(Draft, Please Do Not Quote. Comments Most Welcome!) Ideational Semiperiphery: Israeli Economics as a Case Study Ronen Mandelkern1 The Hebrew University of Jerusalem ronenmm@pob.huji.ac.il Paper prepared for Workshop on Policy Ideas, Discourses and Debates in the Globalisation Process: Have Developing Countries a Chance to Compete? European Consortium for Political Research, Joint Sessions of Workshops, Nicosia 2006: 25-30 April 2006 1 PhD candidate, Department of Political Science. My sincere thanks to Michael Shalev. Abstract One of the contributions of world-system theory was to break down the dichotomy between developed and developing countries by introducing the concept of semiperiphery. I wish to claim that applying this concept to an ideational instead of materialist analysis may serve us in better understanding the logic of ideational influence in international politics. The first part of this paper is dedicated to a theoretical analysis of the concept of ideational semiperiphery. In parallel to the original definition in world-system theory, it will be claimed here that when it comes to the ideational sphere, semiperipheral countries are an intermediate stratum between core and periphery, and their existence supports the political viability of the system as a whole. Semiperipheral countries' limited partnership with the core, at certain stages in the process of international ideational influence, contributes to their cooperation with the hegemonic system. At the same time, for peripheral countries this partnership signifies a potential option to impact the system, and thus gives (a certain amount of) legitimacy to the existing situation of unequal influence. In the second part of the paper the relevance of this theoretical framework is examined in relation to the world of economic knowledge. Using comparative data on the performance of economists in different countries I produce a rough mapping of the core, periphery and semiperiphery in the economics world and empirically identify the characteristics of the semiperiphery. The third section of the paper examines academic economics in Israel during the 1970s and the beginning of the 1980s, treated as a case study of the semiperiphery. The dependence of Israeli economics on American economics is reflected by the training of most Israeli senior economists in American universities, and by their continuous reference to and reliance on American knowledge bases, such as American economic journals or American economic research centers and universities. Furthermore, the Israeli case also demonstrates the importance of "imported" ideational influence on actual policymaking. Finally, comparing Israel with other semiperipheral cases points to a dialectic dynamic between ideational and materialist dominance and influence, and signifies the importance of the interplay of different kinds of power resources and impacts in studying the international system.. 2 Introduction The original use of the term semiperiphery, in Wallerstein's world-systems theory, has a clear materialist orientation (Wallerstein 1974; 1979; 2004). In this paper I wish to somewhat abandon this orientation and to examine the meaning of semiperiphery from an ideational perspective. Thus, the main theoretical questions that will lead this paper are can we indeed put this concept to meaningful use within ideational analysis, and if so how we should understand it. In order to provide a satisfactory answer to these questions, two main steps need to be taken. First, the concept of semiperiphery cannot stand on its own, by definition. The term is part of a broader theoretical perspective that needs to be under consideration. I will suggest possible ideational applications of Wallerstein's world-systems theory in general, and then examine the applicability of the world-system perspective on international ideational influence in the context of real world examples from the sphere of economic ideas. The second step will be employing this concept to describe and analyze Israeli economists' role within the world of economic research. It should be mentioned that my initial motivation for examining the term semiperiphery from an ideational perspective was Israel's seemingly deviant place within the conventional frameworks for understanding international ideational influence. Economics in Israel is distinguished by the high degree to which it is subject to American influence, on the one hand, and its high status in conventional economic research rankings on the other. I will claim that this seeming contradiction is not only possible but even plausible if we understand Israel as a case of ideational semiperiphery. Nevertheless, although the theoretical discussion was inspired by the Israeli case, my argument is not built exclusively on the Israeli experience but also on comparisons to different but related cases such as Mexico and South-Korea, which also suggest the usefulness of the concept of ideational semiperiphery. In addition, comparison of such diverse cases will provide us with useful insights regarding common features of different trajectories towards semiperipheral status within the international system of ideational influence. 3 I conclude that the concept of semiperiphery is indeed useful in ideational analysis. First, in breaking the dichotomy between developing and developed countries, or between influencing and being influenced. That is not to say that there are no longer systems of unequal influence, only that the relationships within such systems are more complicated in some cases. Secondly, this concept may help us create a qualitative, and not only quantitative, distinction between levels and types of influence. Finally, although my discussion begins by seeking an alternative to materialist analysis, I conclude that there are benefits to an integrated perspective. Theoretical Framework Brief reference to central characteristics of the original world-systems theory is necessary before entering our main discussion. First, one should note that world-systems theory is based on Marxist-materialist analysis, thus applying to it an ideational perspective which is not necessarily based on economic conditions is contrary to its spirit. The second main component of its ontology is the meaningless of a state or a country on its own, especially in the current era. According to this theory, since the 19th century there has been one capitalist world economy that should be examined as a whole if one wishes to make substantive observations (e.g. Wallerstein 1979; 1984; 2004).1 Although rejecting these assumptions, I wish to claim that world-systems theory can still inspire and enrich an analysis that is founded on different basic assumptions.2 One of the most important contributions of world-systems theory was the breaking of the dichotomy between the developed and developing world, and the creation of a three-layered division between the states in the world (Arrighi and Drangel 1986; Wallerstein 1976b). Wallerstein's original typology of core, periphery and semiperiphery builds on different patterns of economic production and reflects the hierarchy of exploitation not only within states (i.e. class exploitation) but also between them. This division is also politically 1 Wallerstein assumes that there have been occasions when specific isolated countries existed, but in the modern era that option diminished. 2 See Skocpol (1977) for an important critique of world-systems theory. 4 significant, since it enables the survival of such a system of exploitation. The existence of an intermediate layer between the core and the periphery reduces the risks created for the core from its exploitative position, since a large part of its exploitation does not occur directly. It also reduces the pay-offs the core has to offer to any opposition that might arise, since a significant opposition could be launched only by the semiperiphery (Wallerstein 1979: 2124). Furthermore, and probably most important for our topic, the semiperiphery provides an environment in which change for the weak is possible, and is perceived as such. As one author put it, the political meaning of semiperiphery "emphasizes the voluntary action of states to improve the relative position of their countries by accepting competition but by pursuing a policy of catching-up. The solutions can vary all over the place, going from isolation or protective interlude [...] to the most extreme form of liberal integration." (Aymard 1985: 40) And as Wallerstein noted, the significance of accepting competition cannot be underestimated: "Since there is a game of geographical musical chairs, there is hope for "mobility" despite "polarization" – mobility for states as well as for individuals. What is usually omitted from the analysis is that, in a stratified system, upward mobility for one unit is downward mobility for another. The wonder is not that there is so little class consciousness, but that there is so much." (Wallerstein 1984: 9) Can we draw a parallel to these observations when we come from an ideational standpoint? It seems that if we put aside the highly materialist concepts of production and exploitation, and focus on the political importance of the concept according to world-system analysis, some useful insights may be derived. Thus, when applying the concept of semiperiphery to an ideational analysis one should primarily focus on the stability and legitimacy that a threelayered mechanism provides to the international system of ideational influence. As in materialist analysis, the most relevant notion for our topic is the acceptance of competition by the weak countries as a means for upward mobility. When it comes to 5 ideational processes, competition is not over economic resources but over influence, prestige, and most important for our purposes, relative autonomy in setting one's norms and theoretical ideas. These resources are not distributed equally between countries around the world; rather, some of them enjoy an autonomous position and compete over influencing others, and may be termed core, whereas others are mainly influenced and lack autonomous stand, not to mention prestige, and will be termed periphery. But we can also think of a third bloc of countries, that are indeed highly influenced but are not passive or helpless, instead playing an important role within the process of ideational influence, as an active agent. Such countries will be termed here semiperiphery, and they are marked by their partial autonomy in the process of setting their own norms and ideas. In the spirit of Wallerstein's theory, it can be assumed that countries in the ideational semiperiphery perform two significant political functions for the system as a whole. First, with their face towards the periphery, they serve as an important source of legitimacy for the system. The semiperiphery signals peripheral countries that their passive stand in the face of ideational influence from the core is not necessarily the only option; instead, they can make an effort and acquire a right to participate in the process of ideational influence and even impact it to some extent. The second political function of the semiperiphery is rooted in its relations with the countries that constitute the core. One may regard this relationship as totally unequal and claim that its effects on the core are negligible. Such a claim would only emphasize the system legitimating function of these relationships: the participation of the semiperiphery within the process of ideational influence enhances its obligation to the process itself, and gives legitimacy to the results of that process. Thus, the semiperiphery cooperates with ideational influence and hegemony and does not pose it significant opposition, while the core in its turn provides the semiperiphery only symbolic opportunities to participate in the process of agenda-setting. I wish to argue against the claim that this participation has only symbolic significance that does not create a real chance for meaningful influence by the semiperiphery. The active role of semiperipheral countries within the ideational process is reflected by their ability to choose 6 the core country they wish to be exposed to and interact with, or even specific ideas they select as a source of influence. One should be cautious and not make a claim that implies that semiperipheral countries actually lead the directions of ideational processes. But these countries do play an active part in determining the demand for ideas, thus they do influence the process of ideational competition within core countries, and the determination of ideational hegemonic trends. Semiperipheral countries play an important role in certain stages of international ideational influence. Adler and Haas (1992; Haas 1992) divided the process of policy evolution to four stages which are innovation, diffusion, selection and persistence. Adopting this division I hypothesize that in contrast to the core, semiperipheral countries play only a marginal part in the innovation stage. Their main involvement in this process is most likely to occur at the stages of selection and diffusion, and in this respect unlike peripheral countries they can be expected to play an active role in the process of international ideational influence. A final theoretical observation concerns the above-mentioned political functions of the semiperiphery.3 Semiperipheral countries are a source of system stability and consistency: as a source of legitimacy they serve as stabilizers. But as 'consumers' in the process of ideational competition they may also serve as a source of change, influencing the competition between hegemonic powers and perhaps even under some circumstances stimulating movement of countries from the semiperiphery to the core. Needless to say, core countries, as "suppliers", need to pay a price for semiperipheral cooperation. Such price may be restricted to the ideational sphere, e.g. allowing for participation in the ideational process within the core, or take a material form, such as financial aid. To summarize, according to the theoretical framework posited above, ideational influence occurs within a triple-layered world-system, in which semiperipheral countries play a pivotal role in the diffusion and selection of ideas. In the next part of this paper I will try to apply this theoretical framework to the world of economics and to use several practical measures in 3 These claims are inspired also by Wallerstein (1976b: 351-2) 7 order to place specific countries within the categories of ideational core, periphery and semiperiphery. Ideational Core, Periphery and Semiperiphery: Some Examples When thinking of a country which is the core of economics scholarship in today's world, the United States immediately comes to mind not only as part of the core but also as the hegemonic power within it. One may even wonder is there any competition to American economics these days and whether economic research and study in all countries is in fact American in essence (Coats 1997).4 Most importantly, does this lack of competition derive from some objective or unavoidable circumstances, thus having no significant political explanation? Recall that competition between core countries is essential in the suggested theoretical framework, thus the answer to the question of whether any other country can be regarded as belonging to the core, when the economics profession is considered, is crucial.5 Indeed, if American standards for measuring influence in economics are taken as the criterion, the answer is probably negative (e.g. Kalaitzidakis et al. 2001; Portes 1987). Nevertheless, as several studies have shown, at least until the early 1990s continental European economics has had important unique characteristics that not only distinguish it from American economics but also imply that its position is still autonomous in respect to both structure and content. American economists tend to publish much more in general, and specifically many more journal articles than European economists. American and European economists also differ in the contents of their research, which is theoretically oriented in the US as opposed to the practical and policy orientation in Europe. European economists also tend to focus as teachers in undergraduate students as opposed to their American counterparts 4 Assuming there is, in spite important internal differences, something that we may call American economics. See also Hansen (1991: 1085) 5 It is worth mentioning that in the materialist world-system analysis only three countries were always regarded as core. These were the USA, the UK and West Germany (Terlouw 1993: 88). One may claim that in an enormous ideational arena such as the US we can talk about a substantial competition within a country. 8 that invest most of their efforts in postgraduate students (Frey and Eichenberger 1992; 1993; Kolm 1988). A measure of the autonomous position of continental European economics is reflected by their independent training, i.e. socialization, of academic economists. Data from the "Who's Who in Economics" survey provides a rough but useful measure for this purpose. This source catalogs the most influential economists in the world, but to a large extent according to American standards (i.e. influence is mostly regarded as publication in highly ranked journals) (Blaug 1986; Blaug 1999; Blaug and Sturges 1983; Blaug and Vane 2003). European economists that appear in this survey are not a representative sample of all European economists, but we may assume that they are equally or more oriented towards American economics than their colleagues that are not included in this list. Thus, we can expect that if most of the French economists listed in "Who's Who" took their graduate studies in France, the rate of locally trained economists in France in general is at least the same. From the data of the 1st edition of this survey from 1983 we can indeed learn about relative European autonomy: 20 of 25 French economists and 19 of 20 German economists that appear in the list have graduated in France or Germany, respectively. In Canada, on the other hand, 15 of 19 economists were trained in the US and none was trained locally. According to the data of the last edition from 2003, it seems that European autonomy was somewhat reduced: a large share of economists in the list from Central European countries, that is 11 out of 28, graduated in the US. But still, 16 others graduated locally. This numbers imply relatively significant autonomy, especially when compared to Canada in which 18 of 22 economists in the list were trained in the US, or to Southern European countries where 11 of 12 economists in the list completed their PhDs in the US or the UK. Note that the Scandinavian countries had a relatively strong autonomous position during all the period: in 9 1983 all seven Scandinavian economists on the list graduated locally; while in 2003 10 of 11 and only one graduated in the US.6 There are also a number of examples of autonomous scholarship before the current era of American hegemony in economics. The main cases of independent schools in economics are the Stockholm School in Sweden, the French regulation school, and the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA) (Babb 2001: 4).7 To this we may add British economics, which before 1945 was probably the most influential source of economic knowledge (Backhouse 1997). Referring to peripheral countries, most of the African countries are natural representatives for that category, and also certain states in Latin America, South East Asia and the Middle East. It is obvious that a certain threshold of economic development is a necessary condition for the existence of institutions that will perform economic research worthy of its name. Countries within these regions, such as Sudan in Africa or Bangladesh in South East Asia, with their approximately $2000 GDP per capita, cannot build such institutions. Obviously, without their existence autonomous research and study is unlikely, to say the least. One may question whether these countries should be regarded at all as being part of the economics world: they are certainly affected by economic policy designed in core countries but probably do not engage with economics research at all. I would argue that if a country is starting to be a part of economics world (by creating institutions and providing an infrastructure for researchers to significantly engage with economists from core countries), then it is becoming a part of the semiperiphery. The reason is that when a country is allocating resources for such activity it also needs to decide which country's knowledge it will rely upon. This type of dependency on the activity of the core is essentially different from that 6 Data from 2003 was aggregated according the country clusters in order to provide a simpler picture which still reflects general trends. Local graduation means in all the countries of the region, but this does not imply that we should consider regions instead of countries as the main unit of analysis (especially since most local graduation were in the original country and not in other countries in the region). Central Europe includes France, Germany, the Netherlands, Belgium and Switzerland; Southern Europe includes Italy, Spain, Greece and Cyprus; Scandinavia includes Sweden and Norway in 1983 and Sweden, Denmark and Finland in 2003. See Appendix 1 for full data. 7 On the independence of French economics see Kolm (1988: 208). Sandelin and Veiderpass doubt the existence of a truly independent Swedish school in economics (Sandelin and Veiderpass 1997). 10 of the periphery. The rest of this paper will be focused on the semiperipheral class of countries. In semiperipheral countries institutions of economic research and study exist and play a meaningful and significant role in social and public life, while nevertheless being highly dependent on external sources of knowledge and training. Although they perform important functions within the local political environment, these institutions cannot stand on their own. Mexico and South Korea serve as good examples. Both of them have established and strengthened their academic institutions, and specifically their economic research, in the last few decades. But in both countries this development was highly dependent on American support, especially during the training process, and on the American knowledge centers and networks, that served as a focal point of reference (Babb 2001; Choi 1997).8 Again, the place where economics faculty members conducted their PhD studies serves as a good measure for estimating such dependency on the hegemonic power: the vast majority of economics faculty members of the leading universities in these countries are American trained: 17 out of 22 PhD holders in ITAM, Mexico and 27 out of 32 in Seoul National University, South Korea.9. A further useful tool for assessing the system of American hegemonic power in economics and the countries related to it is the statistical data provided by the ISI-Thompson company on journal publications in the field of business and economics.10 It should be emphasized that these data and ranking are very American oriented for two reasons: first, as mentioned above, publication in academic journals is less common in Europe; secondly, ISI-Thompson data include only journals in which paper titles, abstracts and keywords appear in English.11 Thus, 8 Materialist world-systems analysts have also placed these specific countries within the semiperiphery (Arrighi and Drangel 1986; Terlouw 1993: 88 [without Chile]; Wallerstein 1976a) 9 The definitions of the leading economics departments in Mexico are based on Babb and Harberger, and those of Korea are based on Choi. The specific departments were selected according to English available websites of these departments. ITAM website: http://economics.itam.mx/ ; SNU website: http://econ.snu.ac.kr/eng/main/ (April 2, 2006). 10 Binding together economics and business limits this indicator's contribution, and may also reflect an American orientation towards business studies. 11 For example, it is clear that the numbers provided by ISI-Thompson regarding Germany and France probably do not reflect actual research conducted in these countries: according to these data German and French scholars have published significantly less than their British counterparts in the given period (approximately 1:4 ratios). This could not be interpreted as an indicator of weakness in economic 11 this quantitative data is useful only in relation to countries that we accept from the start as dependent on American economics and much less to relatively autonomous countries in this field. Data for selected relevant countries is provided in Table 1. TABLE 1 Country USA England Canada Australia Israel Taiwan South Korea Brazil Mexico Argentina Chile Thailand Colombia Costa Rica Uruguay Original rank by total number of papers 1995-2005 1 2 3 5 14 18 19 36 37 39 40 48 51 60 67 Total papers 1995-2005 Total citations 1995-2005 64,389 15,467 7,512 4,639 1,766 1,232 1,222 410 335 285 237 78 64 31 24 424,479 70,659 34,179 16,980 9,843 2,648 4,211 1,008 910 351 1008 180 104 63 49 Source: ISI Web of Science / Essential Science Indicators, April 2nd, 2006, http://portal.isiknowledge.com/portal.cgi?DestApp=ESI&Func=Frame Assuming that all countries that appear in the table may be regarded at least as semiperipheral, it is clear that the semiperiphery is not unified and that we can divide it into an upper stratum which contains Israel, Taiwan and South Korea, and lower and middle strata which contains Latin American countries and Thailand. A comparison between Harberger's (1997) account of the progress of economics within different states in Latin America (that is Americanization) and the ISI-Thompson data provided in the table is useful for further analyzing internal stratification between the middle and the lower strata within the semiperiphery. Harberger provides names of academic institutions in seven Latin American states in which "good economics" research and study is carried out, that is in other words American-oriented economics. When comparing the countries named by Harberger to the country ranking research, but also of the essential difference between Anglo-Saxon research in economics and the continental model (see also Kolm 1988). 12 provided by ISI in the field of Business and Economics, we can indeed locate all seven among the 76 countries ranked. What is interesting in the present context is the clear division between four countries that are ranked in the middle, that is between places 36th to 40th, with several hundred papers between 1995 to 2005 (Argentina, Brazil, Mexico and Chile) and three others that are ranked quite low, between the 51st to 67th places, with only a few dozen papers in the given period (Colombia, Uruguay and Costa Rica). On the one hand, the difference between the two groups is remarkable. But on the other hand, both of them share the same essential characteristics, of meaningful academic institutions in the local arena which are highly dependent on American ideational resources, and thus both deserve to be regarded as semiperipheral (Montecinos 1997). As will be further shown, in spite of Israel's high position in economics "performance", especially when defined in American measures, it cannot be regarded as part of the core, rather it exemplifies the higher stratum of the semiperiphery. Israel 1973-1985: a Case of Ideational Semiperiphery So far I have provided data that reflects the contemporary situation in the economics world. In the discussion on Israel, however, I will mainly focus on an earlier period, the 1970s and the early 1980s. During this period Israel suffered a severe economic crisis that was composed of stagnation, high foreign debt and at the end also hyperinflation. The close of this period marks an essential change in Israeli economic policy towards acceptance of the main components of the Washington Consensus, especially fiscal and monetary restraint.12 My hypothesis, that will be examined elsewhere, is that this change is strongly connected to the American character of economics study and research in Israel and that local economists played an important part in pushing for that change. Here I shall focus on the characteristics of Israeli 12 Coats (1997, 351-2) provides a concise description of the Washington Consensus term. 13 economics during that time and on the usefulness of the concept of ideational semiperiphery for capturing its essence.13 First, some words on Israel and its higher education system. Israel is a small country (population 7 million), and until the 1990s, when a new law enabled community colleges to provide academic degrees, it also had a small and condensed higher education system that consisted of only eight universities, none of them private. Only 6 of the universities included economics studies. The budgeting process of universities in Israel was, and still is, very centralized: the lion's share of their income is provided by the government and is allocated by a central body dominated by senior Israeli academics.14 The structural centralization within the higher education system reflects the general centralized or étatist character of the Israeli state as a whole during the 1970s and 1980s (Kleiman 1999; Levi-Faur 1999). Practically, economists' impact on Israeli economic policy took two main forms: a direct one, when an economist was formally or informally appointed as an advisor (e.g. Michael Bruno or Yakir Plessner),15 and an indirect one, when professional economists within the state administration were trained by academic economists. The two main bodies within state bureaucracy that absorbed professional economics and affected economic policy are the Ministry of Finance (especially its Budget Division) and the Bank of Israel (Kleiman 1981; Naveh 1972). The American character of Israeli economics dates back to the early 1950s and the establishment of the Department of Economics at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem (the only Israeli University at that time). The department's founding and establishment was mainly carried out by Don Patinkin, a leading Jewish-American economist who had just immigrated to the new state. Patinkin's role in the Americanization of the department was not necessarily expressed in the content of his teaching. Rather, his main contribution in this direction was connected to the structure of the department, its programs and most important, its promotions 13 Note that Israel during the research period is considered as semiperiphery also from the materialist perspective of world-system analysis (Silver 1990). 14 Council for Higher Education website: http://www.che.org.il 15 See also Maman and Rosenhek (2005) and Keren (1993). 14 system which was based on success in publishing in highly-ranked (American) economics journals (Naveh 1972). Moreover, Patinkin's status enabled him to "send" his students to the best departments of economics in the United States to earn their PhDs (Kleiman 1981; Michaeli 2005). Indeed, Patinkin's contribution in that area cannot be underestimated. Checking the data regarding senior Israeli economists within the two leading departments in 1980, reveals an unequivocal picture: of the 34 relevant economists, only five completed their doctoral dissertations in Israel; almost all the others (except two), earned their PhDs in the US. Note that 78% of them studied in the top six US departments (Hansen 1991).16 I wish to claim that this measure is not only indicative of the process of professional socialization of Israeli economists but also signals its results, even without turning to the specific content of economic research in Israel. Analyzing Israeli economists' performance reveals some very interesting facts, that may make one wonder whether Israeli economics are so Americanized that they should actually be regarded as part of the core. First, Israeli economists published at impressive rates in the most highly-ranked American journals: during the 1970s, 82% of senior academic economists (as defined earlier) published at least one research article in the six highest-ranked journals, with an average of 3.4 papers per economist.17 Their participation in other arenas of American research corresponds with these data. Israeli economists spent most of their sabbaticals in American universities; many of them served as journal editors and were part of American research institutions such as the National Bureau for Economic Research and the RAND 16 The economists included were only those in research tenure track who completed their Ph.D's in 1975 or before (the reason for this time limit relates to the analysis below of their publication characteristics, i.e. "giving" one enough time to publish within the research period). All members of the departments were included, even if they are considered by the colleagues as mathematicians or statisticians. Hansen's data regards the 1980s. The universities included are Chicago, Harvard, MIT, Princeton, Stanford and Yale. 17 The journals included are the American Economic Review, Econometrica, Journal of Political Economy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Review of Economic Studies, Review of Economics and Statistics. All these six journals are research journals that appear in the top-ten in all rankings I survey at the past and present, and specifically at a ranking from the early 1980 which is most relevant for the research period (Hirsch et al. 1984). 15 Corporation. Others took part in Americanized international economic institutions like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund.18 One of the most impressive measures of the achievements of Israeli economists may be found in the "Who's Who in Economics" project that was already mentioned. Comparing the numbers of economists by country reveals that in the first edition Israel was placed 6th, after the US, the UK, Canada, Germany and France. In the last edition, Israel was ranked in 5th place. Indicators that rank institutions place Israeli universities very high worldwide and also in relation to European universities (Hirsch et al. 1984; Kalaitzidakis et al. 2001) There is a worn out phrase in Israel according to which Israel is actually the 51st state of the USA. Indeed, it seems that in our case there is some truth in that phrase. Again, one may even wonder whether Israel is not actually a part of the American economics, i.e. the core, rather than an autonomous locale of economics study. This raises a more general question, that is can we indeed apply a real meaning to local economics? I suggest that local economics should be understood as the interface between academic economic research and the local political context, in the conjunction between claims to universal knowledge and specific policy making. Israeli economics cannot be regarded as part of US economics in this sense, simply because the ideas that are discussed in the economics departments of Israeli universities will impact, directly or indirectly, policy makers in Israel and not in Mississippi or North Dakota. Furthermore, the data we have presented indicate the need to distinguish between research quality, research autonomy and ideational influence. Our indicators undoubtedly reveal high research quality, but within the context of an influenced and dependent research environment. Israeli economics could have been regarded as part of the core in the world of economics if it was not so dependent on American institutions. Also note the fact that Israeli economics were, and still are, actually very small and even negligible in comparison to American economics:19 Israeli papers in the above mentioned journals during the 1970s constitute approximately 2.5% of all papers; Israeli researchers 18 19 This data is based on analyzing Israeli economists' CVs. This claim was also made by two senior Israeli economists with whom I had background talks. 16 were a small minority within the organizations they participated in; and the Israeli economists listed in "Who's Who in Economics" were only 4% of non-American economists, and approximately 2% of the number of American economists. Referring to the stages of international ideational influence defined at the beginning of this paper, it seems that in addition to their participation in the stages of selection and diffusion, Israeli economists also played a marginal part in the innovation stage. But this fact places Israeli economics only in the higher strata within the ideational semiperiphery, and not within the core. How has Israel's semiperipheral stand within the world of economics affected its economic policy? As described above, the significant and influential economics departments in Israeli universities were Americanized quite from the start (one should note that Tel-Aviv University was established by the Hebrew University). But the country's political orientation was alien to the spirit of professional economics that Patinkin and his students promoted. In the 1950s and 1960s the socialist self-perception of the political leaders made them reject the notion that Israel is subject to the universal economic rules that are discussed in the academy (Kleiman 1981; Michaeli 2005). But gradually professional economists who received their economic education within the American-oriented academic system took positions within the relevant government offices, such as the Ministry of Finance and the Bank of Israel, and started to affect economic policy from within (Kleiman 1981). As mentioned earlier, during the 1970s and the beginning of the 1980s the Israeli economy suffered from severe stagflation, along with a huge debt problem that reflected an overarching dependency upon American economic resources. The combination of economic dependency on American financial aid, along with an Americanized economic staff, both within the government and the academy, provided as remarkably strong infrastructure for implementing an economic plan whose roots may be found in the Washington Consensus. As Maman and Rosenhek show, the combined influence of local economists on the one hand and American economists sent by the U.S. government on the other, stood behind the Emergency Economic Stabilization Plan that was introduced in 1985 (Maman and Rosenhak 2005). 17 Discussion: Further Insights on Ideational Semiperiphery Comparing Israel with the two other countries identified as cases of ideational semiperiphery, Mexico and South Korea, is useful for an enhanced understanding of the concept. Whereas Israeli economics, as mentioned above, was brought to life Americanized, in Mexico and South Korea this was not the obvious choice. Mexican economists' conceptions matched those of the ECLA, which stressed that economics and economic policy making should be established locally and cannot be imported (Babb 2001; Montecinos 1997). The initial reference point for Korean economics, on the other hand, was Japanese economics and economists (most of whom were communist-oriented) (Choi 1997; Ikeo 1997). If the Americanization of economics was not inevitable, what made it happen? An important feature common to all three cases is their geopolitical position in relation to the United States, especially during the Cold War. The interests of the US in Mexico are quite obvious, and this was especially true when left-wing powers rose in other Latin American countries; South Korea served as a capitalist-democratic anchor against communist spread in South-East Asia; and in the Middle East the US stood by Israel in competition with the Soviet Union that stood by most Arab states. It seems that the shared characteristics of geopolitical importance and Americanized economics are not accidental. One should also note that Americanization of the economics profession was also dependent on financial investments by the United States and the governments concerned, mainly by allocating scholarships and other means that enabled studies in the US. Thus, the last two points emphasize that ideational processes of influence are connected to materialist processes, and this suggests that there is also a place for materialist analysis. It might even be said that in the end what we have learned is that the engine behind ideational influence was in fact material considerations, and that what we thought to be meaningful ideational influence was actually only a byproduct of other processes, reflecting these processes but actually of no real significance. However I wish to claim, to the contrary, that what we may learn from this comparison is that politics are actually constituted by both ideas and material factors. The Americanization of economics in 18 all three cases was indeed dependent on American interests and on American financial investment, but on the other hand, further American influence, reflected in the liberalization of economic policy, was dependent on common ideational perspective between the semiperipheral state and the United States. . Babb (2001), and Maman and Rosenhek (2005) have discussed combinations of coercive influence and normative or expert influence in cases of changing economic policy (in Israel and Mexico respectively). Babb stressed the importance of experts' impact in understanding the influence of the US on Mexican economic policy via American-oriented Mexican economists. As mentioned above, Maman and Rosenhek claim that in Israel the combined effect of coercive threats and expert pressures has led policy towards economic liberalization. It seems to me that the possibility of expert influence among non-core countries is connected to the location of a country in the ideational semiperiphery, whereas peripheral countries will be mainly influenced by coercive forces like political and economic threats or sanctions. In semiperipheral countries, that are mainly influenced by American hegemony, there is relatively strong initial legitimacy for economic liberalization. The existence of such legitimacy reduces the need to use coercive measures in order to affect policy making. Thus, from an historical perspective we can identify the moments in which ideational influence is a consequence of materialist geopolitical power relations, as well as the times when it serves as an independent force that drives further developments in international relations. 19 Bibliography: Adler, Emanuel, and Peter M. Haas. 1992. Epistemic Communities, World Order, and the Creation of a Reflective Research Program. International Organization 46 (1):367-90 Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. 1986. The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone. Review 10 (1):9-74 Aymard, Maurice. 1985. Nation-States and Interregional Disparities of Development. In Semiperipheral Development : The Politics of Southern Europe in the Twentieth Century, edited by G. Arrighi. Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications Babb, Sarah L. 2001. Managing Mexico : Economists from Nationalism to Neoliberalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press Backhouse, Roger E. 1997. The Changing Character of British Economics. In The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Blaug, Mark. 1986. Who's Who in Economics : A Biographical Dictionary of Major Economists, 1700-1986. 2nd ed. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press Blaug, Mark. 1999. Who's Who in Economics. 3rd ed. Cheltenham, UK ; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Pub. Blaug, Mark, and R. P. Sturges. 1983. Who's Who in Economics : A Biographical Dictionary of Major Economists, 1700-1981. 1st MIT Press ed. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press Blaug, Mark, and Howard R. Vane. 2003. Who's Who in Economics. 4th ed. Cheltenham, UK ; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Pub. Choi, Young Back. 1997. The Americanization of Economics in Korea. In The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Coats, A. W. 1997. The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Frey, Bruno S., and Reiner Eichenberger. 1992. Economics and Economists: A European Perspective. American Economic Review 82 (2):216-20 Frey, Bruno S., and Reiner Eichenberger. 1993. American and European Economics and Economists. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7 (4):185-93 Haas, Peter M. 1992. Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coordination. International Organization 46 (1):1-35 Hansen, W. Lee. 1991. The Education and Training of Economics Doctorates: Major Findings of the Executive Secretary of the American Economic Association's Commission on Graduate Education in Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 29 (3):1054-87 20 Harberger, Arnold C. 1997. Good Economics Comes to Latin America, 1955-95. In The Post1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Hirsch, B. T., R. Austin, J. Brooks, and J. B. Moore. 1984. Economics Departmental Rankings - Comment. American Economic Review 74 (4):822-26 Ikeo, Aiko. 1997. The Internationalization of Economics in Japan. In The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Kalaitzidakis, Pantelis, Theofanis P. Mamuneas, and Thanasis Stengos. 2001. Rankings of Academic Journals and Institutions in Economics. In Economics of Education Review. Nicosia: DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, UNIVERSITY OF CYPRUS. Keren, Michael. 1993. Economists and Economic Policy Making in Israel: The Politics of Expertise in the Stabilization Program. Policy Sciences 26 (4):331-46 Kleiman, Ephraim. 1981. Israel: Economists in a New State. History of Political Economy 13 (3):548-79 Kleiman, Ephraim. 1999. The Political Economy of Israel: Etatism on the Crossroads. In Israel Towards the Year 2000: Society, Politics and Culture, edited by M. Lissak and B. Knei-Paz. Jerusalem: Hebrew University Magnes Press and Eshkol Institute (Hebrew). Kolm, S. C. 1988. Economics in Europe and in the United-States. European Economic Review 32 (1):207-12 Levi-Faur, David. 1999. Warfare, Polity Formation and the Israeli National Policy Patterns. Israel Affairs 5 (2-3):156-68 Maman, Daniel, and Zeev Rosenhak. 2005. The Politics of Institutional Reform: The 'Declaration of Independence' of the Israeli Central Bank. Paper read at Fronties of Sociology: The 37th World Congress of the International Institute of Sociology, July, at Stockholm, Sweden Michaeli, Micha. 2005. Early Days - a Personal Perspective. Jerusalem (Hebrew). http://economics.huji.ac.il/Early%20Days.pdf Montecinos, Veronica. 1997. Economists in Political and Policy Elites in Latin America. In The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Naveh, David. 1972. The Impact of Economists on Economic Policy Making. M.A., Department of Political Science, Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv Portes, R. 1987. Economics in Europe. European Economic Review 31 (6):1329-40 Sandelin, Bo, and Ann Veiderpass. 1997. The Dissolution of the Swedish Tradition. In The Post-1945 Internationalization of Economics, edited by A. W. Coats. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press Silver, Beverly. 1990. The Contradictions of Semiperipheral Success:The Case of Israel. Ramat Efal: Yad Tabenkin (Hebrew). 21 Skocpol, Theda. 1977. Review: Wallerstein's World Capitalist System: A Theoretical and Historical Critique. American Journal of Sociology 82 (5):1075-90 Terlouw, C. P. 1993. The Elusive Semiperiphery: A Critical Examination of the Concept Semiperiphery. International Journal of Comparative Sociology 34 (1-2):87-102 Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1974. The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System: Concepts for Comparative Analysis. Comparative Studies in Society and History 16 (4):387-415 Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1976a. Semi-Peripheral Countries and the Contemporary World Crisis. Theory and Society 3 (4):461-83 Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1976b. A World-System Perspective on the Social Sciences. The British Journal of Sociology 27 (3):343-52 Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1979. The Capitalist World-Economy : Essays, Studies in Modern Capitalism. Cambridge Eng. ; New York: Cambridge University Press Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1984. The Politics of the World-Economy : The States, the Movements, and the Civilizations : Essays. Cambridge Cambridgeshire; New York; Paris: Cambridge University Press; Editions de la Maison des sciences de l'homme Wallerstein, Immanuel. 2004. World-Systems Analysis : An Introduction. Durham: Duke University Press 22 Appendix 1: Who's Who in Economics (2003), place of PhD studies, data by country Country Total # local PhDs # US PhDs # UK PhDs # Other n.a. Kingdom United Canada Australia 64 22 4 50 3 3 10 18 - (50) 1 3 - 1 1 - France Netherlands Belgium Switzerland Germany Central Europe 11 8 2 2 5 28 5 5 2 1 3 16 5 3 1 2 11 1 - - - Italy Spain Cyprus Greece South Europe 6 3 1 2 12 - 3 1 2 6 2 2 1 5 1 1 - Sweden Denmark Finland Scandinavia 6 4 1 11 5 4 1 10 1 1 - - - Hong Kong Japan Korea Singapore Thailand South-East Asia 3 3 2 1 1 10 1 1 3 2 2 1 1 9 - - - Israel 9 4 5 - - - 23