CHAPTER 14.1 14 GAINS FROM TRADE Introduction Of Absolute & Comparative Advantage A. Absolute advantage A country is said to have an absolute advantage in producing a good if it can produce of a good with the amount of resources. E.g Food(F) Clothing(C) Country A 10 OR 6 Country B 5 OR 10 Country A has an absolute advantage in producing Country B has an absolute advantage in producing . . B. Comparative advantage A country is said to have a comparative advantage in producing a good if it can produce that good at a lower than other countries. E.g. Machine(M) Bread(B) Country X 10 OR 20 Country Y 9 OR 10 Country has absolute advantage in producing both M and B. But it only has comparative advantage in producing only. The other country has comparative advantage in producing . 14.2 The Model Of Absolute Advantage & The Model Of Comparative Advantage A. The model of absolute advantage (Reciprocal absolute advantage) (p.248) If one country has absolute advantage on one good and the other country on the other, then each country should specialize in producing the good in which it has absolute advantage and then trade. They are able to enjoy a level of output than before. Refer to the example on p.248 Q. If there is no reciprocal absolute advantage, e.g. Country A has absolute advantage in both F and C, then no trade will be possible ?! 1 B. The model of comparative advantage (p.250) If each country specializes in producing the good (or range of goods) in which it has opportunity cost compared to other countries and then trades with other countries, it is able to enjoy a level of output higher than that which it would have if it attempted to be self-sufficient. Refer to the example on p.250 14.3 Graphic Analysis Of International Trade (p.259) We can illustrate the gains from trade by using PPC. Constant cost is assumed PPC is a line (i.e., constant slope). A. The model of absolute advantage (Reciprocal absolute advantage) Refer to fig.1 on p.259 Notes : (i) For each country, some consumption bundles which are not attainable before are now attainable with s and t . (ii) Terms of trade (TOT) curve is also the consumption possibility curve (CPC). B. The model of comparative advantage Refer to fig.2 on p.261 Q. If other information e.g. labour requirements for producing goods are given, how to discover the comparative advantage? Refer to the case on p.253 14.4 The Terms Of Trade (TOT) (p.254) A. The meaning (i) It means the amount of goods that a country must give up (export) to get one unit of imported good. E.g. 1F can be exchanged for 2C. That means if a country import F, TOT = if a country import C, TOT = But in fact, we usually express like this 1F : 2C . (ii) TOT simply represents the of obtaining goods through international trade. 2 (iii) However, it is customary in official government statistic to define TOT in another way. TOT = x 100 Hence, as TOT rises TOT is improved (it is a favourable change). As TOT falls TOT is deteriorated (it is an unfavourable change). Note: An improvement or deterioration of the TOT does not necessarily mean that a country is better off or worse off. It may be that (a) productivity is improved Px TOT But improved productivity is a good thing to the country. (b) better quality of imports Pm TOT But, of course, the country is not necessarily worse off! Exercise 1 “When TOT rises, the balance of trade (BOT) rises, too.” Is this correct? Why? B. Mutually beneficial TOT (i) Both countries will gain from trade if the TOT lies between the domestic opportunity cost or exchange ratios of the 2 countries. E.g. The domestic cost or exchange ratio of the 2 countries in the example provided in the textbook is : Food(F) Country A 0.6C Country B 2C That means : A’s cost in producing 1F is exchange B’s cost in producing 1F is in exchange TOT : < 1F < Alternatively, B’s cost in producing 1C is exchange A’s cost in producing 1C is in exchange TOT : < 1C < Remark : (i) The potential gain in the above case is 3 Clothing(C) 1.67F 0.5F it minimum gets in it maximum forgoes it minimum gets it maximum forgoes C or F if the in transaction cost is greater than C or F, no trade will take place. (ii) The distribution of the gains from trade determined by TOT which in turn depends on the of the 2 trading countries. 14.5 Assumption Behind The Trade Models, Other Gains From Trade & Some Remarks A. Assumptions Refer to p.255 B. Other gains from trade Refer to p.256 C. Remarks Refer to p.258 14.6 Trade Models With Increasing Cost Of Production Because of specialization transfer resources to produce a specific good returns to scale will eventually set in relative cost in producing that good changes lose comparative advantage So, we need trade models with increasing cost of production. A. Trade model with only 2 countries (p.263) Consider : 1 good (good X), 2 demand and supply curves (of exporting and importing countries). P S=MC P D S=MC D 0 - Q 0 Q are equilibrium P and Q under self-sufficiency in A and B respectively. - Cost and use value at the marginal unit are different ( , ). - MC and MUV in country A is than those of B A is an of good X and B is the . - Pe must be at a level at which the amount of = the amount of If they are unequal, equilibrium price will change until they are equal. 4 Q. What are the gains from trade? Ans. There are 2 sources of gains : (p.264) (i) gains It comes from reallocating consumption from the country with MUV to the country with MUV. (ii) gains It comes from reallocating production from the country with the country with MC. P S=MC MC to P D S=MC D 0 Q 0 Q Continue the example above, (a) gains to Country A (i) increase consumption by the UV from consuming than the cost in obtaining them (i.e., area ) is (ii) decrease production by save in production cost is than the cost of purchase (i.e., area ) (b) gains to Country B (i) decrease consumption by the loss of UV from consuming is than the receipts from selling them (i.e., area ) (ii) increase production by the extra production cost is than the receipts from selling (i.e., area ) B. Trade model in a price-takers’ market (p.265) Large no. of countries in the international market any shifts in domestic demand and supply will lead to changes in quantity imported and exported, but will remain unchanged. C. Analysis with PPC ( 1 country, 2 goods ) (i) With increasing cost PPC is (ii) PPC = CPC when there is no (p.265) to the origin. . 5 good Y 0 Example : At point A, there is no trade. good X Slope of the straight line (TOT) represents Q of good that can be exchanged for 1 unit of good in the international trade. Slope at point A is than that of the straight line. That means, cost of producing good X is than the cost of exchanging good X in the international market. reducing production of good and exchange good for in the open market. this process continues until the cost of producing good by itself = the cost of exchanging it in the international market (i.e., point B). With trade, moving away from B along the straight line until a higher IC is reached (i.e., IC2) Vertical difference between point B and C is and the horizontal difference between point B and C is . Q. Can you work out the reverse case yourself? 6