Central European University Department of Economics Term paper for the course ‘Labor economics’ APPLICABILITY OF THE THEORY OF COMPENSATING DIFFERENTIALS TO THE RUSSIAN ECONOMY Professor John Earle. Student Willen Lipatov. Abstract The paper shows that the theory of compensating differentials finds an empirical support in Russia in 1998. Differences in riskiness of work across the regions significantly influence wages paid. At the same time, differences across five aggregated sectors are insignificant. The value of life in Russia is estimated to be lower than in developed countries. Budapest, 2001 CONTENT Introduction 3 Hypothesis 4 Data 5 Estimation 6 Industry indicators 9 Value of life 12 Conclusion 13 Bibliography 15 2 Introduction The theory of compensating differentials has been being tested since long ago. The first empirical studies were undertaken in the United States; United Kingdom and other developed countries followed. For a detailed survey of studies undertaken one can look at Viscusi[5]. Nevertheless, there are hardly any tries to do it in transition economies, mainly because of major problems with data. However, the question whether the theory of interest is applicable is of great interest. In particular, non-applicability would mean that transition undermined basic mechanism of income – risk tradeoff on the labor market, since the theory finds strong support in developed economies. The other interesting topic is assessment of the value of life that is possible only when the theory is valid. Therefore, despite extremely poor data used to achieve these two goals, the conclusions are still worth consideration. The tests showed that compensating differentials existed in Russia in 1998, so the higher fatality risk was associated with higher wages. 3 Hypothesis The hypothesis to be tested is that riskiness of an occupation influences the wage. In terms of hedonic wage equation it should mean significantly positive coefficient at the variable measuring risk. The project is based on replication of approach presented in the study by Marin and Psacharopoulus [3], applied to the United Kingdom economy in seventies. The reason why other, more advanced studies [1, 2, 4] were considered, but not taken as a pattern, is the poor data. It is hardly sufficient even for a simple model employed here, and would be irrelevant for more complicated estimations. Nevertheless, the equation employed in the study [3] was lnY = f(S, EX, EX2, lnWEEKS, RISK, UNION, OCC, UNION*RISK) + error, where Y is annual earnings, S – number of years of schooling, EX – years of experience in the labor force, WEEKS – number of weeks worked in the survey year, RISK – a measure of fatality risk, UNION – the proportion if the workers in industry covered by the collective agreement. OCC – occupation desirability ranking, In this project, however, the data for variables UNION and OCC was completely unavailable, so they were omitted. The variables S and EX remained exactly in the 4 same specification. A new variable was added as especially relevant to the Russian economy. As a result, we arrive at the following equation: lnY = f(S, EX, EX2, lnWEEK, RISK, DIFFPW, SITE8) + error, where Y is after-tax wages per hour on the primary job in the last month; lnWEEK is a number of hours in average workweek; DIFFPW is a difference in logarithms of Y and wages actually paid on time (Russian specific variable); SITE8 – code of region where the survey was conducted (nominal variable); RISK – number of deaths caused by professional activity per 1000 workers. Data The main source of data for this project is Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey (RLMS), round VIII (end 1998 – beginning 1999). The variables Y, SITE8 and EX were taken directly from it, S was calculated as a sum of years spent at school, professional courses, PTU, technical (medical, musical etc.) school, university and graduate study. For constructing variable DIFFPW the amount monthly paid on time was used. The other source is Goskomstat site www.gks.ru, from which the variable RISK was computed across regions. The Russian statistical agency gives death rates (number of death per 1000 workers) for every region of the country (totally 89). The problem is that the RLMS gives identifiers only for 8 ‘super-regions’. Accordingly, the death rate for every ‘super’ were calculated as weighted averages of death rates for every region 5 constituting ‘super’. Certainly, only regions that actually participated in the RLMS were taken into account in averaging1. The final table with average deathrates looks as following: Region Identifiers (SITE8) Death rate Moscow, SPetersburg 138-141 0,095 North, NorthWest 1-8, 89-91, 105 0,248 Central, Centralnochernozemn. 14-38, 67-69, 72, 135, 136, 142-160 0,1353 Volga, VolgoVyatskiy 39-45, 48-51, 70, 100-104, 116-128 0,1262 Northern Caucasus 9, 52-57, 77-83, 129-134, 137 0,1163 Ural 10-13, 46, 47, 106-115 0,1104 Western Siberia 58-65, 71, 84-88 0,14 Eastern Siberia, Far East 66, 73-76, 92-99 0,197 RLMS survey round VIII comprises 8700 observations. First, all observations corresponding to not working people were eliminated. Then observations with zero working hours on the primary job, as well as with zero wages were eliminated. Technically it was necessary to do not to divide by zero and not to take a log of zero. Statistically it is justified as obvious outliers were eliminated. After such an adjustment 2538 observations remained. Estimation Using the data described the wage hedonic equation was estimated with the help of statistical package EViews: 1 The map of the survey is available on http://www.cpc.unc.edu/projects/rlms/project/phase2.html 6 LNW = 1.358311107 + 0.0677868371*EDU1 + 0.02199658098*I8YRSWRK + 0.4437301143*DIFFPW - 0.3695981822*LNWEEK + 0.002576878351*SITE8 + 1.37812277*RISK - 0.0004725221389*EX2 - 0.2935844143*GENDER + error All coefficients are significant, and for more detailed information the estimation output presented in the appendix A can be checked. It’s necessary to mention that significant female dummy was included, showing that on average males were getting 1,35 women’s wage per hour. The variable SITE8 was included for controlling the regional differences. The coefficients of variables S, EX and EX2 have ‘classical’ signs, indicating that there is positive return on education, and wage is increasing concave function of experience. The marginal effect of education estimated at mean level of wages Y = 3,789 is equal to 0,258. This shows, that additional year of schooling on average brings about 26 kopecks increase in wage per hour. Marginal effect of experience estimated at mean value of Y is equal to 3,789(0,022 – 0,000946*EX), which gives 0,083 for persons entering labor force and 0,011 for people with 20 years experience (median value of the sample). The variable LNWEEK was included to control for differences in hours worked. The coefficient obtained shows decreasing marginal reward to work, which is consistent both with the theory and common sense. The variable DIFFPW was intended to control for wage arrears, but the sign and value of corresponding coefficient turned out to be meaningful. Indeed, highly significant positive coefficient indicates that larger arrears are associated with higher wages. Namely, elasticity of wages with 7 respect to accounted/paid wage ratio is equal to 0,44. It means that 1% increase in the ratio leads to 0,44% in wages. At last, the most interesting for us RISK variable has significantly positive (even with 1% confidence and White-wash) coefficient. It indicates that the risk premium estimated at mean value of Y is 5,22. That is, for 0,1% increase of death-rate in a region the wage is raised by 5,22 rubles per hour. It seems to be a very substantial amount, if we take into consideration that returns on 13 years of schooling are twice as low. Such sensitivity is unlikely to result from individual risk aversion, as people do not usually move from region to region because they care about 0,0005 difference in probability to die. It also can hardly be attributed to the profit-maximizing behavior of firms, as the data does not tell us anything about risks of certain occupations or industries. The possible explanation goes back to the Soviet era, when wages were planned, taking into account regional specificities, and riskiness among them. Transition did not probably destroy this tradition completely, as it is rational and in line with compensating differentials. The influence of risk on wages was not significantly different for males and females, which is illustrated in appendix B1, unlike influences of accounted/paid wage ratio and experience. Both effects of experience and of arrears were larger for females, as shown in appendix B2. It seems to be an interesting result, but the discussion of it is beyond the scope of this paper. 8 Nevertheless, males and females subsamples were considered, the results are represented in appendices CMale and CFemale. Basically, they remained unchanged. The experience variable for males became insignificant that indicates the consequences of transition (a lot of experienced professionals lost their jobs and had to take unqualified work). Also the risk variable is significant only with 7% confidence. Industry indicators Being aware of imperfections of data for the RISK variable, an attempt was made to include another indicator of risk, this time measured across industries. The Russian statistical agency provides data for death rates for 5 aggregated industries in 1999: manufacturing, agriculture, forestry, transport and construction. The problem is that RLMS doe not give any hint in which industry an individual works. However, there is ILO classification of occupations contained in the survey. From this classification every observation was associated to some industry with the use of the following scheme: Industry ILO code Manufacturing 121,1222,123, 1312, 2145-7, 241, 3112-7, 4131,2, 711, 72, 81, 82, 9311, 932 Agriculture 113,1221,1311, 32, 611-3,5, 62, 833, 9211,3 Forestry 1221,1311,3211,3212, 614, 9212 Transport 1226, 1316, 2144, 314, 4133, 511, 831,2,4, 933 Construction 1223, 1313, 712-4, 9312,3 Other 111,112, 114,1224-25, 27-29, 1314-15, 17-19, 211,212, 213, 2141-3,8,9, 22, 23, 242-6, 3111,8,9, 312, 313, 315, 322-324, 33, 34, 411,412, 414, 419, 42, 9 512-6, 52, 73, 74, 91, 0 Then the risk indicators taken from Goskomstat are: Industry total males females Manufacturing 0.137 0.222 0.022 Agriculture 0.199 0.296 0.027 0.21 0.245 0.059 Transport 0.151 0.208 0.03 Construction 0.291 0.377 0.036 Other 0.134 0.22 0.021 Forestry The ‘other’ category was used because many occupations didn’t fit any of industries (a major part of services, for example). The values of death rates for this category is estimated intuitively to be 0.01 below average. The constructed variable was called IND. This time the equation estimated had a form of LNW = 1.723544988 + 0.05707124226*EDU1 + 0.0223825037*I8YRSWRK 0.0004807891561*EX2 + 0.4408332668*DIFFPW - 0.3693461084*LNWEEK + 0.00260083928*SITE8 + 1.413290956*RISK - 2.112218096e-05*JOB 0.3330831896*GENDER - 0.7165202745*IND + error, where variable JOB is ILO classification code of the occupation of the observed individual. It was introduced to control for differences in occupations. It turned out to be significantly negative, which goes well with expectations about the sign: larger numbers in ILO classification roughly correspond to less skilled workers. 10 The coefficient of IND is insignificant, however, which can be explained by large errors in constructing data required. For more detailed information about the regression output appendix D can be consulted. The estimations of other coefficients didn’t change much that proves validity of the model as a whole. The construction of an aggregate variable for risk as geometrical mean of RISK and IND proved to be invalid, as the corresponding coefficient was insignificant. From this it could be concluded that the model without IND fits data better. Interestingly enough, however, the difference in the influence of IND on wages for males and females is significant, so the two sub-samples were considered separately. The results are shown in Appendices Emale and Efemale correspondingly. For males sub-sample all the coefficients are significant, but the coefficient of MALEIND variable (measure of industry risk for males) has a ‘wrong’ sign. It can be again attributed to the data imperfections and is not worth paying attention to. For females sub-sample the controlling variable for occupations is significant only at 6% level of confidence. The coefficient of FEMIND (measure of industry risk for females) is significant and unbelievably large. So, although there is an evidence of different influence of industry risks on males versus females wages, the magnitude of the influence itself is undetermined, as the data is unreliable. 11 Value of life Since the theory of compensating differentials is supported, we are able to calculate the value of life in Russia. Just as in the article, it is equal to 1000 * Y (dlnY/dRISK), evaluated at the means of Y. We take the coefficient from the most complete equation (represented in Appendix F): LNW = 1.911680346 + 0.05717096486*EDU1 + 0.01724346371*I8YRSWRK 0.0004483781282*EX2 + 0.3918445718*DIFFPW - 0.3733768822*LNWEEK + 0.002635627428*SITE8 + 1.468386116*RISK - 2.361770183e-05*JOB 0.8595151231*GENDER - 1.220156672*IND + 2.587242416*(GENDER*IND) + 0.007216082746*(GENDER*I8YRSWRK) + 0.1167141898*(GENDER*DIFFPW) Although it considers data on industry risks that proved to be unreliable, the coefficient at RISK is higher than in other representations. As John E. Caren claims, the estimations of this coefficient are subject to downward simultaneity bias. So, this biggest estimation is justified to be used in assessment of the value of life. It should be noted, too, that the estimation of the RISK coefficient is very robust: it does not vary significantly over the number of specifications presented here. So, the value of life in Russia is 5562 * hours worked in the last 30 days estimated at the mean * 12 months = 5562*166*12 = 11 080 006 rubles or $ 382 069. This is much lower than in any developed countries, as expected. We believe that it happens mostly because of lower per capita income. However, the difference is possible to be enhanced by the lower risk aversion of Russian workers, weaker safety regulations or poorer information about risks available for workers. The magnitude of the difference is of great interest. It is not that huge, especially if 12 adjusted for PPP. So, it is natural to suggest that the risk aversion of the worker in Russia and in, say, US, does not differ substantially. For more precise calculation of the value of life, the measure of non-fatal accident risk should also be included in the estimation to control for its influence on the wage. This is pointed out in Vscusi . Omitting of non-fatal risks leads to the upward bias of the estimation of fatality risk coefficient. The number of other biases are discussed by Viscusi, but the possible ways to eliminate them require much more refined data, which is unavailable so far. Still, the present estimation can be considered to be a first approximation for the value of life in Russia. Conclusion The study undoubtedly showed that the theory of compensating differentials is applicable to Russian economy. The coefficient of regional risk is significantly positive and robust in different specifications of hedonic wage equation. We can deduct that transition did not only undermine basic trade-off between income and risk, but even preserved a mechanism of realization of this trade-off in-built in the planned economy. The estimated value of life is 11 mln rubles, which is a very substantial sum for an average Russian. Still, the study taken as a pattern for this paper estimated the value of life in the UK at $2,8 mln, which is seven times higher. Taking into account differences in GDP per capita, it does not make a big surprise. 13 Thus, the two conclusions of the paper appear to be plausible. For future research in this field it would be interesting to look at the same results if non-fatal risks are included. It is also possible to compare the results for different years of transition. Finally, it would be great to get some improvements to the data. 14 Bibliography 1. Richard J. Arnolds, Len M. Nichols “Wage–Risk Premiums and Worker’s Compensation: Refinement of Estimates of Compensating Wage Differentials”, Journal of Political Economy, April 1983, #91(3) 2. John E. Caren “Compensating Wage Differentials and the Endogeneity of Job Riskiness”, Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1988, #70(1) 3. Alan Marin, George Psaharopoulos “The Rewards for Risk in the Labor Market: Evidence from the UK and Reconciliation with Other Studies”, Journal of Political Economy, August 1982, #90(4) 4. Michael Moore, W. Kip Viscusi “The Quantity Adjusted Value of Life”, Economic Inquiry, July 1988, #26(3) 5. W. Kip Viscusi “The Value of Risks to Life and Health”, Journal of Economic Literature, December 1993 15