Valuations of Life and Health Risks: Evidence from the Indian Labor Market S.Madheswaran* and K.R.Shanmugam** *Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics, Pune 411 004, India. Email: smadhes@hotmail.com **Madras School of Economics, Chennai. Abstract Development in environment can have a significant impact on it. This is true of projects in major sectors, including power and energy, industry, transportation, sanitation and sewage. Exposure to environment contaminants may cause risks to human life and health. In order to regulate these risks, the government undertakes various projects that impose costs on society in exchange for reducing the risks. To determine whether a project is socially desirable, one needs to compare the value of reducing risks to the cost of such reductions. Several methods have been proposed in the literature for estimating the implicit prices for life and health. The willingness to pay approach (WTP), however, has been increasingly considered as the relevant method. The approaches to estimating WTP to reduce the risks of death and injury fall into four basic categories: wage differentials between alternative occupations with different statistical risks, contingent valuation studies, consumer market studies and foregone earnings. This paper deals with the first category. There are considerable empirical works to analyze the workers employment decisions in the market with potentially hazardous work. However, most of the work is related to developed countries. Empirical study on this problem is practically non-existent in India and perhaps in developing countries, mainly due to data constraints. In this backdrop, this paper attempts to estimate the values of life and health risk based on compensating wage differential framework using the primary data from Chennai, southern part of India. The empirical part of this paper examines the worker’s behavior in choosing their job risks and the role trade unions in influencing the wage-risk trade-off. It also analyses the problem of sample selection and its effects on the estimated compensation for job risks. The empirical results provide a strong support for the efficiency of labor market in deriving the optimal risk level. They also imply that the unionists receive a higher compensation for work related risks than the non-unionists. Allowing for sample selectivity produces a down ward bias in the estimated union wage differentials for deadly hazards. The value of statistical life is also calculated. The empirical results show that the calculated value of statistical life is Rs.15.55 million and Rs.5.49 million and the estimated value of injury is Rs.5598 and Rs.2059 for the union and non-union sector workers respectively. Comparison of our estimated value of life with those from developed nations indicates that as expected, our value is lower than the values from developed nations. The estimated values life and injury can be used to value reductions in risk of death achieved by industrial safety programs or environmental health programs. Hence, the study may be useful to policy makers, international agencies and researchers evaluating health projects in developing nations Key Words: Compensating wage differentials, hedonic price, Value of life and injury JEL Classification: J17, J28, J31 Valuations of Life and Health Risk: Evidence from the Indian Labor Market S.Madheswaran* and K.R.Shanmugam** *Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics, Pune 411 004, India. Email: smadhes@hotmail.com **Madras School of Economics, Chennai. 1.Introduction Environmental development can have significant impacts in areas such as power and energy, industry, transportation, sanitation and sewage. Exposure to environment contaminants may cause risks to human life and health. In order to regulate these risks, the government undertakes various projects that impose costs on society in exchange for reducing the risks. To determine whether a project is socially desirable, one needs to compare the value of reducing risks to the cost of such reductions. Several methods have been proposed in the literature for estimating the implicit prices for life and health. They include cost of illness approach, human capital approach, insurance approach, court awards and compensation approach and portfolio approach (Linnerooth, 1979). The willingness to pay (WTP) approach, however, has been increasingly considered as the relevant method. WTP is typically measured by analyzing prices paid for goods and services. Prices paid for preventing health and death risks cannot directly be obtained because prevention of these risks is not directly purchased in the market. However, there are instances when these prices can be observed or measured. There are two principal methodologies for measuring these prices. The first known as the contingent valuation approach, rests on data generated through questionnaires ( Alberini et.al 1977, Gerking et.al 1988). In this approach, individuals are directly asked how much they would be willing to pay to reduce, for instance, their death risks at work or in traffic accidents. The second is the revealed preference approach. This method infers the hedonic (that is quality adjusted) value of an environmental good affecting the value of a market such as air quality. This method relies on property values and wage data. The approach using wages is popular because the availability of information on work related environmental risks and associated wages that workers receive enable the estimation of the market generated wage-risk trade off. Several empirical studies emerged to estimate the value of life or injury, but most of them concern developed nations (viscusi, 1993). A study on this topic is practically scanty in developing countries, mainly due to data constraints. Those valuing the health impacts of projects in developing countries have two options. First, they can develop monetary value estimates based on data from developed nations by making appropriate adjustments (using per capita GDP). This simple transfer mechanism does not take into account differences in WTP values between different countries due to differences in factors like living standards, culture and educational attainment. Second, they can rely on the human capital approach such as loss of earnings. But this approach provides no guide to action when there are a variety of impacts on unknown value and ignores the quality of life lengthened. New research on valuing health and death risks in developing countries is the only way to resolve this problem (Asian Development Bank, 1996). In the past, India had neglected the environmental consequences of economic growth. However, in recent years, its approach on environmental problems has changed. It implements many environmental programs and spends huge amounts on health and safety programs. Since resources are scarce, it is essential to evaluate these programs and reallocate funds to achieve maximum net benefit to society. In this context, we estimate the compensating wage differentials for job related fatal and injury risk using the data from Indian labor market.. The problem posed by sample selection is also addressed and its impact on the estimated wage differential is investigated. The organization of the paper is as follows. Section 2 deals with theoretical and empirical studies existed in this area. Section 3 gives brief outlines the source of data and econometric methodology. Empirical results are discussed in Section 4 followed by a conclusion. 2.Review of Literature 2.1. An Economic Settings for Job Risks and Wages The causes of accidents (or job risks) are related to technical and human factor; it has attracted the attention of Psychologists, Sociologists and Engineers for a long period. In recent years, economists have used their analytical tools to investigate the problem of employment accidents or risks in a different context. They consider job hazards as a component of job evaluation system that gives each job rating, which in turn affects the wages, that is, job risk is taken as one of the determinants of wage differentials. They use the theory of compensating or equalizing differentials, developed in the context of hedonic reconstruction of demand theory to analyze the wage-risk relationship. The theory posits that jobs with more risks require a wage premium to attract workers, other things being equal. This extra wage or premium is called compensating wage differentials. However, the required risk premium may be quite different for different people. Firms attempting to attract workers to hazardous jobs will only offer an adequate premium to staff those positions with capable employees. This premium will provide a sufficient inducement for workers most willing to accept risks, while those requiring a very large wage premium will tend to select safe occupational pursuits. Thus, the heterogeneity of workers behavior and firms form the basis for labor market equilibrium and the compensating wage differentials acts as an equalizing or a balancing factor in keeping the workers in the risky jobs. That is, compensating differentials play a vital role in allocating labor and resources amongst their various uses. Suppose there is no compensating differentials, then no worker will choose a dangerous or an unpleasant work; choosing instead to accept equal wages for employment in relatively clean, safe and pleasant job. Further, the need to pay compensation for risky job provides financial incentive for the firms to invest in safety equipment and other risk reducing controls within the workplace in order to reduce the wage costs necessary to attract workers. However, making the work place safer typically involves substantial costs. Hence, a firm has two principal choices. It can simply pay the workers for incurring or it can reduce its wage costs by making larger safety investments in the work site. Typically these mechanisms are inter-related. The firm increases its expenditures on safety until the incremental wage reductions generated by improved safety no longer exceed the added costs of these improvements. Workers welfare enters the firm’s calculations through the influence of the risk level on wages. The worker’s own valuations of risk in effect determine the price the firm must pay if it does not financially worthwhile to diminish the risk. Thus, the economic analysis of wage-risk trade off reflected in decisions of worker and firm suggests that these choices produce powerful incentive for safety. To the extent that expected costs of industrial accidents to firms reflected in the prevailing compensating wage differentials for hazardous work, the firm has an incentive to invest in safety equipment, supervision and training to the socially optimal extent, as the firm must bear the full social costs of accidents. In recent years, the notion of compensating wage differentials due to work accident has been generalized in terms of probability. It considers a situation in which workers face some lotteries on their health status. Thus the problem of the worker is to choose job risks to maximize his expected utility. Thus, the problem turns to be one of testing the economic rationality of workers in the markets with uncertainty. To estimate the compensating differentials for job risks, economists during the last fifteen years, have, thus, approached the problem from a microanalysis taking an individual worker as unit of analysis. They have used cross-section data pertain to individual workers’ wage, job risks and other factors which affect wages. The present project proposal follows this economic tradition. One interesting application of this approach is that it can be used to place a money value on fatal and non-fatal accidents. By accepting wage premium for job hazards, workers implicitly reveal their value of life and limb. Thus, the estimated wage premium for job related risk can be used to determine the economic value of saving a human life and limb. Since the firm can compensate the workers for risks either through ex ante compensation (i.e., compensating wage differentials) or ex post compensation (i.e., compensation benefits etc.), economists have recently analyzed the role of this expost component of compensation in affecting the wage-risk trade-off through its financial mechanism. In India, both ESI scheme and WCA (Workmen Compensation Act) play vital role in providing compensation for industrial accidents. However, these partial replacement benefit amounts can’t eliminate all losses in welfare resulting from work accidents. Hence, the problem of assessing whether these benefits are optimal is important. The life-cycle issues such as variations across workers in the potential losses resulting from death and the discounting problem are also important. Three different approaches are available in the existing literature to analyze the issues. They are: discounted life-years-lost approach, life cycle and markov model of the lifetime job choices. Since no single modeling is dominant in terms of its theoretical and empirical properties, three approaches are equally plausible. Hence these 3 approaches will be utilized in the proposed study to assess whether worker’s choice with respect to job risk is consistent with rational behavior in the market that combines the elements of both intertemporal choice and uncertainty. The alternative way is interview or contingent valuation method (CVM). In this approach, the individuals are asked directly what their trade-offs or how much they would be willing to pay for a particular risk reduction. In other words, the interviewer asks individual quite directly what their subjective trade-offs are. The CVM receives attention in valuing workers life. Viscusi and O’connor (1984) have interviewed the workers in chemical industry. They ask a series of questions pertaining to risk perception of the workers. They elicited willingness to accept for non-fatal job risks and estimated value ranges from $10,000 to $13000. Gerking, Hann and Schulze (1988) are the first study to examine contingent values of job related fatal accidents and willingness to pay for avoiding those risks. They have estimated the marginal value of safety by directly asking respondents about their willingness to substitute money for changes in job related fatal accidents. They adopt both WTP and WTA principles. He estimated value of life is $2.66 million in WTP measures and $6.82 million in WTA measures. This method is free from measurement error in risk-measures and failure to control personal and job characteristics. However, this method is not free from criticism. It is criticized that: (1) respondents have no incentive to give thoughtful or honest answers and the process of thinking about choices involving small probabilities is notoriously difficult; (2) individuals may misrepresent their preferences if they believe that their responses will affect the benefits they will receive or taxes they must pay to support a public program to save lives. Therefore Blomquist (1982) has remarked that contingent values may be unreliable due to hypothetical or strategic bias. 2.2. Theoretical Framework The hedonic approach views that the labor market transactions as a tied sale. On the one hand, workers sell their services for wages. At the same time, they purchase nonpecuniary work attributes. These attributes may vary from job to job. Hence, the workers exercise a choice over preferred job attributes by choosing an appropriate job. On the other hand, firms simultaneously buy the services and characteristics of workers and sell their attributes of jobs offered to the market. Since the characteristics may differ among workers, firms have a choice to exercise. An acceptable match occurs when the preferred choices of both the employer and the employee are mutually consistent. The actual wage, therefore, embodies a series of implicit prices for both workers characteristics and job attributes such as pace of work and probability of injury/death accidents. Controlling for other aspects of a job, one can estimate the wage premium that workers receive for job related risks. Thus, the observed distribution of wages clear both markets over all worker characteristics and job attributes. In this sense labor market is viewed as an implicit market in job and worker attributes. The purpose of this section is to illustrate the properties of the optimal job choice of a worker who is choosing from a set of job opportunities that involve the same number of work hours but have different probabilities of an adverse consequence. Consider a state dependent utility model. Let Y be the initial asset and W(p) be the schedule of earnings for the jobs with probability p of an event that leads to ones death or injury. Therefore, (1-p) is the probability that the worker remains healthy. Suppose U(x) denotes the utility of being healthy state and V(x) denotes the utility of being injured or dead, for any given consumption level x which is equal to Y+W(p). It is assumed that the wage and utility functions are continuous and twice differentiable. Let be the shadow price of the good constraint. It is also assumed that the worker would rather be healthy than not (i.e. U(x) > V(x) >0); the marginal utility of consumption is positive and greater in health state than in ill health state (i.e., Ux > Vx > 0) and the marginal utility of consumption is diminishing or the workers are either risk averse or risk neutral (i.e., Uxx , Vxx < 0). The workers optimal choice among hazardous job alternatives is determined by maximizing the lagrangian given by L = (1-p) U(x) + p V(x) + [ x-Y-W(p)] (1) The job with the optimal risk p is determined by solving the following first-order conditions for a maximum as well as the budget constraint: Lx = 0 = (1-p) Ux + p Vx + (2) Lp = 0 = -U +V - Wp (3) = 0 = x – Y –W(p) (4) Solving for Wp produces the result Wp U( x ) V( x ) 0 (1 p) U x pVx (5) The necessary condition for an interior maximum is that the marginal increase in earnings due to increased risk equals the differences in the two state’s utilities divided by the expected marginal utility of consumption and the resulting value is positive. Notice that the positive sign of Wp is a result of the nature of the job choice problem. To assure that a solution to equation (5) is indeed a maximum, the second order condition also must be satisfied. In mathematical terms, the marginal rate of change of Wp with respect to further rise in p must be negative or positive, but not too large. Totally differentiating the first order conditions (2-4) and solving for resultant equations using Cramer’s rule, the second order condition can be shown as: Wpp < {-(Wp )2 [(1-p) Uxx + PVxx ] –2 Wp [ Ux – Vx]} {pVx + (1-p) Ux}-1 (6) In equation (19), the RHS is positive due to plausible restrictions stated above on the utility functions. Thus, the compensating wage differential result as in (5) implies that curve relating to W and p must have a positive slope if workers are to be attracted to jobs along with it. The choice of a job will satisfy the second-order conditions for an optimum given by (6) if the wage premium per unit of risk with the level of p is constant or increase at not too great a rate. Wealth Effect and the Optimal Job Risk An objection raised against the validity of the theory is that the best jobs in the society also tend to be the highest paid. To resolve this apparent paradox, the wealth effect is useful. Because safety is a normal good, those with more assets will choose safer jobs. Let us investigate the role of worker’s wealth in influencing the optimal job risk level by totally differentiating the first order conditions, and solving for dp/dY using Cramers’s rule as: [(1 p) U xx pVxx ]Wp [ U x VX ] dp (7) 0 2 dY ( Wp )[(1 p) U xx pVxx ] 2Wp [ U x Vx ] Wpp [pVx (1 p) U x ] Since numerator is clearly positive, the sign of dp/dY is the same as that of the denominator. Hazardous jobs will be inferior occupational pursuit as is plausible if : (Wp )2 [(1-p) Uxx + PVxx ] +2Wp [ Ux – Vx]}+ Wpp [pVx + (1-p) Ux] < 0 (8) if equation (8) is solved for W, the condition reduces to equation (6) – the second order condition for maximum. Consequently, the extent of job hazard one chooses necessarily decreases with one’s wealth. 2. 3. Empirical Studies Conceptually, the wage-risk trade-off is interpreted as the amount of wage that a worker requires for a small amount of additional risk. That is, it measures a required compensation for an increase in risk. Hence, it is a willingness-to-accept measure. However, Moore and Viscusi (1988) argue that for sufficiently small changes in risk, the willingness-to accept risk equals the willingness to pay for a reduction in risk. Aggregating such a measure across individuals can provide an estimated value of a statistical life or injury. (The value of life literature is vast. Various approaches are discussed in the literature. They include human capital approach, insurance approach, court awards and compensation approach, portfolio approach and willingness to pay approach. However, economists have increasingly accepted the willingness-to-pay approach as the relevant one. There are two principal methodologies for measuring the Willingness-to-pay prices: Contingent Valuation Techniques and labor market approach (see Linnerooth, 1979 for a review of these approaches). The estimated value represents the collective WTP for reducing each member’s risk by a small amount. The estimated values of life and injury have important implications for policy analysis of projects involving risks to life and health. Many public projects have been undertaken to regulate the risks of life and health. The evaluation of these projects is complicated by the fact that these risks are not traded explicitly in a market with readily observed market prices. Economists have a strong belief that the estimated values from the labor market would be one of the best indices to reflect the value of life or health. Thaler and Rosen (1976) carried out the first empirical study to estimate the positive compensating differentials for fatal risks. Consequently, a large number of studies have been done to estimate the value of life and limb of workers in man countries, including United States, Britain, Canada, Australia and Japan (See Rosen, 1986 and Viscusi 1993 for surveys). In most of the studies, the occupational risk variable enters the earnings equation with a positive and significant coefficient. Rosen (1986) in his survey article also remarks that “ Virtually all studies undertaken so far have shown that wagerisk gradient is positive. The actual extent to which a degree of risk affects earnings is, however, a matter of debate. When the risk premiums are converted into the value of a statistical life/injury, the magnitudes vary dramatically. Table-1 summarizes selected studies on the implicit value of life and injury. As Dillingham (1985) argues that money values vary dramatically among these studies due to either specification errors or an errors in variables. Table 1: Labor Market Studies on the value of life and injury Author/Year Sample Alberini et.al (1997) Brown (1980) Primary survey, Taiwan, 1992 National Longitudinal Survey (1966-71, 1973) Labor Survey, Canada, 1979 Cousineau, Lacroix and Girard (1992) Dillingham (1985) French and Kendall (1992) Garen (1988) Gerking et.al (1988) Hersch and Viscusi (1990) Herzog and Schlottman (1990) Jones-lee (1976) Jones-Lee (1989) Kniesner Leeth (1991) and Source for risk variable Acute respiratory illness Society of actuaries Value of life ($ Million) ---- Value of injury ($) 0.8 -- Quebec compensation board Bureau of Labor Statistics 3.6 -- 2.5 - 5.3 -- -- 38159 PSID, USA, 198182 Mail survey, USA, 1984 Primary survey in Eugene, 1987 Federal Rail road administration injury data Bureau of Labor statistics (BLS) WTP and WTA change in job risk Worker’s assessed injury rate 13.5 21021 3.4(WTP) 8.8(WTA) -- --- US Census, 1970 BLS 9.1 30781(smokers 92245(seat belt users) -- Mail Survey, UK Survey on Motor Vechile accidents, UK, 1982 2-digit manufacturing data, Japan, 1984 Airline safety WTP for risk reduction 15.6 3.8 --- Year book of labor statistics 7.6 77547 Industrial accident data 3.3 8943 0.6 47281 9.7 and 10.3 -- Quality of employment Survey, 1977 CPS Survey, USA, 1980 2-digit manufacturing data, Australia, 1984 and CPS, USA, 1978 Leigh and Folsom (1984) PSID, 1974 and Quality of employment Survey, USA, 1977 National traumatic occupation fatality survey BLS 39.20 Marin and Psacharopoulos (1982) Miller and Guria (1991) Population Census and Surveys, UK, 1977 New Zealand Survey 1989-1990 Moore and Viscusi (1988) Olson (1981) Thaler and Rosen (1976) PSID, USA, 1982 Occupational Mortality Tables 2.8 -- Series of contingent valuation questions on traffic safety BLS 1.2 -- 2.5 and 7.3 -- CPS,1978 BLS 5.2 -Survey of Society of 0.8 -economic actuaries opportunity, USA Viscusi (1981) PSID, USA, 1976 BLS 6.5 46200 Viscusi and Primary Survey in Workers assessed -13890-17761 O’conner (1984) chemical Industry, injury and illness USA, 1982 Simon, Cropper, Fourth 1.53-3.58 477-2870 et.al (1999) Occupational Wage Survey of India Note: Values of life and injury except Alberini e.t.al (1997) were converted in 1990 US dollars. The values in Alberini’s study related to 1992 US dollars. Unions play a leading role in the compensating wage differential literature. Variations in job risk compensation in the union and non-union contexts are also important in understanding the functioning of the wage setting mechanisms. Many empirical studies have attempted to distinguish the premium in the union and non-union jobs. They used either the whole sample method or a split sample method. Firstly, the estimates of a single equation with a risk and union interaction term would provide the differential impact of union status on the compensation for job risks. Secondly, the estimates of separate wage equations for unionist and non-unionists would provide the union differentials. Until 1981, all studies found that unionized workers obtained substantially higher premiums for death risks. Examples are Thaler and Rosen (1976) and Viscusi (1979, 1980). Olson (1981) was the first to estimate a lower risk premium for the unionists in USA., following which Marin and Psacharopoulos (1982) found a negative premium for death risks in UK. Since then, various other studies have emerged on one or the other side of the issue. For example, Ruser (1985) found that the non-union male workers in the USA received larger wage differentials for injury risks than did union workers, and female non-union employees had a negative premium. Cousineau et.al (1992) found a negative but insignificant premium in the non-union jobs in Canada. Herzog and Schlottmann (1990) showed that the union differentials for deadly hazards were lower in UK. Some studies in USA also found that the magnitude of union/nonunion risk premium varied when different data sets were used (Freeman and Medoff, 1981) and the sign changed when the measure of risk changed (Dillingham and Smith, 1984). In theory unions may either raise or lower the risk premium. As a result, the effect of trade union on risk premium is an empirical question. The rationale for a higher premium is that unions are better situated to have job hazard information than the workers themselves. Moreover, they provide a mechanism for voicing their concerns over the risks. The opponents of this view argue that unions preferences between risk and reward may be determined by a union voting mechanism that fails to reflect the preference of the minority of the union members who face the highest risks. Unions may reallocate the jobs with the highest risk to least senior members. On this view, the market in unionized workplace fails to reveal the appropriate return to risk although the workers on the high-risk jobs still share a rent with other unionized workers that is large enough to keep them in the risky jobs. This perplexing state of affairs is correctly addressed by two studies. One study (Dillingham and Smith, 1984) concluded that at this point, we do not know what effect the unions have on the wage-risk trade-off. Another study (Dickens, 1984) remarked that one is forced to conclude that the available data may simple be inadequate to support investigation of market performance. 3. Data and Methodology 3.1 Source of Data In order to analyze the workers behavior in choosing their occupational risks, the micro level workers data were collected through a sample survey in 1993, covering 522 blue collar male workers employed in manufacturing industries in Madras district of Tamil Nadu, a state in southern part of India. The sampling procedure adopted was the multi-stage random sampling method. First, Madras district is selected as the study area as it is one of the major districts (and capital) of Tamil Nadu with large number of registered factories. In the second stage, blue-collar male employees in manufacture industries are chosen as they alone face employment death risks in Madras district over the period from 1987 to 1990. Then, these workers are stratified in to 17 groups according to their industrial codes at 2 digit National Industrial classification (NIC) level. Fixing 1 per cent from each stratum, 522 workers are randomly selected for interview on the basis of four workers from each randomly selected factory. The collected data set consists of information on workers personal as well as enterprise characteristics. The data source for the job risk is the Administrative Report of the Chief Inspector of Factories, Madras. The report provides the data pertaining to the total number of male workers and the number of death and injury accidents to them on an annual basis at 2-digit NIC level. Since these risks may vary substantially across years, particularly when there is a major catastrophe resulting in multiple deaths. Therefore we computed the average probability of job related fatal risks per 1 lakh workers (RISK) and the average probability of injury risk per 100 workers (INJURY) over the years 19871990. The computed average measures would eliminate the distorting influence of such random fluctuations. Then, these risk measures are matched to the workers in the sample using NIC code. Obviously, there is a measurement problem common to this type of study because not all the workers in the same industry face the same level of risks. This problem seems to be most troublesome for white-collar workers since they encounter much different and much safer working conditions (Garen, 1988). Since this study covers only blue-collar workers, this problem may not be as serious as in other studies. Besides, we use a third measure of risk, DANGER which is a subjective variable for whether or not the worker’s job explore him to dangerous or unhealthy conditions. Measurement of Variables and definitions used in the analysis are reported in appendix Table-1. 3.2. Econometric Methodology The existence of risk premium in the union and non-union context is investigated using the model described below: I *i Z'i i I =1 if I>0 I =0 if I 0 (9) ln Yu R ' X' U u (10) ln Yu R ' X' U u (11) In the above equations, ln Y is the natural logarithm of after tax hourly earnings. Subscripts u and n refer to the unionists and the non-unionists respectively. II* represents the individuals (unobserved) intensity of preference for union membership. I take the value 1 for a unionist and is 0 otherwise. X and Z are vectors of exogenous variables other than Risk variables (Risk and Injury). , Uu, Un are random variables which are assumed to be serially uncorrelated and normally distributed with zero expectation, constant variance and covariance u; and , and are parameters to be estimated. In equation (9), Z is vector of variables assumed to influence the desire to join a trade union and includes age, age squared and education based on human capital arguments. In addition, we include the backward class dummy variable to account for differences in preferences due to the caste system, as well as, a dummy for supervisory status. We also include the job characteristic variables- whether job has shift hours and has pleasant work site in order to account for differences in the costs of union membership. The other variables included are marital status, number of children in the family and firm size. Since there are economies of scale in both organizing and maintaining a union presence in a large firm, it is hypothesized that the firm size and collective bargaining will be positively associated. In equation (10) and (11), X includes all the variables defined in Z, except marital status, number of children and work force. Estimation of equation (10) and (11) using OLS leads to inconsistent estimates of the parameters due to non-random sorting between union and non-union. The consistent estimates can be obtained using Heckman’s (1979) step procedure. The first stage involves estimating a union membership equation (9) using a probit method. The estimates are then used to compute a selectivity variable . In the second stage, the selectivity variable is included in the appropriate wage equation to control for the potential bias in the earnings equations (10) and (11). These wage equations are estimated using OLS. The series for members and non-members included in their respective wage equations is of the form: u n ( Z' u ) ( Z' u ) (Z' n ) 1 ( Z' n ) (12) (13) Where and are the cumulative normal distribution function and the standard normal density function respectively, each evaluated at the probit estimate and Z for each worker. The coefficient of can be interpreted as the covariance between the disturbances in the earnings equations and the disturbances in the union member (choice) equation. 4. Empirical Results Probit Estimates of Union Membership: The maximum likelihood probit estimates of the union membership equation and the corresponding marginal effects are reported in Table 2. The maximized value of the log-likelihood function and chi-square statistic for testing the null hypothesis that all the slope coefficients in the model are zero. We reject the null hypothesis that the explanatory variables have no effect. The computed Pseduo R-square can be interpreted as r-square in OLS equation. The computer Pseduo R-square value is 60 percent. This implies that equation fits well overall. The impact of education on union status is clear attractive. The propensity to become a unionist is positively and significantly associated with schooling attainment. The coefficient of age and its square term are significant and it reveals that age has an inverted U shaped effect. The workers belonging to a backward community and those employed in pleasant work sites are less likely to be unionist. The employee living with spouse and those with shift work hours are marginally more likely to join the unions. As expected, the firm size has a positive and significant on the probability of membership. The variables indicating number of children and supervisory status have least impact on the union membership. Table 2: Compensating Wage Differentials: Estimates of Union Choice and Wage Equation Variables Mean (S.D.) Constant Probit Estimates for Union Status Wage Equation (Total Sample) Coefficients -4.1944 (-2.59) Marginal Effects -1.6551 -0.7562(-2.935) Education 9.98 (2.46) 0.1206 (4.51) 0.0476 0.0341(6.808) Age 34.14 (6.69) 0.1143(1.23) 0.0451 0.0779(5.567) Age Square -- -0.0012(-1.02) -0.0005 -0.0007(-3.708) BC 0.64(0.48) -0.2154(-1.69) -0.0850 0.0548(2.233) Supervisor 0.27(0.44) 0.0288(0.87) 0.0114 0.1352(4.553) Shift 0.41(0.49) 0.6358(4.97) 0.2509 0.0286(1.135) Pleasant 0.52(0.49) -0.4285(-3.48) -0.1691 -0.0153(-0.651) Married 0.81(0.39) 0.5240(2.47) 0.2068 -- Number of 1.37(1.16) 0.1292(1.82) 0.0509 -- Children Work Size 90.96(27.66) Risk 10.44(9.26) 0.0016(0.933) Injury 7.29(16.54) 0.0031(2.033) Risk X Union -- 0.0149(6.399) Risk X Injury -- 0.0005(0.293) No. of Obs. Log-likelihood Pseduo R2 %corr. Predicted R-Ssquare F-Value Value of life: Union (Rs. In Millions Value of life Nonunion (Rs. In Millions) Value of Injury: Union (in Rs.) Value of Injury Non-Union (in Rs. 522 0.0026(3.24) 522 -290.02 0.602 55.63% 0.0010 ----- -- 522 ---0.603 70.68 17.49 1.70 3816 3286 Note : Figures in parentheses indicates t-values Estimates of Earnings Function: In order to compare, we present the estimated coefficients of the earnings equation for the whole sample in column 5 of Table-4. In this specification, we allow union status to interact with risk variables. The results show that the age earnings profile exhibits an inverted U shape as expected in the human capital theory with a maximum at age 56 years (by letting W/age=0). The return to education is about 3.4 percent. Backward community workers and supervisors tend to earn more wages while the nonmonetary job attributes show little effect on wages. Before considering the effects of risk and unions. We turn to separate estimates for members and non-members of the union. The results are reported in Table 3. There are significant differences between two groups, which is evident from the significant F-value (chow test). First, let us consider the OLS estimation results without the selectivity term. The return to education is 1.5 percent in the union jobs and 4.8 percent in the non-union jobs. The unionists have a more hamped age earnings profile with a peak at 64 years, while the non-unionist show a clear nonlinear relationship between age and earnings with a maximum at 47 years. Supervisory status and community dummy variables influence only the non-union earnings significantly. Both union and non-union wages are insensitive to job attributes. In selectivity corrected estimates, the effects of human capital variables are strongly evident only in non-union context. We now turn to the effects of risk and union variables that are of direct interest. In the OLS regression for the Whole sample (Table), the estimated coefficients on the union and fatal risk interaction term is positive and statistically significant and larger than the coefficient of RISK itself, suggesting that hazard compensation occur mostly in the union context. The union interaction with INJURY is not significant, whereas INJURY is statistically significant at 5 percent level. It implies that unions are less worried about minor injuries. The estimated union wage effect is not similar across risk levels. It is 15.5 percent (=0.0149 x 10.44 x100) for fatal risk and 0.3 percent (=0.0005 x 7.29 x100) for non-fatal risk. These results may be biased since we do not take in to account the sample selection effect of the union membership. In the split sample specification (Table 3), the risk coefficients are positive and statistically significant at 5 percent level in both OLS and selectivity corrected estimates except INJURY in non-union jobs. These results imply the existence of positive wage compensation for employment related accidental risks in the Indian labor market. The coefficient of RISK indicates the effect of a unit increase in RISK, for a rise in the annual death risk by 1/100000 (0.00001). Its effect on the value of the logarithm of wage equals 0.0124. Evaluating at the mean level of wage, this would give an estimated trade-off 0.0771 between hourly wage and fatality rate in the union jobs. Multiplying by 2000 hours to annualize the figure and by one lakh to reflect the scale of risk variable yield a trade-off Rs.15.55 million and Rs.5.49 million per statistical life in the union and non-union sector respectively. Using the same terminology one can estimate the implicit values for all specifications. The estimated values of life and injury in the union and non-union jobs are shown at the bottom of Tables 2 and 3. There are variations in the values between union and non-union jobs and between OLS and selectivity corrected estimates. These results indicates that the significance of the effect of union status and the self-selection problem. Hence, the estimated values of life and limb without considering the selection problem may provide misleading results for making relevant policy. Table 3: Estimates of Earnings function Dependent variable: ln(after tax hourly wage rate) Variables Union Non-Union Mean (SD) Uncorrected Corrected Mean(SD) Uncorrected Corrected Constant --0.2764 1.5320 --0.9817 -1.1944 (-0.69) (2.22) (-2.86) (-2.70) Education 10.35 0.0158 0.0065 9.57 0.0476 0.0521 (2.47) (2.56) (1.67) (2.39) (6.08) (5.27) Age 35.52 0.0641 0.0031 32.62 0.0815 0.0931 (6.20) (2.98) (1.99) (6.89) (4.34) (3.86) 2 Age 1299.81 -0.0004 -0.0002 1111.38 -0.0008 -0.0009 (462.36) (1.80) (1.73) (490.24) (-3.18) (-3.09) BC 0.63 0.0466 0.0798 0.67 0.0802 0.0712 (0.48) (1.59) (2.23) (0.47) (2.04) (1.74) Supervisor 0.31 0.0602 0.0811 0.22 0.2486 0.2497 (0.46) (1.73) (1.97) (0.42) (5.20) (5.27) Shift 0.52 0.0057 0.1117 0.29 0.0232 0.0544 (0.50) (0.19) (2.24) (0.45) (0.57) (0.94) Pleasant 0.43 0.0044 0.0736 0.62 -0.0181 -0.0376 (0.50) (0.15) (1.82) (0.49) (-0.47) (-0.82) Risk 10.19 0.0124 0.0125 10.72 0.0065 0.0064 Injury (9.71) 10.04 (9.47) -- (6.18) 0.0047 (4.68) -- (6.50) 0.0045 (4.38) -0.3122 (-3.39) 0.639 46.64 274 15.55 R2 -0.615 F -46.90 N 274 274 Value of -15.42 life (Rs.in Million) Value of -5847 5598 Injury (in Rs.) Note: Figures in parentheses indicates t-values (8.74) 4.26 (11.90) -- (2.84) 0.0022 (1.38) -- --248 -- 0.480 24.46 248 5.58 (2.84) 0.0024 (1.50) 0.0814 (0.74) 0.481 22.00 248 5.49 -- 1888 2059 Job Risk Equation Estimates A separate account is made in this section to test whether the optimal job risk would necessarily decrease with the workers wealth. The OLS estimates of the job risk equations are reported in Table 4. The explanatory variables included are: (a) the variables which affect earnings such as education, age, union status and occupational dummies; (b) the variables denoting the non-labor income and the value of assets including the house owned; (c) proxies for the degree of risk aversion. Since the measures of the stability of worker's life style are inversely correlated with the degree of risk aversion, the following proxy measures of stability are included: the number of dependents (DC), the marital status and dummy capturing the employment status of the spouse; and (d) the industrial dummies to capture the differences in production process which presumably influence the safety levels of the firms. The human capital variables are expected to have a negative relation with job risk variables. On the contrary to the expectation, they have the opposite sign, but not statistically significant at 5 percent level. BC is included to test the hypothesis that the workers belonging to backward class are discriminated in terms of the riskiness of their jobs. Such a discrimination hypothesis is not supported by the result. As expected, UNION influences risk negatively. But its impact on INJURY is positive and significant. Though the results are puzzling, they imply that the unions play a significant role in reducing the fatal risks and they are least worried about injuries. As expected, DC, SPOUSE and MARRIED are negatively associated with risks. However, these results are not supported by t-values. Occupation dummies have positive impact on risk variables, while the industrial dummies show negative impact. Notably most of them are statistically significant at 5 percent level. INCOME and ASSET influence the job risks negatively as expected, but they are not statistically significant. The elasticity’s of fatal and injury risks with respect to non-labor income are estimated as 0.02 and 0.06 respectively. The respective elasticity’s with respect to ASSET are 0.02 and 0.004. For comparative purpose, the maximum likelihood estimates of the logit parameters pertaining to the DANGER perception variable is depicted in Column 3 of Table-4. The personal (SCHOOL, AGE) and social characteristics variables (DC, MARRIED, SPOUSE) are having least impact on danger perception. UNION is positively related with DANGER and statistically significant at 1 percent level, indicating that the union workers are capable of identifying the hazards they face since they are having the provision of job hazard information through collective bargaining. The negative impact of ASSISTANT indicates that the assistants are not capable of identifying the risks or they are safer. The final matter of empirical interest is the influence of ASSET and INCOME. As expected, both are negative and INCOME is statistically significant at 1 percent level, confirming the result that the optimal job risk would necessarily decrease with workers’ wealth. Table 4: Ordinary Least Squares and Logit Estimates of Job Risk Equations Variables OLS Estimates Logit Estimates Dep Var: Risk Dep.Var: Injury (Dep.Var: Danger) Constant 5.0902 (0.56) -21.8500(-1.117) 0.6299(0.16) Education 0.2245(1.49) 0.6220(1.90) -0.0849(-1.11) Age 0.2297(0.45) 1.0313(0.93) 0.1054(0.50) 2 Age -0.0011(-0.16) -0.0132(-0.91) -0.0014(-0.52) BC -0.2003(-0.29) -0.2414(-0.16 0.5532(1.59) Union -0.4917(-0.69) 5.9345(3.83) 1.5656(3.89) DC -0.2378(-0.65) -0.3801(-0.47) -0.2013(-1.05) Married -1.2162(-1.05) -1.1083(-0.44) -0.0162(-0.02) Spouse 0.2705(0.23) 4.2378(1.69) 0.5277(0.95) Work size 0.0019(1.49) 0.0040(1.43) 0.0021(1.16) Private -0.8651(-0.86) 1.2776(0.58) 0.5803(1.06) Supervisor 2.6334(2.60) 3.2462(1.47) 0.8498(1.44) Machinist 3.5820(4.04) 4.2056(2.17) 0.1198(0.26) Turner 5.6138(1.79) -8.9770(-1.32) 0.1037(0.30) Assistant 3.6847(2.88) 2.7649(0.99) -1.2408(-2.38) Income -0.0010(-1.07) -0.0023(-1.11) -0.0011(-3.03) Asset -0.00001(-0.28) -0.0000(-0.59) -0.14E-5(0.69) Ind-1 -14.4111(-9.24) -9.9514(-2.92) 0.1004(0.06) Ind-2 -13.0975(-13.13) -6.3253(-2.91) -1.5582(-3.50) Ind-3 -8.6012(-7.89) -8.3512(-3.51) -1.2418(-2.41) 2 R 0.3997 0.1990 -F 17.5920 14.100 -Log-likelihood ---128.332 Chi-square --97.82 Pseduo R2 --0.1304 N 522 522 522 Note: Figures in parentheses indicates t-values 5.Conclusion In this paper attempt has been made to test the predictions of the competitive wage theory and assess the role of trade unions in determining the wage premiums for job related death and injury risks for Indian workers. Since union status is not exogenous, we have applied the standard Heckman’s two step procedure to correct the self-selection bias. The results show no evidence of selectivity bias in the non-union earnings equation. But we have observed a strong evidence of selectivity bias in the union context. The results imply that on an average, the union male worker employed in a manufacturing factory receives approximately Rs.155.50 in annual wages for an increase in the risk of deadly hazards at work by a probability of 0.00001 and Rs.55.98 for a rise in the risk of injury by 0.01. The respective values for the non-union workers are Rs.54.90 and Rs.20.59. Since union and non-union compensation vary widely, the imperfect information is probably the most often cited justification for government interference in the matter of job safety. It may take the role of providing necessary risk details and adequate compensation for employment risks. The empirical results provide the estimated value of statistical life is Rs.15.55 millions and 5.49 millions and the estimated value of injury is Rs.5598 and Rs.2059 for the union and non-union sector workers respectively. The value of life here represents the rate for very small risks, not the amount that worker will pay for certain life extension. Besides, life is priceless and no money can compensate a person for his life. A comparison of our estimates with those from developed nations (given in Table-1) indicates that our value is lower than the values from developed nations. In view of this, our estimates seem reasonable. These results also have important implications for policy analyses of projects involving risks to life and health. This value can be used to value reductions in risk of death achieved by industrial safety programs or environmental health programs. It should be, however, noticed that this study is not free from limitations. Estimates of this study may be biased due to the fact that it fails to include the impact of insurance benefit variables and life cycle issues such as age related differences in value of life and discounting problem. Appendix Table1. Measurement of Variables and its Definition Variables Definition Risk Job related fatal risks per 1 lakh workers Injury Danger Education Age BC Married Spouse DC Union Job related non-fatal risks per 100 workers Job hazard perception=1 if job exposes the worker to dangers; 0 otherwise Education (in completed years) Worker’s age in years Worker’s community=1 if he belongs to backward community; 0 otherwise Marital Status=1 if married; 0 otherwise Employment of spouse=1 if the spouse is employed; 0 otherwise The number of dependent children, aged 0-16 Union status=1 if worker is a member of union; 0 otherwise Work Size Supervisor Machinist Assistant Turner Security Pleasant Decision Irregular Private Income Asset Ind-1 Ind-2 Ind-3 Wage Total work force of the firm where he works If worker is a supervisor=1; 0 other wise If worker is a machinist=1; 0 otherwise If worker is an assistant=1; 0 otherwise If worker is turner=1; 0 otherwise If workers job provides security=1; 0 otherwise Condition of work site: if workers job has pleasant=1; 0 other wise Workers decision on the job: if worker is the decision maker=1; 0 otherwise Irregular work hours: if the worker has shift hour works=1; 0 otherwise If the worker’s employment is in private sector=1; 0 otherwise Non labor income of the respondent The value of the property owned by the respondent including the house If the industry is manufacture of rubber, plastic, petroleum and coal products=1; 0 otherwise If the industry is manufacture of machinery, machine tools and parts=1; 0 other wise If the industry is manufacture of transport equipment and parts=1; 0 otherwise Natural logarithm of after tax hourly wage rate References Alberini, A., M.Cropper, Tsu-Tan Fu, A.Krupnick, J.T.Liu and D.Shaw and W.Harrington. (1997), “Valuing Health Effects of Air Pollution in Developing Countries: The Case of Taiwan”,Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 34, 107-126. Asian Development Bank (1996), “Economic Evaluation of environmental Impacts (PartI and II): A Work Book. Brown,C. (1980),”Equalizing Differences in the Labor Market, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 113-34. Cousineau,J.M. and R.Lacroix amd A.M.Girard (1992), “Occupational Hazard and Wage Compensating Differentials”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 166-169. Dickens, W.T. (1984), Differences Between risk Premiums in Union and Non-Union wages and the Case for Occupational Safety Regulation, American Economic Review, 96, 320-323. Dillingham,A.E. (1985),”The Influence of Risk Variable Definition on Value-of-Life Estimates, Economic Inquiry,23, 277-294. Dillingham,a.E. and R.S.Smith (1984),”Union Effects in Valuation of Fatal Risk”, 36th Annual Proceedings, Industrial Relations research Association, pp.270-277. Freeman, R. and F.Medoff (1981), “The Impact of the per cent organized on Union and Non-Union Wages”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 63, 651-672. French, M.T. and David L.Kendall (1992), The Value of Job Safety for Rail Road Workers” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 175-185. Garen,J.E (1988), “Compensating Wage Differentials and the Endogenetity of Job Riskiness”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 70, 9-16 Gerking,S. and M.De Hann and W.Schulze (1988), “The Marginal Value of Job Safety: A Contingent Valuation Study”, Journal of risk and Uncertainty, 1, 185-199. Heckman, J.J. (1979), Sample Selection Bias as Specification Error, Econometrica, Vol.47, 153-161. Hersch,J and W.Kip Viscusi (1990), “Cigarette Smoking, Seat Belt use and Differences in Wage Risk Trade offs”, Journal of Human Resources, 25, 202-227. Herzog,H.W. and A.M.Schlottmann (1990), “Valuing Risk in the Workplace: Market Price, Willingness to Pay and the Optimal Provision of safety”, The Review of Economics and Statistics,72,463-470. Jones-Lee,M.W (1976), The Value of Life: An Economic Analysis”, University of Chicago Press. Jones-Lee,M.W. (1989),The Economics of Safety and Physical Risk”, Basil Blackwell. Kniesner,T.J. and J.D.Leeth (1991), “Compensating Wage differentials for Fatal Injury risks in Australia, Japan, and United States, Journal of Risk and uncertainty, 4, 75-90. Leigh.P.J (1989),”Compensating Wage for Job-Related Death: The Opposing Arguments”, Journal of Economic Issues, 23, 823-842. Leigh, P.J. and R.N.Folsom (1984), “Estimates of the value of Accident Avoidance at the Job Dependent on the concavity of the Equalizing Difference Curve, Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, 24, 56-66. Linnerooth,J. (1979), “The Value of Human Life: A Review of the Models” Economic Inquiry, 17, 52-74. Marin,A. and G.Psacharopoulos (1982), “The Reward for Risk in the Labor Market: Evidence from UK and a Reconciliation with other studies”, Journal of Political Economy, 90, 827-853. Mincer, J. (1974), Schooling , Experience and Earnings, NBER, Colombia University Press, New York Miller,T and J.Guria (1991), “The Value of Statistical Life in New Zealand”, Report to the Ministry of Transport, Land Transport Division. Moore, G.A (1976), The Effect of Collective Bargaining on Internal Salary Structures in the Public School, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, April. Moore,M.J andW.Kip.Viscusi (1988),”Doubling the Estimated Value of Life: Results Using New Occupational Fatality Data, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 7, 476-490. Olson,C (1981),”An Analysis of the wage Differentials Received by Workers on Dangerous Jobs, Journal of Human Resources, 67, 167-185. Rosen, S. (1974), “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure Competition”, Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34-55. Rosen, S. (1986), The Theory of Equalizing Differences, in O.Ashenfelter and P.R.G. Layard (eds.) Hand Book in Labor Economics, Elsevier Science Publishers, North Holland, pp. 641-692. Ruser, J. (1985), Worker’s Compensation Benefits and Compensating Wage Differentials, Working Paper No.153, U.S. Bureau of Labor Studies. Sandy R. and R.F.Elliot (1996), Unions and Risk: Their Impact on the Level of compensation for Fatal Risk, Economica, 63, 291-309. Thaler,R. and S.Rosen (1976),” The Value of Saving a Life : Evidence from the Market”, in Nestor E.Terlecky ed., Household Production and Consumption, NBER, 265298. Viscusi, W.P (1979), Employment Hazards: An Investigation of Market Performance, Harvard University Press. Viscusi, W.P. (1980), Union, Labor Market structure and the Welfare implications of the Quality of Work, Journal of Labor Research, vol.1, 175-92. Viscusi,W.P. (1981),”Occupational Safety and health Regulations: Its Impact on Policy alternatives”, in J.C.Greenwich (ed.)., Research in Public Policy Analysis and Management, JAI Press, 281-299. Viscusi, W.P. (1983), Risk By Choice: Regulating Health and Safety in the Workplace, Harvard University Press. Viscusi,W.P(1993),” The Vale of Risks to Life and Limb”, Journal of Economic Literature, 31, 1912-1946. Viscusi, W.P and C.J.O’Conner (1984), “Adaptive responses to Chemical Labeling: Are workers Bayesian Decision Makers” The American Economic Review,74, 942956. Weiss, L.W. (1966), Concentration and Labor Earnings, American Economic Review, March, Vol.56.