Funding Options Capital Works Professor Chris Guilding of Griffith University presented a session on funding capital works on common property at a recent national conference. These works might include painting, balcony repairs and roof replacement. He looked at the merits and otherwise of three funding alternatives: Special levy Debt funding (bank finance) and Sinking fund (savings). The professor looked at the costs over time of the options and concluded that sinking funds accumulated over many years were for most circumstances the preferred funding option. On the debt funding side, there are now more options and suppliers available. The cost can be high in accord with the risks taken by the financier. He concluded that although one size does not fit all... the sinking fund option appears to rank highest.. We hope you find his research useful. Call our office (08 8333 5200) if your management committee or group wish to discuss funding options. Examining Common Property Capital Expenditure Funding Alternatives Chris Guilding Griffith University 1. Introduction Motivation No academic paper providing analysis of common property capital expenditure funding alternatives. Objectives 1. Identify strata title common property capital expenditure funding alternatives available. 2. Develop a criteria set for appraising relative merits of funding alternatives. 3. Use the criteria to assess the relative merits of the common property capital expenditure funding alternatives. 2. Criteria to appraise merit of funding options Broad, holistic criterion The funding approach should facilitate common property infrastructure being of a quality and functionality that is consistent with the level of physical, social, aesthetic and economic amenity provided by the property infrastructure at the beginning of a strata titled scheme’s life or to a modified level of amenity, as agreed to by the unit owners’ collective. 2. Criteria to appraise merit of funding options Subordinate criteria Cost efficiency Temporal equity (user pays) Financial distress minimisation Speed of fund access in an emergency situation Minimisation of disharmony 3. Alternative ways of funding common property capital expenditure 1. 2. 3. Special levy Debt funding Sinking fund A Working Example 200 units in a complex where $1 million is to be spent on major lift overhaul in 10 years time. Assume sinking fund earns 4% per year in trust account and 5 year loan can be raised at 8% pa. Years 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 0 0 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 Special levy: per unit cash flow in $K 0 0 0 0 0 0 Sinking fund: per unit cash flow in $K 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 Debt funding: per unit cash flow in $K 0 0 0 0 0 0 4. Appraising the relative merits of the 3 funding options a. Owner cost minimisation Special levy Administrative cost is low (few collections) if things go well, but administratively expensive if outstanding levies result. Outstanding levies can trigger accelerated physical deterioration costs if common property capital expenditure has to be deferred. Sinking fund Funds invested in a trust account earn low return relative to: Alternative returns available to wealthy unit owners (stock market). Cost of raising money for less affluent owners living on credit card debt. Debt funding So long as loan can be arranged at a competitive rate, this option appears to be a strong performer on cost minimisation. Tax implications of options need to be considered if an investor owner. 4. Appraising the relative merits of the 3 funding options b. Temporal equity (user pays) Special levy Low on temporal equity as individual may sell a unit 5 years into life of scheme and pay nothing toward common property deterioration for this period, as rectification work may not start until 6th year. Debt funding Initially low on temporal equity for same reason as above. At end of honeymoon period, degree of temporal inequity will lessen as capital expenditures and resulting loan servicing costs are spread evenly over time. Sinking fund Due to owner payment smoothing across time, the sinking fund approach achieves high temporal equity. 4. Appraising the relative merits of the 3 funding options c. Financial distress minimisation Special levy Special levies are not conducive to conditioning lot owners to anticipate the amount and timing of all of their property ownership expenses. Highest association with unanticipated levies, therefore high propensity for triggering financial distress. Debt funding At end of ‘honeymoon period’, first debt funding levies can be expected to trigger some financial distress (albeit lower than for special levy). Sinking fund Payment smoothing effect results in low propensity to trigger financial distress. 4. Appraising the relative merits of the 3 funding options d. Speed of access in an emergency situation Special levy Delays in agreeing to raise the special levy and then longer delays in collecting the special levy from all lot owners can be expected. Debt funding Likely to be a faster source of funding, although a series of steps will need to be taken prior to the funds being available. Sinking fund Fastest in terms of accessibility as the funds are already raised and available in an account. Practicalities surrounding whether the fund can be drawn on for non-forecast expenditure need to be recognised, however. 4. Appraising the relative merits of the 3 funding options e. Inter-owner disharmony minimisation Special levy The immediate cash flow implications for unit owners resulting from voting on a motion to raise a special levy signifies a high propensity to fractionalise owner groups within a scheme. This fractionalisation will likely be exacerbated if the special levy triggers a number of overdue accounts that delay capital expenditure. Debt funding The ‘moderate’ smoothing effect achieved by debt funding signifies a moderate propensity to trigger inter-owner disharmony. Sinking fund The high smoothing effect achieved by SF signifies a low propensity to trigger inter-owner disharmony. SF levies would condition owners to expect common property expenditure, thereby lessening disharmony arising around expenditure decision process. 5. Conclusion 1. Where sinking funds are invested in low return accounts (trust accounts) and if a loan can be arranged at a competitive interest rate, the debt funding option may be the most cost effective common property funding source. 2. At a general level of abstraction, the sinking fund option appears to rank highest on the other 4 criteria. 3. However, consistent with many facets of strata titled property management, it appears misguided to expect a “one size fits all” policy to satisfy the particular needs of all strata titled properties. 5. Conclusion A special levy approach may well be optimal in a very small complex with low per unit common property expenditure. A debt funding approach may well be optimal for a small complex with readily visible common property in a wealthy rental neighbourhood and a tax regime benign to loan cost servicing tax deductibility. The sinking fund approach, based on a professionally prepared common property capital expenditure budget, likely to be optimal in a large complex managing the organisational challenge of getting 2,000 owners to commit to common property capital expenditure, especially where infrastructure is expensive, technologically complex or not readily observable. Conclusion In further theoretical examinations of this nature it would be helpful to: 1. Identify the relative weightings that should be attached to the five criteria. 2. Determine what strata scheme specific factors affect the relative weightings attached to the five criteria. Possible factors include: Size of the scheme $ value of per lot common property capital expenditure Observability of common property status for owners