Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 1 INTERVIEW WITH PROF. EUGENE FAMA BY PROF. RICHARD ROLL August 15, 2008 (edited for clarity and readability) RICHARD ROLL: Good morning. The American Finance Association is conducting a series of interviews with founding contributors to the field of finance. I am happy to say that the founding contributor for today is Professor Eugene Fama of the University of Chicago. He is probably the most widely cited finance professor ever. So, I’m going to ask about your research, of course, but first let's talk about some personal things, like family background. I know the name Fama was mentioned in the Iliad. I don’t want to go back that far, but how about a little background about your parents and grandparents? EUGENE FAMA: My grandparents emigrated from Sicily to Boston around the turn of the 20th century. I think my grandfather’s family had 13 children. They all moved at the same time. My grandmother’s family also moved at the same time, and they had 13 children of their own. [LAUGHTER] So, within 50 years the Boston phonebook was full of Famas. Everybody lived in Boston. I think I was the first one in the family, third generation, to go to college. I went to Tufts, basically, because they had a good athletic department. RICHARD ROLL: You played high-school football, right? EUGENE FAMA: Yes. My high-school team won the state football championship. They came in second in baseball, and the hockey team, I didn’t play hockey, but the hockey team won the state championship almost every year. RICHARD ROLL: Was that Malden Catholic? Hall of Fame there? EUGENE FAMA: Right. You are in the Athletic Hall of Fame. RICHARD ROLL: They have a Hall of Fame at Malden Catholic? I see. And then at Tufts you played baseball too? EUGENE FAMA: I got less serious about sports at Tufts because Sally, my wife, and I were married by the time we 1 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 2 were just turning 20. We had a child by the time I was a junior, and so sports became less important. Getting on with my life and education became more important. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: You were a French major? For the first two years. Then what happened? EUGENE FAMA: I got bored with Voltaire. Reading the same stuff over and over again just wasn’t appealing to me. I had taken an economics course. I loved it, and I was pretty good at it. The professors were reading my exams to the class. I thought maybe I should stick to this. It was much more interesting. Then, when I was graduating I was trying to go off to business school. I wanted to go for a PhD, and I really didn’t have much of an intention of working for a living. I wanted something that would allow me to continue my sports life. [LAUGHTER] RICHARD ROLL: You mean you thought PhDs didn’t have to do any work. [LAUGHTER] EUGENE FAMA: Right. Or at least they could do it when they pleased. So I went to my professors and said “where should I apply?” They were all Harvard graduates, and they said "Go the University of Chicago. Harvard is not intellectual enough for you, at least not the business school. So go to Chicago." There’s a really funny story about Chicago. RICHARD ROLL: into Chicago. Yeah? Tell us the story about how you got EUGENE FAMA: So, April comes along. It's the end of April, and I haven’t heard a word. The school was much smaller then. I called, and the Dean of Students actually answered the phone. I said, “I haven’t heard anything about my application”. He’s fumbling around with the papers. He said, “We have no record of your application.” I said, “What, I sent this in months ago”. He said, “Well, what school did you go to?” I said, “Tufts.” He said, “Pretty good grades?” I said, “Yeah, pretty much straight A’s.” He said, “Well we just happen to have a scholarship for somebody from Tufts. Do you want it?” [LAUGHTER] 2 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 3 That’s how I ended up in Chicago. They wouldn’t let me in the PhD program right away. So Joel Siegel, who was the director of the PhD program at that time, said to me at the beginning of the first quarter, “You know, graduate school is a lot different from undergraduate school. I said, “Fine.” So at the end of the quarter I went up to him, and I said, ”You know, you were right, graduate school is much easier." The competition was much fiercer at Tufts than it was at Chicago in the business school in those days. So they let me into the PhD program at that point. RICHARD ROLL: That was 1960. You graduated from Tufts, went immediately to Chicago, and you’ve been at Chicago ever since. Right? So 1960 to 2008. That's 50 years. When you try something you don’t give up that easily. Well, your wife too. You mentioned you married Sally when you were still in college. EUGENE FAMA: ranch. We just had our 50th anniversary, at your RICHARD ROLL: Right, in fact you’ve stayed in Chicago except for visiting a couple of places. EUGENE FAMA: A year and a half in Belgium. RICHARD ROLL: A year and a half in Belgium, and I think you visited out here a couple times. EUGENE FAMA: UCLA in the winters for a while. RICHARD ROLL: But other than that you’ve been at Chicago. Is there anyone who has been there longer? EUGENE FAMA: I think I’m the longest serving in the whole University. I’m not totally sure of that. RICHARD ROLL: anytime soon? They’re not insisting that you retire EUGENE FAMA: Well, you’re aware that we are classified as non-essential workers. So, we can’t be forcibly retired. RICHARD ROLL: What about your family, your children? EUGENE FAMA: We have four children, two adult men, two adult women, and ten grandchildren. 3 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 4 RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Los Angeles. Ten grandchildren! Split just about evenly between Chicago and RICHARD ROLL: That’s very productive. It’s not thirteen. You said you’re grandparents had thirteen. So the Fama’s are slowing down a little bit. EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: Right. Well, not that much. [LAUGHTER] RICHARD ROLL: Let’s talk about your research career. I think that’s the main reason we’re doing these tapings. We are getting people to talk about what they’ve contributed. You have published, I think right around a hundred papers, mostly in the top journals. In The Journal of Finance, I think you have something like … I counted them … did you ever count them? EUGENE FAMA: No RICHARD ROLL: There are twenty in The Journal of Finance. And there are nineteen in the Journal of Financial Economics. Those are probably the two top journals in finance. You’ve got about twelve in the Journal of Business. Nine in the AER. You’ve got the JPE. And you have published papers in five decades. EUGENE FAMA: How about with you in the Journal of American Statistical Association? RICHARD ROLL: And the Journal of American Statistical Association. You’ve got something like thirty-five papers in other miscellaneous journals like the Journal of Monetary Economics. EUGENE FAMA: When I was younger it was much easier to publish in other fields than it is now. They’ve all become much more technical. They wouldn’t even look at any of my self now. RICHARD ROLL: Well, it’s also true that it’s hard to publish in finance. Isn’t it? You’ve got a lot more people competing for the slots. 4 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 5 EUGENE FAMA: Yeah. RICHARD ROLL: It doesn’t look as if that has slowed you down, because if you look at the five decades that you’ve published papers: the sixties, seventies, eighties, nineties and two thousand. I actually calculated that you have been publishing a little more than two and a half papers per year in every decade. How can you keep doing that with all this increase in competition? Do you have to keep getting better and better? EUGENE FAMA: No. You have to pick up somebody like Ken French, who is a compulsive worker. RICHARD ROLL: French? How many papers did you published with Ken EUGENE FAMA: I haven’t counted them, but almost everything since the late eighties. RICHARD ROLL: I think it’s about twenty-eight, something like that. He’s been a good co-author for you. EUGENE FAMA: Yeah. He has the same work habits that I do. So we work very well together. We almost never see each other face to face. RICHARD ROLL: What do you mean the same work habits? EUGENE FAMA: He works seven days a week. I work seven days a week. He works a full day. I don’t work a full day anymore. [laughing] I have to go windsurfing or something, golf in the afternoon. But he works from dawn to dusk except for a bike-ride in the middle of the day. RICHARD ROLL: Really, well that explains the fact that I guess even though you have a lot more people who are trying to get space in the journals you’ve worked harder and you’ve gotten him to work. What about some of your other co-authors like Michael Jensen for instance. EUGENE FAMA: Jensen and I wrote a couple of papers early in the nineteen-eighties, and of course, you, he and I have a very famous paper from the late-sixties. 5 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 6 RICHARD ROLL: But some of the stuff you did with him was more on agency theory and corporate finance. EUGENE FAMA: Actually, Mike has one of the most highly cited papers on agency theory, the Jensen Meckling piece. My piece in the JPE, without Mike, comes in very high I think. Which is a shock to me. I never really realized that until somebody told me it was assigned to lots of students in economics. Then Mike and I wrote a sequence of three papers on the theory of organizations, which is basically agency theory. They have done very well. And I can tell you, we fought over every word in each of those three papers. Every word was a three-hour discussion. RICHARD ROLL: Well that takes a lot of time to fight all the time, doesn’t it? EUGENE FAMA: It does. RICHARD ROLL: Is that why Ken and you, who go through fights so much, is that why you are a more productive duo than most? EUGENE FAMA: [laughing] Well, the Fama-Jensen papers have served us very well. RICHARD ROLL: What about some other people, like Harvey Babiak, what’s happened with him? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: with him. Harvey Babiak was a PhD student. You did a famous paper on dividend policy EUGENE FAMA: Yeah, dividend policy. Unfortunately he died shortly after getting his degree. And Jim MacBeth also died. I have a funny story about Jim MacBeth. I don’t know if you want me to tell it. RICHARD ROLL: MacBeth. I was going to ask about the paper did with EUGENE FAMA: Jim MacBeth was a very good PhD student. He was working for me, and we were working on the Fama-MacBeth paper. Fischer Black had the office next to mine. Fischer came in very early in the morning. I came in very early in 6 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 7 the morning, and Jim came in very early in the morning. Every morning Fischer and I would have a discussion. Finally after about two weeks Jim MacBeth says to me, “You know I’m from Kansas, and if people from Kansas talked to each other that way, some one would end up getting shot. I said, “This is a good friend of mine, we’re not fighting or anything, we are just discussing research.” To him it sounded like we were ready to kill one another. RICHARD ROLL: We might as well talk about the Fama-Macbeth paper because that is one of the most widely cited papers, and it pioneered a technique in finance that was very unusual at the time. EUGENE FAMA: I’ll tell you how that came about. Black, Jensen and Scholes published a paper on testing the CAPM. And in one of the arguments I had with Fischer, I said, “You know, Fischer, with that technique where you form portfolios, all you are doing is running a regression. He said, “No it’s not that.” I said, “Yes, it is.” “No, it isn’t.” “Yes, it is.” So, I said. “We are going to write this paper to show you that is what it does.” The paper doesn’t really describe it in those terms, but if you read chapter nine of The Foundations of Finance, it describes it exactly in those terms. That’s what’s going on. So basically I wrote The Foundations of Finance in order to show Fischer in detail that these two techniques were exactly the same. What the Fama-Macbeth paper does is it gives you a framework for conducting cross-section tests of asset pricing models, or anything where you have something resembling panel data. You can get standard errors that don’t require you to estimate the covariance matrix of the residuals. That is very important because the covariance matrix is typically too big to estimate if you have a cross section of stock returns, for example. And this technique produces correct standard errors. RICHARD ROLL: You mention panel data. I think that at the time you wrote that paper with MacBeth, nobody had used the term "panel data". EUGENE FAMA: No. And we didn’t either. RICHARD ROLL: You didn’t use the term, but since then, it’s been a widely used term in economics. You had a time series of cross-sections. That used economics as well as econometrics because the insight about testing the time 7 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 8 series coefficients was that those things were like portfolio returns. Yours was one of the first papers that really did that. EUGENE FAMA: They are portfolio returns. RICHARD ROLL: They are portfolio returns, and they should be independent over time. So you should get a standard error for that, which is easier to test. That was a major contribution to the testing of asset-pricing models. EUGENE FAMA: Well, it’s made its way into cross sectional regressions of all sorts because of this advantage it has. RICHARD ROLL: But sometimes the coefficients in the crosssection are not portfolio returns. EUGENE FAMA: They don’t have to be. It doesn’t matter. RICHARD ROLL: People do it with variances and such. And that would be exactly the same thing. EUGENE FAMA: Right. It doesn’t have the same economic interpretation, but it has the same statistical advantages. RICHARD ROLL: Let me turn to another line of research. Your first paper, the very first paper you published, was called Mandelbrot and the Stable Paretian Hypothesis. That was, I think, in 63’ or something like that. EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: all about? Maybe earlier. A little before my thesis. Yeah, before you finished. What was that EUGENE FAMA: Well, and this is the period when work on efficient markets wasn’t called that. Work on stock market returns was just beginning to take hold. It was more or less restricted to the University of Chicago and MIT. Modigliani was at MIT, and Merton Miller was at the University of Chicago. They were both interested in this. Harry Roberts was also at the University of Chicago. RICHARD ROLL: Harry Roberts, yeah. EUGENE FAMA: Harry Roberts was very interested in it. He had written a paper on “random walks” in stock market 8 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 9 prices around that time. So, there was a lot of interest. Benoit Mandelbrot came and visited for a quarter. He came periodically thereafter quite a bit. So, I spent a lot of time with him, and if you look at my thesis, about twothirds of it is on the distribution of stock returns, not on the time-series behavior. RICHARD ROLL: Well, you know if you look at his website, he says you’re his student. [laughing] EUGENE FAMA: Well, in some sense that’s true. Harry Roberts and Merton Miller are really important, but I’m Mandelbrot’s student in the sense that two-thirds of my thesis was a take-off on his work. RICHARD ROLL: So, explain what these distributions are. EUGENE FAMA: Benoit had spent his life showing that almost all stochastic variables are fat-tailed. He characterizes them with this class of stable distributions which we are all very familiar with. For example the Nile river overflows way more then you would expect if rain follows a normal distirbution. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Or we have market crashes more often. We have market crashes way more often. RICHARD ROLL: The crash of 87’ would happen every hundred and fifty billion years. EUGENE FAMA: A zillion. Even more than that. A twenty standard deviation event. That’s almost totally unlikely. RICHARD ROLL: So fat tails means that these very unusual things happen much more frequently. EUGENE FAMA: Right. The pencil leaves the paper more often than you would ever predict under normal distribution. So he had a substantial influence. But basically it was Harry Roberts and Merton Miller at that time. RICHARD ROLL: Those were the people that encouraged you to work on your thesis, which was on stock return distributions? 9 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 10 EUGENE FAMA: Well as I’ve said, we had two children by the time I came along to writing my thesis my third year at the school. So economics were pressing from another perspective, and I wanted to get done. I went to Merton with five topics that I thought I could pursue. He went through them and said, “No. No. No. No. Do this one.” That was the thesis. Basically, he said, “Do the distribution of stock returns.” RICHARD ROLL: That turned into a famous piece of work, The Behavior of Stock Market Prices, which is one of the most widely cited things in finance. EUGENE FAMA: But if you look in there, there is no clear statement of what an efficient market is. It wasn’t in any of the research at that time. RICHARD ROLL: Later, but not that much later in the early seventies, you wrote a review paper. By that time, people had been talking about efficient markets. You gave a complete analysis of it in that review paper. So, talk about now, 2008, what does efficient market mean to you these days? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: information. What does it mean to me? Yes. What is an efficient market? Well, in the extreme form, prices reflect all That model is almost surely false. RICHARD ROLL: All information that anybody has you mean? That’s a strong form. EUGENE FAMA: That’s really strong. It can’t possibly be true. No model is ever true, but I think it’s a good approximation for almost every practical purpose I’ve come across. So I think it was and is a good approximation to the way prices actually behave. RICHARD ROLL: Well, for instance, one of the early things about efficient markets was that Harry Roberts had this idea that it applies to technical trading rules, those kind of things, mechanical and costless things. That’s probably still true, don’t you think, essentially? Are there exceptions to that? 10 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 11 EUGENE FAMA: What the seventies review paper that I wrote said was that you couldn’t test market efficiency without combining it with some hypothesis about what the market is trying to do. You needed a model of market equilibrium. So basically you need an asset-pricing model. Then you can test market efficiency. The reverse is also true. You can’t test most asset pricing models without testing market efficiency. There’s always this joint-hypothesis problem, both in tests of market efficiency and in tests of asset pricing models. I forgot what the question is. RICHARD ROLL: Well, we were talking about technical … EUGENE FAMA: Technical trading rules. You see, that doesn’t work anymore because, for example, there’s lots of work on the predictability of returns. And predictability of returns isn’t ruled out by market efficiency. Once you take into account that the expected return is just a price. The price can vary through time, and it can vary in predictable ways. All you are looking at is the evolution. RICHARD ROLL: That’s the evolution of expected returns. Or maybe the evolution of risk premiums. However, the deviations about it … EUGENE FAMA: The deviations about that have to be random. That’s the definition of efficiency. RICHARD ROLL: Yes. But would a long-term investor make extra return if he takes advantage of these time varying expected returns? EUGENE FAMA: No, he wouldn’t be able to. In fact, Ken and I wrote lots of the papers, and I wrote some before I started working with Ken, on predictability. And I’m really skeptical of that literature. Enough stuff has come since then that says there are funny statistical problems involved in these tests, and that the evidence of predictability is not that solid. What that says to me in practical terms is the standard errors are too big. You are not going to be able to take advantage of it. RICHARD ROLL: That makes me think back about the stable distributions too, because you said that Mandlebrot had this idea that these were a particular class of distributions. The alternative is that you have non stationary mixtures which produce these fat tails. One type 11 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 12 of non stationarity would be changes in means. That won’t produce fat tails, but variances could do that. EUGENE FAMA: Variances could do that easily. RICHARD ROLL: But those are more predictable probably. Don’t you think? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: stuff, right? EUGENE FAMA: predictable. I don’t know. Well, there’s ARCH and GARCH and all that That stuff says that volatility is more RICHARD ROLL: But, it’s time varying. So when you unconditionally mix those things together… EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: They can become fat-tailed. Do you think Mandlebrot is right. EUGENE FAMA: Jim Press wrote a statistics text book. He also wrote a couple of papers back in the seventies, I think, back when he was at the University of Chicago. He showed that you could generate Mandlebrot’s stable distributions as mixtures of normals with changing variances. RICHARD ROLL: So that’s a hypothesis. Which is right? EUGENE FAMA: Oh empirically, they’re indistinguishable. Press said you could get the stable class. RICHARD ROLL: stable? Can you test whether it is a mixture or EUGENE FAMA: No. Well, maybe you could, but you’d have to have a specific model about the mixture. RICHARD ROLL: Let’s go to dividends. You mentioned Babiak and your paper on dividends. First, tell us what that was about. Secondly, let’s scroll forward to disappearing dividends and talk about what that’s about. That’s another paper, by the way, with Ken French, so tell us about that. 12 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 13 EUGENE FAMA: Harvey Babiak and I wrote this paper back in the seventies. I forget the exact title. We basically looked at dividend policies of individual firms. John Lintner had written his thesis on dividend policy, but all he had was aggregate data. Compustat came along in the early seventies. So Harvey and I tested Lintner’s model on individual companies, and we estimated speed of adjustment coefficients. RICHARD ROLL: Lintner’s model was that companies are slow to change their dividends? EUGENE FAMA: In Lintner’s model, companies are slow to change their dividends. They have a target dividend, which is just a fraction of earnings, but they only adjust partially to the target. So it was a partial adjustment model. The statistical issue was to estimate the pay out ratio. RICHARD ROLL: Why do companies do that? Are they choosing that policy for some signaling reason? It reminds me of another paper. EUGENE FAMA: [laughing] Right, Fischer’s paper. Why do firms pay dividends? The answer is three words. I don’t know. RICHARD ROLL: Well, there is this idea that firms use changes in dividends to signal what they think the future prospects are going to be. EUGENE FAMA: And people have tried to test that, with little success. RICHARD ROLL: Is it true your paper with Ken about disappearing dividends seems to go back to Fischer’s thing, in the sense that now firms seem to be cutting dividends and buying up shares. EUGENE FAMA: In 1978, so this is five years after we have CRSP data on NYSE, AMEX and NASDAQ, you get the full sample. In 1978 I think around eighty percent of companies on those three exchanges were paying dividends. By 2000 the number had fallen to something a little less than twenty percent. I think it might have come back a little bit since then, but I’m not sure. 13 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 14 RICHARD ROLL: Those companies are still paying out cash, they’re just using share repurchases. EUGENE FAMA: There is lots of work on repurchases. think much of it overstates repurchases. RICHARD ROLL: I It overstates the extent of repurchases? EUGENE FAMA: Yeah, because companies do a lot of repurchasing. They buy the stock back. Then it goes immediately into employee benefit plans, and things like that. If you try to net it out, it is much less important than if you look at gross repurchases, where it looks like everybody’s doing massive amounts. It turns out that most of the repurchasing is done by the same companies that pay dividends. RICHARD ROLL: So the net of this sounds like companies are just retaining a lot more cash? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Yes. They are retaining a lot more cash. And why is that? I have no idea. RICHARD ROLL: No idea? Do they have better investment opportunities? EUGENE FAMA: It’s a good research question, because I don’t think this phenomenon is observed in other countries. I have always said I wish you could measure tax effects some way. I don’t think it’s very easy to measure tax effects, but here’s a case where you’ll observe that most countries don’t have double taxation of dividends. The US does, and dividends have slowly disappeared, whereas they haven’t in other countries. I think that is important from a corporate governance perspective. RICHARD ROLL: Yeah, because they’re accumulating more cash, and they are spending it. Maybe not so wisely in some cases. EUGENE FAMA: [LAUGHING] Right. 14 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 15 RICHARD ROLL: One of my favorite papers that you wrote was on inflation and short-term interest rates as predictors of inflation. EUGENE FAMA: it. That does have a funny story associated with RICHARD ROLL: Just to tell the audience about it, at the time you wrote the paper, there had been a lot of tests of the Fischer equation relation between inflation and interest rates, but they had all done stuff like build models of inflation and use those inflation rates to predict short-term interest rates. Basically you turned it around. Tell us how you got that idea. EUGENE FAMA: This is when personal computers were first coming out. Bob Graves sent me one. He figured I was a big mainframe user, and I was poo-pooing this latest box that had come around. So he sent me one, and it wasn’t good for anything. I don’t know how many memory locations it had. So I said, well maybe I’ll just take these two time series and see how they’re related. The idea was, and I don’t know how people had missed it, was if you’re looking for the effect of expected inflation on interest rates, you want to put the x-post variable on the left, and you want to put the forecasting variable on the right. Until then people had run it the other way. They basically didn’t realize that with a regression you are estimating a conditional expected value. Conditional expected value on the left-hand side is a function of the right-hand side variable. That made it natural to put the interest rate on the right rather than on the left. RICHARD ROLL: there too. But you had an efficient market idea in EUGENE FAMA: Well, yeah, the efficient market idea is that interest rates should incorporate the best possible forecast of inflation. That is basically all they have to do plus the expected real rate of return. RICHARD ROLL: Well, I think that is an important insight because the way you run that equation, first of all you know you should put the expectation on the right, secondly you know that there shouldn’t be anything else on the right-hand side, if you have the right expected inflation on it. But you tested that. 15 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 16 EUGENE FAMA: Right, the test works in those data, which I call the golden age of the Fischer effect because it’s the only period in time where the expected real short-term rate didn’t vary very much. Before that, the short rate was basically zero from the late thirties to the early fifties, and after that, the tests I did in that paper-work don’t work. RICHARD ROLL: They don’t give you a coefficient of one? EUGENE FAMA: No. You need a better model for the expected real rate of return. RICHARD ROLL: But, they still work in the sense that the short-term interest rate does predict inflation. It’s just that it’s also interesting, and I don’t know haw many people know this, but if you look at different forecast horizons, one month, three-months, six-months, the remarkable thing is the further out you went the better it predicted. Do you remember that? EUGENE FAMA: That is a simple phenomenon though. That’s a mechanical phenomenon. Basically what is happening is that expected inflation has high auto correlation. I am working with continuously compounded returns. So the residuals just add. There is no covariance. But the forecasting part has all these covariances that are building up. So the fraction of the variance that you explain actually gets bigger along the horizons. But the residual variance grows like the number of periods. RICHARD ROLL: What about some of the other papers that followed on term-structure? EUGENE FAMA: Give me a tool and I’ll use it multiple times. [LAUGHTER] RICHARD ROLL: You looked at risk premiums in the term structure for instance. Let’s talk about that. EUGENE FAMA: Well, after the inflation papers, I took up the issue of how well forward interest rates, and forward exchange rates, predict future spot rates. The technique was the same. You put the ex post variable on the left. You put the ex ante variable on the right, and you run a regression. The interest rate forecasting papers basically 16 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 17 said that forward interest rates didn’t contain that much information about future spot rates beyond a couple of months. So the variation you would observe in the forward rate is basically variation in expected risk premiums. RICHARD ROLL: What about exchange rates? EUGENE FAMA: With exchange rates, and there are many hedge funds operating on the same principle. What do they call it now? The carry or something like that? RICHARD ROLL: The carry trade. EUGENE FAMA: Right. It says that if forward rates don’t predict future spot-interest rates RICHARD ROLL: Exchange rates, EUGENE FAMA: Sorry, future exchange rates. Then forward rates are picking up the difference of the expected bonds of the two countries, and that has worked, I guess. RICHARD ROLL: Well, that’s the same thing. If the forward spot rate is the forward exchange rate, if that is a good predictor, then the carry trade won’t work. But if it is not a very good predictor, then is that an arbitrage thing? EUGENE FAMA: It’s not an arbitrage, no. RICHARD ROLL: It's speculation. But is it one that beats the risk involved, the carry trade? People have been doing this for a while. They make a lot of money for a short period, and then they get killed. So it’s one of these, kind of funny distributions. EUGENE FAMA: Well, it’s basically working under the hypothesis that purchasing power parity doesn’t hold. And purchasing power parity may not hold in the short term, but it is really pushing things to say it’s not going to hold in the long term. I don’t believe that. I think it does hold in the long term. RICHARD ROLL: So, you think the Euro is going to come down against the dollar? We were just in France eating dinner at places that were horribly expensive because the exchange rate is one point six dollars per Euro. That doesn’t sound like purchasing power parity is holding very well, does it? 17 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 18 EUGENE FAMA: You’d have to do all the tests. That’s a different topic. The exchange rate hasn’t come anywhere near balancing the current account deficit. RICHARD ROLL: No, of course not. But I don’t know. It doesn’t seem to me that one point six dollars per Euro comes anywhere close to purchasing power parity, does it? EUGENE FAMA: test it out. It doesn’t, but I don’t know, I’d have to RICHARD ROLL: Yeah. (LAUGHTER) How about we go to another topic? We were talking about inflation. You wrote some other papers about inflation, one with Bill Schwert, who was another student at Chicago, later than me. Talk about inflation and stock prices. That’s a very big topic. Today we saw the inflation rate was five point eight percent in the US. It’s not as bad as in Zimbabwe, which is three billion percent per annum. But what is going to happen if the inflation rate keeps going up? What is going to happen to the stock market, and why should stocks go down when inflation goes up? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: Oh, I think that result disappeared actually. The Schwert result where you use inflation? EUGENE FAMA: The paper about asset returns and inflation was an off-shoot of the paper about interest rates and inflation, which we talked about. The economic proposition is that every asset class should be a hedge against expected inflation. Not just bonds, but stocks, and everything you look at. Human capital, real estate, everything should be a hedge against expected inflation. So, we ran the regressions of nominal asset returns on, short term interest rates, one month, three months, six months. Again, this was during the golden age of the Fischer effect, and everything produced a slope of one. Which is saying on average these are pretty good hedges against expected inflation, except stock returns. They had a big negative number. RICHARD ROLL: That was kind of a puzzle, right? EUGENE FAMA: It was a puzzle, because what it says is either the stock market is inefficient and all other 18 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 19 markets are efficient, which doesn’t make sense to me, or the hypothesis that the expected real return of stocks is unrelated to expected inflation is wrong. It’s got to be negatively related to expected inflation to make that work. So then I wrote another paper in the AER, about stock returns. I forget what it’s called. RICHARD ROLL: Demand for money? EUGENE FAMA: There’s two of them. One was about the demand for money, which basically said you’re going to see high inflation when real activity goes down relative to money supply. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: It’s a spurious correlation? Right. RICHARD ROLL: But you said it’s no longer true. Would the Fama-Schwert model still have that negative coefficient on inflation? EUGENE FAMA: I’ve had students do papers on this for my PhD course. What happens now is you can’t tell the difference between the slope and zero anymore. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Really? Right, it’s not that it’s plus one. RICHARD ROLL: Well, does that have anything to do with the golden age of the Fischer effect? (LAUGHTER) EUGENE FAMA: It might have something to do with it. But what I said in the AER paper was basically, if you account for expectations of real activity, then that negative slope went away. That made it plausible that what you were looking at was time variation in expected returns related to real activity. At that point I didn’t think it was a problem anymore. RICHARD ROLL: We mentioned a bunch of people who were your PhD students: MacBeth, Babiak, Jensen, EUGENE FAMA: And you (LAUGHTER) RICHARD ROLL: And me. 19 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 20 EUGENE FAMA: And Myron. RICHARD ROLL: And Myron. There have been a lot. Do you know how many students have you supervised? EUGENE FAMA: Oh, no. RICHARD ROLL: I tried to find something out about that on the website. Do they keep records? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: had… EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Not very good ones. So every year for forty-eight years you’ve On average, maybe two a year. That’s like ninety. Around a hundred. RICHARD ROLL: That’s right. A hundred, and most of them are still practicing finance. EUGENE FAMA: Right RICHARD ROLL: Some of them aren’t professors though. You’ve had a couple of students who’ve started hedge funds. EUGENE FAMA: Right. Lots of colleagues have started hedge funds too. Everybody with a marginal statistical result comes out with a hedge fund these days. (LAUGHTER) They lever it up, but that doesn’t change the t-statistic. RICHARD ROLL: student? What about Cliff Asness? Was he a PhD EUGENE FAMA: Yes. He was the best student we had in maybe twenty years. He never published his thesis, but there were three essays in his thesis that were just first rate. Now he’s a very successful investment manager. RICHARD ROLL: So he decided to make money instead of following the intellectual life. Well, I guess those two aren’t incompatible. 20 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 21 EUGENE FAMA: David Booth is another. RICHARD ROLL: Yeah. We talked before about your stability. You went to Chicago, you stayed there. You married Sally, and stuck with it. How about DFA? You started in '82, and here you are. EUGENE FAMA: Right, I'm still involved. Lots of people have used my finance ideas over the years. Usually they don’t pay you. (LAUGHTER) They just use the ideas. But David Booth and Rex Sinquefield decided it made sense to have me actually involved with the company. I think it has worked out well for both sides. RICHARD ROLL: Do you want to talk about that? EUGENE FAMA: Well, basically David and Rex were strong believers in market efficiency. As strong as anybody I know, including me. They were convinced that professional investment managers really couldn’t add any value, and they started the company, basically on the proposition that defined benefit pension plans weren’t invested enough in small stocks. That was an asset class that they could provide, and there would be a market for it. RICHARD ROLL: this… And that didn’t have anything to do with EUGENE FAMA: Well, let me finish. When they brought me along I said, “you’ve come along at just the right time, because Rolf Banz has just finished his thesis that says, small stocks have expected returns that can’t be explained very well by the capital asset pricing model." So that was a double kicker in getting the business started. It was a small cap business to begin with. They started some bond products based upon the research we’ve already talked about. But it has evolved after the Fama-French stuff came along. Efficient markets took a long time to make its way into investment practice. Still now, I think Ken, in his Presidential paper, estimated less than twenty percent of money is managed passively. But the value growth stuff hit immediately. I showed David Booth a cross-section of expected stock returns. I showed him the output for that paper on my computer in 1991, and he said, "I have a big institutional investor I think he would want to buy that.” This fellow came to my office with Booth. I showed him the stuff on the computer screen, and he said, “Great. Here’s a 21 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 22 few billion dollars to invest in a small cap and large cap versions of that. So this stuff hit the business world before it was even published. RICHARD ROLL: We jumped a little ahead because we haven’t really talked about the three-factor model. But I did want to get into that. So why don’t you talk about the original three-factor model you did with Ken and what the factors were. It’s a multi factor model, but specifically what are those factors? EUGENE FAMA: I’ve always thought research has a huge dose of serendipity associated with it. Ken and I wrote this paper about the cross-section of expected stock returns which basically said if you look at all the variables people have looked at, two seem to do pretty well, marketcap and book to market ratio. Book to market ratio is just a price ratio, and lots of price ratios work pretty well. There was nothing new in that paper, nothing new at all. It was just putting together lots of previous work. Up until that point there had been a lot of studies that said the CAPM doesn’t work for this reason, or the CAPM doesn’t work for this different reason. We just put it all together and said, “It doesn’t seem to work at all.” (LAUGHTER) And that somehow, caught the interest of people. And that paper is, I think, the most highly cited paper in The Journal of Finance in the subsequent period. Then we said, ok, you can tell rational stories for that. Or you can tell irrational stories. So let’s put forward an empirical asset pricing model that would capture these two premiums. RICHARD ROLL: What is the rational story, and what is the irrational story. EUGENE FAMA: There are higher expected returns for small stocks over big stocks, and there are higher expected returns for value stocks over growth stocks. The rational story is that the size premium and the value premium are compensation for risks associated with those stocks, whereas the behavioral story says the premiums are just the result of mispricing. RICHARD ROLL: It seems odd. I can understand small versus large. Small stocks generally do have more risk than large stocks, but value stocks? 22 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 23 EUGENE FAMA: That’s not really the issue. The issue is why isn’t the risk captured by beta? RICHARD ROLL: Yeah, but why are value stocks more risky than growth stocks? EUGENE FAMA: Well, that story you have told for small stocks holds better for value stocks, because value stocks tend to be relatively distressed relative to growth stocks. RICHARD ROLL: They’re fallen angels? EUGENE FAMA: They are. Lots of them are fallen angels. So it’s reasonable to think they have higher costs of capital than growth stocks. Whereas the CAPM says the opposite. Basically growth stocks have higher betas than value stocks. So that model is saying growth stocks have higher costs of capital. RICHARD ROLL: Normally you think of a high beta stock like a growth stock. The CAPM says it’s more risky. This is contrary to that. EUGENE FAMA: Right, but to make full sense of that, you have to go back to something like Merton’s I-CAPM, or the APT, or something where there are multiple factors. Then you have to tell some kind of story about why there are differential risk premiums per unit of variance. That is the essence of the multi-factor model. RICHARD ROLL: If you take the APT model, those things should be related to the covariance matrix of returns. They couldn’t be risk premiums if they weren’t related. So are they? EUGENE FAMA: They are indeed. If you go back and look at the original paper by Lakonishok, Shleifer and Vishny, it basically says that the value premium is an arbitrage opportunity. You can go long value stocks and short growth stocks and have a portfolio that has zero variance, essentially. I remember going to dinner with Andre and after a bottle or so of wine, I pulled out some output, and said, “Here’s what happens if you actually do this. The variance that you get is on the order of the variance of the market. It doesn’t look like an arbitrage opportunity to me." Andre said, “Well ok, maybe it looks like a risk factor, but the risk premium is irrational.” Now at that 23 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 24 point you’re in a box. You can’t tell the difference between the rational story and the irrational story. So that’s basically where it stands today. I think everybody agrees that the difference between value and growth returns has a big variance associated with it. They disagree about the explanation. RICHARD ROLL: Whether it’s a risk premium or a market opportunity? But as you have said, if you take a hedge portfolio, that’s certainly not risk free. EUGENE FAMA: No, far from it. RICHARD ROLL: What about other things in addition to value growth and size? You use momentum too? What is that? EUGENE FAMA: Momentum gives me a problem because the winners and the losers in momentum sorts change so frequently that if momentum is a risk story, the risk has to be changing in a very volatile way. RICHARD ROLL: If you look at prior six-month returns, to see if the ones that have done better continue to do well, that changes every month or so? EUGENE FAMA: This happens around the world, except Japan. The Japanese are somehow immune to this. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: risk. Well, maybe they’re more rational. Who knows, right. (LAUGHTER) Or maybe less, maybe they don’t care about EUGENE FAMA: Another way to put it is, I don’t know what fraction the Japanese market is of the total but the remaining fraction is basically the one that shows momentum, and that fraction doesn’t, so the game is still open. Remember now, what goes on in finance. We have two tapes, we have CRSP and we have Compustat. There are some others thrown in there, but you have thousands of finance professors spinning the tapes, and they all want to get tenure. Some want to do even better than that. So they are going to find whatever is there, even if it is there by chance. 24 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 25 RICHARD ROLL: Well, that is why your out-of-sample things tend to be international. I think you mentioned some of that. EUGENE FAMA: When we first showed Fischer Black the value growth stuff, he had a different take on it. Fischer was, of course, one of the originators of the CAPM. He said, "The CAPM is right. It just doesn’t work." (LAUGHTER) Fischer had conundrums like that. Anyway, so he said, “I think this is just data-dredging. So then we said, “Well, the classic cure for data dredging is to get out-of-sample data.” So, we extended the data back to 26’, and we looked at foreign markets. Everything replicated. RICHARD ROLL: If you look at foreign markets for value and growth you generally find it works in most of these other markets as well. EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: well? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: The premiums are all on the same order. And momentum, is that generally true as Except for Japan. What is it about Japan? EUGENE FAMA: In my mind that raises hope, but it’s just a hope, that momentum is a result of data dredging. RICHARD ROLL: Well, it would have to be an incredible kind of data dredging. These markets are not that correlated with each other. They are correlated but not that correlated. They are not completely independent samples, but they’re quite independent. If you look at twenty different markets, and it works in every single market except for one. EUGENE FAMA: I don’t know about twenty different markets. I’d say three. You’ve got the US, Britain and continental developed, and you’ve got Japan. That’s it. RICHARD ROLL: But other people have looked at momentum in other markets. EUGENE FAMA: Emerging markets? 25 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 26 RICHARD ROLL: Sure. Indonesia and places like that. It works there too. EUGENE FAMA: Maybe you’re right. I don’t know that data. RICHARD ROLL: OK. So what about some of the other FamaFrench papers. You’ve got twenty-eight papers. One of them is disappearing dividends we’ve talked about. Some of the others are on industry costs of capital. Do you want to talk about that? EUGENE FAMA: Well, that one just uses the CAPM and the three factor model to try to estimate industry costs of capital. That gets me into a favorite line of thought of mine. Basically what we find is that it is almost impossible to estimate industry costs of capital. (LAUGHTER) RICHARD ROLL: Using the three-factor model. EUGENE FAMA: Using the three factor model, but the problem is that the three slopes, the market loading, the size loading and the value growth loading vary so much over time, within industries, that using two years of data is just as good as using twenty years of data. You don’t get better out-of-sample forecasts by extending the data period. Now, the regression slopes estimated with two years of data are basically garbage. RICHARD ROLL: Well, then how would you estimate industry costs of capital? EUGENE FAMA: You know, this is why they don’t let me teach corporate finance anymore. (LAUGHTER) I used to teach corporate finance, and when I first started teaching it in the early nineteen-sixties, I had M & M, which I could stretch out for two weeks. Then I did cases because there was nothing else to talk about. Now we have all of these theories and empirical work. So here is a question I posed at the beginning of the class. I am going to easily be able to fill out the ten weeks, but ask me at the end if you’ve learned any more about the cost of capital. I don’t think you can estimate the cost of capital. RICHARD ROLL: But they have to estimate it. If you’re a CEO of a company in the electric utility industry, you have to come up with a number. How would you advise them? 26 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 27 EUGENE FAMA: That’s assuming that discounted cash flow in a world of uncertainty provides better estimates of value then some alternative. Let’s say payback. What’s the evidence on that? There is none. Our use of discounted cash flow is based on, in my experience, it’s Irving Fischer. If you want to read something more recent, which is nevertheless Irving Fischer, read chapters one through three of Fama-Miller, the Theory of Finance. It’s perfect certainty. That’s where you can justify that. In a world of uncertainty it’s much more difficult to justify discounted cash flow. RICHARD ROLL: Well, I mean, you’re not saying that’s not the right way to do it if you can get a good estimate on the discount rate for expected cash flows. That still works, right? EUGENE FAMA: I don’t know because you’re dividing by a random variable. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: Of course, we know the reciprocal. If the number came down from heaven? RICHARD ROLL: That’s what I’m saying. If you had a really good estimate, there’s nothing wrong with discounted cash flow, right? EUGENE FAMA: Right. RICHARD ROLL: Except that you can’t figure what to put into the equation. EUGENE FAMA: In either the numerator or the denominator. RICHARD ROLL: Numerator or denominator? Is that a general conclusion? What do you think of corporate finance? It sounds like you say they don’t let you teach it anymore. Is there anything in corporate finance that you do like? You are talking to the American Finance Association. They had a hundred papers in the last issue of The Journal of Finance. So, what is in those papers? EUGENE FAMA: Well, I think there is a lot of interesting research on capital structure. What determines capital 27 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 28 structure? students. But I don’t think that’s much help for MBA RICHARD ROLL: What determines capital structures? EUGENE FAMA: We have various theories. We also have lots of stylized evidence about stuff, and it doesn’t conform to any of the theories. M & M looks as good as the target capital structure models, or the pecking-order model. RICHARD ROLL: M & M, had several papers. Then finally Miller had dividends and taxes and debt and taxes that basically said what you are saying. EUGENE FAMA: The bottom line from debt and taxes and dividends and taxes is we don’t know what the tax effects are. When I was teaching corporate finance I said, now the first question in corporate finance is, what marginal tax bracket is built into the pricing of debt and equity, so that you could at least tell me about the tax advantages of one or the other. There are no convincing papers on that topic. RICHARD ROLL: What about international data? You mentioned the fact that dividends, for instance, are double-taxed in the US. Wouldn’t that offer some opportunity to try and estimate… EUGENE FAMA: It might, I haven’t seen anybody do it in a convincing way. RICHARD ROLL: So there’s a research topic your next PhD student could work on. But you might think it’s hopeless and not advise them to do this. EUGENE FAMA: I don’t know. I’d have to look and see if there’s any hope when you assemble the data, that you could get something that was within the range of standard errors that was likely to come out of it. RICHARD ROLL: One obvious question in an interview like this is what are you going to work on next? You’ve got a bunch of working papers. I’m not talking about them. What is something that is not a working paper yet? EUGENE FAMA: I never plan. 28 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 29 RICHARD ROLL: So you have an efficient markets idea on research as well. You don’t know what you’re going to do until you do it. EUGENE FAMA: Totally unpredictable. That makes it more fun. That's the way I’ve always worked. Interest rates and inflation is a good example. You have what seems like a small idea and it just keeps growing on its own. You just keep pursuing it. I think the Fama-French stuff is another good example. We pushed that in lots of different directions. RICHARD ROLL: When you are doing empirical work, which is mostly, but not everything, are you always surprised because stuff appears you don’t expect? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: You never end up where you started. It’s good to just do anything? EUGENE FAMA: Do It! RICHARD ROLL: We should mention how important CRSP was. It fostered a lot of research. Jim Lorie, I guess was the guy that first got the grant from who, Merrill Lynch, to put together CRSP with Larry Fisher. Tell us a little about that. EUGENE FAMA: I think finance had a very simple beginning. It was basically the coming of the first computers that made it possible to do large-scale empirical work. Jim Lorie, who was a marketing professor at that time, went to Merrill Lynch and said, you know, you don’t really know what the stock return was historically. You don’t have a very good estimate of it, and we will put together a tape that will give you the background numbers that you can use to calculate the return on the NYSE. He got Larry Fisher to do all of the development of the project. Larry thought about everything. I don’t know how he did it. He thought about everything that could possibly be relevant for making the data perfect. What you needed to calculate, every detail, all the capital structure, all the capital changes you had to take account of. RICHARD ROLL: And all the things like name changes? 29 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 30 EUGENE FAMA: Name changes. Everything. He thought of all of that in advance. Eventually they put together a tape from 1926 to I think 1960 was the ending date on the first tape. Then they came out with this number, which was the return on the NYSE from 1926 to 1960. I think it was a few basis points away from the S & P return, but it was very accurate. RICHARD ROLL: It was a pretty big number, too, Merrill Lynch took out a… EUGENE FAMA: Merrill Lynch took out a full-page add in the Wall Street Journal trumpeting this number as the reason why you should be investing in stocks. RICHARD ROLL: People are still trumpeting this number. Stocks in the long run. People are still talking about it. But then, you don’t think the number is the size it was from '26 to '60. Or do you. It’s the average return of the stock market. I mean this is like the risk premium in equity-return. EUGENE FAMA: I think the equity-premium, historically in the US is a little high relative to the expected value. RICHARD ROLL: How high? EUGENE FAMA: That’s difficult to say. bias in effect. The market survived. There’s a survivor RICHARD ROLL: You’re talking about the US as one of the markets that was a successful survivor? EUGENE FAMA: Right. That tells you that you’ve got a higher realized return, probably higher than expected. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: But you don’t know how much higher? Well, Ken and I wrote a paper on… Is it two percent? EUGENE FAMA: Is it two percent higher? Yeah, that’s probably not a bad number. I always think of the number, the equity premium, as five percent. 30 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 31 RICHARD ROLL: Five percent is the excess return of the market over the risk-free rate? EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: data. Right Before it was seven percent. That’s the number presented before in the RICHARD ROLL: Anyway, go back to CRSP, in 1960 Larry put the tape together, then what happened in finance. EUGENE FAMA: Well, you know what happened in finance. Lorie became nervous. Merrill Lynch gave us this massive amount of money to develop this tape, two hundred and fifty thousand dollars, to develop this tape. And two hundred and fifty thousand dollars was real dollars back in 1960. But how do we know anybody is going to use it? So Lorie said, why don’t you do a study of stock splits? That’s where the study of stock splits came from. RICHARD ROLL: Well, we did have splits on the tape. That’s one thing that Larry collected. EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: We didn’t have the actual date, right? No, we had the month of the split. EUGENE FAMA: Right, we didn’t have the announcement date. Eventually the announcement date got on there. But that became, as you well know, became a very famous paper. That was the birth of event studies basically. And again, who knew at that time whether that was going to be a big deal. I don’t know if you remember, but, where did we publish that? RICHARD ROLL: The International Economic Review, some obscure place. EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: Franco was the referee it turns out. Was he? I didn’t know that. EUGENE FAMA: He didn’t say a word. He said, “This paper’s perfect, just publish it.” [LAUGHTER] 31 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 32 RICHARD ROLL: We should have sent it to the AER. EUGENE FAMA: Never again did I have that experience. But looking back on the paper, and I’m sure you have, is there anything that strikes you in there? RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: was. No what do you mean? There’s not a single standard error in there. Oh no. We didn’t know what a standard error EUGENE FAMA: I know, I looked at it and said, “This is perfect.” It’s just totally flat. We don’t need a standard error. RICHARD ROLL: When I first saw that pattern, when we got it out of the computer, I thought we had an error in our computer code, because I didn’t think anything could look like that. But then what you realize after the fact is that it had to look like that, or else markets weren’t working well. EUGENE FAMA: Well, you know, for many years that paper was the most highly cited paper in accounting. RICHARD ROLL: Yeah, well there are so many event studies in accounting. EUGENE FAMA: Merton Miller always said, “Accounting is event studies.” [LAUGHTER] Assets equal liabilities and then event studies. RICHARD ROLL: But you know when CRSP came along, and the data were available, in the form they were available, and the computer becoming much easier to use, that really made finance what it is today. EUGENE FAMA: With the way data are organized and the way you can search through data, you can do in an afternoon stuff that would have taken months with the initial computers. RICHARD ROLL: Sure. 32 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 33 EUGENE FAMA: '60s. RICHARD ROLL: Chicago? EUGENE FAMA: OK, so ask about the state of finance in the OK, what was it, 1960, when you went to I went to Chicago in 1960. RICHARD ROLL: Was there finance in 1960? Who did you look up to as a graduate student as being a great scholar in finance? Or maybe I’ll put it the other way, who did you not want to emulate? EUGENE FAMA: I didn’t take any finance courses. RICHARD ROLL: Were there any finance courses? EUGENE FAMA: Yeah, there was a course in security analysis. There was a course on money and banking, which I didn’t take because I took it in the economics department. And that was it. So, there weren’t any finance courses. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: Was Markowitz being used at that time? Markowitz was not being used. That was earlier. That was the fifties. EUGENE FAMA: Markowitz was 53’. And it was a thesis in the economics department, which he had trouble getting through. RICHARD ROLL: economics. Because Friedman didn’t think it was EUGENE FAMA: He didn’t think it was very good. Shows you what he knew. [LAUGHTER] RICHARD ROLL: Well, we can say that now since he’s no longer around. EUGENE FAMA: Anyway, when I finished my thesis and Chicago hired me, I went to Miller. I hadn’t had a course from Miller, he hadn’t taught. To attract him from Carnegie I think they gave him a year or two off. So although I’d worked with him on my thesis, he still hadn’t taught there. So I had never had a course from him. 33 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 34 RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: But, the first M & M paper was 58’? 58’ RICHARD ROLL: So that was just two years before you got to Chicago, and he was not teaching that first year. EUGENE FAMA: Well, no this was just 62’. So he came and he didn’t teach that first year or two. RICHARD ROLL: Chicago? EUGENE FAMA: Markowitz. RICHARD ROLL: So you taught the first finance course at I taught the first finance course that used Used Markowitz, huh. EUGENE FAMA: Right, and it had three numbers in those days. It had an MBA number, an advanced MBA number, and a PhD number. At that point it was just Markowitz, because the CAPM wasn’t… RICHARD ROLL: Yeah, that was 64’. EUGENE FAMA: Then the CAPM came out. So, when I went to Miller and asked him what I should teach, he said, “Look, we hired you to teach the new stuff. You have to do it.” That’s how that course came about, which I’ve been teaching ever since. RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: EUGENE FAMA: RICHARD ROLL: So you’ve been teaching the same course? I’ve added a few things. [LAUGHTER] You’ve added a few things? [LAUGHTER] It’s all Fama-French now. [LAUGHTER] It’s the same course number though. EUGENE FAMA: No, the course numbers have changed across the whole University. Anyway, we had at that time, there weren’t good finance departments anywhere, and Chicago, for whatever reason, attracted the best PhD students. We had a group of PhD students. You, Myron, Mike Jensen, and a few 34 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 35 other people who went off to other Universities and started first rate finance departments. Finance has kind of grown out from that base. And very quickly, people like Steve Ross and Bob Merton came along who turned out to be giants in their own right. RICHARD ROLL: Well, you know Ross, for example, I know why he switched to finance. He was at Wharton. He was an economist from Harvard who didn’t know anything about finance. Then he went to a couple of seminars, and decided he was going to switch over to the field. A couple of Chicago people went to Wharton. But yeah, people that Chicago graduated and sent out went to start all these other places. EUGENE FAMA: Marshall Bloom went to Wharton for example. RICHARD ROLL: Marshall Bloom went to Wharton. Chicago was kind of the center of the whole finance world. EUGENE FAMA: It certainly was at that time. I think it still is. We have very little trouble attracting new PhDs to join our faculty. We rarely lose to other schools when we are hiring people. And even if they don’t make it at Chicago, they always go off to great new jobs. So, there’s almost no downside to it, but there are good departments in lots of places. RICHARD ROLL: When you went to Belgium back in 1975, was there anybody in Europe who knew much about finance? EUGENE FAMA: No. Well, there were a couple. RICHARD ROLL: A couple. in the US and London. EUGENE FAMA: But usually they had been trained Right RICHARD ROLL: Now if you go to Europe there are lots of, well all over the world. I mean it’s not just a US phenomenon. EUGENE FAMA: In my view, biased obviously, finance is the most successful area of economics. It came from nowhere. Before Markowitz there was nothing. And in that halfcentury, empirically it’s clearly the most successful. 35 Int. w/ Eugene Fama by Richard Roll 36 RICHARD ROLL: Well, it has better data than anything. EUGENE FAMA: The data is better, and it is used in a very careful and logical, sensible way. I’m not sure we know a lot more than we did then, but we know why we don’t know. [LAUGHTER] RICHARD ROLL: You are saying there’s still plenty of room for discovering answers to questions that we don’t know about. Like leverage, cost of capital, and stuff like that. EUGENE FAMA: Right. Cost effects, risk and return, the three-factor model. RICHARD ROLL: Asset pricing. EUGENE FAMA: Yeah, the three-factor model galls the purists in asset pricing because it is empirically motivated. It doesn’t come out of consumption data or anything like that. RICHARD ROLL: regularity? EUGENE FAMA: It comes because you observe an empirical And you work backward from there. RICHARD ROLL: Backward from there. But a lot of things do that. Theorists are just waiting for some new empirical discovery so they have something to exploit. EUGENE FAMA: Right. RICHARD ROLL: That’s basically the way the science works. So thanks you very much Gene. EUGENE FAMA: Thank You. RICHARD ROLL: I enjoyed it. I hope you did too. And thanks everybody for watching. 36