Cost of Capital Determination - Telecommunications Regulatory

advertisement

Cost of Capital

Determination

3 November 2009

Ref: MCD/11/09/090

Purpose: To set the cost of capital to be used in subsequent calculations for the costs of provision of telecommunications services in the Kingdom of

Bahrain.

DETERMINATION

HAVING REGARD TO THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS LAW, ALL

ADMISSIBLE EVIDENCE AND SUBMISSIONS RECEIVED BY THE

TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATORY AUTHORITY, THE ANNEX TO

THIS DETERMINATION WHICH SETS THE REASONING FOR THIS

DETERMINATION, THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS REGULATORY

AUTHORITY HEREBY MAKES THE FOLLOWING DETERMINATION:

1. The value for the nominal cost of capital for the Bahrain

Telecommunications Company B.S.C (“Batelco”) and MTC-Vodafone

Bahrain B.S.C. (“Zain”) is 9.5%.

2. This Determination shall take effect from its date of issue.

3. This Determination shall be reviewed after a two-year period has elapsed from its date of issue, unless circumstances justify otherwise.

For the Telecommunications Regulatory Authority

Alan Horne

General Director

3 November 2009

- 2 -

Reasoning for the Cost of Capital Determination

Table of contents

Executive Summary ................................................................................................ 5

Introduction .............................................................................................................. 6

Application of the CAPM to the cost of capital ........................................................ 9

Capital structure .................................................................................................... 15

Risk-free rate ......................................................................................................... 23

Country risk premium ............................................................................................ 39

Equity risk premium ............................................................................................... 46

Equity beta ............................................................................................................. 57

Cost of capital estimates ....................................................................................... 71

Appendix 1: Cost of debt ....................................................................................... 75

Appendix 2: Regulatory precedents for the cost of capital ................................... 76

Appendix 3: Equity beta cluster analysis dendrograms ........................................ 78

Appendix 4: Equity beta estimates and gearing for comparator telecommunications companies ............................................................................ 81

- 3 -

List of acronyms

IMF

IV

IPVPN

KWD

LIBOR

MM

MTR

NYSE

PPP

RFR

S&P

TRA

USD

VPN

WACC

APV

AMEX

AW

BD

BFV

Bp

CAPEX

CAPM

DMS

EBITDA

ERP

EV

FTSE adjusted present value

American Stock Exchange all world

Bahraini dinar

Bloomberg Fair Value basis points capital expenditure capital asset pricing model

Dimson, Marsh and Staunton earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation equity risk premium enterprise value

Financial Times Stock Exchange

International Monetary Fund implied volatility

Internet Protocol virtual private network

Kuwaiti dinar

London Interbank Offered Rate

Modigliani–Miller mobile termination rate

New York Stock Exchange purchasing power parity

Risk-free rate

Standard & Poor’s

Telecommunications Regulatory Authority of the Kingdom of Bahrain

United States dollar virtual private network weighted average cost of capital

- 4 -

Executive Summary

a. The objective of the Determination is to set the appropriate level of the cost of capital for regulated telecommunications services in the Kingdom of Bahrain. TRA proposes a nominal cost of capital of 9.5% for both fixed and mobile telecommunications services regulated in Bahrain. This Determination shall be effective for two years from its date of issue, unless circumstances justify otherwise. b. This estimate lies within the upper halves of the estimated ranges, based on a rigorous analysis of the latest economic and capital market data. It represents the top of the range of the base case scenario. The point estimate is also consistent with relevant regulatory precedents. c. TRA is of the view that at this stage there is no sufficient, robust evidence to support the introduction of a differential in the cost of capital estimates between different regulated business activities. In particular, there is no robust evidence to conclude that the level of systematic risk differs between the relevant fixed and mobile services. Therefore, TRA proposes to set a single cost of capital for all regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain. d. For both conceptual and practical reasons, TRA is of the view that it is appropriate to estimate the cost of capital from the perspective of an international investor who holds a diversified portfolio of investments. The alternative approach also considered by TRA (which estimates the rate of return from the perspective of the local, potentially less diversified, investor using recent data from the local capital markets) produces a similar estimate. e. The estimates are based on a notional, equity-only capital structure, which ensures that the regulated companies retain discretion to choose their optimal capital structures. Since there are limited incentives for companies in Bahrain to increase leverage (ie, there is no corporate taxation), TRA sees limited risk of this approach overstating the true, lower cost of capital that companies might be able to achieve by increasing leverage. f. TRA’s estimate also takes into account the current, Bahrain-specific characteristics, as well as the global market characteristics that might affect the expected rate of return, including recent volatility in capital markets, the relative illiquidity of the local stock market, and the country risk for which an international investor might expect compensation. Specific premia for these factors are incorporated into the cost of capital estimates (where relevant) in line with the conservative approach to the cost of capital estimation adopted by TRA to ensure that investments by the regulated companies are financeable.

- 5 -

Introduction

1. This Determination sets out TRA’s approach to estimating the cost of capital and the evidence used to estimate both a range and a point estimate.

1

The cost of capital is an essential input to calculate the cost of regulated telecommunications services, and therefore has direct implications for the regulated companies, consumers and other stakeholders.

2. TRA wishes to emphasise that this Determination is without prejudice to the ongoing consultation on mobile termination rates (“MTRs”) which may result in the regulation of Zain’s MTRs.

2

Consultation process

3. TRA issued for consultation a Draft Determination on the cost of capital (the “Draft

Determination”) on 20 July 2009 (Ref. MCD/07/09/049).

4. TRA received responses from: Bahrain Telecommunications Company B.S.C.

(“Batelco”); Lightspeed Communications W.L.L. (“Lightspeed”); and MTC-Vodafone

Bahrain B.S.C. (“Zain”).

5. For clarity purposes, this Annex largely reproduces the text included in the Draft

Determination, with minor amendments, before summarising and addressing the comments received on the Draft Determination. The Determination follows the same structure as the Draft Determination and the order of questions therein.

Purpose of the Determination

6. The objective of the Determination is to set the appropriate level of the nominal cost of capital and therefore the rate of return applicable for regulated telecommunications services in the Kingdom of Bahrain. It will apply to Batelco and, without prejudice to the ongoing consultation on MTRs, to Zain for regulatory purposes.

7. The estimated cost of capital will be an input into companies’ regulatory accounts and the bottom-up cost models that TRA intends to develop in 2009 and 2010.

Consequently, the allowed rate of return will be used to determine the prices that

Batelco and Zain can charge for services supplied in markets in which they have significant market power and/or are dominant. Given the current environment and the expected timeline for the implementation of bottom-up cost models, TRA considers that setting the cost of capital for a period of two years is appropriate.

8. For this Determination, the cost of capital is estimated for a notional telecommunications company in Bahrain providing a range of telecommunications services. This is based on an empirical analysis of underlying risk and other parameters of the cost of capital, detailed below. This approach is also consistent with TRA’s position expressed in the Draft Statement on MTRs that there is no longer any compelling reason for asymmetric MTRs between Batelco and Zain.

3

                                                       

1

2

This document is based on analysis by Oxera Consulting Ltd.

TRA (2008), “Dominance Designation for Termination Services on Individual Mobile Networks”, Draft

Determination, and “The Regulation of Mobile Termination Services”, Draft Statement, November

25th.

3

TRA (2008), “The Regulation of Mobile Termination Services”, Draft Statement, November 25th.

- 6 -

Background to this Determination

9. Batelco provides a wide range of fixed-line and mobile telecommunications services to customers in Bahrain. Zain is the other current provider of mobile services in

Bahrain and also offers fixed wireless services. A third mobile licence was awarded to Saudi Telecom Company (“STC”) in March 2009. Only Batelco is currently subject to price regulation. Zain MTRs will, without prejudice to the completion of the ongoing consultation on MTRs, be subject to price regulation for termination services on its mobile network.

10. TRA has previously estimated the cost of capital for Batelco in 2003 and 2005.

4 A review of these two determinations suggests that some elements of the approaches adopted previously require revision in order for the estimate to be based on appropriate empirical techniques and for the analysis to be more in line with the best practice on cost of capital estimation.

11. The parameters of the cost of capital are not static and may vary over time.

Consequently, they need to be updated periodically. Interest rates around the world have decreased substantially since the start of the global financial turmoil in August

2007. Risk premiums have been volatile, and the riskiness of companies and industries relative to the overall equity market may have changed. The new evidence and up-to-date market information need to be reflected in the latest estimates.

12. Furthermore, the Bahraini telecommunications market has seen Zain’s market share grow rapidly, culminating in the Draft Statement on the regulation of MTRs and Draft

Dominance Determination, which concluded that both Batelco and Zain are dominant for termination services on their mobile networks. The upcoming cost of capital determination will therefore be used, for the first time and without prejudice to the ongoing consultation on MTRs, to set the cost of capital to regulate Zain’s

MTRs.

13. This new Determination takes the changed economic environment into account when setting the cost of capital.

Base-case scenario: the international investor

14. The cost of capital is the weighted average of different forms of capital, where different sources of capital are used—in particular, the costs of debt and equity. In the context of Bahrain, the cost of equity is the main driver of the weighted average cost of capital (“WACC”) because there are limited tax incentives associated with debt financing, and domestic operators exhibit relatively low levels of gearing.

15. The WACC estimate may be sensitive to assumptions about the degree to which investors are globally diversified. For the reasons outlined below, TRA believes that the appropriate base-case assumption is to consider the required rate of return to an international investor that holds a globally diversified investment portfolio, in line with corporate finance theory. There are a number of reasons for this; some of the key conceptual ones are listed below.

                                                       

4

See TRA Determination of 20 November 2005 (available at: http://www.tra.org.bh/en/pdf/Batelco_WACC_Determination_final_formattedd.pdf), and Determination of 9 August 2003 (available at: http://www.tra.org.bh/en/pdf/Batelco_Cost_of_Capital_ERU_DE_004_v1.0_%20PDF.pdf).

- 7 -

Portfolio theory suggests that since risks are less than perfectly correlated across countries, investors can reduce the total risk of their portfolios by internationally diversifying their investments.

The Bahraini market is likely to account for only a proportion of large investors’ investment portfolios, and hence is unlikely to be considered separately from other Middle Eastern or other markets when these investors make investment and asset allocation decisions.

16. There are also a number of reasons related to the empirical estimation of parameters of the cost of capital that support this base-case assumption, including the following.

Potential problems with the robustness of pricing signals might mean that the local Bahraini capital markets do not provide robust estimates of the cost of capital parameters.

The available Bahraini benchmarks for the risk-free rate might not provide accurate estimates given the limited activity in the Bahraini government bond market.

There is insufficient data to provide robust estimates of the equity risk premium

(“ERP”) for Bahrain.

17. However, given that the regulated activities of Batelco and Zain take place in

Bahrain, the evidence based on local market benchmarks is also taken into consideration. This is used to estimate the cost of capital under an alternative scenario based on an investor that holds a less internationally diversified investment portfolio. This estimate is used as a cross-check on the results under the base case.

- 8 -

Application of the CAPM to the cost of capital

18. The cost of capital is a key value driver for a capital-intensive, regulated business since it sets the allowed return on invested capital. It represents the weighted average return across the components of a company’s capital structure.

19. A key parameter of the WACC is the cost of equity. As this is not directly observable, a number of models and approaches can be used to estimate it.

Industry practitioners and regulators commonly use the capital asset pricing model

(“CAPM”) in setting the cost of capital for regulated entities.

5

20. This Determination estimates the cost of capital from the perspective of an investor with an internationally diversified portfolio of assets. Results under the base case are checked against an alternative scenario, in which it is assumed that investors hold less diversified portfolios, and parameters are estimated using data from

Bahraini capital markets.

21. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• the conceptual issues associated with the assessment of the cost of capital are summarised;

• the models and approaches that can be used to estimate the cost of equity are described, and the CAPM is presented;

• the approach to checking the sensitivity of results to the assumption that investors hold internationally diversified portfolios is outlined.

Conceptual issues

22. The cost of capital is the expected rate of return on the capital invested in a firm, which compensates the providers of capital for both the time value of money and the underlying risk of the business. It depends on the firm’s risk characteristics, the market in which it operates, and the current situation in capital markets.

23. The WACC represents the average return across the different components of a company’s capital structure, weighted by the proportion of each component in the overall capital structure of the firm. It represents the cost to a firm of raising funds to finance existing operations and/or to undertake new investment.

24. Investors need to recover efficient investment costs—referred to as the return “of” the capital invested—along with the expected return on investment—the return “on” capital. In a regulatory context, the return of the invested capital is remunerated through the allowed depreciation charge, whereas the return on the invested capital is remunerated by applying the WACC to the company’s invested capital.

25. The regulatory WACC is a key value driver for a capital-intensive regulated business. Adjustments to the WACC have a direct impact on the cost base of operators and allowed rates of regulated services; hence, setting a WACC commensurate with a firm’s underlying business risks is essential if the firm is to be

                                                       

5

See, for example, Ofcom (2008), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach – second consultation”,

December 5th; ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163; Competition

Commission (2008), “Stansted Airport Ltd, Q5 Price control review—Presented to the Civil Aviation

Authority”, October 23rd; Competition Commission (2007), “Report on the economic regulation of

Heathrow and Gatwick Airports”, September 28th; Commerce Commission of New Zealand (2005),

“Determination on the application for pricing review for designated interconnection services”, April

11th.

- 9 -

able to finance its functions without making excessive profits, which would be detrimental to consumers.

26. Determination of the WACC requires estimation of each of the different components of a company’s capital structure. However, for simplicity, these are typically limited to the cost of debt and the cost of equity (weighted by the market values of debt and equity respectively), or just the cost of equity, which is equivalent to the overall cost of capital in the absence of debt.

27. The WACC can be expressed on a different basis depending on the treatment of corporate taxation. The vanilla WACC (ie, post-tax cost of equity, pre-tax cost of debt) represents the allowed rate of return excluding tax allowances. However, since corporate taxes are not applicable to the activities of Batelco and Zain in

Bahrain, pre-tax WACC that includes tax allowances will be equal to the vanilla (and post-tax) WACC, and can be expressed as:

6

( r d

× g )

+ r e

×

( 1

− g ) where g is gearing, r d

is the cost of debt, and r e

is the cost of equity.

Models for the cost of equity

The Draft Determination

28. In general, the costs of debt and equity can be measured based on past and/or current data. Although the required return to equity is not directly observable, a number of asset pricing models can be used to estimate the cost of equity, including:

the

• arbitrage pricing and multi-factor models;

• proxies.

29. The CAPM relates the cost of equity of a particular firm to its exposure to systematic, or non-diversifiable, equity market risk. Systematic risk relates to the possibility that returns may deviate from expected returns in correlation with the market returns. The CAPM asserts that investors do not need compensation for non-systematic risk because it can be eliminated through portfolio diversification.

The level of exposure is expressed as a single beta factor describing the correlation between returns on the firm’s equity and the overall equity market. The CAPM is commonly used by industry practitioners and regulators in setting the cost of capital for regulated entities, indicating that it is widely considered as the model of choice when estimating the cost of equity.

7

                                                       

6

The corporate tax rate does not take into account personal taxation. In practice, investors do face personal taxation, but this is not taken into account in the cost of capital to corporations.

7

See, for example, Ofcom (2008), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach – second consultation”,

December 5th; ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163; Competition

Commission (2008), “Stansted Airport Ltd, Q5 Price control review—Presented to the Civil Aviation

Authority”, October 23rd; Competition Commission (2007), “Report on the economic regulation of

Heathrow and Gatwick Airports”, September 28th; Commerce Commission of New Zealand (2005),

“Determination on the application for pricing review for designated interconnection services”, April

11th, and (2005), “Draft Guidelines on the Commerce Commission’s Approach to Estimating the Cost of Capital”, October.

- 10 -

30. Arbitrage pricing and multi-factor models, such as the Fama–French three-factor model or Cahart’s four-factor model, represent alternatives to the CAPM.

8

Robust estimates of the cost of capital derived from multi-factor models depend on the availability of a considerable amount of data to estimate both the premiums for, and individual companies’ exposure to, the specified risk factors. In the case of Bahrain, there appears to be no sufficient market data to estimate these risk factors robustly.

This suggests that the application of models other than CAPM is unlikely to offer additional reliable insight into required returns. These empirical models are also often criticised for lacking strong theoretical foundations.

31. Direct proxies, such as observed yields on corporate debt, might also be used in the cost of capital estimation. Given the seniority of debt over equity in a company’s capital structure, the additional risk to which equity investors are exposed implies that the upper bound of the yield on corporate debt could be seen as a lower bound to the cost of equity. The rates of return targeted by equity investors might also be used as a proxy for the cost of equity. However, there are typically few directly observable proxies that do not carry biases and can be independently verified.

32. In the absence of adequate data to implement the alternative models and having regards to the strong theoretical foundations of the CAPM and its widespread use by regulators and practitioners TRA has used the CAPM to estimate the cost of equity in line with international regulatory practice.

Responses to the Draft Determination

33. In its submission, Batelco states that “We agree with TRA that the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) is the most appropriate framework for calculating the cost of equity”.

9

34. The other respondents did not express a view on the appropriate model for calculating the cost of equity.

TRA analysis and conclusion

35. TRA is of the view that, for the reasons set out in the Draft Determination, the

CAPM is the appropriate framework for calculating the cost of equity in this context.

The capital asset pricing model

36. The required return to equity is often estimated using the CAPM where the required return on a given asset is determined by the relative contribution of that asset’s risk to the risk of the overall market portfolio. A central principle of this model is that investors hold a broad portfolio of assets so that the idiosyncratic risk of any single asset is diversified away, leaving only the systematic risk component. Therefore, only the systematic risk component is expected to be remunerated through the return on the market portfolio.

37. The degree to which the expected return to any one specific asset is correlated with the expected return on the market for all assets determines investors’ required returns on a forward-looking basis.

                                                       

8

Fama, E. and French, K. (1992), “The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns”, Journal of Finance ,

47 :2, June; Cahart, M. (1997), “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance”, Journal of Finance , 52 ,

57–82.

9

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 8.

- 11 -

38. According to the CAPM, the required return to an asset is estimated as follows: risk-free rate + equity beta of the asset

×

ERP where:

• equity beta is the risk of the asset relative to the market, estimated as:

β =

Cov

(

R

Var

, R e

( ) m

) where:

R e is the return on the asset, R m is the return on the market portfolio (proxied by a broad equity market index), and Var(R m

) is the variance of the market portfolio;

ERP is estimated as the excess return on the market portfolio over the risk-free rate (r m

– r f

).

39. Figure 1 presents a stylised illustration of the relationship between the individual cost of capital parameters under the CAPM.

Figure 1 Parameters of the weighted average cost of capital

Weighted average cost of capital under CAPM

Cost of equity Equity/total value Debt/total value Cost of debt

‘Risk-free’ rate

Country risk premium

Equity risk premium

Equity beta

Asset beta

Debt beta

Debt risk premium

Source: TRA.

40. Some of the main parameters in the WACC—gearing, the debt risk premium and asset beta—are specific to the activity or company being assessed. The other parameters—the risk-free rate and the ERP—are generic to all applications of the

CAPM at any given time.

Base-case and alternative scenarios for the cost of capital

The Draft Determination

41. The CAPM suggests that investors can diversify exposure to idiosyncratic risks by investing in a global portfolio of securities. This is optimal because, by diversifying, investors reduce risk. In practice, it is not always the case that all investors hold fully diversified investment portfolios. For example, investors sometimes exhibit a preference for domestic equities (termed the “home-bias puzzle”), whereby

- 12 -

investments outside the home country are held in a lower proportion than would be the case in a market value-weighted portfolio.

10

42. Although the home-bias puzzle might indicate that investors have preferences for investments that are located geographically near to their home market, international capital markets are closely interlinked and global investors have access to capital markets across the world. Improved information flows and global links across economies facilitate cross-country diversification. Nevertheless, to the extent that variations across markets in expected inflation, country risk and liquidity could be a significant factor for the cost of capital, these factors have been controlled for in this

Determination where relevant.

43. Therefore, in this Determination, TRA estimates the cost of capital under a basecase scenario from the perspective of an international, globally diversified investor.

This is the preferred scenario because it assumes that investors are both rational and diversify their investments (see also paragraphs 15-16).

44. An alternative scenario is also considered as a cross-check on the estimates from the base case. In this alternative scenario, the cost of capital is estimated from the perspective of a less diversified, “domestic” investor. Provided that the difference between the results under the two scenarios is not material, TRA considers the results estimated under the base case to be more robust and conceptually preferable.

Responses to the Draft Determination

45. While Batelco agreed that it is appropriate to consider the cost of capital from both local and worldwide market portfolio perspectives, Batelco stated that it is

“inappropriate to consider the cost of capital primarily from an international perspective as the typical marginal investor in Batelco is clearly not globally diversified”.

11

Batelco believed that the typical investor in Batelco is likely to lie

“somewhere between the pure global and domestic categories and is likely to be more comparable to a domestic investor”.

12

46. Batelco also noted that “it is standard practice to use the domestic portfolio as the benchmark in cost of equity calculation.”

13

47. The other respondents did not express a view on TRA’s approach to applying the

CAPM in an international context.

TRA analysis and conclusion

48. Batelco’s assertion that TRA has considered the cost of capital primarily from an international perspective does not accurately reflect TRA’s position in the Draft

Determination. TRA has estimated the cost of capital from both an international and a domestic perspective. While TRA regards the results estimated under the base case to be more robust, the overall value proposed for the WACC has been set above the midpoints of both scenarios.

11

12

13

                                                       

10

French, K. and Poterba, J. (1991), “Investor diversification and international equity markets”, American

Economic Review, 81 , 222–26.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 22.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 22.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 22.

- 13 -

49. While a domestic equity market index has often been used in regulatory determinations as the reference portfolio for estimating equity betas in jurisdictions with mature equity markets, TRA does not consider this approach to be sufficient in the current context.

50. The analysis of equity betas where companies comprise a relatively large proportion of the total value of the domestic equity market index, and where the domestic market is significantly less liquid than mature equity markets, produces less robust estimates. TRA has therefore supplemented the analysis based on a domestic market portfolio with analysis based on an international portfolio, consistent with the overall approach of assessing both the domestic and international investor perspectives. This approach appears to be consistent with Batelco’s belief that the typical investor in Batelco is neither a pure international nor a pure domestic investor.

51. The approach followed by TRA also enables a more robust empirical estimation of the parameters of the cost of capital.

52. Having considered the views of respondents, TRA remains of the view that it is appropriate to estimate the cost of capital under both a base-case scenario from the perspective of an international, globally diversified investor, and an alternative scenario from the perspective of a less diversified, domestic investor.

- 14 -

Capital structure

53. The capital structure of a company describes the relative proportions of different types of financial security in the overall financing of a company. In the context of cost of capital analysis, capital structure is usually focused on the relative proportions of debt and equity. Leverage, or gearing, is the ratio of debt to total capital.

54. The optimal capital structure for a company is determined by a number of factors, including corporate taxation rates and the costs of financial distress. In general, companies would be expected to target an optimal capital structure that maximises the value of the company, while minimising the associated cost of capital, although other considerations might cause the actual and optimal capital structures of a company to differ.

55. Instead of using the actual level of gearing, regulators typically adopt a level of gearing that is reflective of a notional, reasonably efficiently financed company. This approach allows the regulated company greater discretion to choose its optimal capital structure. Adopting a notional capital structure also ensures consistent treatment across regulated companies.

56. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• the drivers of optimal capital structure are summarised;

Batelco and Zain’s actual capital structures are analysed, and the extent to which the current capital structures are likely to represent the efficient forwardlooking structures is assessed;

• the concept of a notional capital structure in the regulatory context is discussed;

• the approach proposed by TRA to capital structure is presented.

Drivers of optimal capital structure

57. The conceptually most transparent approach to estimating the appropriate rate of return is to start by assuming an equity-only capital structure.

14

Indeed, Modigliani and Miller (MM) argued that a firm’s value—and the associated cost of capital—are independent of the underlying capital structure, and hence there is no single, optimal capital structure.

15

Figure 2 shows that, under the MM framework, an increase in leverage or gearing raises the cost of equity and the cost of debt, as equity and debt become more risky, leaving the overall WACC unchanged since the increased cost of both debt and equity offsets the effect of using debt to replace the relatively more expensive equity.

16

                                                       

14

Brealey, R. and Myers, S. (1991), Principles of Corporate Finance , 4th edition, chapter 19.

15

Modigliani, F. and Miller, M. (1958), “The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment”, American Economic Review, 48 :3, 261–97.

16

The figure assumes a positive cost of financial distress—ie, as gearing increases, the cost of debt increases owing to the higher probability of financial distress.

- 15 -

Figure 2 Cost of capital under changes in leverage

Rate of return

MM cost of equity

MM cost of capital

MM cost of debt

Leverage

Source: TRA.

58. Modigliani and Miller’s invariance proposition relies on a set of assumptions, including no corporate taxes. The strength of the MM analysis is that these assumptions highlight the factors that might affect the sensitivity of the cost of capital to leverage. For example, relaxing the “no taxes” assumption provides incentives (in jurisdictions where debt interest payments are tax-deductible) to issue more debt. If there are limited costs associated with financial distress, the result would be that the cost of capital can be lowered with increases in leverage. In such a situation, the firm might be incentivised to adopt a capital structure with a substantial amount of debt in order to reduce its cost of capital.

59. Since it is unrealistic to assume that the costs of financial distress are negligible, the optimal financing structure in the presence of both a positive corporate tax rate and the costs of financial distress might lie somewhere between equity-only and debtonly financing.

60. The MM analysis suggests that if an optimal capital structure exists, it will depend on the degree to which the MM assumptions do not hold in each particular case. In general, firms would be expected to make decisions about leverage by balancing the expected benefits and costs associated with increased leverage—for example, the benefit of tax-deductibility of interest against the cost associated with increased probability of financial distress.

61. These decisions about leverage can be informed by delineating the cash-flow effects of financing choices, and hence calculating the adjusted present value

(“APV”) of planned investments. An alternative approach is to incorporate the effects of financing decisions in a single step by adjusting the WACC that is used to discount cash flows.

62. The implication for regulation is that an estimate of the WACC based on an equityonly capital structure can be combined with separate adjustments to the allowed revenue, if required, to pass on to consumers any specific benefits associated with a particular capital structure, if relevant and deemed appropriate. Although an equity-only capital structure used for cost of capital estimation on a ‘pre-tax basis’

(ie, including allowance for tax payments in the WACC) would be likely to

- 16 -

overestimate the required rate of return in the presence of corporate taxation, this consideration is not applicable to Bahrain.

63. In the context of companies based in Bahrain, given that there are no corporate taxes, the benefits of a leveraged capital structure might be low, and therefore an equity-only capital structure represents the most transparent and conceptually appropriate basis for estimating the cost of capital. The sensitivity of results to an equity-only capital structure is checked in Appendix 1, where a gearing level of 20% is assumed.

Actual capital structures of Batelco and Zain

64. The actual capital structures of the regulated companies may provide an indication of the optimal capital structure for these companies, assuming that financial managers take decisions about capital structure aimed to maximise value.

65. The companies’ actual capital structures may differ from what is optimal for reasons other than taxation and the costs of financial distress. For example, a company may choose to increase gearing as a means of reducing free cash flows and enforcing discipline on managers. Alternatively, it may choose to raise debt instead of equity to avoid the risk of sending a negative signal to the market about its earnings prospects—the “pecking-order” theory of financial structure.

66. Furthermore, the capital structure is likely to be set from the perspective of the overall group, which may deviate from the optimal structure for constituent companies within the group, and in particular for the regulated activities in Bahrain.

67. As the primary location of Batelco’s business activities is in Bahrain, its actual capital structure would be expected to be similar to the capital structure of a notional telecommunications company operating in Bahrain. Figure 3 illustrates Batelco’s balance sheet as at 2008. Although debt (both long- and short-term) is recorded on the balance sheet, the positive net working capital (cash and equivalents less shortterm debt) offsets the long-term debt. This implies that net debt—and hence gearing for Batelco—were zero at that time.

- 17 -

Figure 3 Composition of Batelco’s balance sheet (Bahraini dinar, million)

800

700

600

Cash

BD 154m

Non-cash current assets

BD 76m

Long-term debt BD 39m

Current liabilities

BD 201m

500

400

300

200

100

Non-current assets

BD 485m

Equity

BD 475m

0

Assets

Note: The breakdown is shown on the basis of 2008 accounts.

Source: Annual report.

Liabilities

68. Figure 4 plots Batelco’s market value of equity and gearing over time. Given that net debt has been zero since 2004, gearing has also been zero. This level of gearing might be expected in view of the absence of corporate taxes in Bahrain (the primary location of Batelco’s regulated business operations), which means that there are no expected tax benefits from issuing debt for firms pre-dominantly operating in

Bahrain (or other tax-free zones).

17

                                                       

17

A firm operating under such circumstances might still issue debt as a disciplining tool on management or because of transaction costs and liquidity considerations.

- 18 -

Figure 4 Estimates of market value of equity and gearing for Batelco

1,600 100%

1,400

1,200

1,000

800

60%

50%

600

40%

30%

400

200

20%

10%

0

Q1

2004

Q2

2004

Q3

2004

Q4

2004

Q1

2005

Q2

2005

Q3

2005

Q4

2005

Q1

2006

Q2

2006

Q3

2006

Q4

2006

Q1

2007

Q2

2007

Q3

2007

Q4

2007

Q1

2008

Q2

2008

Q3

2008

Q4

2008

0%

90%

80%

70%

Total market value (LHS) Gearing (RHS)

Note: Net debt = short-term + long-term borrowings – cash and equivalents – marketable securities – collaterals. Gearing is estimated as the ratio between net debt and the sum of net debt and the market value of equity.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

69. Given that Bahrain is the primary location of Batelco’s activities, the company’s actual capital structure may be a good proxy for the optimal capital structure of a notional telecommunications company operating in Bahrain.

70. In contrast, Bahrain is not the primary location for Zain’s business activities—it derives only 3% of its revenue from Bahrain.

18

Therefore, Zain’s actual capital structure would not be expected to be a reliable indication of the optimal capital structure for a notional telecommunications company operating in Bahrain.

71. Figure 5 illustrates Zain’s balance sheet as of 2008. The proportions of long- and short-term debt in the balance sheet, combined with negative net working capital, imply positive net debt and gearing for Zain.

                                                       

18

Zain (2008), “Earnings release – 2008 Q4”.

- 19 -

Figure 5 Composition of balance sheet of Zain (Kuwaiti dinar, million)

6,000

5,000

Cash KD 368m

Non-cash current assets

KD 421m

Long-term debt

KD 1,671m

4,000

Current liabilities

KD 1,140m

3,000

Non-current assets

KD 4,666m

2,000

Equity

KD 2,644m

1,000

0

Assets

Note: The breakdown is shown on the basis of 2008 accounts.

Source: Annual report.

Liabilities

72. Figure 6 shows the trend in market value of equity, net debt and gearing over time for Zain. One explanation for the trend of increasing gearing may be that this represents a relatively short-term deviation from the optimal long-term capital structure. This might arise, for example, if debt finance is perceived to be a more flexible means of funding Zain’s recent acquisitions and international expansion than equity issuance.

73. A combination of Zain’s relatively high cash flow and the requirement that several

Middle Eastern governments have stipulated for initial public offerings might be expected to lead to a reversal in the trend towards increased gearing, once the rate of expansion slows in the longer term.

19

                                                       

19

Several Middle Eastern governments have required initial public offerings as part of the award of mobile licences.

- 20 -

Figure 6 Estimates of Zain’s market value of equity, net debt and gearing

(Kuwaiti dinar, million)

14,000 40%

35%

12,000

30%

10,000

25%

8,000

20%

6,000

15%

4,000

10%

2,000

5%

0

Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1

2004 2004 2004 2004 2005

Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2

2005 2005 2005 2006 2006

Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3

2006 2006 2007 2007 2007

Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1

2007 2008 2008 2008 2008 2009

0%

Total market value (LHS) Net debt (LHS) Gearing (RHS)

Note: Net debt = short-term + long-term borrowings – cash and equivalents – marketable securities – collaterals. Gearing is estimated as the ratio between net debt and the sum of net debt and the market value of equity.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

74. Since Bahrain accounts for a very small proportion of Zain’s operations, and Zain’s current level of gearing may not be indicative of the longer-term level that would be expected for a mobile telecommunications company operating in Bahrain given the tax environment, it is unlikely to provide an appropriate basis to determine the level of gearing for this Determination.

75. The actual capital structure of Batelco suggests that low or zero gearing is appropriate for a company operating in Bahrain. The actual capital structure of

Batelco provides a cross-check on the assumption that the optimal capital structure is close to zero gearing.

Capital structure in the regulatory context

76. Regulators generally set the cost of capital for regulated entities by using a notional gearing assumption—ie, the level of gearing that might be characteristic of a reasonably financed company carrying out similar operations as the company under consideration—instead of the actual level of gearing. As such, this approach ensures a consistent treatment of the cost of capital for different firms within the industry. The approach reflects a regulatory position that firms, rather than the regulator, are best placed to undertake decisions related to capital structure.

77. In jurisdictions where there is a positive rate of corporate taxation, one of the main advantages to increasing gearing is the tax-deductibility of interest payments.

Regulatory attention to notional gearing attempts to limit the potential for over-

/under-recovery of tax expenses when the cost of capital is set on a pre-tax basis. If notional gearing is set higher than the actual level, the company may under-recover

- 21 -

its cost of capital unless it increases gearing to take advantage of tax shields implicitly assumed in the cost of capital set by the regulator. However, if the notional gearing level is set lower than the actual level, the regulated company may be able to over-recover its cost of capital compared with what it would incur under the notional capital structure. This is because the company would receive more remuneration for tax than the tax expense actually incurred (on average).

78. When there is a positive rate of corporate taxation, the appropriate notional level of gearing may be determined by reference to regulatory precedents for similar companies and/or the gearing levels of comparator companies. Regulators may also undertake a financeability analysis to assess what gearing level a company is able to support while retaining access to reasonably priced debt finance.

79. As there is no corporate taxation in Bahrain—and hence no risk of companies overrecovering their tax expenses—TRA considers that there is no reason to assume a notional capital structure that contains debt.

Proposed approach to capital structure

The Draft Determination

80. The absence of any corporate taxes in Bahrain indicates that the optimal capital structure is likely to be close to 100% equity, owing to the absence of tax shield benefits associated with issuing debt. The company may still choose positive gearing because of some benefits associated with debt, such as lower agency costs. However, TRA believes that the risk of overestimating the cost of capital by adopting a zero-gearing approach is small because the potential gains to the company from adopting higher leverage, and hence bringing the cost of capital down, are likely to be limited.

81. For regulatory purposes, assuming zero gearing would be expected to allow the company at least a sufficient return to cover its cost of capital under any capital structure. A 100% equity-financed structure could be seen to represent an upper bound for the actual cost of capital and allow full recovery of investment costs.

82. A company could still choose to take on some debt instead of relying on 100% equity finance if it can benefit from the lower cost of capital compared to the zero gearing assumption, or generate other benefits such as access to a liquid source of finance. Therefore, an advantage of assuming an equity-only capital structure in the regulatory determination is that the company is implicitly given discretion to choose the optimal corporate financial policy.

83. For the reasons set out above, TRA is of the view that zero gearing is appropriate for the calculation of the cost of capital for the provision of regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain.

Responses to the Draft Determination

84. All respondents agreed that, in the absence of corporate taxes in Bahrain, the optimal capital structure is likely to be close to 100% equity, and hence the overall cost of capital will be equal to the cost of equity.

TRA analysis and conclusion

85. TRA is of the view that, for the reasons set out in the Draft Determination, the appropriate capital structure to assume for setting the cost of capital for regulatory purposes is 100% equity.

- 22 -

Risk-free rate

86. The risk-free rate is a key parameter of the cost of capital, to which risk premiums are added to estimate the costs of equity and debt. The nominal risk-free rate comprises the real risk-free rate adjusted for inflation.

87. The nominal risk-free rate is typically estimated with reference to the yield to maturity on debt instruments that are notionally assumed to be free of default risk.

Once proxy measures for the risk-free rate have been identified, there are two critical aspects to the estimation process in a regulatory context: the maturity of the proxy security; and the relative weights to place on historical and current data, which might be an important consideration at a time of significant volatility in interest rates.

88. The risk-free rate could be estimated based on the yields on the Bahraini government debt securities. Alternatively, as interest rates across different countries are conceptually related according to a set of interest parity conditions, the nominal risk-free rate for Bahrain could be estimated with respect to the current trading yields on government debt from other countries. The estimate might require adjustment for risk, expected devaluation and other factors, where relevant.

89. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• the risk-free rate is defined;

• issues associated with estimating the risk-free rate in the regulatory context are reviewed, before presenting estimates of the risk-free rate based on Bahraini government securities;

• the conceptual relationship between the risk-free rates in different countries, as predicted by international parity conditions, is discussed and used to identify a suitable international proxy for the risk-free rate in the Bahraini market;

• factors that might bias the predictions of such parity conditions are considered, alongside the evidence on these factors, before presenting estimates of the risk-free rate based on US Treasury bond yields;

TRA’s proposed ranges for the nominal risk-free rate are summarised.

Definition of the risk-free rate

90. The risk-free rate reflects the remuneration that investors require for inter-temporal transfers of consumption. In a sense, therefore, it is a measure of the time value of money: the return an investor requires as compensation for sacrificing current consumption in favour of future consumption.

91. A risk-free asset can be defined as one where the actual return is equal to the expected return. This necessarily requires that, when holding a risk-free asset, the investor is not exposed to any risk over the investment horizon.

92. The risk-free rate is a parameter used to estimate both the cost of equity and the cost of debt. Investors require additional risk premiums in the form of higher expected returns if they are to hold risky, rather than risk-free, assets.

93. In the context of the regulation of telecommunications services in Bahrain, the relevant definition is the nominal risk-free rate, which is implicitly comprised of a real risk-free rate and an expected level of general price inflation. Expected inflation, and

- 23 -

4.0

3.5

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

hence nominal risk-free rates, can vary from one geographic market to another, and is therefore an important consideration when estimating the risk-free rate in an international context.

Estimation of the risk-free rate in the regulatory context

94. The nominal risk-free rate is typically estimated with reference to the yield to maturity on debt instruments that are notionally free of default risk. Where the yields to maturity on nominal government bonds are observed, they typically provide suitable estimates of the nominal risk-free rate if the risk of government default is low.

95. Besides the identification of suitable proxies, determining the nominal risk-free rate involves:

• selecting the appropriate maturity of the proxy measure;

• considering the balance between spot yields and historical averages in case there are large deviations.

The Draft Determination

96. The impact of the choice of maturity on the estimate of the risk-free rate depends on the slope of the yield curve. Figure 7 shows a consistent upward-sloping pattern across yield curves in mature capital markets, demonstrating that investors currently require higher annual returns for investing over longer time horizons.

Figure 7 US, UK and German yield curves (%)

4.5

0.5

0.0

1 2 3 4 5 6

Years to maturity

7 8 9

UK gilts German bunds US Treasury bonds

Note: Yield curves as at June 8th 2009.

Source: Federal Reserve Bank, The Bank of England, Deutsche Bundesbank and TRA calculations.

10

97. When choosing the maturity for the nominal risk-free rate, a number of approaches can be considered, including:

• matching the maturity to the duration of the price control;

- 24 -

• ensuring that firms are able to access capital markets for future funding requirements;

• matching the maturity to the useful economic lives of assets.

98. Matching to the length of the price control period would align the maturity of the riskfree rate to the period over which the cost of capital used for setting output prices is fixed. If the regulated company were to raise financing for the duration of the current price control and then refinance, it would effectively align its actual cost of raising capital with the regulatory determination of the allowed rate of return for the next price control. This is the approach favoured by a number of regulators.

20

99. Since there is no defined length for the regulatory period in the case of Bahrain, this cannot be used as a unique reference point for determining the appropriate maturity for the risk-free rate. However, the period for which the present Determination will apply (ie two years) can be taken as a useful reference point.

100. Companies’ financing and investment decisions do not always match the duration of the price control and investors typically face residual value risk beyond the next control period. Therefore, it is appropriate also to consider maturities that are longer than the length of the control period as the basis for the maturity of the risk-free rate proxy.

101. The estimated cost of raising capital should also take into account the maturity of instruments that broadly match the company’s asset lives. This implicitly assumes a degree of asset-liability matching for the company, and may thereby reduce its risk exposure from any asset-liability mismatch that would occur otherwise. Analysis of regulatory accounts suggests that the weighted average remaining asset life for the regulated companies is approximately seven years, suggesting that maturities up to seven years might be considered.

102. Taking the above considerations into account, TRA considers the appropriate benchmark for the maturity of the risk-free rate to be a range from two to seven years. For the purpose of this Determination and faced with the current steep yield curve, TRA intends to follow a conservative approach and estimate the risk-free rate based on government debt instruments of up to seven years’ maturity.

Responses to the Draft Determination

103. In its submission, Batelco claimed that most telecommunications regulators have examined yields on ten-year maturity bonds when formulating views on the risk-free rate.

21

104. Batelco also expressed the view that the appropriate bond maturity for estimating the risk-free rate is the entire remaining economic life of the assets, which may not be in line with accounting asset lives.

22

The submission also stated that “using the average remaining life suggests that the assets will not be replaced, and only need to be rewarded over their remaining lives”, and that “Batelco needs to be incentivised to invest in assets.”

23

21

22

23

                                                       

20

For example, Ofcom’s preferred maturity is five years as this broadly matches the length of charge control review periods. Ofcom (2009), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach”, May 22nd.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 27.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 28.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, pp. 27–

28.

- 25 -

105. Batelco suggests that the higher volatility of yields on short-term maturity bonds in comparison with long-term maturities makes short-term maturity bonds “less useful” for determining an RFR.

24

106. Zain agreed with the use of yields on debt instruments of 2-7years’ maturity to estimate the RFR.

107. Lightspeed did not express views on the appropriate maturity for the RFR.

TRA analysis and conclusion

108. Relevance of past regulatory precedents to cost of capital determination depends on the understanding of different context and circumstances across jurisdictions as well as over time when such determinations were made. For example, maturities used in regulatory precedents fall into a wide range from one to twenty years.

25

Therefore, while regulatory precedent can sometimes provide useful guidance on the approach to assessing the appropriate maturity for the RFR, it does not necessarily indicate the appropriate value to adopt for the RFR maturity in the particular circumstances relevant to the cost of capital determination.

109. Furthermore, regulatory precedents constitute only one source of evidence and cannot be treated as a substitute for analysis of primary evidence relevant to the particular companies and regulatory regime under consideration.

110. Notwithstanding the limitations of regulatory precedent as an input into cost of capital determination, it is important to note that TRA’s analysis of yields on government bonds with maturities up to seven years falls within the range of maturities used in regulatory precedents mentioned by Batelco and in particular is slightly above Ofcom’s ‘preferred gilt length [of] 5 years’ for Openreach, the division within BT in charge of the access network, which is the business segment with particularly long-lived assets, such as ducts.

26

111. Batelco’s view, that the appropriate bond maturity for estimating the risk-free rate is the entire remaining economic life of the assets, is consistent with both TRA’s approach and with the regulatory regime applied to telecommunications operators in

Bahrain.

112. The regulatory regime in Bahrain uses regulatory asset lives to calculate regulatory depreciation, which is a component of the “building blocks” used to set price controls. If the maturity for the RFR was based on asset lives longer than currently recorded in regulatory accounts, then consistency would require corresponding reductions to the regulatory depreciation allowances.

113. TRA has therefore set the upper-end of the range for the maturity for the RFR based on an estimate of the remaining economic life of assets derived from regulatory asset lives and accumulated depreciation.

114. Batelco’s alternative suggestion of using the average total economic life of assets rather than the remaining economic life as a point of reference might be appropriate

                                                       

24

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 28.

25

For example see Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”,

August 23rd, Table 6 and Commerce Commission (2009), “Final TSO Cost Calculation Determination for TSO Instrument for Local Residential Telephone Service for period between 1 July 2007 and 30

June 2008”, October 7th.

26

Ofcom (2009), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach”, May 22nd, p. 256.

- 26 -

if the regulated company was planning to replace all its assets now. However, it is not relevant under the more likely scenario of a gradual approach to replacing assets as they wear out or become obsolete, and where investments are made on an incremental basis.

115. Batelco has not submitted any evidence to demonstrate that levels of investment sufficient to cause a significant increase in the average remaining economic life of assets are planned. Therefore, TRA considers it is more appropriate to set the upper end of the range for the maturity of the risk-free rate according to the remaining economic life of assets.

116. Although Batelco appears to suggest that a higher cost of capital is required to provide incentives to invest in new assets, Batelco has not submitted evidence of plans for significant levels of investment in new assets in Bahrain, nor any evidence that the systematic risk of these investments would clearly be higher than that of existing assets.

117. Batelco’s suggestion that higher volatility of yields on short-term maturity government bonds makes them “less useful” for determining an RFR, is not supported by evidence that spot yields are significantly distorted or do not provide an efficient pricing signal.

118. Without clear, robust evidence that current pricing signals are distorted or inefficient, yields would be expected to reflect the rate of return required by investors at a particular point in time and as such represent the best estimate of the forwardlooking RFR. TRA therefore does not consider it appropriate to put less weight on spot yields compared to alternative sources of evidence.

119. Higher volatility of yields suggests that there is an increased risk that the RFR set in the Determination is significantly below the actual RFR over the period over which the Determination is effective. To address this risk, TRA has added an uplift over spot yields to allow for potential increases in the RFR over the time horizon for which this Determination will apply. This is a conservative approach, which means that as TRA has selected a point estimate at the upper-end of the range for the overall cost of capital, the implied RFR allows the regulated companies significant headroom over current spot yields.

120. TRA therefore remains of the view that the appropriate maturity for assessing the risk-free rate is between two and seven years based on the period for which this

Determination will apply and the average remaining economic life of assets. Given the upward sloping yield curve, TRA has adopted a conservative approach by estimating the RFR based on government bond yields up to a maturity of seven years.

The Draft Determination

121. The second key measurement issue is the trade-off between using spot yields or historical averages. In efficient markets, there is no reason to assume that the price signal based on the latest spot estimate is not indicative of the expected, forwardlooking returns. However, at times of significant volatility, some consideration may need to be given to long-term historical averages. This approach requires caution because the spot yields should reflect all the relevant, current information and expectations, and hence the most up-to-date price of raising capital.

122. Any estimate of the risk-free rate is subject to a greater degree of uncertainty now than before the financial crisis. The recent increase in volatility of yields on nominal

US Treasury bonds is seen in Figure 8, which shows that the 50% confidence

- 27 -

interval for forecasts of the Treasury bond yield is wider when calculated using yields from the period after the start of the financial crisis than before it.

Figure 8 Increase in uncertainty around the nominal risk-free rate

6

5

4

3.7

3.2

3

2

50% confidence interval is calculated using the standard deviation (1.11) of yields on US sovereign bonds with maturities of 5 to 7 years for the period between July 2004 and June 2009

50% confidence interval is calculated using the standard deviation (0.80) of yields on US sovereign bonds with maturities of 5 to 7 years for the period between July 2004 and July 2007

1

01-Jan-04 01-Jan-05 01-Jan-06 01-Jan-07 01-Jan-08 01-Jan-09 01-Jan-10 01-Jan-11

US Treasury 5–7Y Lower bound of RFR Upper bound of RFR Spot

Note: Based on Merrill Lynch US Treasury Index with maturities 5–7 years. Confidence intervals for the riskfree rate (RFR) are calculated as follows: yield at June 24th 2009 ±0.67*T*standard deviation (where standard deviation is based on daily changes in yields and T is the forecast time period after June 24th 2009).

Source: Datastream, TRA calculations.

123. The volatility of Treasury bond yields illustrates the current uncertainty associated with yields going forward. It suggests that additional headroom might be appropriate to limit the risk that the regulatory determination of the risk-free rate significantly differs from the actual risk-free rate in the future and hence allows the companies to finance their operations over the regulatory period.

124. Based on the above considerations, TRA proposes to allow for some additional headroom in the risk-free rate to reflect the asymmetric risk that this uncertainty presents for financing.

Responses to the Draft Determination

125. Batelco disagreed with using spot rates as the basis for estimating the risk-free rate, and stated that “utilities and telecoms regulators have generally taken a medium to long term view by examining historical trends (as opposed to spot rates)”.

27

126. Batelco noted that yields have generally been low over the past year relative to average yields taken over longer time horizons, and that spot yields are currently below the range typically used by European regulators in the past.

28

Batelco recommends using a 10 year averaging period.

                                                       

27

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 25.

28

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 26.

- 28 -

127. Batelco also expressed the view that the increased volatility of yields on US government bonds since the onset of the current financial turmoil “may complicate the use of current market data.”

29

128. Lightspeed agreed with the use of spot yields to estimate the RFR.

129. Zain did not express a position on the use of spot yields.

TRA analysis and conclusion

130. Long-term averages of the kind recommended by Batelco are backward-looking and reflect the higher yields observed over the past ten years, whereas spot yields reflect the most recent information regarding the expected future level of the RFR.

As the objective of the Determination is to set the forward-looking cost of capital,

TRA considers that spot yields are more appropriate than long-term averages unless it can be clearly shown that spot prices are distorted or inefficient.

131. Past decisions by European regulators are necessarily based on historical yields rather than yields that are currently observed in the market. In efficient markets, historical yields do not contain information that can be used to forecast future yields.

Therefore, TRA does not consider it is appropriate to attach significant weight to past estimates of the RFR used in different regulatory decisions in other jurisdictions and in different market circumstances.

132. Unless it can be clearly shown that spot prices are distorted or inefficient, increased volatility does not “complicate the use of current market data”,

30 but rather suggests that there is an increased risk that the RFR set in the Determination is significantly below the actual RFR over the period for which the Determination is effective.

133. To address this risk, TRA has added an uplift over spot yields to allow for potential increases in the RFR over the time horizon for which this Determination will apply.

This is a conservative approach, which means that as TRA has selected a point estimate at the upper-end of the range for the overall cost of capital, the implied

RFR allows the regulated companies significant headroom over current spot yields.

134. TRA therefore remains of the view that it is appropriate to set the RFR with respect to current spot yields and also to allow headroom for asymmetric risk.

Estimation from Bahrain government securities

The Draft Determination

135. Conceptually, the “risk-free” rate for a less diversified, domestic investor can be proxied by the yields on debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain.

136. However, as the nominal yield on debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of

Bahrain should include a country risk premium, it may not meet the strict definition of a “risk-free” asset, but rather a combination of the risk-free rate and the “country risk premium”. Long-term Ijara Sukuks (Islamic Al-Salam securities) are denominated in US dollars and have a maturity between three and ten years, whereas short-term Sukuks are usually denominated in Bahraini dinars and have maturities ranging between 91 and 182 days. The latter would therefore be expected to include a currency risk premium as well. Figure 9 shows the quarterly

                                                       

29

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 26.

30

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 26.

- 29 -

4

3

2

1 average nominal yields on long- and short-term Sukuks as reported by the Central

Bank of Bahrain.

Figure 9 Yields on government securities issued in Bahrain (%)

6

5

0

Q4 2003 Q2 2004 Q4 2004 Q2 2005 Q4 2005 Q2 2006 Q4 2006 Q2 2007 Q4 2007 Q2 2008 Q4 2008

Long-term (3-10Y) Short-term (90-182D)

Average yield on long-term securities Average yield on short-term securities

Note: This figure reports the average quarterly return on short- and long-term Ijara-Sukuk securities over the period considered.

Source: Central Bank of Bahrain and TRA calculations.

137. The yield on the long- and short-term Bahraini government securities ranged from around 4.0% to 5.5% between the fourth quarter (Q4) of 2005 and Q3 2007. Since the onset of the financial turmoil in Q3 2007, yields have declined significantly, similar to the pattern observed in international markets.

138. On June 11th, the Bahraini government issued a five-year maturity Ijara Sukuk bond of $750m. This bond provides the latest available information and was trading at a price equivalent to a yield to maturity of 5.8% as at June 24th 2009.

31

139. Table 1 shows the yields on long- and short-term Sukuks averaged across different time periods. The yield on long-term Sukuks has averaged around 3.9%, measured over the past five years. Data on spot yields for long-term Sukuks is not available, but the three-month average is 2.4%.

                                                       

31

Datastream.

- 30 -

Table 1 Average yields on debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of

Bahrain (%)

Averaging period

3-month average

Short-term Al-Salam Sukuks

(90–182-day maturity)

1.4

1-year 2.0

3-year 4.0

5-year 3.6

Long-term Ijara Sukuks

(3–10-year maturity)

2.4

3.9

4.5

3.9

Note: The figures reported are based on the average quarterly return on short- and long-term Sukuks. Spot yields are not reported in the data available from the Central Bank of Bahrain.

Source: Central Bank of Bahrain, TRA calculations.

140. Given that TRA intends to estimate the risk-free rate based on government bonds up to seven years’ maturity, the yield on long-term Ijara Sukuks might provide a reasonable proxy for the underlying nominal risk-free rate in Bahrain. However, the robustness of these estimates might be undermined for two reasons:

Al-Salam Sukuks are priced as a spread to the London Interbank Offered Rate

(LIBOR)—a reference rate driven by various factors in international capital markets (e.g. inter-bank borrowing)—and implicitly include a risk premium for the possibility of default by the Bahraini Government over and above the perceived default risk of international banks;

• the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain issues long-term Ijara Sukuk securities on an ad hoc basis and these are therefore priced infrequently. In the absence of frequent data on secondary market trading of these securities, they are less likely to provide an accurate estimate of the current risk-free rate.

141. Given available information, the Ijara Sukuks and the bond issued on June 11th are two essential sources of information to estimate the domestic risk-free rate. The resulting estimate reflects the combined risk-free rate and country risk premium required by a less diversified investor. No country risk premium needs to be added when calculating the cost of capital from the perspective of the less diversified investor, as the proxies used to estimate the risk-free rate already incorporate such a premium.

142. The yield on the bond issued by the Bahraini government on June 11th suggests that a nominal risk-free rate of up to 5.8% might be appropriate. Yields on the longterm Ijara Sukuks calculated by the Central Bank of Bahrain suggest a lower rate, nearer to 2.5%.

143. Given that TRA proposes to provide additional headroom in the risk-free rate to allow for the uncertainty created by turmoil in financial markets, a range of 3.5–5.8% for the risk-free rate is proposed, assuming a less diversified, domestic investor.

The width of this range reflects the uncertainty of estimates based on data for securities issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain.

Responses to the Draft Determination

144. Batelco agreed with TRA “that the RFR should be established primarily by looking to the US government yields rather than returns on domestic securities”,

32

and did not

                                                       

32

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 25.

- 31 -

provide detailed comments on the estimation of the risk-free rate from Bahrain government securities.

145. Zain stated that “the alternative scenario of a range of 3.5–5.8% based on long-term securities issued by the Bahraini Government also appears to be appropriate.”

33

146. Lightspeed did not comment on the alternative scenario.

TRA analysis and conclusion

147. As the respondents did not raise detailed concerns regarding the estimates of the risk-free rate in the alternative scenario, for the reasons outlined in the Draft

Determination TRA remains of the view that a range of 3.5–5.8% appropriately reflects the risk-free rate, assuming a less diversified, domestic investor.

Risk-free rate in the international context

148. The potential shortcomings of using data based on government bonds issued by the

Kingdom of Bahrain can be addressed by estimating the risk-free rate with reference to the current trading yields on government debt from other countries. The resulting estimate of the risk-free rate might provide more reliable information about investors’ expectations regarding the risk-free rate because it is based on instruments that are frequently traded in liquid financial markets.

149. There is a relationship between interest rates in different countries, which is characterised by a number of ‘parity conditions’. The interest rate parity condition specifies a relationship expected to hold between interest rates or yields on securities issued in different jurisdictions. In particular, the so-called ‘uncovered interest parity’ condition implies that the differential between domestic (eg, Bahrain) and foreign or ‘world’ (eg, US) interest rates will be equal to the expected change in the price of the domestic currency in terms of the foreign currency, assuming free capital mobility and no risk.

150. With the fixed exchange rate between the Bahraini dinar and US dollar—based on an arrangement where the Central Bank of Bahrain can buy and sell US dollars at rates very close to the official exchange rate—and assuming no risk of a change in this regime, expected currency depreciation would be zero. Hence, the domestic and foreign interest rates might be expected to be equal. Therefore, given the fixed exchange rate, the yields on US government debt can be seen as the appropriate reference point for the risk-free rate for an investor investing in Bahrain.

151. Even where the nominal exchange rate is fixed, the real exchange rate might change over time, if there is a difference in inflation between the domestic and foreign market. If the domestic market (eg, Bahrain) has lower inflation than the foreign market (eg, the USA) and the nominal exchange rate is fixed, the domestic currency is appreciating in real terms. Thus, under the same interest rates and in the absence of a risk differential, an investor in the domestic market would benefit compared with one investing (and consuming) in foreign markets in the event that the inflation rate in Bahrain is lower than in the foreign market.

152. Using the law of one price, according to the purchasing power parity (PPP) condition, under the assumption of small or negligible transaction costs and import tariffs, the difference in nominal interest rates between two countries would then be

                                                       

33

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

- 32 -

equal to the difference in expected inflation. In other words, if there is a positive inflation differential and arbitrage is possible, PPP requires that the nominal interest rates differ by the difference in inflation such that real interest rates in the two countries remain equal.

153. If the interest parity and PPP conditions hold, the interest rate in the USA provides the appropriate reference point for the international investor investing in Bahrain. If the international investor was assumed to invest (and consume) in Bahrain, he would be earning Bahraini nominal interest rate, but the same real interest rate as the investor investing in the assets abroad (eg in the USA). If the international investor was to invest in Bahrain but use the returns to consume abroad (eg, in the

USA), he would then need to earn the equivalent of the nominal US interest rate that would provide him with the appropriate compensation for the same real interest rate as well as the difference in inflation.

International risk-free rate in practice

The Draft Determination

154. Persistent inflation differentials between Bahrain and the USA would imply continuous changes in the real exchange rate, despite the fixed nominal exchange rate between the Bahraini dinar and the US dollar. This would also imply persistent differences in nominal interest rates, even if the interest parity conditions hold. This might not be sustainable in the long run.

155. Figure 10 shows the real and nominal exchange rates between the Bahraini dinar and the US dollar. Whereas the nominal exchange rate has been fixed at 0.376 dinars to the dollar, the dinar has appreciated steadily in real terms against the US dollar. This suggests that differences in inflation rates between the USA and

Bahrain have persisted for several years, suggesting a difference in the nominal interest rates as well. That is, a higher nominal interest in the USA would have been expected to compensate investors for higher inflation in the USA compared with the return on Bahraini assets.

156. Nevertheless, the evidence suggests that, since 2001, the inflation differential has been relatively small (Figure 10). The latest forecasts from the International

Monetary Fund (“IMF”) suggest that the differential observed historically will reverse over the next two years and then reduce to approximately zero after 2010. This suggests that yields on US government debt are a good proxy for the nominal riskfree rate in Bahrain and the appropriate reference benchmark for the international investor investing in Bahrain. TRA therefore considers that the yield on nominal US government debt can be used as a proxy measure for the risk-free rate used to estimate the cost of capital in the base-case scenario.

- 33 -

Figure 10 Real and nominal exchange rates (Bahraini dinar versus US dollar)

0.40

Forecasts start after 2008

0.35

0.30

0.25

0.20

1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

Nominal exchange rate Real exchange rate

Note: The real exchange rate is defined as the nominal exchange rate multiplied by the ratio between the price indices in Bahrain and the USA.

Source: IMF (2009), “World Economic Outlook Database”, April; Datastream and TRA calculations.

157. The assumptions underlying the parity conditions described above may not always hold, particularly in the short run, for several reasons. For example, in less developed countries, there could be significant transaction costs associated with cross-border transactions or there might be imperfect capital mobility. Domestic and foreign assets might also not be substitutable owing to country risk premiums.

158. Investors would also require compensation for economic, political, institutional and financial risks associated with Bahrain, if applicable. The discussion thus far has assumed that there is no risk premium associated with domestic assets (ie, there is no risk premium that investors might require for investing in Bahrain compared with the US benchmark). If the yield on US Treasury bonds is assumed to be the proxy for the international risk-free rate, an international investor might require a country risk premium to invest in Bahrain rather than the USA. Hence, in the presence of additional country risks, the Bahraini rates of return would be higher than in the

USA.

34

This issue is addressed in the section on the country risk premium.

Responses to the Draft Determination

159. Batelco noted that the IMF data forecasts higher inflation in Bahrain in comparison with the USA over the period 2009–11. Batelco recommended that TRA apply an uplift to the risk-free rate estimated from US government bond yields, equivalent to the average inflation differential forecast for the ten years starting from 2010.

35

                                                       

34

The relative impact of any persistent difference in expected inflation rates and the presence of a risk premium might be expected to determine the actual differences in nominal interest rates between

Bahrain and the USA. These two effects could act in opposite directions and hence may, to some extent, cancel each other out.

35

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 29.

- 34 -

160. The other respondents did not comment on the treatment of inflation differentials.

TRA analysis and conclusion

161. If the interest parity conditions hold, then under a floating exchange rate differences in rates of inflation between countries would be expected to be reflected in a differential in nominal interest rates between countries and expected changes in the exchange rate. If the exchange rate is fixed but markets are fully internationally integrated, nominal interest rates and inflation would be expected to equalise.

162. To the extent that markets are segmented into separate national markets, it is possible for there to be differences in interest rates and inflation, particularly in the short-run. Therefore, in this Determination TRA has considered the cost of capital from the perspectives of both international foreign and domestic investors to account for any potential differences.

163. A domestic investor would expect to receive compensation for the domestic rate of inflation to compensate for changes in purchasing power in the domestic market, hence the relevant interest rate would reflect the expected rate of inflation in

Bahrain. This is implicitly included in the estimation of the RFR from the perspective of the domestic investor, because this approach is based on yields from securities issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain. The domestic interest rate could also be approximated by the sum of an international interest rate plus the expected inflation differential and adjusted for country risk if relevant.

164. A foreign investor (eg, from the USA), would need to be compensated for the rate of inflation in the foreign market. This is because the foreign investor is assumed to ultimately use investment proceeds to fund consumption in the foreign market. If higher returns were permanently available in Bahrain compared to the foreign market (in the absence of risk of the fixed nominal exchange rate changing), this would represent a risk-free profit opportunity for the foreign investor, who could invest in Bahrain but use proceeds for consumption in the foreign market.

36

165. In any case, under a fixed exchange rate, significant inflation differentials would not be expected to persist because they would imply permanent shifts in the real exchange rate until price differentials are equalised. Under free capital flows and free trade, higher domestic inflation would imply that domestic consumers would import goods and services from abroad (where inflation and hence prices are lower) until price differentials are equalised. This dynamic appears to be reflected in the

IMF forecasts as inflation is expected to increase and the real exchange rate is expected to fall over the next two years after a period of an increase prior to 2008.

166. TRA therefore remains of the view that, in the absence of risk of the fixed nominal exchange rate changing, the yield on nominal US government debt can be used as a proxy measure for the risk-free rate used to estimate the expected return to the foreign investor. From the perspective of the domestic investor, the inflation differential is already implicitly accounted for as a part of the yields on securities issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain. TRA also notes that any country-specific risks are already accounted for in the country risk premium added to the cost of capital estimates.

                                                       

36

As discussed in the section on the country risk premium, exchange rate risk is assumed to be small.

- 35 -

5

4

3

2

1

0

-1

-2

Estimation from US government securities

The Draft Determination

167. The risk-free rate can be proxied by the yield to maturity on US Treasury bonds.

Figure 11 shows the evolution of the yield to maturity on benchmark indices of US

Treasury bonds of 3–5- and 5–7-year maturities, along with the implied rate of inflation, estimated as the difference between yields on nominal and index-linked

US Treasury bonds. The nominal yield on US Treasury bonds gradually increased between 2005 and 2007, subsequently decreasing significantly after the onset of the financial turmoil around July 2007. The differential between yields on nominal and real bonds currently implies that inflation will be close to 1% over a five-year time horizon.

Figure 11 Yields on nominal US Treasury bonds and implied inflation (%)

6

-3

24/02/05 24/08/05 24/02/06 24/08/06 24/02/07 24/08/07 24/02/08 24/08/08 24/02/09

US Treasury 3–5Y US Treasury 5–7Y Implied inflation 3–5 years Implied inflation 5–7 years

Note: Based on Merrill Lynch US Treasury Index with maturities of 3–5 years and 5–7 years. Implied inflation calculated using Fisher’s formula.

Source: Datastream, TRA calculations.

168. Table 2 summarises the average yields across different time periods and maturities.

- 36 -

Table 2 Average nominal yields on US Treasury bonds (%)

Averaging period 3–5-year maturity 5–7-year maturity

1-month 2.2 3.2

3-month 1.8 2.6

Note: The spot yields are reported as at June 24th 2009.

Source: Datastream, TRA calculations.

169. Over the past three years, yields have been following a downward trend, and spot yields for the relevant part of the maturity curve are now 3.2% or lower. Such a reduction may in part be a result of lower inflation expectations. This trend suggests that estimates of the forward-looking risk-free rate based on longer-term averages do not provide relevant, forward-looking information. Therefore TRA considers that, in the US Treasury Bond market, spot yields are currently the best indicator of the risk-free rate.

170. Overall, for the reasons set out above, TRA is of the view that the appropriate range for the risk-free rate under the base case is 3.2–3.7% based on US government spot yields of 5–7-year maturity. This is a conservative estimate which includes an uplift of 50 basis points (bp) to the upper end of the range in recognition of the current uncertainty in financial markets.

Responses to the Draft Determination

171. Batelco disagreed with the estimates from the perspective of a foreign investor that have been proposed by TRA. Specifically, Batelco recommended a range of 4.3–

5.3% based on ten-year averages of yields on US government bonds of five and 30 years’ maturity respectively, “adjusted for the forecast inflation differential”.

37

172. Both Zain and Lightspeed agreed with TRA’s proposed range of 3.2–3.7% for the risk-free rate from the perspective of a foreign investor.

TRA analysis and conclusion

173. Batelco has used a range of 5–30 years for the maturity of the risk-free rate in comparison with the range of two to seven years used by TRA. Given the two-year period for which this Determination will apply and the approximately seven-year average remaining economic life of assets, TRA does not consider it appropriate to use a maturity greater than seven years as the reference point.

174. Within the range of two to seven years defined by the period for which this

Determination will apply and the average remaining economic life of assets, TRA has adopted a conservative approach by using the US government bond benchmark of five to seven years’ maturity.

175. Therefore, TRA remains of the view that 3.2–3.7% is appropriate for the risk-free rate from the perspective of an international investor, where the lower-end of the

                                                       

37

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 30.

- 37 -

range is based on spot yields on US Treasury bonds of five to seven years’ maturity and the upper-end of the range includes 50bps headroom to reflect current levels of volatility in yields.

Proposed ranges for the risk-free rate

176. TRA proposes to use a range for the nominal risk-free rate of 3.2–3.7%, based on yields on US Treasury bonds for the international investor. This range reflects headroom over spot rates to allow for uncertainty in financial markets. The question of whether it is appropriate to add a country risk premium to reflect the additional risk that an investor might face in investing in Bahrain rather than the USA is discussed in the next section.

177. Under the alternative scenario considered by TRA based on a domestic investor, a range of 3.5–5.8% is proposed, based on average yields for long-term Ijara Sukuks over a range of time periods. The wider range compared with the range based on

US Treasury bonds is a reflection of the additional uncertainty caused by using data based on less frequently traded securities.

Responses to the Draft Determination

178. The responses received have been noted in the relevant parts of this analysis of the risk-free rate.

TRA analysis and conclusion

179. The responses have been addressed in the relevant sections of this analysis of the risk-free rate.

180. TRA remains of the view that 3.2–3.7% and 3.5–5.8% are appropriate ranges for the estimates of the risk-free rate, based on US Treasury bonds and securities issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain, respectively.

- 38 -

Country risk premium

181. Investors may be exposed to additional risk as a result of investing in Bahrain rather than in other countries such as the USA. To the extent that this risk is systematic and non-diversifiable, investors would expect additional compensation for exposure to that risk.

182. In addition to country risk, there may be currency risk. Currency risk may arise where the cash flows to an investor are denominated in a currency different to that in which the investor intends ultimately to use the proceeds of investment to pay for their consumption of goods and services.

183. The magnitude of the country risk premium for investing in Bahrain can be proxied by sovereign credit risk, which can be estimated with reference to the yields on debt issued by governments with similar sovereign credit ratings to Bahrain. An estimate of the country risk premium may be added to the risk-free rate for the calculation of the cost of capital in the base-case scenario. However, a country risk premium is not warranted for the alternative scenario as the yields used to estimate the risk-free rate used in that case would already be expected to include such a premium.

184. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• currency risk is considered, together with an examination of whether an associated premium is applicable to the current assessment;

• the concept of country risk and the effect on investors’ required returns are discussed next;

• country risk premiums are assessed on the basis of sovereign debt spreads;

TRA’s proposed estimate of the country risk premium is presented.

Currency risk

The Draft Determination

185. The currency risk faced by an investor in assets denominated in Bahraini dinar is that the value of the investment will change as a result of unanticipated movements in the nominal exchange rate. As the Bahraini dinar has in effect been pegged to the US dollar at a constant rate of 0.376 dinars to the dollar since 1980,

38

the nominal exchange rate might be expected to remain constant over the duration of this Determination. Therefore, currency risk is unlikely to be a major risk for investment and does not provide justification for an additional premium for currency risk.

186. One indication of the actual currency risk might be the difference between yields on different debt securities issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain with equal maturities but denominated in Bahraini dinars and US dollars. The difference between the yield on short-term Bahraini dinar-denominated Al-Salam securities, adjusted for the maturity premium based on US Treasuries,

39

and the yield on long-

                                                       

38

Central Bank of Bahrain “Exchange rate policy”, http://www.bma.gov.bh/cmsrule/index.jsp?action=article&ID=1323, accessed on June 5th 2009.

39

The maturity premium reflects the additional compensation required to compensate for holding longermaturity securities, and was estimated by taking the differences between the yields on US Treasury bonds of 3–5- and 5–7-year maturities and those on short-term Treasury bills of maturities between 0

- 39 -

term US dollar-denominated Ijara Sukuks can be used to estimate the currency risk.

The evidence suggests that, on average over the past five years, the differential in yields has been very close to zero, supporting the expectation that the currency risk perceived by investors for investing in Bahrain is close to zero.

187. Overall, given that the nominal exchange rate peg between the Bahraini dinar and the US dollar is expected to remain stable, and that the average differential in yields between Bahraini government securities denominated in dinars and dollars has been close to zero, TRA considers that there is no justification for a currency risk premium.

Responses to the Draft Determination

188. None of the respondents expressed a view on whether there was any justification for a currency risk premium.

TRA analysis and conclusion

189. TRA remains of the view that there is no justification for a currency risk premium.

Country risk

190. Investments may be exposed to the risk of the country in which they generate cash flows. This risk may be systematic—related to the returns on the global market—or idiosyncratic. From the perspective of a globally diversified investor, any compensation for additional risk would be contingent on whether the risk is systematic or diversifiable.

191. To the extent that country risk is idiosyncratic, it could be diversified by holding a global portfolio of assets; hence, globally diversified investors would not be expected to be compensated for this risk, on average, and hence would require no premium for country risk. In practice, the country risk might not be diversifiable and would need to be compensated for in the cost of capital for the following reasons:

• imperfect international capital flows and investors’ propensity to exhibit a preference for domestic securities—the home-bias puzzle;

40

• increasing correlation between national economies and equity markets, implying that a greater proportion of the overall risk is non-diversifiable;

• a requirement on the regulated company to pay the full amount of the risk premium investors' demand as compensation for the probability of loss from default.

41

192. The home-bias phenomenon might be due to barriers to international capital flows, the effects of national boundaries, or preferences for geographically proximate investments.

42

                                                                                                                                                                    and 9 months. This analysis assumes that the term structures of interest rates are the same in Bahrain and the USA.

40

French, K. and Poterba, J. (1991), “Investor diversification and international equity markets”, American

Economic Review , 81 , 222–26.

41

With a positive probability of default, the actual amount the company expects to pay will be lower than the full amount promised to investors, as the companies’ payments to creditors would be lowered after a default event.

- 40 -

193. Closer correlation between national economies and equity markets due to increased international trade and capital flows might be expected to have reduced the ease of diversifying non-systematic risks. Hence, investors may now require compensation for a greater element of country risk. Furthermore, there is evidence to suggest that correlation between national equity markets increases at times of crisis.

43

194. Therefore, if investors require compensation for this risk, it should form part of the allowed returns.

Estimation of the country risk

The Draft Determination

195. The country risk premium could be proxied by sovereign credit risk, which can be estimated by measuring the premium for yields on US dollar-denominated debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain over debt issued by the US government.

196. The difference between the yields on long-term US dollar-denominated Ijara Sukuks

(3–10-year maturities) and US government bond indices of comparable maturities indicates a spread of around 115bp on average over the past year.

44

However, the calculation might not provide a robust estimate of the country risk premium since the lack of active secondary market trading for Ijara Sukuks means that the yields on these securities are not frequently updated to reflect changes in country risk, or in the risk-free rate.

197. In the absence of a significant quantity of actively traded long-term debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of Bahrain, the yields to maturity on US dollardenominated sovereign debt issued by countries with comparable credit ratings to

Bahrain can be used as proxies for the country risk that an investor faces.

45

198. Bahrain currently has a sovereign long-term foreign currency credit rating of A.

46

Figure 12 displays the yields to maturity on indices for nominal US dollardenominated Treasury bonds and sovereign US dollar-denominated benchmarks with varying credit ratings. Since August 2007, yields on US Treasury Bonds have declined significantly, while yields on the AA and A rated sovereign debt benchmarks have been broadly stable (Figure 12).

                                                                                                                                                                   

42

Coval, J. and Moskowitz, T. (1999), “Home Bias at Home: Local Equity Preference in Domestic

Portfolios”, Journal of Finance , 54 :6, December.

43

Ball, C. and Torous, W. (2000), “Stochastic Correlation Across International Stock Markets”, Journal of

Empirical Finance , 7 :3–4, 373–88, November.

44

45

The difference was estimated using US government bonds with maturities between one and ten years.

Another alternative would be to examine the credit spreads on A rated US dollar-denominated corporate debt compared with AAA rated bonds as a proxy for the country risk premium. However, data from the corporate bond markets is likely to be less relevant where adequate data exists on comparable sovereign debt.

46

Standard & Poor’s (2008), “Bahrain (Kingdom of)”, December 17th.

- 41 -

Figure 12 Yields on foreign sovereign debt denominated in US dollars and the US

Treasury bond benchmark (%)

6.0

5.5

5.0

4.5

4.0

3.5

3.0

2.5

2.0

1.5

1.0

01-Jan-05 01-Jul-05 01-Jan-06 01-Jul-06 01-Jan-07 01-Jul-07 01-Jan-08 01-Jul-08

May 28th 2009

01-Jan-09

A (5-year) AA (5-year) US Government (5-year)

Note: Bloomberg Fair Value (“BFV”) indices are used in this analysis. These represent yields on sovereign debt issued in US dollars.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

199. Figure 13 displays the spreads of the sovereign debt indices against the US benchmark, calculated from the same data used in Figure 12. Before the financial crisis, the spreads on the single A rated index traded at approximately 50bp.

Following the onset of the financial crisis, spreads first increased significantly and then declined sharply. However, it should be noted that Figure 12 suggests that the primary driver of this volatility has been a reduction in yields on US Treasury bonds rather than an increase in yields on A rated sovereign debt.

- 42 -

Figure 13 Spreads of foreign sovereign debt denominated in US dollars over the

US Treasury bond benchmark (bp)

300

Onset of the financial crisis

250

200

150

100

50

May 28th 2009

0

01-Jan-05 01-Jul-05 01-Jan-06 01-Jul-06 01-Jan-07 01-Jul-07 01-Jan-08 01-Jul-08 01-Jan-09

A (5-year) AA (5-year)

Note: BFV indices are used in this analysis. These represent yields on sovereign debt issued in US dollars.

Implied spreads are calculated as the differences between yields on the BFV indices and the US benchmarks of the corresponding maturities.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

Proposed country risk premium

200. Considering that sovereign debt spreads based on single A rated government debt currently suggest that a country risk premium of up to 150bp might be required for an investment in Bahrain compared with an equivalent investment in the USA, TRA proposes to add a country risk premium of 150bp to the required returns under the base-case scenario of an internationally diversified investor.

201. As the risk-free rate under the alternative scenario of a less diversified investor is estimated from the yields on debt issued by the Government of the Kingdom of

Bahrain, it would be expected to contain a premium for country risk; hence, no additional premium is required in the alternative scenario.

Responses to the Draft Determination

202. Batelco presented estimates of the country risk premium for Bahrain and other countries in the Middle East derived from PricewaterhouseCoopers’ Country Risk

Model.

47

Batelco then calculated the average country risk premium over the last year for these countries, as Batelco considered “the average CRP to provide a better indicator of expected CRP as it smoothes out any short term fluctuations.”

48

Based on this data, Batelco considered that “relative to other countries with similar

                                                       

47

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 34.

48

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 33.

- 43 -

bond ratings, 2.0% would also appear to be a reasonable estimate of Bahrain’s

CRP”.

49

203. Batelco then added that “allowing for additional risk factors such as size of country and economy, level of diversification of the economy, and developing legal and commercial framework we believe an additional risk factor of between 0.3% and

0.6% would need to be added”.

50

Batelco suggested that the overall country risk premium was 2.3%.

204. Zain agreed with TRA’s approach to the country risk premium and “views the uplift of 150bps to be appropriate”.

51

205. Lightspeed “rejected the TRA proposition to add a country risk premium of 150bp to the required returns under the base-case scenario of an internationally diversified investor. Lightspeed sees that adding 100 BP as country risk premium is more reasonable and will reflect the average country risk premium before the Financial crisis (50 BP) and after the financial crisis (150 BP)”.

52

TRA analysis and conclusion

206. It is important that the country risk premium is estimated in a manner consistent with the risk-free rate. Batelco’s approach is internally inconsistent because ten-year averages are used to estimate the risk-free rate, while a one-year average is used to estimate the country risk premium. Lightspeed’s proposal to apply a 50% weighting to estimates of the country risk premium based on data prior to the onset of the financial crisis is internally inconsistent because it does not propose a similar weighting for the risk-free rate.

207. TRA has applied a consistent approach by using spot rates to estimate both the risk-free rate and the country risk premium. TRA considers that spot rates would be expected to provide a relevant estimate of the forward-looking country risk premium.

208. The additional source of evidence presented by Batelco indicates an average country risk premium for Bahrain over 2009 Q2 of 1.8%, which is slightly above the country risk premium of 1.5% estimated by TRA, but significantly below the 2.3% proposed by Batelco. TRA has adopted consistent approaches to the country risk premium and the risk-free rate by estimating both based on spot yields at the same point in time.

209. If the country risk premium were to be estimated as an average over 2009 Q2, for consistency the risk-free rate would be based on an average of US Treasury bond yields over the same period. Table 2 above indicates that the 3-month average of

Treasury bond yields at the cut-off date for the Draft Determination was lower than the spot rate, and hence there would be a corresponding reduction in the risk-free rate.

210. The country risk premium is intended to measure the factors described by Batelco as “additional risk factors”.

53

A proxy measure to quantify the level of these risk

                                                       

49

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ’Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 33.

50

51

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ’Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 33.

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ’Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

52

Lightspeed (2009), “Lightspeed submission in response to the Telecommunications Regulatory

Authority (TRA) Consultation Paper on ’Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd.

53

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ’Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 33.

- 44 -

factors in combination is the sovereign credit rating of Bahrain. If Bahrain is significantly more risky than other single A rated countries, then it would be expected to have a lower sovereign credit rating. TRA considers that by adding an additional premium for the factors identified by Batelco it would be double-counting their effect on the cost of capital given the addition of the country risk premium.

211. Therefore, TRA remains of the view that 150bp is an appropriate estimate of the country risk premium under the base-case scenario of an internationally diversified investor.

- 45 -

Equity risk premium

212. The equity risk premium (ERP) is a key parameter in the cost of equity. It represents the expected return by an investor over and above the risk-free rate for investing into a portfolio of equities that represents the equity market as a whole. Assuming that investors hold internationally diversified investment portfolios, there is a single world ERP.

213. The robust estimation of the ERP specifically for Bahrain is not possible due to the lack of sufficiently long-run time-series data for the Bahraini equity market.

Nevertheless, a comparative analysis of the Bahraini and international equity markets might suggest whether, in principle, one might expect a material difference between the world and the Bahraini ERPs.

214. Several sources of evidence and methods of estimation are available to inform an estimate of the ERP for mature equity markets, including:

• long-run averages of realised equity returns in excess of the risk-free rate;

• dividend or earnings-growth rate models;

• surveys of investor expectations.

215. As estimation methods forecast the average ERP over a given time horizon, a choice needs to be made between using arithmetic or geometric averages.

216. Estimation methods based on long-run average realised excess returns also require consideration of the effects of the recent financial turmoil and the extent to which the average ERP over the forecast horizon is likely to have changed recently, and might be above or below the long-run average. This is important to ensure that capital markets can be accessed by regulated companies.

217. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• having defined the ERP, the characteristics of Bahraini and international equity markets are compared to see whether there are any material differences that are likely to affect the ERP;

• issues associated with the empirical estimation of the ERP are discussed and the estimates of the world ERP prepared, which are then compared against regulatory precedents;

• the effects of the financial turmoil on the ERP are considered;

• the relative illiquidity of the Bahraini equity market is discussed;

• finally the proposed range for the ERP is presented.

Definition of the ERP

218. The ERP represents the additional expected remuneration above the risk-free rate that investors require to invest in a broad market portfolio of equities. For investment decisions, the forward-looking ERP and cost of equity are relevant, and these can be estimated from historical returns or forward-looking models. The actual forwardlooking ERP is unobservable, but can be estimated by modelling expected returns.

219. Under the assumption that international capital markets are integrated, there is a single global ERP. Investors can benefit from global diversification if they hold the global market portfolio. However, to the extent that international capital flow is impaired by transaction costs or other barriers and investors do not invest in the full global market portfolio because of home bias, investors in different national equity

- 46 -

markets might require different ERPs. These variations are present across developed markets.

220. Variations in ERP across countries could be caused by a variety of factors. For example, different weightings of industrial sectors across national stock indices might result in different ERP estimates. In less developed stock markets, where a small number of companies account for a relatively large proportion of total market capitalisations, the effect of such a deviation in risk composition may be more pronounced than for the global average, and this could affect the ERP upward or downward. That said, such deviations are difficult to estimate with any degree of robustness in the absence of long-term data on returns.

221. Given the available data, TRA is of the view that the world ERP is the best proxy for investments in Bahrain.

Comparison of Bahraini and international equity markets

222. If there is less than perfect international capital flow and there is a degree of segmentation in national equity markets, investors may require different ERPs according to the country in which they are investing. This would require estimation of an ERP specific to Bahrain. However, there is a lack of robust estimates for a

Bahrain-specific ERP that are comparable in robustness to the estimates for some other markets. Dimson, Marsh and Staunton (“DMS”), a widely used source of data on historical ERP estimates, does not report ERP estimates for either Bahrain or other Middle Eastern countries.

54

223. Direct estimation of the ERP for Bahrain based on excess returns to the Bahrain Allshare index over the risk-free rate is unlikely to be robust for the following reasons.

• the number of years of data is limited. The Bahrain Stock Exchange began operations in 1989 and the Bahrain All-share Index has existed since 2004 only.

• as discussed in section 4, there is a lack of indicators to estimate robustly the historical risk-free rate for Bahrain that must be subtracted from equity returns to estimate the ERP.

• the Bahrain All-share index is relatively illiquid compared with either the

Standard & Poor’s (“S&P”) 500 or FTSE All-world indices.

224. The relative illiquidity of the Bahrain All-share index is demonstrated by Table 3, which compares annual share turnover ratios for the Bahrain All-share index, S&P

500 and FTSE All-world indices.

Table 3 Average annual share turnover ratios

Averaging period Bahrain All-share FTSE All-world S&P 500

2-year 0.43 4.74 4.10

5-year n/a n/a 4.07

Note: Annual turnover ratios are defined as the average of the ratio between the value of shares traded per year and total market capitalisation.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

                                                       

54

Dimson, E., Marsh, P. and Staunton, M. (2009), “Global Investment Returns Sourcebook 2009”,

London Business School/Credit Suisse.

- 47 -

225. The approach adopted in this Determination is to compare the Bahraini equity market with international equity markets to identify whether there are any material differences in the patterns of returns and volatility, and whether there is any compelling evidence to suggest that the Bahraini ERP differs materially from the world ERP.

226. Figure 14 presents the Bahrain All-share, S&P 500 and FTSE All-world indices (rebased) over the past five years. The Bahrain All-share index closely follows both the

S&P 500 and FTSE All-world indices, suggesting that realised returns may have been similar over multi-year time horizons.

Figure 14 Equity indices over the past five years

200

180

160

140

120

100

80

60

40

20

0

Jul-04 Nov-04 Mar-05 Jun-05 Oct-05 Feb-06 Jun-06 Oct-06 Feb-07 Jun-07 Oct-07 Feb-08 Jun-08 Oct-08 Feb-09

Bahrain All-share FTSE All-world S&P 500

Note: Equity indices have been rebased to 100 in July 2004.

Source: Bloomberg.

227. Table 4 presents estimates of the annualised volatility of the Bahrain All-share, S&P

500 and FTSE All-world indices measured using monthly returns over 2- and 5-year periods. When measured monthly, the volatility of the Bahrain All-share index is similar to that of the S&P 500 and FTSE All-world indices. The differences observed in the case of weekly returns are likely to be caused by the low liquidity of the

Bahrain Stock Exchange compared with the stock exchanges on which the US and world indices are based, hence little weight is placed on weekly returns in this section.

55

                                                       

55

Furthermore, the low liquidity of the Bahrain Stock Exchange index might be one reason for the less than perfect correlation between returns on the Bahraini index and those on international stock indices.

- 48 -

Table 4 Annualised volatility of returns (%)

Weekly

Bahrain All-share FTSE All-world S&P 500

2-year 12.8 20.9 20.4

5-year 13.1 29.1 28.4

Monthly

2-year 19.1 19.1 21.9

5-year 14.6 16.3 16.9

Note: Annualised volatility is estimated as the annualised standard deviation of weekly and monthly returns on equity indices.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

228. Given the evidence presented above, there does not appear to have been a material difference between the returns or volatility of the Bahraini, US and world equity markets on a monthly basis over the past five years. If anything, the data suggests that the Bahraini equity market exhibits lower volatility, and hence might be associated with lower risk. However, owing to the limited number of years of data and the uncertainty inherent in estimates of the ERP, it is not possible to reach a firm conclusion about the ERP for Bahrain from this data.

229. TRA therefore considers that the best estimate of the ERP for Bahrain would be the world ERP. The issue of liquidity is not a factor priced by the CAPM and is therefore addressed separately.

Estimation of the ERP

230. The ERP can be estimated from long-run averages of historical data, or implied from current market data. The ERP implied by current market data may be more representative of the forward-looking ERP. However, this technique produces volatile results that are sensitive to assumptions about the risk-free rate and longrun growth rates of dividends or earnings.

231. TRA considers that robust ERP estimates from independent sources based on longrun averages of historical data constitute a more appropriate basis for estimating a stable long-run ERP for use in a regulatory determination of the cost of capital.

232. Historical data on equity returns in excess of the risk-free rate is available for a number of mature equity markets. As such, the choice of equity market to use as a benchmark is also an important determinant of the estimated ERP. Given that there is wide variation between historical excess equity returns across geographic markets, TRA considers that a robust approach to estimating the world ERP is to use an average across these markets.

233. The estimated ERP also varies according to whether bonds or bills are used to estimate the risk-free rate. Given that yield curves tend to be upward-sloping, measures against bills of relatively short maturity tend to be higher than those against long-term bonds. An important consideration is consistency with the maturity used for the risk-free rate. Given the time horizon adopted for the risk-free rate, this

Determination considers measures of the ERP against longer-term bonds.

234. Estimates of the ERP using historical data can be based on geometric or arithmetic averages. Geometric averages are lower than arithmetic averages and produce what can be seen as an unbiased forecast over a very long time horizon. Arithmetic

- 49 -

averages produce unbiased forecasts for one-year time horizons, according to academic research—a weighted average of the two could be appropriate for a forecast time horizon of two years, with the majority of the weight being placed on arithmetic averages.

56

235. The latest geometric average of historical equity returns in excess of the risk-free rate for the international equity markets that comprise the world portfolio is 3.4%

(see Table 5). This may be viewed as a reasonable estimate of the world ERP over a long time horizon. For the purpose of a forecast over a two-year time horizon,

TRA considers the arithmetic average of 4.6% to be more appropriate, assuming that the ERP required by investors is currently similar to its long-term average level.

Table 5 Worldwide equity risk premiums relative to bonds, 1900–2008 (%)

Country Geometric mean Arithmetic mean Standard error Standard deviation

World 3.4 4.6 1.5 15.6

Note: The world ERP estimates represent averages of the estimates for 17 national equity markets.

Source: Dimson, E., Marsh, P. and Staunton, M. (2009), “Global Investment Returns Sourcebook 2009”,

London Business School/Credit Suisse.

236. Estimates of the ERP based on historical data are subject to some degree of uncertainty. This uncertainty is reflected in the relatively large standard errors on estimates of the ERP seen in Table 5. The standard error of the estimate for the world ERP is 1.5%, which suggests that a range of 1% between the low and high estimates of the ERP is required to reflect the uncertainty of this estimate.

Therefore, TRA considers that a range of 4.1–5.1% would be an appropriate estimate for the world ERP.

Regulatory precedents for the ERP

237. As there is conceptually a single, world ERP applicable to all companies and sectors, it is useful to consider the ERP used by a range of international regulators as a cross-check. The selection of regulatory benchmarks presented in Table 5 indicates a range from 3.0 to 6.0%. The range of 4.1–5.1% for the world ERP is therefore consistent with regulatory precedent.

                                                       

56

The formula for the weight to be placed on the arithmetic average is k=1 – H/T, where H is the number of years in the forecast horizon and T is the number of years in the historical average. Therefore, in the case of Bahrain, the weight on the arithmetic average might be approximately 0.981 = 1 – 2/108.

For more details, see Jacquier, E., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. (2005), “Optimal Estimation of the Risk

Premium for the Long Run and Asset Allocation: A Case of Compounded Estimation Risk”, Journal of

Financial Econometrics , 3 :1, 37–55.

- 50 -

Table 6 Regulatory benchmarks on ERP estimates (%)

Country Regulator

New Zealand Commerce Commission of New

Zealand (2009)

Company

All regulated companies

UK

UK

Ofcom (2009)

Ofcom (2009)

BT Openreach

Rest of BT

Eircom

UK

5.5

1

4.5–5.0

4.5–5.0

4.8–6.0

3.0–5.0

KPN 6.0

UK

New Zealand

Ofcom (2005)

Commerce Commission of New

Zealand (2005)

BT copper access

Telecom

New Zealand Ltd

4.0–5.0

5.5

1

KPN 6.0

Note:

1

The Commerce Commission of New Zealand applies the simplified Brennan-Lally CAPM to estimate the cost of equity. As such, the equity risk premium of 7.0% must be adjusted down by the risk-free rate multiplied by the rate of personal income tax, resulting in an ERP of approximately 5.5%, assuming a risk-free rate of approximately 4.5% and a personal income tax rate of 33%.

Source: Regulatory documents.

The effects of the recent financial turmoil

238. When using long time periods to derive more precise estimates of the historical

ERP, the greater statistical precision of averages over long time periods has to be balanced against the consideration that, over the short term, the ERP may deviate from its long-term average level, and therefore historical data may not be an accurate estimate of the current ERP. As such, TRA proposes to use an estimate based on an average over a longer time period, but adjusted to reflect current market evidence. This reflects a conservative approach.

239. One source of market data that can be used to infer the current ERP and the likelihood of it being above or below its long-run average over the next few years is the volatility implied by the prices of call options on a broad equity index. These prices reflect, among other factors, the price that investors are willing to pay for insurance against equity risk, and hence would be expected to be positively correlated with the ERP. This relationship between implied volatility (“IV") and the

ERP has been empirically verified.

57

Figure 15 shows the level of IV on the S&P 500 index.

                                                       

57

See, for example, Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A. and MacKinley, C. (1997), The Econometrics of Financial

Markets , Princeton University Press; Scruggs, J.T. (1998), “Resolving the Puzzling Intertemporal

Relation Between the Market Risk Premium and the Conditional Market Variance: A Two Factor

Approach”, Journal of Finance , 53 :2; Bliss, R. and Panigirtzoglou, N. (2004). “Option-implied Risk

Aversion Estimates”, The Journal of Finance , 59 , 407–43.

- 51 -

Figure 15 S&P 500 implied and historical volatilities

70%

60%

50%

40%

1800

1600

1400

1200

1000

800

30%

600

20%

400

10%

200

0%

Jan-02 Jan-03 Jan-04 Jan-05

3-month implied volatility

Source: Datastream, TRA calculations.

June 5th 2009

Jan-06 Jan-07

3-month historic standard deviation

Jan-08

S&P 500

Jan-09

0

240. After the onset of the financial crisis in August 2007, the level of IV on the S&P 500 increased significantly from its long-term level of approximately 15–20% and then decreased sharply at the end of 2008. However, at approximately 30% it currently remains above its long-term level. This suggests that the forward-looking ERP may have increased since August 2007 and may be higher at present than its long-term average, as suggested by an analysis of historical returns.

241. Although the ERP is likely to have increased relative to its long-term average, statistical ERP estimates based on data for short time horizons are inherently uncertain. Therefore, a precise estimation of the magnitude of potentially increased returns required by investors is not possible. In order to reflect the evidence of the potential increase in required returns in equity markets, TRA proposes an uplift of

50bp to the long-run historical arithmetic average world ERP of 4.6%, yielding a point estimate of 5.1% for the forward-looking ERP within a 4.6–5.6% range. This reflects the conservative approach adopted by TRA to the estimation of the allowed rate of return.

Liquidity premium

242. The evidence presented suggests that the Bahraini market is characterised by relatively low liquidity. Therefore, it might be reasonable to assume that both local and international investors would require compensation for being exposed to liquidity risk. This risk includes the possibility of large bid–ask spreads and trading costs, which would reduce expected returns. Hence, although there is no explicit theoretical basis for a liquidity premium under the CAPM framework, an additional liquidity premium might need to be applied to the ERP.

243. Empirical studies have provided some evidence that supports the proposition that liquidity is a factor that investors price into required returns on equity. An early

- 52 -

exposition of the hypothesis that expected return is an increasing function of the bid–ask spread was provided by Amihud and Mendelson (1986).

58

244. Compensation for differences in liquidity across firms within a single equity market has been found to account for a significant component of returns in developed equity markets.

59

Recently, this empirical analysis has been extended to differences in liquidity between equity markets, where positive relationships between liquidity and equity returns have been measured.

60

245. The extent to which return premiums represent compensation for liquidity rather than for other factors not priced by the CAPM (such as market capitalisation and market to book value ratios) is unclear.

61

Nevertheless, as shown by Table 3, one measure of liquidity—the equity turnover ratio—indicates that the Bahrain Stock

Exchange is significantly less liquid than the US stock market. This suggests that the ERP estimated for more developed stock markets may underestimate the returns required by an investor in the Bahrain All-share index.

246. A potential source of evidence on the magnitude of the liquidity premium is given in

Acharya and Pedersen (2003), which shows that a security’s required return depends on both its expected illiquidity and the covariances of its own return and illiquidity with market return and market illiquidity.

62

The study constructed 25 valueweighted portfolios for all common shares listed on the New York Stock Exchange

(“NYSE”) and American Stock Exchange (“AMEX”) over the period 1964–99, and estimated a variant of the CAPM that controlled for differences in liquidity. The difference in excess returns between the least and most liquid portfolios was approximately 60bp.

247. Acharya and Pedersen estimated a measure of the liquidity premium for the least liquid US stocks compared with the most liquid. This study therefore does not provide a direct estimate of the liquidity premium that an investor in a company listed on the Bahrain Stock Exchange might expect compared with one listed on a more developed equity index. In particular, the liquidity premium for large companies in local stock markets might be smaller than that for the least liquid stocks in mature stock markets. However, it does suggest an order of magnitude for the premium that might be expected.

248. Given the evidence that additional premiums are required to compensate for investments in illiquid securities, and that the Bahrain Stock Exchange is less liquid than more developed equity markets, TRA considers that for the purposes of calculating the cost of capital in this Determination, a premium of 50bp is appropriate to allow for the additional illiquidity of the Bahrain Stock Exchange compared with the equity markets used to estimate the ERP.

                                                       

58

Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. (1986), “Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread”, Journal of Financial

Economics , 17 , 223–49.

59

Gibson, R. and Mougeot, N. (2004), “The pricing of systematic liquidity risk: Empirical evidence from the US stock market”, Journal of Banking & Finance , 28 , 157–78.

60

Baekart, G., Harvey, C.R. and Lundblad, C. (2007), “Liquidity and Expected Returns: Lessons from

Emerging Markets”, The Review of Financial Studies , 20 :6, 1783–831.

61

Rouwenhorst, G. (1999), “Local Return Factors and Turnover in Emerging Stock Markets”, Journal of

Finance , 54 :4, August.

62

Acharya, V. and Pedersen, L. (2003), “Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk”, Journal of Financial

Economics, 77 :2, 375-410.

- 53 -

Proposed estimate of the ERP

The Draft Determination

249. Based on the analysis set out above, TRA considers that an appropriate range for the ERP is 5.1–6.1%. This is based on an estimated range of 4.1–5.1% for the world ERP, a 50bp premium for the effects of financial turmoil, and a 50bp premium for the relative illiquidity of the Bahraini equity market compared with more mature equity markets. The additional premiums applied to the base ERP estimates reflect the conservative approach adopted by TRA to the estimation of the required returns.

Responses to the Draft Determination

250. Batelco stated that “the typical marginal investor in Batelco is likely to hold a domestic or regional portfolio of assets.”

63

Batelco therefore estimated the ERP for a developed economy and then applied an uplift to “reflect the difference between the

EMRP for Bahrain and a developed economy”.

64

251. Batelco estimated the ERP to have been 4.5% for a developed economy prior to the onset of financial turmoil, based on a selection of studies of the ex post and ex ante

ERP that is predominantly focused on estimates for the US, UK, French, and

Canadian markets.

252. Batelco considered that, with respect to the effects of the current financial turmoil on the ERP, “an uplift of 0.5% is appropriate and consistent with TRA’s view”.

65

253. Batelco expressed the view that “the expected EMRP for less developed and emerging markets such as Bahrain would typically be higher than that for developed markets to account for higher levels of equity market volatility.”

66

254. Batelco estimated the size of the uplift by examining the ERP used in a selection of determinations by telecommunications regulators since 2004. The difference between the average ERP used by regulators in “maturing developed” markets

(Spain, Portugal, Ireland) and in “matured developed” markets (the UK, France,

Norway, Belgium, Italy) was assessed by Batelco to be approximately 200bp.

Batelco then stated that “given that Bahrain is less developed than the sample of maturing developed markets examined above, it is likely to warrant a greater uplift than 2 percentage points”,

67

and proposed an uplift of 200–300bp.

255. Batelco’s overall recommended ERP is 7–8%, incorporating a pre-financial turmoil

ERP for a developed economy, the effects of the current financial turmoil, and a

‘developing-market’ uplift.

64

65

66

67

68

256. Batelco also applied a default risk premium of 1.7% to account for “non payment of interest or principal”.

68

Batelco did not include this in either the ERP or in the riskfree rate so it is not clear where this parameter is intended to fit into the CAPM framework, but TRA has considered this element of Batelco’s submission in this section on the ERP.

                                                       

63

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 35.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 35.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’“, August 23rd, p. 38.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 38.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 39.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 35.

- 54 -

257. Zain stated that the ERP range proposed by TRA “appears to be well formulated”.

69

However, Zain raised the issue of whether a geometric average of historical equity market excess returns would be more appropriate than an arithmetic average, given that “Bahraini operators such as, for example, Batelco and Zain, will be in operation in the Kingdom for the long term.”

70

Zain stated that estimating the ERP on the basis of a geometric average would reduce the ERP by 1.2%. It is not clear from Zain’s response whether Zain is proposing such a reduction.

258. Lightspeed agreed with TRA’s proposed range for the ERP.

TRA analysis and conclusion

259. Batelco has not provided any primary evidence to support the statement that there is a difference in the ERP for Bahrain and a developed economy apart from the reference to equity market volatility. Although Batelco suggests that the ERP for markets such as Bahrain would “typically be higher than that for developed markets to account for higher levels of equity market volatility”,

71

TRA’s analysis in Figure 4 of the volatility of returns on the Bahrain All-share index indicates that volatility is lower in comparison with either the FTSE All-world or the S&P 500.

260. Batelco stated that higher equity market volatility would be expected as a result of a number of risk factors, including “higher political risk, higher liquidity premia, weaker corporate governance structure and legal framework”.

72

The combined effect of all of these risk factors would be expected to be captured in the country risk premium and therefore has been allowed for by TRA by including the country risk premium in the estimates.

261. Regarding liquidity, TRA has sought to quantify the order of magnitude of the premium investors might require in addition to the country risk premium, as compensation for the lower liquidity of the Bahrain All-share index relative to the national equity indices on which the estimate of the world ERP is based. TRA is therefore of the view that the additional risk of investing in Bahrain equities, relative to a diversified world equity index, is adequately represented by the country risk premium and an uplift of 50bp to the world ERP to compensate investors for lower liquidity of the Bahraini market. To the extent that lower liquidity might be already captured by the country risk premium, this reflects TRA’s overall conservative approach to this Determination.

262. Batelco’s segmentation of past regulatory determinations into “matured developed” and “maturing developed” markets does not provide robust information on fundamental differences in the ERP between different countries. It is to be expected that, for an uncertain parameter such as the ERP, different regulators at different points in time will adopt different values. This is because the actual ERP and the level of uncertainty around estimates of the ERP are likely to be different at different points in time. For example, the ERP used by one of the regulators in Batelco’s

“maturing developed” markets category, PTC, was 125bp higher in 2007 in comparison with the ERP used by PTC in 2006. The ERP set by regulators also involves a degree of judgment.

                                                       

69

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

70

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

71

72

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 38.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’“, August 23rd, p. 38.

- 55 -

263. While regulatory precedents can be used to cross-check estimates based on primary market evidence, regulatory precedents are insufficient as the basis for estimating any of the parameters of the cost of capital for regulated telecommunications operators in Bahrain at any particular point in time. Batelco’s submission appears to share this view when discussing the equity beta: “a degree of caution needs to be exercised when interpreting this evidence since it is likely to include an element of judgement by regulators rather than being based on primary market data.”

73

264. TRA’s analysis of the pattern of returns and volatility for the Bahraini equity market relative to international equity markets (Tables 3 and 4, and Figure 14 above) does not suggest a material difference or support a clear differential in the ERP for the

Bahraini equity market relative to a more developed equity market. Therefore, in the absence of a robust estimate for an ERP specific to Bahrain, TRA considers that the world ERP is the best proxy and that the “developing market uplift” advocated by

Batelco is not justified.

265. Regarding the appropriate weighting of geometric and arithmetic averages to estimate the world ERP, TRA agrees that, as the length of the forecast time period increases, an unbiased forecast of the ERP, based on historical averages, will place increasing weight on the geometric average. This will reduce the estimate of the

ERP.

266. However, even if Zain’s statement that “indefinite renewals beyond two years should be assumed”

74

is reasonable, TRA does not consider that this would justify using a forecast horizon for assessing the ERP greater than a maturity consistent with the risk-free rate. The minimum weight on the arithmetic average that could be justified under this approach is 94%.

75

TRA therefore maintains that the arithmetic average of historical returns is the appropriate basis for estimating the forward-looking ERP.

267. Regarding the default risk premium proposed by Batelco, TRA does not consider that this is an appropriate component of the cost of equity. As described by Batelco, this relates to the risk of “non payment of interest or principal”,

76

which appears to be relevant to the estimation of the cost of debt. The nature of equity securities is that they do not bear contractual obligations to make interest or principal payments, and as such cannot contain default risk. Since a default risk premium does not appear in the calculation of returns expected by equity investors, TRA does not see the basis for considering the inclusion of a default risk premium.

268. In summary, TRA maintains the position that an appropriate range for the ERP is

5.1–6.1%, based on an estimated range of 4.1–5.1% for the world ERP, a 50bp premium for the effects of the current financial turmoil, and a 50bp premium for the relative illiquidity of the Bahraini equity market in comparison with more mature equity markets.

                                                       

73

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’“, August 23rd, p. 41.

74

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

75

Assuming a forecast horizon of seven years, consistent with the upper end of the range for the maturity of the risk-free rate. This leads to the weight on the arithmetic average being approximately

0.935 = 1 – 7/108. For more details, see Jacquier, E., Kane, A. and Marcus, A. (2005), “Optimal

Estimation of the Risk Premium for the Long Run and Asset Allocation: A Case of Compounded

Estimation Risk”, Journal of Financial Econometrics , 3 :1, 37–55.

76

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 35.

- 56 -

Equity beta

269. The equity beta reflects the exposure to systematic risk of a company’s equity relative to the overall equity market risk.

A range of evidence can be used to estimate equity betas, including direct estimates of betas for companies under consideration and indirect estimates based on comparator companies.

270. In principle, beta estimation can be done for regulated telecommunications services in aggregate, and potentially also for disaggregated business activities. In practice, the latter poses significant empirical challenges in order to arrive at robust estimates. This section explores methods for estimating beta, and discusses potential risk differentials across different businesses in the telecommunications market.

271. The remainder of the section is structured as follows:

• the analytical framework for estimating beta at the aggregate and disaggregate levels is outlined before presenting direct estimates of the equity beta and estimates from comparator companies;

• regulatory precedents for asset betas are then presented;

• the potential for systematic risk differentials between different business areas in the Bahraini market context is examined;

• lastly, ranges for the beta for regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain are proposed.

Analytical framework for estimating beta

272. The beta measures the sensitivity of an investment’s return to the market return.

The equity beta of the overall equity market is equal to one, and, by construction, the market capitalisation weighted average of the equity betas for the constituents of the market must also equal one. Therefore, the equity beta for an individual company can be interpreted as the amount of systematic or non-diversifiable risk that the company contributes to the market portfolio.

273. The analytical framework used for estimating equity beta in this Determination is depicted in Figure 16.

- 57 -

Figure 16 Analytical framework for estimating equity beta

Fixed-line

Aggregate beta

Potential disaggregation

Mobile

Within fixed-line

Potential sources of evidence

Direct estimation

Potential sources of evidence

Comparator analysis

Comparator analysis

Risk metrics

Regulatory precedent

Regulatory precedent

Source: TRA.

274. The first step is to estimate a beta for all regulated services in aggregate—ie, at the company level. Three sources of evidence are considered:

• direct estimation of the equity betas of regulated telecommunications companies operating in Bahrain: Batelco and Zain;

• analysis of a wider sample of betas for telecommunications companies comparable to Batelco and Zain;

• regulatory precedents for estimates of betas in the telecommunications sector.

275. Once the beta has been estimated at the aggregate level, the extent to which different business areas might have different exposures to systematic risk needs to be considered. Where any differences are found, these need to be quantified where possible, and supported by robust evidence that allows the delineation of potentially different levels of systematic risk for different telecommunications services with sufficient certainty. TRA has considered the potential for disaggregation at three levels:

• between fixed-line and mobile;

• fixed-line;

• for new property developments compared with existing infrastructure.

276. The sources of evidence available to assess risk differentials between different business areas include:

• analysis of betas for companies judged to be “pure-play” comparators to different business areas;

• analysis of risk metrics based on accounting or operational data for different business areas;

• regulatory precedents for the disaggregation of beta.

277. Equity betas are a function of both the systematic risk of the business and the financial risk deriving from a company’s choice of capital structure. Therefore, each

- 58 -

comparator equity beta must be un-levered according to the appropriate leverage ratio to ensure like-for-like comparison. The asset betas must then be re-levered using the forward-looking leverage ratio estimated for the company or market of interest, which produces an estimate of the forward-looking equity beta.

Equity beta estimation: direct estimates

278. Direct estimates of the asset betas for Zain and Batelco are presented in Table 7.

These have been obtained using regression analysis measuring the correlation of equity returns for these companies with returns on either the local equity markets where the companies are listed or the world equity market.

279. The asset betas presented in the table are derived from Bayesian-adjusted estimates of equity betas, which are calculated as: 2/3

×

raw beta estimate + 1/3

×

1. This adjustment controls for the tendency of statistical analysis to overestimate betas higher than one and underestimate betas lower than one.

77

As equity betas for network companies are often lower than one, this adjustment will tend to produce larger and hence more conservative beta estimates.

280. The betas are based on weekly returns over two- and five-year time horizons, and monthly returns over a five-year horizon. There is no consensus regarding the frequency of data to use in such analysis. On the one hand, from a theoretical perspective, betas measured using more frequent data are likely to be more affected by statistical biases such as autocorrelation than those measured using less frequent data. This is because of the impact of factors such as thin and nonsynchronous trading. On the other hand, betas measured using more frequent data tend to be less uncertain (which would be reflected by narrower confidence intervals). This is because the use of shorter frequencies leads to more observations for the same estimation period.

281. Because of the potential for illiquid stock markets to affect the results, no beta is estimated using daily data, in order to minimise the risk that the estimates are affected by statistical biases and noise.

Table 7 Asset betas: direct estimates (adjusted

1

)

Local

2 weekly weekly

5-year monthly

2-year weekly

5-year weekly

5-year monthly

Zain 0.91 0.72 0.63 0.39 0.39 0.66

Notes: Asset betas are based on the equity beta and gearing estimates presented in the tables in Appendix 4.

Asset beta is defined as equity beta multiplied by one minus gearing plus debt beta multiplied by gearing, where debt beta is assumed to be equal to zero.

1

Calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: 2/3*raw beta +

1/3. Raw betas represent estimated coefficients from a regression where returns on the equity are regressed on returns on either the local or the world index (see Tables A5 to A7 in Appendix 4).

2

The stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, Bahrain Stock Exchange index and Kuwait Stock

Exchange index are the local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

282. Table 7 indicates that when measured against the FTSE All-world index betas are consistently lower than when measured against the relevant local indices. This suggests that investors active in the local market may not always hold investment

                                                       

77

Blume, M.E. (1968), “On the Assessment of Risk”, Journal of Finance , 43 , March.

- 59 -

portfolios that are internationally diversified, and that betas measured against local indices might be influenced by home bias. Alternatively, it could mean that these companies have very low systematic risk.

283. A domestic investor with an investment portfolio that is relatively undiversified across international markets might expect to require compensation for exposure to the systematic risk of a local stock market index. Comparison of betas estimated against local market indices over five- and two-year time horizons suggests that

Zain’s systematic risk may have increased, while that of Batelco has decreased over time. As betas are measured at the group level, it is possible that the beta for

Zain may have increased as a result of the acquisition of an 85% stake in the

African mobile operator, Celtel, in 2005.

78

284. Overall, the direct estimates suggest a range of 0.65–1.00 for the asset beta relevant to a domestic investor, though it should be noted that these estimates suffer from limitations (see below). These estimates are based on the assumption that the local investor does not diversify optimally across markets. Thus, from the theoretical point of view, using these estimates might overstate the required rates of return.

285. Direct estimation of Batelco’s equity beta against the Bahrain All-share index is not likely to give a robust estimate of the company’s systematic risk exposure. Batelco’s market capitalisation is around 13% of the overall market capitalisation of the

Bahrain Stock Exchange.

79

Hence, the returns on the Bahrain All-share index can be significantly influenced by those on Batelco. By virtue of the way the index is constructed, an estimation of beta against this index is likely to be close to one. This suggests that estimates of beta against the FTSE All-world index would be preferable from both a theoretical and empirical point of view.

286. Estimates of beta against both local and international indices may also be distorted because Batelco’s equity is infrequently traded.

80

As such, its equity returns are likely to provide a relatively poor signal of expected changes in company value compared with equity returns for stocks quoted on more liquid exchanges in the

USA or Europe. Given that beta estimation is based on statistical analysis, the estimate becomes less reliable when less frequent data is used. The extent to which investors demand an additional risk premium for the relative illiquidity of Batelco’s equity was considered in the equity risk premium section.

287. These data issues are also problematic for estimating Zain’s equity beta, although to a lesser extent than for Batelco, given more frequent trading of Zain’s equity (as measured by the share turnover ratio). The impact of these issues is also reduced when betas are estimated against international equity indices. However, Zain beta estimated at the group level may not be representative as the geographic scale and scope of Zain activities has dramatically changed over the last five years.

288. An investor with an internationally diversified portfolio would consider company risk relative to an international market index. Table 7 suggests that, on this basis, betas estimated from weekly data have been relatively stable over the past five years, and that a range of 0.40–0.70 would be relevant for an international investor.

                                                       

78

Zain corporate website: http://www.zain.com/muse/obj/lang.default/portal.view/content/About us/Overview/Milestones

79

Bloomberg.

80

Over the past year the average share turnover ratio for Batelco—the total value of Batelco equity traded per day as a percentage of Batelco’s market capitalisation—is less than 1%.

- 60 -

289. The direct estimation of beta therefore suggests that ranges of 0.40–0.70 and 0.65–

1.00 may be appropriate estimates of the asset beta for an international and a domestic investor respectively.

Equity beta estimation: comparator analysis

290. An alternative source of evidence is an analysis of comparator companies. By using information on a wider sample of companies, this approach could mitigate the concerns about the robustness of direct estimates.

291. Cluster analysis was used to select the comparator companies. Peer comparators were identified through a two-step approach. The first step involved the identification of markets comparable to Bahrain according to selected characteristics of telecommunications markets.

Total population allows the identification of markets of similar size. The size of the market might be important for several reasons, including its impact on the number of operators that may be supported and the potential for economies of scale.

The proportion of urban population might be an indicator of the cost structure of the market. For example, the high proportion of urban population in Bahrain might be expected to lower the cost per subscriber of operating a telecommunications network compared with less urbanised countries.

GDP per head indicates the level of income per capita, and might therefore be seen as an indicator of the overall wealth of the country, and hence the potential willingness to pay and demand for telecommunications services.

Fixed-line telephony penetration might indicate the degree of development of fixed-line telephony in the market, while mobile telephony penetration would indicate the importance of mobile telephony in the market. Implicitly, the combination of these two metrics would capture the mix of fixed and mobile telephony in the market.

The provides a measure of the status of the broadband market and the potential for its growth.

292. These criteria have been used to identify markets with characteristics similar to those observed in Bahrain.

81

The analysis identifies a cluster of markets (see

Table 8).

Table 8 Comparator markets

Country

Cluster Qatar, Kuwait, Slovenia, Greece, Portugal, Cyprus, Estonia, Slovak Republic, Romania,

Poland, Latvia, Hungary, Croatia, Lithuania, Czech Republic, Bulgaria, United Arab

Emirates.

Source: TRA.

293. The second step of the analysis involved identifying which of the listed companies from the comparable markets are most comparable to Batelco and Zain. The companies were allocated to two clusters (a Batelco and a Zain cluster) depending

                                                       

81

These countries were selected from the dendrogram presented in Appendix 3 (Figure A1).

- 61 -

on their level of dissimilarity to Batelco or Zain—estimated using the three-year average values for the company characteristics outlined below.

82

The proportion of revenue from mobile activities helps to identify whether a company’s primary activity is the provision of mobile telecommunications services. This enables the identification of companies with a similar business mix to Batelco and Zain.

Enterprise value (“EV”) represents the market value of the company, and allows identification of companies of similar size to Batelco and Zain.

The is a measure of the intensity of a company’s capital investment programme. CAPEX might be regarded as an important additional source of risk since it can substantially reduce net cash flows in the short term.

The EV to EBITDA (“earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation”) identifies companies with similar levels of profitability.

Companies with higher profitability might be expected to be able to absorb market shocks more easily.

294. Using these criteria, two potential clusters were identified (see Table 9).

Table 9 Comparator markets and telecommunications operators

Company

Cluster 1

(Zain)

TEO LT AB, National Mobile Telecommunication Company KSC, Qatar Telecom Q-Tel

QSC, Etihad Etisalat Company

Cluster 2

(Batelco)

Tele2 AB, Hellenic Telecomm Organize SA, Magyar Telekom Telecommunications Plc,

Hrvatske Telekom, Telekomunikacja Polska SA, Telekom Austria AG, Portugal Telecom

SA, Eesti Telecom, Elisa OYJ, Telefonica O2 Czech Republic AS

Source: TRA.

295. Table 10 presents the results of beta estimation from the comparator analysis based on clustering of companies.

83

                                                       

82

The dendrogram that shows the level of dissimilarity of companies used in the analysis is presented in

Appendix 3 (Figure A2).

83

Table A9 in Appendix 4 provides a detailed review of comparator asset betas.

- 62 -

Table 10 Asset betas: comparator companies (adjusted

1

)

Local

2 weekly weekly

5-year monthly

2-year weekly

5-year weekly

5-year monthly

Zain’s comparators

Average 0.75 0.72 0.59 0.51 0.49 0.58

Batelco’s comparators

Average 0.65 0.65 0.59 0.58 0.59 0.58

Average

(overall)

0.68 0.67 0.59 0.56 0.56 0.58

Notes: Asset betas are based on the equity beta and gearing estimates presented in Tables A5 to A8 in

Appendix 4. Asset beta is defined as equity beta multiplied by one minus gearing plus debt beta multiplied by gearing, where debt beta is assumed to be equal to zero.

1

Calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: (twothirds)*raw beta + (one-third). Raw betas represent estimated coefficients from a regression where returns on the equity are regressed on returns on either the local or the world index (see Tables A5 to A7 in Appendix 4).

2

The stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, Bahrain Stock Exchange index and Kuwait Stock Exchange index are the local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

296. A domestic investor with an investment portfolio that is relatively undiversified across international markets may require compensation for exposure to the systematic risk of a local stock market index. Overall, the averages across comparator estimates suggest a range of 0.60–0.70 for the asset beta relevant to a domestic investor.

297. In contrast, an investor with an internationally diversified portfolio would consider company risk relative to an international market index. Similarly to the direct estimates of betas for Batelco and Zain, betas for comparator companies estimated against the FTSE All-world index are lower than betas estimated against local equity indices. This suggests that investors benefit from international diversification and consequently might be expected to target lower required returns. The averages across comparator estimates in Table 10 suggest that a range of 0.55–0.60 would be relevant for an international investor.

Regulatory precedents

298. Recent European regulatory precedents on the cost of capital could also provide a potentially useful reference point for the asset beta for telecommunications companies. However, a degree of caution needs to be exercised when interpreting this evidence since it is likely to include an element of judgement by regulators rather than being based on primary market data. Table 11 summarises a selection of regulatory precedents for fixed-line operators. They range from 0.45 to 0.80.

- 63 -

Table 11 Selected precedents for fixed-line beta

Regulator and year of

Ofcom (2009)

Ofcom (2009)

ComReg (2008)

ARCEP (2008)

UK

UK

Ireland

BT Openreach

BT Group

0.55

1

0.68

1

Eircom 0.45–0.70

Telecom

OPTA (2006)

FICORA (2006)

Netherlands

Finland

KPN

Fixed-line operators

0.66

0.65–0.80

BIPT (2006) Belgium Belgacom 0.72

Commerce Commission of New

Zealand (2005)

New Zealand Telecom New Zealand 0.50–0.80

Ofcom (2005) UK BT copper access 0.56–0.59

1

0.80

1

Ofcom (2005) UK Rest of BT Group

Note:

1

Asset betas were implied from the reported equity betas, gearing and an assumption of a zero debt beta.

Sources: Ofcom (2009), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach”, May 22nd; ComReg (2008), “Eircom’s

Cost of Capital: Response to Consultation and Decision Notice”, May 22nd; ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163 ; NERA (2006), “The cost of capital for KPN’s wholesale activities”, a final report for OPTA, February 21st; FICORA (2006), “Assessment principles for the pricing of fixed network interconnection”, June 28th; BIPT (2006), “Décision du Conseil de l'IBPT du 22 Novembre 2006 Concernant le Coût du Capital à Utiliser Dans les offres de Référence de Belgacom”, November 22nd; Commerce

Commission of New Zealand (2005), “Draft Determination on the Application for Pricing Review for

Designated Interconnection Services”, April 11th; Ofcom (2005), “Ofcom’s approach to risk in the assessment of the cost of capital”, August 18th.

299. Betas evolve over time as the systematic risk of a company or industry changes relative to the overall equity market. For the 2005 Determination, TRA assumed an asset beta of 1.05. However, most recent regulatory determinations in other telecommunications markets suggest that betas are now lower.

300. In some cases, regulatory decisions on the cost of capital for mobile telecommunications have used higher estimates for asset beta than the range reported in Table 11 for fixed-line operators. For example, FICORA (2008) assumed an asset beta of 1.1–1.3 for mobile operators in Finland, and PTS (2008) assumed

1.2 for operators in Sweden.

84

However, more recent decisions have lowered the asset beta for mobile relative to fixed-line. ARCEP (2008) set equal equity betas for mobile and fixed-line by lowering the equity beta for mobile to 1.0 compared with 1.2 in the previous determination. In combination with gearing of 30% assumed by

ARCEP, this implies an asset beta of 0.7.

85

301. Overall, regulatory precedents suggest a broader and somewhat higher range for asset betas of regulated telecommunications services compared with other sources of evidence. Although there are examples of regulators assuming higher asset betas for mobile compared with fixed-line operators, based on direct estimates and comparator analysis there is no evidence to support a robust conclusion that such a differential in asset betas would be appropriate, as discussed below.

                                                       

84

Ficora (2008), “Ficora’s assessment principles for the pricing of mobile termination”, July 3rd; PTS

(2008), ‘slutlig riskfri ränta för mobil WACC”, May 6th.

85

ARCEP (2008), Decision number 2008-0162 and decision number 2008-0163.

- 64 -

Disaggregate equity beta

302. Different projects and business activities of a company might exhibit different risk characteristics. For regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain, these differences could occur along the following dimensions:

fixed-line/mobile

• within fixed-line telecommunications;

• risk differentials for new property developments.

303. As a project- or business-specific allowed rate of return may provide more economically efficient investment incentives, it is important to assess whether the level of risk might be materially different for various activities of a company, and hence whether there might be justification for adopting a split cost of capital.

Fixed/mobile risk differentials

304. One source of evidence might be to estimate risk differentials based on betas for comparator companies to mobile and fixed-line activities. However, there are very few, if any, “pure” fixed-line operators in practice, restricting the comparison to one between principally mobile and integrated operators. In the context of the Bahraini telecommunications market, mobile and integrated activities could be proxied by the comparators to Zain and Batelco respectively.

305. Table 12 reports the results of a statistical test of the difference between the average betas for the two samples of comparator companies, and suggests that there is not a statistically significant difference in the asset betas for integrated and mobile operators.

Table 12 Student’s t-test for differences between integrated and mobile asset betas

Hypothesis tested t-statistic Probability associated with t-statistic

0.81 48%

Results

Hypothesis for 1 : the average asset beta for a sample based on Zain’s comparators is equal to the average asset beta for a sample based on Batelco’s comparators (2-year, weekly, local index)

Cannot reject the hypothesis at the 95% confidence level

Hypothesis 2 : the average asset beta for a sample based on Zain’s comparators is equal to the average asset beta for a sample based on Batelco’s comparators (2-year, weekly,

FTSE All-world)

–0.74 51% Cannot reject the hypothesis at the 95% confidence level

Note: These t-test results are two-tiered and do not assume equal variance for the two samples. The rule for whether to reject the hypothesis at 95% confidence level is as follows: if the probability associated with the tstatistic is less than 5%, the hypothesis is rejected, otherwise it cannot be rejected. T-tests for asset betas estimated according to the five-year window (both weekly and monthly) give similar results.

Source: TRA.

306. Furthermore, the test in Table 12 implicitly assumes that there is no underlying uncertainty about the asset betas for the companies in the two samples. In practice, at least two sources of uncertainty are not captured by this test:

- 65 -

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.0

1.4

1.2

1.0

• asset beta estimates vary according to whether they are measured over a two- or five-year time horizon—this uncertainty is depicted by the size of the solid bars in Figure 17;

• as asset beta estimates are the result of statistical analysis, there is a degree of uncertainty around the central estimates—as represented by the lines above and below the solid bars in Figure 17.

307. Zain’s comparators are grouped on the left of Figure 17 and Batelco’s comparators are on the right. Consideration of the point estimates together with the two sources of uncertainty around these estimates suggests that, based on the sample relevant for Bahrain, there is no statistically significant difference between the asset betas for mobile and integrated operators.

Figure 17 Asset beta ranges and estimation errors

Zain's comparators

Batelco's comparators

Note: Equity beta estimates are based on local indices. The solid bars represent the ranges between the two- and five-year weekly estimates. The lines measure two standard errors above and below the bars.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

308. To the extent that betas for comparator companies do not suggest statistically significant differences, bottom-up analysis of segmental data on business characteristics might be able to capture the differences in actual risks between fixed and mobile activities. Examples of potential, measurable bottom-up risk metrics include:

• revenue, cost and profit volatility (including demand risk);

• operational gearing (fixed to variable costs);

CAPEX intensity and depreciation (including technology risk);

• growth rates (market maturity).

309. However, even if various metrics of risk differentials could be shown to be statistically significant, it is difficult to translate them robustly into WACC

- 66 -

differentials. Furthermore, even if one activity can be shown to be clearly more risky, this may represent idiosyncratic rather than non-diversifiable risk, and hence would not be priced in the CAPM. If risk differentials are implemented incorrectly there is a risk that they will distort rather than improve cost of capital estimates and hence incentives. For example, if one business activity is incorrectly judged to have less exposure to systematic risk than another activity, and the beta and WACC are lowered accordingly, the allowed return for this activity will be below the actual cost of capital, and hence discourage investment in this activity.

310. The third source of evidence which might suggest risk differentials between fixed and mobile activities is regulatory precedent. Past empirical research has indicated that there may be some risk differentials between fixed and mobile markets. For example, in the UK, when revising the charges for the provision of wholesale voice call termination in 2005, Ofcom determined that the equity beta for mobile operators was above the beta for the fixed-line business, although there are a number of issues related to these estimates.

86

311. More recently, Ofcom has noted that “one of the key trends affecting the consumer experience of communications services is convergence”.

87

From the consumer perspective, convergence might imply greater substitutability between services provided over fixed-line and mobile networks. Furthermore, as mobile and fixed-line telecommunications services increasingly compete with each other, fixed-line operators are looking to more risky areas for additional revenue and are adopting new commercial policies.

312. Regulatory determinations suggest that, in some cases, regulators have set higher asset betas for mobile than for fixed-line activities. However, the most recent determinations in 2008 by French regulator, ARCEP, set the same equity beta for both fixed and mobile activities, effectively setting the same cost of equity for the two activities and lowering the equity beta applicable to mobile operators by 0.2 compared with the previous determination.

88

313. Although a number of regulators have adopted separate asset betas for fixed-line and mobile activities, TRA considers that there is no clear consensus on this issue and, critically, that there is no robust evidence relevant to the cost of capital determination in Bahrain to support introducing such a differential. The top-down analysis of betas for comparator companies suggests that it is unlikely that a statistically significant difference exists. Even if the necessary financial and operational data to estimate risk differentials on a bottom-up basis for different business activities was available, such data would need to establish a clear relationship between the level of risk of different business units and returns to investments in equity market indices or economic growth more broadly to indicate systematic risk. Based on the above, TRA does not propose to apply separate asset betas to fixed and mobile activities.

Risk differentials within fixed-line activities

314. Another way to disaggregate the beta of the fixed-line operations of telecommunications companies is between access, core and retail operations

                                                       

86

Ofcom (2005), “Wholesale Mobile Call Termination”, Statement, June, p. 123.

87

Ofcom (2008), “The Consumer Experience 2008: Telecommunications, Internet and Digital

Broadcasting”, November 24th.

88

ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163.

- 67 -

(described below, alongside their business characteristics), often in line with the split in the regulatory accounts.

Local access network includes the customer-dedicated network components running from the local exchanges to the end-user premises (houses and businesses). It enables the company’s retail division to deliver telecommunications products to end-users. Products provided under the local access network could include unbundled local loops, wholesale terminating segments of leased lines, and wholesale broadband access.

Core network comprises all network components, with the exception of those used in the local access network. It enables a company’s customers to communicate with customers of the same or another operator, or to access services provided by another operator directly. Products provided under the core network could include wholesale call origination/termination, wholesale transit/interconnection services (national and international), and wholesale trunk segments of leased lines.

Retail business is made up of all the activities involved in the sale of services to end-users (businesses and individuals). Retail products can be broadly classified as “volume-sensitive” (eg, fixed local, national and international calls, calls to mobile, calls to the Internet, public payphones and directory enquiries), and “non-volume-sensitive” (eg, retail access and, to a lesser extent, retail broadband and leased lines). Other services include operator assistance, premium-rate services, managed answering services, and VPN/IPVPN.

315. The difficulty of finding pure-play comparators for different business areas within fixed-line activities is even greater than finding comparators for fixed-line overall.

This difficulty arises because of the lack of examples of separate parts of fixed-line businesses being operated by distinct companies with publicly traded equity.

316. There is also very limited regulatory precedent for separating out access networks from fixed-line activities more generally. In the UK, Ofcom has set a lower asset beta for Openreach, which owns the copper-access network, compared with the rest of BT Group.

89

However, given the differences between the UK and Bahraini markets, TRA places relatively little weight on this evidence.

90

317. As in the case of fixed-line compared with mobile activities, TRA does not have access to the data that would allow a robust, bottom-up estimation of risk differentials between different fixed-line activities. Therefore, TRA does not propose to apply separate asset betas to different fixed-line activities.

Risk differentials for new property developments

318. Investments in infrastructure associated with extending networks to the new property developments in Bahrain (such as the Amwaj Island) may, in principle, be exposed to a different level of risk than the infrastructure that already exists to serve the rest of Bahrain. For example, the rate at which the developments become occupied by potential telecommunications customers might make the cash flows from these developments more risky.

319. However, this does not necessarily imply a systematic risk differential between investments in these areas and the existing network infrastructure. Also, the

                                                       

89

Ofcom (2008), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach – second consultation”, December 5th.

90

The UK does not form one of the comparator markets to Bahrain identified in Table 8.

- 68 -

additional costs (if any) of servicing such areas would be appropriately taken into account in the level of investment and ongoing costs rather than the cost of capital.

320. The purpose of this Determination is to set the cost of capital based on existing levels of capital employed and CAPEX forecasts. As such, TRA does not propose to apply a separate asset beta for new property developments.

Proposed approach to equity beta

The Draft Determination

321. Based on the above analysis, TRA proposes to set the equity beta for regulated telecommunications services in aggregate, with no disaggregation between separate business areas.

322. From the perspective of an international investor, TRA considers that a range of

0.55–0.70 would be appropriate. This puts approximately equal weight on direct estimates (which range from 0.40 to 0.70) and estimates from comparator companies (which range from 0.55 to 0.60).

323. For a domestic investor, a range of 0.65–0.80 is proposed. This puts slightly less weight on direct estimates (which range from 0.65 to 1.00) compared with estimates from comparator companies (which range from 0.60 to 0.70), owing to the concerns about the statistical reliability of estimates of Batelco’s equity beta against the

Bahrain All-share index.

324. These ranges are based on evidence from both direct estimates and comparator betas regressed against international and local equity indices for the international and domestic investor respectively. The domestic investor is likely to face a higher beta as a result of holding a less diversified portfolio of investments. Although there is no theoretical basis for justifying limited diversification, this Determination takes these estimates into account.

Responses to the Draft Determination

325. Batelco agreed that it would be inappropriate to propose values for the equity beta solely on the basis of direct estimates of the beta for Batelco and Zain: “We agree with TRA in respect of the limitations encountered when directly estimating

Batelco’s equity beta and have based our estimate of Batelco’s equity beta on an analysis of companies that we believe are most comparable to the Company.”

91

326. Batelco undertook a similar two-step approach to first identify comparable markets and then to identify comparable companies operating within those markets.

327. Batelco calculated equity betas, applied the Blume adjustment, and un-levered the results to estimate asset betas for the comparator companies. These betas were estimated against both local and world equity indices, on a two-year weekly and five-year monthly basis.

328. Batelco analysed pure-play mobile and integrated companies separately, and also analysed trends over time of selected companies’ equity betas. Batelco concluded that “there should be no differential in the betas used for fixed-line and mobile operators.”

92

                                                       

91

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 42.

92

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 44.

- 69 -

329. Batelco’s proposed range for the equity beta is 0.65–0.80, “where the bottom end of the range is consistent with the average of the global beta estimates and the top end of the range is consistent with the average of the local beta estimates.”

93

330. Zain proposed that “TRA use a neutral equity beta of 1”

94

for both pure-play mobile and integrated operators.

331. Lightspeed agreed with TRA’s proposed range of 0.55–0.70 for the equity beta from the perspective of an international investor.

TRA analysis and conclusion

332. Batelco proposed a range of 0.65–0.80 for the equity beta, which is consistent with the range TRA has estimated for the domestic investor. However, based on the analysis above TRA considers that from the perspective of an international investor, a lower range for the beta is appropriate, to reflect the effects of wider portfolio diversification.

333. Based on a combination of estimates of betas relative to an international equity index for Batelco and Zain, and estimates from TRA’s sample of comparator companies, TRA remains of the view that an appropriate range for the equity beta is

0.55–0.70 from the perspective of an international investor.

334. Zain’s proposal of an equity beta of 1 suggests that the systematic risk of investing in regulated telecommunications companies is equal to the risk of investing in a broad equity market index. However, the evidence on equity betas presented in

Tables A5–7 below indicates that the comparator companies consistently have equity betas lower than 1, and hence lower risk than the average for the equity market overall.

335. Zain disagreed with TRA’s view not to disaggregate the beta between different business areas on the basis that this “does not appear to be in line with international practice”.

95

Nevertheless, Zain has not presented any evidence to support different equity betas for fixed and mobile activities in general or in Bahrain in particular; neither has Zain proposed different values for the equity betas. Therefore, TRA remains of the view that there is no additional robust evidence to support a statistically significant differential in the systematic risk exposure between fixed and mobile activities in Bahrain.

336. TRA remains of the view that the evidence suggests an appropriate range for the equity beta from the perspective of an international investor is 0.55–0.70, and an appropriate range from the perspective of a domestic investor is 0.65–0.80.

                                                       

93

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 45.

94

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

95

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination”’, August 23rd.

- 70 -

Cost of capital estimates

The Draft Determination

337. This section combines the results for individual parameters from all previous sections in order to estimate the overall cost of capital for regulated telecommunications activities in Bahrain.

96

338. The estimates of each individual cost of capital parameter are characterised by a degree of uncertainty, at least partly due to the recent financial turmoil. This uncertainty needs to be accounted for when determining the point estimate in order to ensure that the estimated rate of return allows a telecommunications company operating in Bahrain to raise necessary financing. There are at least two sources of uncertainty:

• uncertainty surrounding the current value of the parameter being estimated;

• uncertainty surrounding the potential evolution of the value of a given parameter in the future.

339. Table 13 reflects this uncertainty by presenting a range for the cost of capital for a notional telecommunications company operating in Bahrain under the base case from the perspective of an internationally diversified investor. The low and high ends of the ranges for the individual parameters are combined to give a range for the overall nominal cost of capital. For illustrative purposes, the midpoint of the overall range is also presented.

Table 13 Summary of the cost of capital parameters—base-case scenario

Parameter Low High

Nominal risk-free rate (%) 3.20 3.70

Country risk premium (%)

ERP (%)

Asset beta

Equity beta

1.50

5.10

0.55

0.55

1.50

6.10

0.70

0.70

Cost of equity (%)

WACC (nominal, %)

Source: TRA.

7.51

7.51 8.45

9.47

9.47

340. To test the sensitivity of these results to the perspective of an internationally diversified investor, Table 14 presents ranges for the cost of capital under the alternative scenario estimated from the perspective of a local, potentially less diversified investor, and using local market data.

                                                       

96

The results represent a vanilla WACC (post-tax cost of equity, pre-tax cost of debt). However, as there is no corporation tax in Bahrain, this is equal to the pre-tax WACC.

- 71 -

Table 14 Summary of the cost of capital parameters—alternative scenario

Nominal risk-free rate (%) 3.50 5.80

Country risk premium (%)

1

0.00 0.00

ERP (%)

Asset beta

5.10

0.65

6.10

0.80

Equity beta

Cost of equity (%)

0.65

6.82

WACC (nominal, %) 6.82 8.71

Note:

1

The country risk premium is implicitly included in the risk-free rate.

Source: TRA.

0.80

10.68

10.68

341. The midpoints of the estimated ranges are approximately the same and the ranges are very similar under both the base and alternative scenarios, which validates the results. These ranges are also consistent with regulatory determinations on the cost of capital for telecommunications services in other countries (see Tables A2 and

A3).

342. As discussed in the introduction, the methodology used to estimate the cost of capital has been revised to bring the analysis more into line with the best practice in cost of capital estimation and to reflect up-to-date market data. The main effects of these revisions are reflected in ERP and equity beta estimates. The fall in interest rates is another driver for the decrease in estimates of the cost of capital.

343. The midpoints of the ranges under both the base-case (8.45%) as well as the alternative scenarios (8.71%) represent a decrease from the cost of capital

Determination in 2005 (12.2%). For the purpose of this Determination, TRA proposes a cost of capital of 9.0% to apply to regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain. This point estimate is above the midpoints of the above ranges to reflect the overall objective to adopt a cautious approach to the estimation of the cost of capital estimation.

Responses to the Draft Determination

344. Batelco recommended a point estimate at the midpoint of Batelco’s proposed range:

“our estimate of the cost of capital for Batelco is in the range of 12.85% to 15.7%, resulting in a midpoint estimate of 14.28%. Taking into account the need to incentivise investment in a sector that requires significant scale, operating in a small country, we recommend a point estimate of 14.28%.”

97

345. Batelco also calculated the cost of equity implied by the sample of regulatory precedents reported in Batelco’s submission. Batelco stated that the “average implied cost of equity for maturing developed markets is 12.85%”.

98

Batelco then suggested that “the implied cost of equity average from our set of maturing developed precedents (14.28%) should serve as good indication of the lower end of the range.”

99

                                                       

97

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 48.

98

99

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 46.

Batelco (2009), “Response to TRA’s ‘Draft Determination of the Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd, p. 46.

- 72 -

346. Zain agreed with the point selection within the range, but recommended that the range be increased, principally through adjustments to the equity beta and ERP parameters, with the effect that “the cost of capital seems to be between 11 to 12% rather than the 9% indicated.”

100

347. Lightspeed proposed a point estimate at the midpoint of the range, and recommended that the range be reduced to 7.00–8.97%, with a midpoint estimate of

7.99%.

101

TRA analysis and conclusion

348. With regard to the point estimate within the range, both Batelco and Lightspeed proposed TRA adopt a lower estimate—the midpoint of the range—while Zain agreed with TRA’s selection within the range. TRA re-iterates that the decision to adopt a point estimate above the midpoint of the range was to reflect a cautious approach to setting the overall cost of capital. As the responses to the Draft

Determination did not provide justification for reducing the point estimate to the midpoint of the range, TRA does not consider that it would be appropriate to adopt the midpoint as the point estimate.

349. With regard to Batelco’s calculation of the cost of equity implied by its sample of regulatory precedents, the calculations underlying Batelco’s analysis are not presented in Batelco’s submission. It is therefore unclear how Batelco has calculated the two values that are attributed to the averages of the cost of equity implied by regulatory precedents (12.85% and 14.28%), or why these two values are different.

350. Moreover, the first value referred to by Batelco (12.85%) is exactly equal to the low end of the range for the overall cost of capital proposed by Batelco, while the second value (14.28%) is exactly equal to the midpoint of this range. This suggests the cost of equity implied by the sample of regulatory precedents may not be independent of the inputs to the primary analysis behind Batelco’s range.

351. Batelco’s calculation of the cost of equity implied by its sample of regulatory precedents does not seem to make any adjustment for the different levels of gearing implied by the sample. If this comparison were to be conducted on a basis consistent with the 100% equity capital structure proposed by TRA, the cost of equity implied by the sample of regulatory precedents would be lower than the values presented by Batelco. This is because any precedents that assume less than

100% equity financing would need to be expressed on an un-levered basis to be comparable to TRA’s proposals, which implies a lower equity beta and a lower cost of equity.

352. To the extent that regulatory precedents are relevant, Tables A2 and A3 demonstrate that the cost of capital proposed by TRA is consistent with regulatory precedents for the nominal, vanilla cost of capital in a range of other countries.

353. However, more fundamentally, even if the cost of equity implied by Batelco’s sample of regulatory precedents had been calculated correctly, the use of this data as a cross-check for the cost of equity for telecommunications operators in Bahrain implicitly assumes no major differences in markets or the risks faced by companies,

                                                       

100

Zain (2009), “Zain Bahrain Response to the TRA Consultation on the ‘Cost of Capital Draft

Determination’”, August 23rd.

101

Lightspeed (2009), “Lightspeed submission in response to the Telecommunications Regulatory

Authority (TRA) Consultation Paper on ‘Cost of Capital’”, August 23rd.

- 73 -

and no major changes in the cost of capital over time. As such, it would not be appropriate to attach much weight to regulatory precedents compared to the analysis of primary data relevant to the companies, market, and time period under consideration without accounting for a number of factors such as the evolution in the cost of capital parameters, market developments or market-specific factors.

354. The adjustments to the overall range proposed by Zain and Lightspeed are as a result of proposed adjustments to the underlying parameters. TRA has addressed these proposed adjustments in the respective sections of this Determination.

355. Overall, TRA remains of the view that it would be appropriate to apply a cost of capital of 9.0% to regulated telecommunications services in Bahrain and to regulatory accounts. This would be comparable to the vanilla WACC applied in regulatory regimes where there is corporate taxation. Since this value is above the midpoints of the range estimates for both the perspectives of an international and a domestic investor, TRA considers that it represents a cautious approach to setting the overall cost of capital value. It also contributes to providing a suitable environment for long-term investment.

356. However, in considering the need to transition from the previously determined cost of capital and to maintain some regulatory stability over time TRA considers that in this instance the cost of capital should be set at 9.5%. This point estimate lies within the upper halves of both ranges; it represents the top of the range of the base case scenario rounded up to the first decimal.

- 74 -

Appendix 1: Cost of debt

357. Although this Determination is based on the estimation of the cost of capital at zero gearing, it is useful to consider the sensitivity of the overall cost of capital to this assumption, if any. Estimation of the WACC with positive gearing requires an estimation of the cost of debt. As Batelco and Zain do not have conventional corporate bonds outstanding, a potential proxy for the debt premium is the rate paid on bank borrowing.

358. Batelco has a syndicated loan facility which charges interest at a rate of LIBOR plus

25bp. Although LIBOR is normally close to the yields on government securities of a comparable maturity, as discussed in the risk-free rate section, there is likely to be a difference between the two.

102

Therefore, TRA considers 50bp to be a conservative estimate of the debt premium over the risk-free rate.

359. Adding this spread to the nominal risk-free rate (3.2% to 3.7%) and country risk premium (1.5%) gives a range for the forward-looking cost of debt of 5.2–5.7%.

360. The equity beta also needs to be recalculated when the gearing assumption changes. Table A1 shows how the cost of equity and the WACC for an international investor change under an assumption of 20% gearing.

Table A1 Gearing sensitivity analysis

Nominal risk-free rate (%)

Country risk premium (%)

ERP (%)

Asset beta

Gearing (%)

Equity beta

Cost of equity (%)

Debt margin (%)

Cost of debt (%)

WACC (nominal, %)

Source: TRA.

3.20

1.50

5.10

0.55

20.00

0.69

8.21

0.50

5.20

7.61 8.55

361. The cost of capital under 20% gearing is between 7.61% and 9.57%. This is very similar to the range for the cost of capital under zero gearing, reflecting the offsetting effects of a higher cost of equity and a lower proportion of relatively expensive equity financing. The slight increase in the cost of capital is partly the result of assuming a zero debt beta.

3.70

1.50

6.10

0.70

20.00

0.88

10.54

0.50

5.70

9.57

                                                       

102

Zain did not disclose the borrowing rate for MTC-Vodafone Bahrain separately from other business segments within the Zain Group.

- 75 -

Appendix 2: Regulatory precedents for the cost of capital

Table A2 Selected precedents for the cost of capital for fixed-line telecommunications (nominal, vanilla)

Regulator and year of determination Country Company

Ofcom (2009) UK BT Openreach

Ofcom (2009)

ARCEP (2008)

ComReg (2008)

BIPT (2006)

UK

France

1

Ireland

Belgium

Netherlands

Finland

UK

UK

Rest of BT Group

France Telecom eircom

Belgacom

KPN

Finnish fixed-line operators

BT Copper access

Rest of BT Group

8.0 (implied)

8.7 (implied)

7.8 (implied)

9.3

2

(implied)

8.3 (implied)

8.3 (implied) OPTA (2006)

FICORA (2006)

Ofcom (2005)

Ofcom (2005 )

6.2–7.9 (implied)

7.6 (implied)

8.5 (implied)

TRA (2005) Bahrain Batelco 12.2

TRA (2003) Bahrain Batelco 8.40–11.71

Note: Vanilla WACC refers to the weighted average of pre-tax cost of debt and post-tax cost of equity. Vanilla

WACC was implied using information provided in regulatory documents.

1

ARCEP estimated the same equity beta for the fixed-line and mobile activities of France Telecom, leading to the same cost of equity across the two activities. The cost of debt differs slightly across the two activities and higher gearing and a zero debt beta for the fixed-line segment drives the difference between the reported nominal WACC across the fixedline and mobile activities.

2

ComReg selected a point estimate above the midpoint of the range.

Source: Ofcom (2009), “A New Pricing Framework for Openreach”, May 22nd; ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163; ComReg (2008), “Eircom’s Cost of Capital: Response to Consultation and Decision Notice”, May 22nd; BIPT (2006), “Décision du Conseil de l'IBPT du 22 Novembre 2006

Concernant le Coût du Capital à Utiliser Dans les offres de Référence de Belgacom”, November 22nd; NERA

(2006), “The cost of capital for KPN’s wholesale activities”, a final report for OPTA, February 21st; FICORA

(2006), “Assessment principles for the pricing of fixed network interconnection”, June 28th; Ofcom (2005),

“Ofcom’s approach to risk in the assessment of the cost of capital”, August 18th; TRA (2005), “Batelco’s cost of capital—A determination issued by the telecommunications regulatory authority, November 20th; TRA

(2003), “Batelco’s cost of capital—A determination issued by the telecommunications regulatory authority”,

August 9th.

- 76 -

Table A3 Selected precedents for the cost of capital for mobile (nominal, vanilla)

Regulator and year of determination

FICORA (2008)

ARCEP (2008)

Country

Finland

France

1

Company

Mobile operators

France Telecom

WACC (%)

8.9–11.0 (implied)

8.1 (implied)

PTS (2008)

Ofcom (2007)

Sweden

UK

Telenor, H3G, Tele2, TeliaSonera

O2, T-Mobile, Vodafone, Hutchison 3G UK,

Orange

Vodafone

9.7–10.0 (implied)

9.2–11.8 (implied)

CMT (2007)

OPTA (2006)

Spain

Netherlands

7.7 (implied)

8.3 (implied) KPN

Mobile operators FICORA (2006)

TRA (2005)

Finland

Bahrain

8.3–10.4 (implied)

12.2 Batelco

TRA (2003) Bahrain Batelco 11.77

Note: Vanilla WACC refers to the weighted average of pre-tax cost of debt and post-tax cost of equity. Vanilla

WACC was implied using information provided in regulatory documents.

1

ARCEP estimated the same equity beta for the fixed-line and mobile activities of France Telecom leading to the same cost of equity across the two activities. The cost of debt differs slightly across the two activities, and higher gearing and a zero debt beta for the fixed-line segment drives the difference between the reported nominal WACC across the fixedline and mobile activities.

Source: FICORA (2008), “FICORA assessment principles for the pricing of mobile termination”, July 3rd;

ARCEP (2008), Decision numbers 2008-0162 and 2008-0163; PTS (2008), “Slutlig riskfri ränta för mobil

WACC”, May 6th; Ofcom (2007), “Mobile call termination statement”, March 27th; Commission Del Mercado

De Las Telecommunications (2007), Decision numbers AEM 2007/699; AEM 2007/343, and AEM 2007/648;

NERA (2006), “The cost of capital for KPN’s wholesale activities”, a final report for OPTA, February 21st;

FICORA (2006), “FICORA’s principles for assessing mobile termination pricing”, December 7th; Commerce

Commission of New Zealand (2005), “Draft Determination on the Application for Pricing Review for

Designated Interconnection Services”, April 11th; TRA (2005), “Batelco’s cost of capital—A determination issued by the telecommunications regulatory authority, November 20th; TRA (2003), “Batelco’s cost of capital—A determination issued by the telecommunications regulatory authority, August 9th.

- 77 -

Appendix 3: Equity beta cluster analysis dendrograms

Figure A1 Dendrogram: level of dissimilarity between Bahrain and world telecommunications markets

Dendrog ram for all cluster analysis

Brazil

Pakistan

Indonesia

Liechtenstein

Qatar

Kuwait

Slovenia

Greece

Portugal

Cyprus

Estonia

Slovak Republic

Romania

Poland

Latvia

Hungary

Croatia

Lithuania

Czech Republic

Bulgaria

United Arab Emirates

Bahrain

Norway

Luxembourg

Iceland

Netherlands

Sweden

Denmark

Ireland

Finland

Spain

Austria

Belgium

Australia

Japan

Italy

Germany

United Kingdom

France

Korea (Rep. of)

Malta

Andorra

Djibouti

Brunei Darussalam

Mexico

Egypt

Paraguay

Guatemala

Peru

Colombia

Venezuela

Chile

Costa Rica

Syria

Sudan

Lesotho

Yemen

Eritrea

Chad

Turkey

Saudi Arabia

Oman

Libya

Jordan

Tunisia

Malaysia

Morocco

South Africa

0

Source: Bloomberg and TRA calculations.

2

L2 dissimilarity measure

4 6

- 78 -

Table A4 Telecommunications operators in comparator markets

Qatar

Kuwait

Slovenia

Greece

Qatar Telecom Q-Tel QSC , Vodafone Qatar

National Mobile Telecommunications Company , Zain

Telekom Slovenija, Zaslon Telecom, TUŠ TELEKOM, Kron Telekom, Vodafone, Mobile

Telecom

Hellenic Telecommunications Organization , Cosmote, On Telecommunications S.A.,

Vodafone, Columbia Telecom S.A., Telecom Italia (mobile)

Portugal

Cyprus

Portugal Telecom , TMN, Vodafone, Merine Telecom, AR Telecom

CyTA, OTEnet, PrimeTel, MTBC Telecom Limited, Alambra Telecom, Cytamobile-

Vodafone, Scancom Cyprus/Areeba, Kuzey Kıbrıs Turkcell (KKTCell)

Estonia Estonian Telephone Company, CSC Telecom, Norby Telecom, Tele2 Eesti AS, Elisa,

Eesti Telekom , Elion, Global Telecom

Slovak Republic Slovak Telecom (ST), WiMAX Telecom, T-Mobile Slovensko, Orange

Romania

Poland

RomTelecom, UPC Romania, Atlas Telecommunication

Latvia

Telekomunikacja Polska (TPSA) , Nordisk Mobiltelefon AB, Tele 2, Orange, Polska

Telefonia Cyfrowa Sp. z.o.o, Telekomunikacja Kolejowa

Lattelecom, CSC Telecom, SIGIS Telecom, Sonore Grupa, Latvijas Mobila Telefone,

Tele2, TRIATEL

Hungary

Croatia

Lithuania

Magyar Telekom , Pannon Telekom, T-Mobile, Vodafone, DND Telecom, Dual Telecom,

DK-Telecom, Cobra Telecom

T-Hrvatski Telekom , H1 Telekom, Optima Telekom, Iskon, Tele 2, VIPnet

Lietuvos Telekomas (TEO) , Omin Tel, Tele 2

Czech Republic Telefónica O2 Czech Republic , Alfa Telecom, Telekom Austria Czech Republic , T-

Mobile, Vodafone Czech Republic

Bulgaria

United Arab

Emirates

Bulgarian Telecommunication Company (BTC), Globul Telecom, Viva Tel, Bulgaria

Telecom, M-Ten, Trans Telecom, Max Telecom

Etihad Etisalat Company , Axiom Telecom, Warid Telecom International, Emirates

Integrated Telecommunication Company

Bahrain Bahrain Telecom Company, Zain

Notes: The first company in each list of telecommunications operators is the incumbent in the respective market. Companies highlighted in bold are considered as close comparators (see Table 9). Includes companies with at least one full year of published financial accounts.

Source: TRA.

- 79 -

Figure A2 Dendrogram: level of dissimilarity between Batelco, Zain and telecommunications companies operating in comparable markets

Dendrogram for all cluster analysis

Vodafone Group PLC

France Telecom SA

Deutsche Telekom AG

Telenor ASA

Tele2 AB

Hellenic Telecommunications Organization SA

Magyar Telekom Telecommunications Plc

Hrvatske telekomunikacije dd

Telekomunikacja Polska SA

Telekom Austria AG

Portugal Telecom SGPS SA

Eesti Telekom

Elisa OYJ

Bahrain Telecom Co

Telefonica O2 Czech Republic AS

TEO LT AB

Zain

National Mobile Telecommunication Co KSC

Qatar Telecom Q-Tel QSC

Etihad Etisalat Co

OT Optima Telekom doo

Emirates Integrated Telecommunication Co

0

Source: Bloomberg and TRA calculations.

Overall comparators

Batelco's comparators

Zain's comparators

2 4

L2 dissimilarity measure

6

- 80 -

Appendix 4: Equity beta estimates and gearing for comparator telecommunications companies

Table A5 Equity betas for comparator companies (2-year, weekly)

Local

Raw

2

1

Adj

3

S.E.

4

S&P 500

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

0.81 0.87 0.09 0.53 0.69 0.14 0.59 0.73 0.13

0.66 0.77 0.07 0.39 0.59 0.13 0.41 0.61 0.12 Qatar Telecom Q-Tel

QSC

National Mobile

Telecommunication Co

KSC

1.20 1.13 0.22 0.23 0.49 0.16 0.34 0.56 0.15

TelefónicaO2 Czech

Republic AS

0.67 0.78 0.08 0.31 0.54 0.09 0.35 0.57 0.09

0.46 0.64 0.06 0.41 0.61 0.09 0.45 0.63 0.08

0.69 0.79 0.11 0.66 0.77 0.11 0.67 0.78 0.11

0.90 0.93 0.07 0.25 0.50 0.10 0.37 0.58 0.10

0.49 0.66 0.07 0.29 0.53 0.09 0.27 0.51 0.09 Telekomunikacja Polska

SA

Hrvatske

Telekomunikacije dd

Portugal Telecom SGPS

SA

0.54 0.69 0.06 0.38 0.59 0.10 0.44 0.63 0.09

0.82 0.88 0.10 0.49 0.66 0.10 0.57 0.72 0.10

Hellenic

Telecommunications

Organization SA

0.58 0.72 0.08 0.65 0.77 0.10 0.72 0.81 0.10

Magyar Telekom

Telecommunications plc

0.68 0.79 0.06 0.46 0.64 0.10 0.51 0.68 0.09

Austria 0.76 0.84 0.07 0.72 0.82 0.13 0.81 0.88 0.12

Batelco

0.82 0.88 0.09 0.81 0.87 0.11 0.88 0.92 0.10

0.46 0.64 0.11 0.00 0.34 0.06 0.04 0.36 0.06

Zain 1.46 1.31 0.21 0.36 0.57 0.16 0.35 0.56 0.16

Notes:

1

Local index refers to the stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, the Bahrain Stock Exchange Index and Kuwait Stock Exchange Index are local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

2

Based on raw equity beta which represents an estimated coefficient from a regression where returns on equity are regressed on returns on either a local or world index.

3

Calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: (2/3)*raw beta + (1/3).

4

Obtained directly from beta estimation procedure

(ordinary least squares).

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

- 81 -

Table A6 Equity betas for comparator companies (5-year, weekly)

Local

Raw

2

1

Adj

3

S.E.

4

S&P 500

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

1.04 1.03 0.06 0.50 0.67 0.16 0.56 0.70 0.15

0.52 0.68 0.05 0.28 0.52 0.10 0.31 0.54 0.10 Qatar Telecom Q-Tel

QSC

National Mobile

Telecommunication Co

KSC

0.93 0.95 0.12 0.21 0.48 0.11 0.29 0.53 0.11

Telefonica O2 Czech

Republic AS

0.62 0.75 0.06 0.29 0.53 0.07 0.33 0.55 0.07

0.51 0.67 0.04 0.43 0.62 0.07 0.48 0.65 0.07

0.71 0.81 0.07 0.71 0.81 0.08 0.71 0.80 0.08

0.75 0.84 0.04 0.27 0.51 0.07 0.37 0.58 0.06

0.66 0.77 0.05 0.41 0.60 0.08 0.41 0.61 0.08 Telekomunikacja Polska

SA

Hrvatske

Telekomunikacije dd

Portugal Telecom SGPS

SA

0.54 0.69 0.06 0.38 0.59 0.10 0.44 0.63 0.09

0.85 0.90 0.06 0.47 0.65 0.07 0.54 0.69 0.07

Hellenic

Telecommunications

Organization SA

0.64 0.76 0.05 0.68 0.78 0.08 0.73 0.82 0.08

Magyar Telekom

Telecommunications plc

0.63 0.76 0.05 0.48 0.65 0.08 0.54 0.69 0.08

Austria 0.73 0.82 0.05 0.69 0.80 0.09 0.76 0.84 0.09

Batelco

0.87 0.91 0.07 0.83 0.89 0.09 0.87 0.92 0.08

1.05 1.03 0.11 0.03 0.35 0.08 0.05 0.37 0.08

Zain 1.07 1.05 0.12 0.38 0.58 0.12 0.35 0.57 0.11

Notes:

1

Local index refers to the stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, the Bahrain Stock Exchange Index and Kuwait Stock Exchange Index are local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

2

Based on raw equity beta which represents an estimated coefficient from a regression where returns on equity are regressed on returns on either a local or world index.

3

Calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: (2/3)*raw beta + (1/3).

4

Obtained directly from beta estimation procedure

(ordinary least squares).

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

- 82 -

Table A7 Equity betas for comparator companies (5-year, monthly)

Local

Raw

2

1

Adj

3

S.E.

4

S&P 500

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

Raw

2

Adj

3

S.E.

4

0.90 0.93 0.13 0.31 0.54 0.42 0.39 0.59 0.36

0.39 0.60 0.08 0.55 0.70 0.24 0.51 0.67 0.20 Qatar Telecom Q-Tel

QSC

National Mobile

Telecommunication Co

KSC

0.39 0.60 0.18 0.87 0.91 0.25 0.70 0.80 0.22

Telefonica O2 Czech

Republic AS

0.56 0.71 0.08 0.54 0.69 0.19 0.49 0.66 0.17

0.45 0.63 0.09 0.43 0.62 0.17 0.38 0.59 0.15

0.53 0.68 0.15 0.77 0.84 0.20 0.64 0.76 0.18

0.63 0.75 0.07 0.67 0.78 0.19 0.61 0.74 0.16

0.56 0.70 0.11 0.51 0.67 0.21 0.42 0.61 0.18 Telekomunikacja Polska

SA

Hrvatske

Telekomunikacije dd

Portugal Telecom SGPS

SA

0.28 0.52 0.10 0.15 0.44 0.25 0.21 0.47 0.21

0.76 0.84 0.11 0.43 0.62 0.18 0.46 0.64 0.15

Hellenic

Telecommunications

Organization SA

0.52 0.68 0.09 1.01 1.00 0.16 0.81 0.87 0.14

Magyar Telekom

Telecommunications plc

0.59 0.73 0.09 0.57 0.71 0.19 0.56 0.70 0.16

Austria 0.57 0.71 0.11 0.88 0.92 0.21 0.69 0.79 0.18

Batelco

0.82 0.88 0.17 0.99 0.99 0.21 0.89 0.93 0.17

0.94 0.96 0.17 0.20 0.47 0.21 0.22 0.48 0.18

Zain 0.87 0.91 0.19 1.25 1.16 0.30 0.93 0.95 0.27

Notes:

1

Local index refers to the stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, the Bahrain Stock Exchange Index and Kuwait Stock Exchange Index are local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

2

Based on raw equity beta which represents an estimated coefficient from a regression where returns on equity are regressed on returns on either a local or world index.

3

Calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: (2/3)*raw beta + (1/3).

4

Obtained directly from beta estimation procedure

(ordinary least squares).

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

- 83 -

Table A8 Gearing level for comparator companies (%)

Etihad Etisalat Co

Qatar Telecom Q-Tel QSC

National Mobile Telecommunication Co KSC

TEO LT AB

Telefonica O2 Czech Republic AS

Elisa OYJ

Eesti Telekom

Telekomunikacja Polska SA

Hrvatske Telekomunikacije dd

Portugal Telecom SGPS SA

Hellenic Telecommunications Organization SA

Magyar Telekom Telecommunications plc

Telekom Austria AG

Tele2 AB

United Arab Emirates

Qatar

Kuwait

Lithuania

Czech Republic

Estonia

Estonia

Poland

Croatia

Portugal

Greece

Hungary

Austria

Poland

0

19

0

16

0

34

27

Gearing

23

32

9

0

25

33

15

Notes: Gearing is estimated as the average ratio of net debt over enterprise value for the period 2006-2008 inclusive.

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

- 84 -

Table A9 Asset betas for comparator companies

Zain’s comparators

Local

1

2-year weekly

Raw

2

Adj

3

5-year weekly

5-year monthly

FTSE All-World

2-year weekly

5-year weekly

5-year monthly

Raw Adj Raw Adj Raw Adj Raw Adj Raw Adj

Qatar Telecom

Q-Tel QSC

National Mobile

Telecommunication Co KSC

TEO AB

Average

Batelco’s comparators

Telefonica O2

Czech Republic AS

Average

0.45 0.52 0.35 0.46 0.27 0.40 0.28 0.41 0.21 0.37 0.34 0.45

1.10 1.03 0.85 0.87 0.36 0.54 0.31 0.51 0.27 0.48 0.64 0.73

0.67 0.78 0.62 0.75 0.56 0.71 0.35 0.57 0.33 0.55 0.49 0.66

0.77 0.78 0.67 0.72 0.50 0.60 0.33 0.49 0.30 0.47 0.48 0.59

0.46 0.64 0.51 0.67 0.45 0.63 0.45 0.63 0.48 0.65 0.38 0.59

0.56 0.64 0.57 0.65 0.43 0.55 0.55 0.63 0.57 0.65 0.52 0.61

0.90 0.93 0.75 0.84 0.63 0.75 0.37 0.58 0.37 0.58 0.61 0.74

0.41 0.56 0.55 0.65 0.47 0.59 0.23 0.43 0.34 0.51 0.35 0.51 Telekomunikacja

Polska SA

Hrvatske telekomunikacije dd

0.54 0.69 0.54 0.69 0.28 0.52 0.44 0.63 0.44 0.63 0.21 0.47

Portugal Telecom

SGPS SA

Hellenic

Telecommunications Organization

SA

Magyar Telekom

Telecommunications Plc

Telekom Austria

AG

0.54 0.58 0.56 0.60 0.50 0.56 0.38 0.47 0.35 0.46 0.30 0.42

0.42 0.53 0.47 0.56 0.38 0.50 0.53 0.60 0.54 0.60 0.59 0.64

0.51 0.59 0.47 0.56 0.44 0.54 0.38 0.51 0.40 0.52 0.41 0.53

0.51 0.57 0.49 0.55 0.39 0.48 0.55 0.59 0.51 0.57 0.47 0.54

0.70 0.75 0.74 0.77 0.70 0.75 0.75 0.78 0.74 0.77 0.75 0.79

0.55 0.65 0.61 0.69 0.51 0.62 0.42 0.56 0.44 0.57 0.44 0.57

Notes: Asset betas are based on the equity beta and gearing estimates presented in Tables A5 to A8 in

Appendix 4. Asset beta is defined as equity beta multiplied by one minus gearing plus debt beta multiplied by gearing, where debt beta is assumed to be equal zero.

1

Local index refers to the stock exchange index of the market where a company is listed, for example, Bahrain Stock Exchange Index and Kuwait Stock Exchange

Index are local indices in the case of Batelco and Zain respectively.

2

Based on the raw equity beta which represents an estimated coefficient from a regression where returns on the equity are regressed on returns on either the local or the world index.

3

Adjusted beta is calculated using the Bayesian adjustment: (2/3)*raw beta + (1/3).

Source: Bloomberg, TRA calculations.

- 85 -

Download