural Water Supply Projects. Environmentally Sustainable Development Occasional Paper Series No.1. The World Bank. Parker, Andrew N. 1995. Decentralization: The Way Forward for Rural Development? Policy Research Working Paper Series, No. 1475. Washington, D.C.: Policy Research Dissemination Center, The World Bank. Piriou-Sall, Suzanne. December 1996. Demand-Driven Rural Investment Fund: A New Generation of Social Funds. AGR Dissemination Notes. Number 13. Platteau J-P. and F. Gaspart. 2003. ‘The Risk of Resource Misappropriation in Community-Driven Development’, World Development 31 (10): 168-1703. 34 Platteau Jean-Philippe. 2003. Institutional and Distributional Aspects of Sustainability in Community-Driven Development. Fifth Biennial World Bank Conference on Evaluation and Development “Evaluating Development Effectiveness: Challenges and the way Forward. Washington DC Romano, Claudia, Alberto Costa, Naercio......, and Hans Binswanger, 2006, Impact evaluation: Hans to provide title and details. Staples, Eugene S., 1992, Forty years: A Learning Curve: The Ford Foundation in India, 1952-1992, Ford Foundation, New York UNCDF, 2005, Delivering the Goods: Building Local Government Capacity to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals, A Practitioner's Guide from UNCDF Experience in Least Developed Countries. New York World Bank. 2000. The Community Driven Development Approach in the Africa region: A Vision of Poverty Reduction Through Empowerment. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. World Bank, 2001a, Attacking Poverty, World Development Report, Washington DC World Bank 2001b. Empowering the Poor through Decentralization: Brazil Rural Poverty Alleviation Program.” Social Development Note No. 51. March 2001. World Bank, 2001c, Promoting Good Governance through Social Funds and Decentralization, Prem Notes # 51, Washington DC. World Bank 2001d. Decentralization and Governance: Does decentralization improve public service delivery? Notes Number 55. World Bank 2001e, Sourcebook for Community-Driven Development in Africa, Washington DC World Bank 2002a, Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook, Washington, D.C.: World Bank World Bank 2002b. Social Funds: Assessing Effectiveness. Operations Evaluation Department. World Bank, 2003a, Making Services work for the Poor, World Development Report, Washington DC World Bank, 2003b, The World Bank Participation Sourcebook. Environmentally Sustainable Development. http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/sourcebook/sbhome.htm, First published in 1996, Washington DC. 35 World Bank 2003c. Community-Driven Reconstruction as an Instrument in War-toPeace Transitions. CPR Working Papers. Paper No. 7 August. Social Development Department ESSD Network. World Bank 2004. Community-Driven Development in Urban Upgrading. Social Development Notes. February, No.85 World Bank 2004a. Community-Driven Development in Local Government Capacity Building Projects: Emerging Approaches in Africa. Social Development Notes November 86 World Bank 2004b. Reducing Poverty Sustaining Growth. Scaling Up Poverty Reduction. A Global Learning Process and Conference in Shanghai May 25-27 2004 World Bank, 2005a, Community-Driven Development, http://www.worldbank.org/CDD World Bank, 2005b, Linking community empowerment, decentralized governance, and public service provision through a local development framework, Washington DC World Bank, 2005c, The Effectiveness of World Bank Support for Community-Based and -Driven Development, Independent Evaluation Group, Washington DC World Bank, 2005d, Community-driven development website. First pubished in 2001? (Steen to provide date when first put up) Washington DC World Bank, 2005e, The Online Sourcebook on Decentralization (http://www.ciesin.org/decentralization/Entryway/english_contents.html). First published in 199? (This was maintained by Melissa Williams, and we need to find out when it was started) 36 37