Endogenous Growth Theory 1. The AK Model AK1 AK2 AK3 Y AK , K ' sY K , L' / L n A0 0 s 1, n0 0 1 Endogenous(3): Y , K ' , L' Predetermined(2): K , L Exogenous(4): A , s , , n Production is proportionate to capital. In particular, there are no diminishing returns to capital. 2. Intensive Form AK Model Define k K / L and y Y / L . Dividing AK1 by L we obtain IF1 y Ak . Dividing AK2 by K , we obtain K ' / K sy / k . We want to eliminate K ' / K from this equation. Taking the natural log of k K / L and differentiating with respect to time yields k ' / k K ' / K L' / L . Assuming L' / L n , and rearranging terms, we have K ' / K k ' / k n . Using this result, we can rewrite the equation K ' / K sy k as k ' / k n sy / k . Multiplying through by k yields IF2 k ' sy nk k Using IF1 and IF2, we may classify the variables in the intensive form model as follows: Endogenous(2): y , k ' Predetermined(1): k Exogenous(4): A , s , , n 3. Analyzing the Intensive Form Substituting IF1 into IF2, we obtain k ' sAk nk k , so AIF1 k ' sA n k Equation AIF1 is a linear homogenous differential equation with state variable k . k k ' / k denote the growth rate of the per capita capital stock k . Equation AIF1 indicates AIF2 k sA n . Real world economic data for developed countries indicates that per capita capital stock grows at roughly a constant rate. The data also indicates that per capita output tends to grow at roughly a constant rate, and at about the same rate as per capita capital stock. Differentiating y Ak with respect to time yields y ' / y A' / A k ' / k . So, to fit the data, the parameter A must remained constant. That is, A' / A 0 must hold so y ' / y k ' / k . Assume A' / A 0 , so y ' / y k ' / k . Define y y ' / y to be the growth rate of per capita output. Using equation AIF2 and the result y ' / y k ' / k , our model indicates AIF3 y sA n . Real world economic data for developed countries also indicates per capita output and capital stock levels grow faster than the employment level. The employment level growth rate is given by L L' / L n . If follows that the difference between the growth rate of per capita output and the growth rate of employment is y L sA n n sA 2n . In order for this difference to be positive, which is what we observe in the real world, we obtain the following restriction on the model’s parameters AIF4 A 2n . s Since A Y / K is the average product of capital, the restriction AIF 4 indicates that the marginal product of capital must be “high” in some sense, or high enough, in order for output and capital per capita to grow faster than employment. The growth rates y and k depend upon the values of the exogenous variables in the model. Increases in either the savings rate s or the average product of capital A lead to higher growth rates y and k . Conversely, a higher population growth rate n or higher depreciation rate leads to a slower rate of economic growth. In summary, the AK model indicates saving and productive capital are the keys to obtaining a higher rate of economic growth, while population growth and a higher depreciation rate hampers growth. This AK model has advantages. One advantage is its simplicity. The primary advantage is we have a model of endogenous technical change. There is no technical change assumed here. In particular, the parameter A is held fixed. The growth in the productivity of labor, as measured by the growth in the per capita output level y , comes when saving is high enough and when capital is productive enough. A disadvantage is that the model does not have a convergence property, which real world economies seem to follow. That is, the growth rate of per capita capital stock does not slow in this AK model as more capital is accumulated. For this reason, economists have sought other ways to model endogenous technical change. 4. GAK1 GAK2 GAK3 A Generalized AK Model Y AK K BL K ' sY K , L' / L n 1 Endogenous(3): Y , K ' , L' Predetermined(3): K , L Exogenous(4): A , B , s , , n , , A 0, 0 s 1, n0 B0 0 1 5. Intensive form of Generalized AK Model Let k K / BL and y Y / BL , then equations GAK1-GAK3 imply y Ak k , A 0 , k ' sy k nk , L' / L n GAK1 GAK2 GAK3 B0 0 s 1, n0 0 1 Endogenous(3): Y , K ' , L' Predetermined(3): K , L Exogenous(3): A , B , s , , n , 6. Analyzing the Generalized Intensive Form Model Together, equations GAK1 and GAK2 imply k ' s Ak k k nk . Letting k k ' / k , we can divide this last equation through by k to obtain AGAK1 k s k 1 sA n . Assume sA n , and define k sA n . It follows that k k s / k 1 , which is positive. This indicates that, when the per capita capital stock level is smaller, its growth rate is larger. Over time, the per capita capital stock grows and the growth rate decreases, asymptotically approaching the level k . Thus, this model predicts that a less developed economy will have a higher growth rate, which is one way of describing the conditional convergence property. Equation AGAK1 exhibits the conditional convergence property. The CES production function can generate both conditional convergence and economic growth. This result is not worked out here, but obtaining this result is a good challenge. 7. Research and Development Model RD1 Y 1 a K K A1 a L L RD2 RD3 RD4 1 A' Ba K K a L L A K ' sY L' nL , 0 1 0 s 1 n0 Endogenous (4): Y , K ' , A' , L' Predetermined (3): K , A , L Exogenous (8): B , s , n , , , a K , a L , Equation RD2 is a new ideas function, which describes how the change in technology A' depends upon the existing stocks of labor and capital, and upon the existing level of technology. The parameter is a measure of the effect of the existing technology level A on the change in technology A' . 8. Special Case: Research and Development Model When 0 and 0 SRD1 Y A1 aL L , SRD2 A' Ba L L A SRD3 K ' sY SRD4 L' nL 0 1 0 s 1 n0 Endogenous (4): Y , K ' , A' , L' Predetermined (3): K , A , L Exogenous (6): B , s , n , a K , a L , 9. Analyzing Special Case Research and Development Model When 0 and 0 Defining g A A' / A , it follows that we can rewrite SRD2 as g A Ba L L A 1 . Taking the natural log and differentiating with respect to time yields ASC1 g A' n 1g A gA Multiplying by g A yields ASC2 g A' ng A 1g A . Equation ASC2 is a nonlinear differential equation in g A . We can find the steady state, where the growth rate of technology is constant, by setting g A' 0 in ASC2. Doing so, we find the two steady states g A 0 and ASC3 g A n . 1 If we assume there are diminishing returns to technological improvement, so 0 1 , then the steady state growth rate of technical change given by ASC3 is positive. Taking the derivative of ASC2 with respect to g A allows us to determine whether these steady states are stable or unstable. We find g A' / g A n 2 1g A . Evaluating this derivative at the steady state g A 0 , we have g A' / g A n 0 , which indicates the steady state g A 0 is unstable. Evaluating the derivative at the steady state ASC3, we find g A' / g A n 0 , so the steady state g A n /1 is stable. Thus, we learn that the growth rate of technology converges over time to the rate given by ASC3. The equation ASC3 informs us about the factors that determine the economy’s long run rate of technological growth. A higher population growth rate n leads to a higher rate of technical change, as does a higher level for , which is a measure of the sensitivity of technical change to the population level. The intuition here is that, when an economy contains more people, there is a greater likelihood that a new idea will be produced because there are more people looking for new ideas. As the diminishing returns to technical change gets smaller (i.e., so approaches 1), the steady state rate of technological improvement gets higher. This captures the idea that new technology begets new technology. Notice the variable a L does not appear in ASC3, which implies the portion of labor devote to technical change does not affect the rate of technical change. This is counter-intuitive, since one would tend to think technical change would be faster when a higher percentage of the labor force is devoted to the production of new ideas. The reason for this result is the same reason why an increase in the savings rate in the standard Solow Swan model does not result in a permanent increase in the growth rate of per capita output. The reason is that temporary improvement is eventually outweighed by diminishing returns, so that there is no long term effect. In this case, an increase in a L would lead to a temporary increase in the growth rate of technology. However, because there is diminishing returns to technological improvement, this increase in the growth rate cannot be maintained. (There would have to be continual increases in the percentage of labor allocated to producing new ideas, for the long term growth rate to be effected.) In the long run, this economy follows a balanced growth path that mimics the paths followed by real world developed economies. Taking the natural log of equation SRD1 and differentiating with respect to time, we find gY g A g L . That is, the growth rate of output grows faster than the growth rate of labor, and the difference between the two is the rate of technical change. The growth rate g Y / L of per capita output is equal to the rate of technical change g A , which is what data for the real world indicates. (Can you show this?) 10. Analyzing General Research and Development Model While the special case model just examined tracks the growth rate of technical change alone, the general model tracks the growth rate for both technical change and capital. Eliminating Y from RD3 using RD1, we obtain K ' s1 a K K A1 a L L by K , we can rewrite this equation as AL AGRD1 g K c K K 1 . Dividing 1 , where g K K ' / K and c K s1 a K 1 a L . Equation AGRD1 gives the growth rate of capital as it depends upon the level of technology, the level of labor, the level of capital, and the model’s fixed parameters. By taking the natural log and differentiating with respect to time, we obtain 1 g K' 1 g A n g K , AGRD2 gK where g A A' / A and n L' / L from RD4. Condition AGRD2 describes how the growth rate of capital changes. We will analyze AGRD2, but will wait to do so until we derive a similar condition that describes how the growth rate of technology changes. Dividing RD2 by A , we obtain A' Ba K K a L L A AGRD3 g A c A K L A 1 , where g A A' / A and c A Ba K a L . Equation AGRD3 gives the growth rate of technology as it depends upon the level of technology, the level of labor, the level of capital, and the model’s fixed parameters. By taking the natural log and differentiating with respect to time, we obtain AGRD4 g A' g K n 1g A . gA Together, equations AGRD2 and AGRD4 are a system of two differential equations with state variables g A and g K . We will describe the dynamics of this system using a phase diagram analysis. A good way to begin the phase diagram analysis is to find the “null-clines” for the state variables g A and g K . The g K null-cline are the points in the ( g K , g A ) space where g K' 0 . Because AGRD1 indicates g K is positive, equation AGRD2 implies AGRD5 g 0 g K g A n ' K The g K null-cline is obtained when the equality holds in AGRD5. It separates the case where g K' , is positive, meaning g K is increasing, from the case where g K' is negative, meaning g K is decreasing. Figure 1 shows these two cases Figure 1: The g K null-cline and the dynamics of g K gK gK n g A g K' 0 n g K' 0 gA The g A null-cline are the points in the ( g K , g A ) space where g A' 0 . Because AGRD2 indicates g A is positive, equation AGRD4 implies n 1 AGRD6 g A' 0 g K gA The g A null-cline is obtained when the equality holds in AGRD5. It separates the case where g A' , is positive, meaning g A is increasing, from the case where g A' is negative, meaning g A is decreasing. Figure 2 shows these two cases, assuming 1 . Figure 2: The g A null-cline and the dynamics of g A gK g A' 0 gK n 1 gA g A' 0 n gA By combining the two null clines in one phase diagram, we can describe the dynamics of the system. We do this for the case where 1 / 1 , or 1 , for this is a case where the steady state is a sink, attracting all possible paths to the steady state ( g K , g A ) , as shown in Figure 3. The two null clines divide the ( g K , g A ) space into four space, where the direction of movement is different in each of the four spaces. In space I, each point ( g K , g A ) is below both null clines, which implies g K is increasing and g A is decreasing, as shown. In space III, each point ( g K , g A ) is above both null clines, which implies g K is decreasing and g A is increasing, as shown. Except for the special “manifold” paths that go directly to the steady state, an initial growth rate combination ( g K , g A ) in either space I or space III will eventually enter either space II or space IV. As shown in the figure, when a path hits a null cline there is a change in direction. Once a path enters space II, the growth rates for g K and g A each increase and converge to the steady state ( g K , g A ) . Once a path enters space IV, the growth rates for g K and g A each decrease and converge to the steady state (g K , g A ) . Figure 3: Phase Diagram for General Research and Development Case gK g A null cline IV g K null cline III gK n II n I gA gA The basic message of the phase diagram presented as Figure 3 is, if the system is not in the steady state, it will head to the steady state. So, it is reasonable to examine the steady state and see what we learn. The steady state occurs when we are on both the g K and g A null clines, or where g K' 0 and g A' 0 . When g K' 0 , we know from AGRD5 that g K g A n . When g A' 0 , we know from AGRD6 that g K n / g A 1 / . Using these two equations to eliminate g K and solve for g A , we obtain AGRD7 g A n . 1 Using AGRD7 and g K g A n , we find AGRD8 g K 1 n . 1 Equations AGRD7 and AGRD8 give the steady state growth rates for capital and technology as they depend upon the exogenous variables of the model. Notice the shares a L and a K , of labor and capital allocated to research and development, do not influence the steady state growth rates g K and g A . Nor does the savings rate s . This is somewhat surprising. Changes in these exogenous variables do impact the growth rates in the short term. However, diminishing returns to capital and labor remove these impacts on the growth rates over time. A higher rate of population growth n increases the steady state growth rates g K and g A . This is true even if 0 , which means additional labor does not influence the rate of technical change directly. In this model, more labor generates more output, which increases the rate of capital accumulation, and this also has a positive effect on the growth rate of technology through research and development. Higher values for the parameters and each also increase the steady state growth rates g K and g A . These variables respectively determine the impact of labor growth and capital accumulation on the development of technology. If is large relative to , then technological improvement is coming through labor more so than through capital. Alternatively, if is large relative to , then technological improvement is coming through capital more so than through labor. This model also is consistent with the salient facts about growth experienced in more developed nations. As long as 1 , as we have assumed, conditions AGRD7 and AGRD8 implies g K g A . Using AGRD5, we know g K g A n in the steady state, which implies the growth rate of capital is greater than the growth rate of labor, the difference being the rate of technological improvement. This is a basic growth characteristic of more developed economies. Finally, taking the natural log of RD1 and differentiating with respect to time, we find gY g K 1 g A 1 n would have to hold in the steady state. Eliminating g A from this equation using the knowledge that g K g A n , we find g Y g K , which is also characteristic of more developed economies. 11. LD1 LD2 LD3 LD4 Learning by Doing Y K AL 1 , A BK K ' sY L' nL 0 1, B 0, 0 1 0 s 1 n0 Endogenous (4): Y , K ' , A' , L' Predetermined (3): K , A , L Exogenous (5): B , s , n , , Equation LD2 indicates that new ideas are generated as a side effect of capital accumulation. That is, people learn as they do. They learn how to produce better machines as they do use machines in the production process. This better machines, or new ideas, augment the productivity of labor through equation LD1. 12. Analyzing the Learning by Doing Model Substituting LD1 and LD2 into LD3, we obtain K ' / K sB 1 L1 K 1 1 . Thus, g K sB1 L1 K 1 1 , where g K K ' / K . Taking the natural log and differentiating with respect to time, and using from LD$ the knowledge that L' / L n we obtain g K' / g K 1 n 1 1g K . This implies the change in the growth rate of capital is given by ALD1 g K' 1 ng K 1 1g K 2 We can think of ALD1 as a new model where the variables are classified as follows: Endogenous (1): g K' Predetermined (1): g K Exogenous (5): n , , Notice that the variables B and s do not appear in equation ALD1. This indicates that neither the savings rate nor the capital productivity parameter B affects the rate at which the growth rate of capital change. This also means they will not impact the steady state growth rate for capital. Setting ALD1 equal to zero, we find the steady state growth rate for capital. It is ALD2 g K n . 1 We can find the growth rates for other variables of interest by treating equations LD1 and LD2 as auxiliary equations. Taking the natural log of LD2 and differentiating with respect to time, we find g A g K . Using ALD2, it therefore follows that ALD3 g A n . 1 Taking the natural log of LD1 and differentiating with respect to time, we find gY g K 1 g A 1 n . Using ALD2 and ALD3, it therefore follows that ALD4 g Y n . 1 Using ALD2-ALD4, we see that g Y g K and we see gY g A n , and these results fit what we observe in real world developed economics. Output and capital grow at the same rate in the steady state. This rate is greater than the rate of population growth. And, the rate of technical change is the differences between the growth rate of output and the population growth rate. What is special about this learning by doing model, compared to the Solow Swan model, is that the rate of technical change is endogenously determined by the model. It is not assumed. In particular, equation ALS3 indicates that the steady state rate of technical change depends upon the rate of population growth, and upon the diminishing returns parameter . When the rate of population growth is higher, the rate of technological improvement is greater. This is because population growth fuels output growth, which fuels capital accumulation through saving, which fuels technological improvement. The parameter is the elasticity of technical change with respect to capital accumulation. As is closer to 1, there is less of a diminishing return effect of capital accumulation on technical change, which magnifies the impact that population growth can have. 13. Deriving an AK Model from a Learning by Doing Model For the learning by doing model presented as equations LD1-LD4, assume there is no population growth so n 0 , and assume there are no diminishing returns to learning by doing so 1 . Then we can rewrite the learning by doing model as LDAK1 LDAK2 LDAK3 Y K AL A BK K ' sY 1 , 0 1, B0 0 s 1 0 1, Endogenous (4): Y , K ' , A' Predetermined (3): K , A Exogenous (5): B , s , n , , L Eliminating the variable A from LDAK1 using LDAK2, we obtain Y bK , where 1 b BL . Using LDAK3, we then have K ' sbK , which implies g K sb . Taking the natural log of LDAK2 and differentiating with respect to time, we find g A g K . So, g A sb must also hold. Using the same approach the equation Y bK implies g Y g K . So, g Y sb must also hold. In summary, we know gY g K g A sb . The growth rates of output, capital, and technology are the same, and each depends upon the savings rate and the variable b . This learning by doing presentation of the AK model allows us to offer an interpretation of the AK model that cannot be offered with a presentation of the model that does not include the labor variable. Capital contributes to growth both directly in production and indirectly through improvements in technology obtained from learning by doing. Unlike the Solow Swan model and other endogenous growth models, the savings rate affects rates of economic growth because capital does not experience diminishing returns. Diminishing returns to capital are assumed in production, but they are precisely compensated for by the learning by doing process. An increase in the labor level increases the variable b in the model, which is the average product of capital. This increase in capital productivity enhances economic growth, both directly and through the learning by doing process. 14. Econometric Estimation of Endogenous Growth Models Substituting LD2 into LD1 to eliminate the variable A , we obtain Y B Taking the natural log we obtain 1 L1 K 1 . EE1 ln Y 1 ln B 1 ln L 1 ln K . Equation EE1 is linear in the natural logs. Because of this linearity, we can estimate the coefficients in this equation if we can obtain data on the variables Y , K , and L . If we have data on Y , K , and L , we can construct ln Y , ln K , and ln L . We can then perform a linear regression using the variable ln Y as the dependent variable and the variables ln K , and ln L as independent or explanatory variables. Doing this, the regression software would give us numbers, or estimates for the constant or intercept term 1 ln B , the coefficient 1 on ln L , and the coefficient 1 . Because there are three parameters here ( , , and B ) and three estimates, our regression model is identified, meaning we can find the values of the parameters from the three estimates obtained from the regression. However, equation EE1 is not a good equation to estimate because it will not tend to have good econometric properties. The problem is ln Y , ln K , and ln L will each tend to trend upward over time. When this is the case, heteroskedasticity and serial correlation will tend to arise. A good way to confront this kind of econometric problem is to differentiate with respect to time. Doing so, equation EE1 becomes EE2 gY 1 g L 1 g K . Equation EE2 relates the growth rate of output to the growth rates of labor and capital. If we have data on output, labor, and capital over time, then we can construct these growth rates, run the regression associated with EE2, and find estimates for the parameters and . Letting t denote a given time period, the regression equation associated with EE2 is EE3 g Y ,t 1 g L ,t 1 g K ,t t . In equation EE3, the quantity g Y ,t 1 g L ,t 1 g K ,t is the model or the estimate of the growth rate of output obtained from the learning by doing model. The quantity t is the error term in the regression, which tells us how far the model is from predicting the actual data during time period t . If the econometrics properties of the model are appropriate, then the error term t will be randomly distributed around a mean value of zero, which implies the model sometimes overestimates, sometimes underestimates, sometimes is off by much, sometimes by little. The randomness of the error indicates that we do not know in advance whether the model will over estimate or underestimate for a given period, not can we guess the magnitude of the error for a given period. Using data available for the U.S. from 1949 to 2004, we obtain an estimated equation EE4 g Y ,t 1.049 g L ,t (0.0164)*** 0.115 g K ,t , R 2 .7748 (0.0633)* where the standard errors for the estimated coefficients are shown in parenthesis. The asterisks are used to indicate the level of significance. One asterisk indicates the coefficient is significantly different than zero at a 10 percent level of significance, two asterisks indicates significance at 5 percent, and three asterisks indicates significance at 1 percent. Figure 4 presents the data for the U.S. for the years 1949 to 2004 for the growth rates of output, labor, and capital used in regression EE4. The output level is measured by U.S. real gross domestic product. The labor level is measured by the number of full time equivalent employees. The capital level is measured by the real value of fixed private assets, multiplied by the capacity utilization rate in manufacturing to adjust for the fact that more capital will sit idle in weak economic times than in strong. Notice the following facts can be seen in Figure 4. The average growth rate for output, labor, and capital are positive. A negative growth rate is relatively rare. (By definition, a negative output growth rate is a recession.) Capital growth is more volitile than output growth, and output growth is more volitile than labor growth. Capital and output growth at about the same average rate, while labor grows at a slower rate. For this data, the mean output growth rates is 3.35 percent per year, the mean capital growth rate is 3.44 percent, and the mean labor growth rate is 1.69 percent. Figure 5 shows how the model EE4 fits the actual output growth rate. The positive coefficient estimates in EE4 indicate that output growth is positively correlated with both labor and capital growth. As can be seen in Figure 5, recessions are associated with weak or negative labor and capital growth. Our assumption in running the regression that produces EE4 is that the variations in labor and capital growth are causing the variations observed in output growth. (Another assumption, and one that is problematic, is that labor growth and capital growth are independent. We would not expect independence because employers simultaneously choose how much labor to hire and how much capital to accumulate.) Figure 4: U.S. Growth rates for output, labor, and capital U.S. Growth Rates: 1949-2004 Output, Labor and Capital 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 1945 (0.05) 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 (0.10) (0.15) gY gL gK Figure 5: Fitting the Learning by Doing Model to the Data U.S. Real GDP Growth Rate: 1949-2004 Actual Versus Models 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 1945 (0.02) 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 (0.04) (0.06) gY Learning by Doing Model The estimate 1 1.049 implies the estimate .049 . The estimate 1 0.115 , along with .049 , implies .049 1 .049 0.115 , or 0.115 .049/1 .049 .141 . The estimate .049 is outside the range we have specified for our model, an indication that this model does not quite capture what is happening in the real world. The estimate .141 is our estimate for the elasticity of technical change with respect to capital. This estimate indicates that a 10 percent increase in capital will produce a 1.4 percent increase in the level of technology, an indication that technological change is responsive to capital accumulation, but inelastically responsive. When we re-estimate the model including a constant we obtain EE5 g Y ,t 0.019 0.596 g L ,t 0.129 g K ,t , (0.002)*** (0.116)*** (0.020)*** R 2 .728 The constant estimate of 0.019 indicates that approximately 2 percent of the growth rate of output is not accounted for by the learning by doing model. The purpose of creating the learning by doing model is to account for technical change endogenously, and what we have learned here is that we cannot account for all of it. We can think of the 0.019 number as independent exogenous technical change, and put it into the model if we recast the learning by doing model letting B e t . Reworking the model to the econometric equation, we find the constant is an estimate of 1 , or 1 0.019 . With this new model, 1 .596 , so .404 and 0.019 /1 0.019 / .596 .032 . Thus, for this model we obtain a realistic value for the variable , which is the elasticity of output with respect to capital under the assumption, abstracting from the effect capital has on technology. The number .404 indicates that, if capital did not affect technology, then a 10 percent increase in capital would generate a 4 percent increase in output. The number .032 indicates the average product of capital increases at 3.2 percent per year, for some reason that we do not understand at this point. For this model 1 0.128 . Using .404 , we obtain 0.46 . Unfortunately, this is not consistent with the learning by doing hypothesis. The negative number indicates capital accumulation has a negative impact on technological change. What we are learning here is that econometric analysis, which forces us to relate our theory to the data, can usefully force us to rethink our theory. The learning by doing model which endogenizes technical change in EE4 indicates capital accumulation has a negative impact on production, which does not make sense. The learning by doing model which allows for some exogenous technical change in EE5 indicates capital accumulation has a negative impact on technology, which indicates we unlearn by doing rather than learn. We must continue to search for an improved model. Let’s adjust the model by recognizing that two our assumption of constant returns to scale with respect to labor and capital may not hold, especially since it is unlikely that our capital variable captures the effect of all non labor inputs in production. To account for this, let’s re-specify equation LD1 as EE6 Y K AL , 0 1, 0 1, If production exhibits constant returns to scale, then 1 should hold, at least approximately. While we are interested in an endogenous model of technical change, let’s start with an exogenous model of technical change so we can first get an idea of whether a constant returns to scale assumption is reasonable. In particular, assume EE7 A ae 0 1t 2t 2 3t 3 , which implies the level of technology changes over time at the exogenous rate EE8 g A 1 2 2 t 33 t 2 , Substituting EE8 into EE7, taking the natural log, and differentiating with respect to time, we obtain the following equation that we can estimate EE9 g Y 1 22 t 33t 2 g K g L . The result of our estimation is EE10 g Y .0325 .0012t .00002t 2 .149 g K .574 g L , R 2 .7704 (.005)*** (.0004)*** (.000007)*** (.04)*** (.11)*** Thus, we find .574 and .149 , or .723 1 , an indication of decreasing returns to scale. Reconstructing EE9 using the estimates, we find g A .057 .002t .0003t 2 . This indicates the rate of technical change has followed a u-shape in the U.S. over the 1949-2004 period, as shown in Figure 7 below. This is sensible in that we might have expecting some significant technical change after World War II in manufacturing, which would have played itself out over time. The increase in the rate of technical change more recently might be associated with innovations in the computer and communications industries. Knowing that our production function is unlikely to exhibit constant returns to scale, lets now extend the learning by doing model by replacing equation LD2 with EE11 A BK (t ) L (t ) , where EE12 (t ) 0 1t 2 t 2 3 t 3 and EE13 (t ) 0 1t 2 t 2 3 t 3 . This is a more general model of technical change in two respects. First, the level the technology can be affected by both capital accumulation and labor accumulation. So, learning by doing not only can occur because more machines are built, but also because there are more people building machines, or more people doing. Second, the elasticity of technology with respect to capital (t ) can change over time, as can the elasticity of technology with respect to labor (t ) . Substituting EE11 into the production function EE6, taking the natural log, differentiating with respect to time, and then using EE12 and EE13, yields the following equation that we can estimate: 3 ln K t g t ln L g t 3 ln L t 2 ln L t g Y 0 g L 0 g K 1 g K t ln K 2 g K t 2 2 ln K t EE14 g t 3 g K t 3 3 L 3 2 1 2 L 2 L 2 Constructing the explanatory variables as needed in EE14 and running the appropriate linear regression, we find that the variables g K t 3 3 ln K t 2 and g Lt 3 3 ln L t 2 do not have a significant explantory effect, so we drop them. The resulting estimated equation, with all coefficients significantly different than zero at a 10 percent level of significance, is g Y .436 g L .265 g K .0137g K t ln K .0002 g K t 2 2 ln K t .013g L t ln L .0002 g L t 2 ln L t EE15 2 . Comparing the coefficients of the variables in EE14 to those of EE15, we can see that there are two more parameters in EE14 than estimated coefficients in EE15, which implies the regression model is under identified. One way to still use the estimates in EE15 is to specify values for two of the parameters in EE14. Suppose we assume .574 and .149 as we obtained from EE10. This allows us to see the implications these fixed parameters have when we assume they are true but allow for endogenous technical change. Using .574 and .149 , we find from EE14 and EE15 that (t ) .764 .024t .0004t 2 gives the time dependent elasticity of technology with respect to capital and (t ) .203 .023t .0004t 2 gives the time dependent elasticity of technology with respect to labor. These are shown in Figure 6. Our results indicate something interesting. As the manufacturing developed over the 1949-1980 period, the evidence indicates learning by doing came less from accumulating capital and more from accumulating labor. Learning by doing through capital accumulation has shown a resurgence and learning by doing through labor a decline more recently, during what we might labor the information age. Figure 6: Elasticity of Technology with Respect to Capital and Labor Elasticity of Technology 0.90 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 With Respect to Capital 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 With Respect to labor Figure 7 shows the rate of technical change estimated from the exogenous technical change model EE10 and the endogenous technical change model EE 15. Notice the u-shape in the exogenous technical change model matches the u-shape for the elasticity of technology with respect to capital in the endogenous technical change model. This is an indication that changes in learning by doing with respect to capital may have been responsible for the change in technical change we obtain when we do not try specify from where it comes. The estimated path for technical change for the endogenous technical change model is volitile because labor and capital growth rates vary, and these are assumed to impact the rate of technical change. A slight u-shape is still noticable in the endogenous technical change path, however, which is consistent with the estimate for technical change obtained from the exogenous technical change model. Figure 7: Estimated paths for the Rate of Technical Change for the U.S. Economy Rate of Technical Change 0.080 0.060 0.040 0.020 1945 (0.020) 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 (0.040) (0.060) Exogenous Tech Change Endogenous Tech Change 2000 2005