The comovement of investor attention Michael S. Drake Brigham Young University mikedrake@byu.edu Jared Jennings Washington University in St. Louis jaredjennings@wustl.edu Darren T. Roulstone The Ohio State University roulstone.1@osu.edu Jacob R. Thornock University of Washington thornocj@uw.edu October 2014 Preliminary and Incomplete: Please do not cite or distribute We thank Mary Barth (editor), an anonymous associate editor, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. We thank Yung-Yu Chen for assistance in acquiring Google search data and Nick Guest for research assistance. The financial support of the Fisher College of Business, Foster School of Business, Olin Business School, and the Marriott School of Management is gratefully acknowledged. Abstract Prior literature has documented that investor attention is associated with the market’s pricing of stocks. We measure comovement in investor attention: the extent to which investor attention paid to a firm is explained by attention paid to the firm’s industry and to the market as a whole. We then use attention comovement to help explain excess comovement in stock returns within in an industry, i.e., the tendency of firm returns to move together more than can be explained by comovement in firm fundamentals. We find that larger, more visible firms have higher attention comovement and that, controlling for firm characteristics and prior determinants of return comovement, attention comovement is positively associated with excess stock return and trading volume comovement. Finally, we show that a prominent information release (a firm’s earnings announcement) contributes to attention comovement. Our results have implications for sentiment-based explanations of excess stock return comovement. 1 1. INTRODUCTION Recent research demonstrates the importance of investor attention to the pricing of stocks, providing consistent evidence that attention (inattention) to firm-specific information and events is associated with positive (negative) capital market effects (e.g., Hirshleifer and Teoh 2003; Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh 2009; Drake, Gee, and Thornock 2014). Another stream of research finds that stock returns comove in ways that fundamentals cannot fully explain, prompting the investigation of behavioral explanations of excess return comovement (e.g., Kumar and Lee 2006; Barberis, Shleifer, and Wurgler 2005). This paper sits at the intersection of these two literatures. Our research objectives are twofold. First, we investigate the extent to which investor attention comoves (i.e., how much of a firm’s attention is explained by industryand market attention). We quantify attention comovement and investigate factors explaining the level of attention comovement for a given firm. Second, we examine whether attention comovement helps explain the excess comovement of stock returns documented in prior work. The investor attention literature is based on the idea that attention is a limited resource. That is, because investors cannot pay attention to all stocks or acquire and process all relevant information, they must be selective about the particular stocks they choose to follow (Hirshleifer and Teoh 2003). This literature has largely focused on firm-specific attention. 1 In this paper, we extend the attention literature by estimating the extent to which firm-specific attention comoves with industry/market attention. We conjecture that investor attention will comove as investors collectively focus on similar firms and their correlated information flows. This notion follows from a noise trader model, such as that in Barberis, Shleifer and Wurgler (2005), in which 1 For example, prior work employs firm-specific measures of attention, such as trading volume (Hou, Xiong, and Peng 2009), past returns (Aboody, Lehavy, and Trueman 2010), 52-week highs (Li and Yu 2012), business press articles (Da et al. 2011), or Google searches (Da et al. 2011; Drake, Roulstone and Thornock 2012) to identify firms that are likely experiencing higher levels of investor attention. 2 different investor groups experience categorical or correlated sentiment, which in turn leads to “sentiment-based” returns comovement. We extend the literatures on investor attention and categorical sentiment by introducing the idea that investor attention will comove as investor groups systematically seek out information for similar categorical stocks or as they experience correlated shocks to the demand for information. To our knowledge, no prior study has explicitly examined the concept of attention comovement, nor its capital market implications. An intuitive category for categorical sentiment is industry. All else equal, we would expect that firms in the same industry would have fundamentals and attention that move together. To develop a measure of attention comovement, we follow a similar methodology to the returns comovement literature to identify the amount of attention a firm receives that is explained by industry and market-wide attention. We use four unique measures of the amount of attention paid to a particular firm: (1) internet searches (i.e., Google search for a firm’s ticker), (2) analyst forecast revisions, (3) business press articles, and (4) requests for a firm’s EDGAR financial filings. We also compile a composite score of all four measures using factor analysis and label the resulting factor “A-Score,” which is short for attention-score. We regress each of our attention proxies on measures of industry and market attention, which are created by aggregating firm-level measures within industries and across the market. We then use the R2 from these annual, firm-specific regressions as a measure of attention comovement—the greater amount of firm-level attention that is explained by industry and market attention (i.e., higher R2), the lower the amount of firm-specific attention paid to the stock. These measures capture the comovement in firm attention with industry and market attention. We conduct our analyses using a broad cross-section of 5,663 firm-year observations from the 2007 to 2011 time period. We first provide evidence on the importance of 3 industry/market attention: we find that the average R2 from these regressions is 17.5%, ranging from 9.9% for Google Internet searches to 25.2% for EDGAR financial filing searches. These numbers reveal that a fair portion of the variation in firm-specific attention is explained by variation in industry/market attention. In other words, some of the attention paid to a firm by investors, analysts, and the business press is associated with attention paid to the firm’s industry or the market in general. The implication of this result is that inferences in prior research focusing on firm-specific attention are partially driven by industry/market attention. Next, we examine factors that are related to attention comovement. We find that firms with higher earnings comovement are more likely to have their attention comove with industry and market attention, suggesting that comovement in firm fundamentals is positively related to attention comovement. In addition, we find that, after controlling for the influence of fundamentals comovement, attention comovement is higher for large firms and more visible firms. This finding suggests that when investors are paying attention to a particular industry or the market as a whole, they also concentrate on the larger, more visible firms within industries and the market. For example, when investor attention moves to tech stocks, it implicitly falls on the prominent players in the tech industry, such as Apple or Microsoft. On the other hand, we find that institutional ownership is negatively related to attention comovement, suggesting that attention comovement is negatively related to investor sophistication. Overall, the implication of these findings is that attention comoves in excess of what is explained by comovement in firm fundamentals and this excess comovement of attention is associated with firm characteristics. The concept of categorical comovement has been proposed in prior research (Barberis et al 2005; 4 Morck et al 2000), but our operationalization and quantification of categorical attention is novel to the literature. 2 Having identified the factors that are associated with cross-sectional variation in attention comovement, we next investigate its capital market effects. In these analyses, we draw on the returns comovement literature. The notion that the returns of related assets move in tandem is a fundamental concept in asset pricing theory. Theoretically, in a well-functioning, frictionless market, the comovement of asset prices should be tightly linked to comovement in asset fundamentals. Early research documented that firm stock returns covary with both market and industry returns (e.g., King 1966) and that firm-level earnings covary with industry and market earnings (e.g., Ball and Brown 1967). The comovement in earnings is consistent with a fundamentals-based explanation for the comovement in returns. However, recent research documents that return comovement cannot be fully explained by comovement in fundamentals (e.g., Barberis et al., 2005). Subsequent comovement research focused on similarities in firm characteristics as an explanation for return comovement. 3 These studies tend to identify categories within which prices, which are the outcome of information acquisition and trading activities, comove. In other words, prior research focuses on the outcome (excess return comovement) without necessarily examining the information flows leading to that outcome. For example, Grullon et al (2014) propose that firms sharing a lead underwriter comove because the lead underwriters share information about these firms with investors; however, these information flows are not 2 Another way to distinguish our work is to note that comovement studies to date basically focus on finding categories and showing that firms in the category comove with each other more than they comove with firms outside the category. Our work is more like the traditional synchronicity literature (e.g., Morck et al. 2000), which investigates determinants of the level of comovement within a particular category (in our case, industry). 3 These include similarities in size (Fama and French, 1993), the book-to-market ratios (Fama and French, 1993), stock price (Green and Hwang 2009), industry membership (Kallberg and Pasquariello, 2007), stock index membership (Barberis, Shleifer, and Wurgler, 2005), investment banking networks (Grullon, Underwood, and Weston, 2014) and analyst following (Muslu et al 2014). 5 observable. In this study, we quantify the correlated actions of investors and information intermediaries to gather and supply information about firms. Therefore, we can speak to the information mechanisms that can influence excess returns comovement. We find that comovement in investor attention is positively related to comovement in returns and trading volume. 4 In other words, when the extent to which market participants pay attention to a stock is strongly associated with their level of attention to the stock’s industry and to the market in general, the stock’s returns and trading volume are more strongly linked to industry and market-level returns and trading volume. These results hold after controlling for comovement in firm fundamentals, as well as after controlling for firm characteristics that prior research finds to be related to returns comovement. The implication of this finding is that the correlated attention of investors and other market participants can affect comovement in asset prices, an idea that is new to the literature. An implication of these findings is that factors that draw attention to a particular firm may also increase the amount of attention that investors pay to other firms that share a similar categorical attribute, such as industry membership. For example, as earnings news draws attention to a given firm, it may also draw attention to related firms. In our final set of tests, we provide direct evidence on whether investors shift their attention based on significant firm events within the industry. We find that earnings announcements also trigger significant increases in investor attention for “peer” firms (other firms in the same industry). We also find that investor attention is stronger for “peer” firms when the announcing firm’s attention comoves more with other firms in the industry and market. This evidence is consistent with significant firm events triggering investors to pay more attention to similar or related firms. 4 We extend prior work by examining trading volume as well as returns. As trading is necessary for price changes, trading comovement should also be related to the attention paid to a firm; we document the existence this relation. 6 Our paper contributes to the literatures on investor attention, comovement in asset prices/volume, and intra-industry information transfer. We introduce new measures of attention and provide the first evidence on how firm-level attention varies with industry and market-level attention. We document that attention has capital market effects: firms that are generally viewed in the context of their industry and the market have stock returns and trading volume closely linked to industry and market activity. Lastly, we provide some evidence that significant corporate events, such as earnings announcements, trigger investor attention for other related firms, which we define as firms that share the same industry. 2. DATA, VARIABLES, AND SAMPLE 2.1. Measures of Attention Our analysis requires measures of investor attention to compute attention comovement. To capture investor attention, we employ four state-of-the-art measures that have been used in prior research: internet search volume, analyst forecast revisions, the count of business press mentions for a particular firm, and the number of EDGAR downloads of a firm’s financial statements. To calculate internet search volume, we obtain a proprietary database of investors’ weekly search activities made available by Google through their Google Trends application. 5 Google Trends tracks and reports the Search Volume Index (SVI), which is a relative measure of user searches for a particular term on the Google search engine. 6 Following Da et al. (2011) and Drake et al. (2012), we use ticker symbols as the search term for the firm which makes it more 5 We employ weekly rather than daily Google search data because it allows us to investigate a much broader sample of firms. As discussed in Drake et al. (2012), daily Google search data is only available for larger, well-recognized firms. Da et al. (2011) is another example of prior research using weekly Google search. 6 For example, the SVI for the term “super bowl” shows a strong increase in Google searches by users in January and February of each year. http://www.google.com/trends/?q=super+bowl 7 likely that the user is searching for financial information, rather than for non-financial information. 7 To control for the normal level of search volume in a firm, we remove from the weekly SVI the median SVI over the past 8 weeks, following Da et al (2011). Thus, the variable Googlei,w measures the abnormal level of internet search during the week for a particular firm. Our second measure of attention, Analyst Fori,w, is equal to the count of earnings forecast revisions made by sell-side analysts for a given firm-week. We obtain these data from the I/B/E/S detail file. Following Frankel et al. (2006), we count the number of unique EPS (earnings per share) revisions issued for each firm-week, including forecasts for all time horizons (i.e., earnings forecasts for one-year, two-year, and all other horizons are included in the Analyst Fori,w variable). We count all revisions that are reported on the same date by the same analyst for the same firm as a single analyst revision. We set all firm-weeks with no recorded analyst revisions to zero as long as we are able to find some analyst coverage during that calendar year. The third measure of attention is business press coverage (Mediai,w). We obtain business press data from RavenPack, which provides data on business press coverage through the Dow Jones (DJ) News Archives and Wall Street Journal (WSJ) (Drake, Guest and Twedt 2014). While the data obtained from RavenPack is not comprehensive of all press outlets, the large circulation of these two outlets makes them well suited to investigate market effects of the business press (Tetlock 2007). The Mediai,w variable is equal to the number of articles issued by the business press for each firm-week. We set all firm-weeks with no recorded news articles to zero as long as we are able to find some media coverage during that calendar year. Our fourth proxy for investor attention, Edgari,w, is the number of EDGAR downloads for a given firm’s 10-Ks or 10-Qs during a given week. EDGAR is the SEC’s online repository for 7 In addition, we delete from our sample any ticker symbols with potential alternative meanings (e.g., ‘CAT,’ ‘TOY,’ and ‘MAT’. 8 all SEC-mandated filings, among which are the 10-K (annual report) and 10-Q (quarterly report). Drake et al. (2014) report that the 10-K and 10-Q reports are among the most highly downloaded SEC filings. Therefore, we use the Edgari,w variable as a proxy for investor attention to financial statements. 2.2. Measures of Comovement Our first objective is to examine the extent to which attention is an industry and market- wide phenomenon. To achieve this objective, we employ a methodology similar to that used in the returns comovement literature, which regresses firm returns on industry and market returns. The explained variation (R2) from the model serves as the measure of comovement (e.g., Morck et al. 2000). We do a very similar calculation with each of the attention measures previously discussed. For each 52-week period prior to the fiscal year-end for a given firm, we estimate the following regression using each attention measure for each firm-year: FIRM ATTNi,w = β0 + β1IND ATTNw + β2MARKET ATTN + εi,w (1) where i indexes firms and w indexes weeks. FIRM ATTN is one of the four measures of attention described above: Googlei,w, Analyst Fori,w, Mediai,w, or Edgari,w. For each of these four measures of attention, we also create an industry-level measure of attention, IND ATTNi,w, by computing the value-weighted attention for the industry, defined by the two-digit SIC code, for a given week. We also create a market-level measure of attention, MARKET ATTNi,w, for each of the four attention variables by computing the value-weighted total attention for all sample firms in a given week. We estimate equation (1) for each firm and fiscal period, requiring at least 45 weekly observations. To obtain an estimate of attention comovement, we take the log transformation of the R2, similar to the approach in Morck et al (2000): 9 ATTN SYNCi,t = log(1 + (R2/(1-R2))) (2) where R2 is the coefficient of determination from the firm-year estimation of equation (1). 8 We compute a “SYNC” variable for each of the four attention variables – Sync Google, Sync Analyst, Sync Media, and Sync Edgar – using this approach. By constructing the comovement measure in this way, we can interpret increases in attention synchronicity variables as indicating that a given firm’s attention is more closely tied to industry and market attention. In other words, higher values of attention synchronicity serve as a proxy for higher attention comovement. 9 Once we calculate each of the attention synchronicity variables, we create a composite attention synchronicity variable (Sync A-Scorei,t). We conduct a factor analysis with our four attention synchronicity variables and retain the principal factor. 10 In our subsequent analyses, we focus primarily on the results using the Sync A-Scorei,t variable because we believe that it best captures the underlying construct of attention comovement. We compute returns and volume comovement measures using a similar methodology. We follow Piotroski and Roulstone (2004) and define the Sync Reti,t variable using the R2 from the following regression calculated for each fiscal year end using the previous 52 weeks of data: Reti,w = ω + ω1Ind Reti,w + ω2Market Reti,w + ε 8 (3) The log transformation allows a bounded variable—the R2 is bounded between 0 and 1—to take a continuous form, and has been used in other studies that employ the R2 as a variable of interest (e.g., Piotroski and Roulstone 2004). 9 We refer to these variables as “synchronicity” variables because they are calculated in a similar manner to the return synchronicity variables in Morck et al. (2000) and Piotroski and Roulstone (2004). We use the general term “comovement” to refer to correlations in returns, trading volume, fundamentals, and our attention proxies across firms in the same industry. 10 The results of principal factor analysis (untabulated) reveal that all four attention variables – Sync Googlei,t, Sync Analysti,t, Sync Mediai,t, and Sync Edgari,t – converge to a single significant underlying factor with an Eigenvalue greater than 1.0. 10 The Reti,w variable is the weekly return for firm i in week w. The Ind Reti,w variable is the valueweighed industry return (two-digit SIC code) in week w. The Market Reti,w variable is the valueweighted market return for week w. Similar to the attention synchronicity variables, we estimate equation (3) for each firm and fiscal period, requiring at least 45 weekly observations. To obtain an estimate of return synchronicity, we take the log transformation of the R2, similar to the approach in Morck et al (2000): Sync Reti,t = log(R2/(1-R2)) (4) We calculate stock turnover synchronicity, Sync Turni,w, in the same fashion. We define stock turnover as the percentage of shares traded during the week. In the prior literature, SYNC RET is often interpreted as a measure of how much firmspecific information is incorporated into a firm’s stock price: firms with high (low) SYNC RET have lower (greater) amounts of firm-specific information in price relative to industry and market related information. 11 2.3. Data and Sample We obtain data from seven different databases including Compustat (financial data), CRSP (market data), IBES (analyst data), Thomson Reuters (institutional ownership data), RavenPack (business press data), Google Trends (Google search data), and EDGAR (SEC filing data). The intersection of these datasets results in 5,663 firm-year observations for the 2007 to 11 Other scholars interpret low SYNC RET as indicating a poor information environment, e.g., Teoh, Yong, and Zhang (2009). Our paper, by linking SYNC RET with attention comovement, suggests that information does play a role in determining SYNC RET. 11 2011 time period. 12 For selected analyses conducted at the firm-week level, these databases yield a sample of 218,331 firm-week observations. 3. RESULTS 3.1. Attention Comovement 3.1.1. Descriptive Statistics and Correlations Table 1, Panel A reports the descriptive statistics for all variables measured at the firmyear level and used to investigate the comovement of investor attention. Across the four measures, EDGAR downloads of financial statements appear to exhibit the highest average comovement (mean raw R2 = 25.2% and mean Sync Edgari,t = 0.347), followed by the comovement of analyst forecast revisions (mean raw R2= 20.1% and Sync Analysti,t = 0.265), business press mentions (mean raw R2 = 14.7% and Sync Mediai,t = 0.211), and internet searches (mean raw R2 S= 9.9% and Sync Googlei,t = 0.138). We note that the average raw R2across the four measures is 17.5%. We also note that the median firm in our sample is relatively large with a market capitalization of 1.3 billion; one fourth of our sample firms are members of the S&P 500. We further note that the majority of firms are profitable (the 25th percentile for ROA is above zero). The median firm has a book-to-market ratio of 0.545 (Bk/Mkti,t), sales growth of 5.6 percent (Sales Growthi,t), has an institutional ownership percentage of approximately 79 percent (Insti,t), and is followed by 7 sell-side analysts (# Analystsi,t). Table 2, Panel A presents pairwise correlations and shows that the attention comovement measures are highly correlated with each other, with correlation coefficients ranging from 33% to 62%. Each of the four individual attention comovement measures is strongly positively associated with the composite 12 Our sample is constrained to the 2007 to 2011 time period due to the availability of SEC EDGAR and Google search data. 12 attention comovement score (Sync A-Scorei,t), indicating a common attention factor among the variables. 3.1.2. Determinants of Attention Comovement We now turn to examining the determinants of attention comovement. The objective of these analyses is to better understand why investors give individual attention to some firms while viewing other firms primarily as members of an industry or market. We do this by regressing attention comovement on comovement in firm fundamentals (proxied by earnings) and other firm characteristics. By so doing, we are able to identify which firm characteristics are associated with a firm’s attention being strongly (or weakly) associated with industry and market-wide attention. The regression is specified as follows: ATTN SYNCi,t = δYEAR + δ1ROAi,t + δ2 Mkt Vali,t + δ3 Bk/Mkti,t + δ4 Sales Growthi,t (5) + δ5 Insti,t + δ6 #Analystsi,t + δ7 Std ROAi,t + δ8 Abs(Reti,t) + δ9 Stk Turni,t + δ10 Earn Synci,t + δ11 SP 500i,t + δ12 Pricei,t, + ε, where ATTN SYNC is one of five variables – Sync A-Scorei,t, Sync Googlei,t, Sync Analysti,t, Sync Mediai,t, and Sync Edgari,t – as defined above and all independent variables are defined in Appendix A. The unit of observation here is the firm-year, capturing the general association between firm characteristics and attention comovement. We include year fixed effects to account for macroeconomic differences and assess statistical significance using standard errors that are clustered by firm. We emphasize that attention comovement is a new construct and thus, our analysis in this section is exploratory in nature. That being said, we do offer the following predictions with respect to selected firm characteristics. First, we expect firms whose fundamentals track closely with the industry and market to have attention that tracks closely with the industry and the 13 market. Thus, we predict a positive association between Sync Earni,t (which measures the comovement of a firm’s return-on-assets with the firm’s industry-level return-on-assets) and our measures of attention comovement. Similarly, firms whose fundamentals are more volatile or idiosyncratic will receive attention that is more volatile and idiosyncratic, suggesting lower attention comovement with the industry and market. Thus, we expect a negative coefficient on Std ROAi,t. Second, investors prefer to invest in securities with which they are familiar (Merton, 1987; Lehavy and Sloan 2008). This intuition, together with the fact that attention is a limited resource (Hirshleifer and Teoh, 2003), suggests that investors are more likely to pay attention to larger, “household name” stocks. Consistent with this intuition, prior research finds that larger, more visible stocks are positively associated with Google searches (Drake at al., 2012), analyst following (Bhushan, 1989), business press coverage (Bushee et al. 2010), and EDGAR requests (Drake et al., 2014). Thus, we predict that large, visible stocks will also receive even greater levels of investor attention when the industry/market receives attention. For example, investors who allocate attention to “tech” stocks in general, will also likely allocate attention to “Apple,” because Apple is such a visible, important player in the industry and in the market as a whole. This is an example of what we mean by attention comovement. On the flip side, attention paid to a small cap stock, that is not a visible stock in the industry, is likely related to something unique about the particular firm and not to the industry in general. Thus, in model (3) we expect a positive coefficient on variables that capture elements of firm size and visibility such as Mkt Vali,t, Sales Growthi,t, Abs (Reti,t), ROAi,t, # Analysts, SP 500i,t, and Stk Turni,t. Third, following a similar line of intuition, individual investors who have fewer resources are more likely to follow large, visible stocks than institutional investors. That is, individual 14 investors are more likely to pay attention to the visible firms in a given sector than the smaller, lesser known companies in the sector. Thus, we expect a negative coefficient on Insti,t as firms with lower institutional ownership and greater individual ownership will have higher attention comovement with the industry and market. Fourth, we include variables that capture possible comovement with firms outside a given firm’s industry. For example, Barberis et al. (2005) show that firms in the S&P 500 index have returns that comove with other index members regardless of their industry affiliation. Thus, comovement with industry (as measured by our attention synchronicity variables) may be lower for members of the S&P 500. On the other hand, membership in the S&P 500 is another indicator of size and visibility; thus, we have no clear prediction for the sign of the coefficient on this variable). We also include Pricei,t in the regression as Green and Hwang (2009) find that firms’ stock returns comove with those of other firms with similar prices. In summary, we include multiple variables to capture firm size and visibility, investor sophistication, and possible categories of comovement outside of industry membership. Given our focus on investor attention, we expect firm size and visibility to be the primary drivers of attention comovement in excess of that explained by comovement in fundamentals. Table 3 presents the results of estimating equation (5). In column (1), the dependent variable is the composite attention comovement score (Sync A-Scorei,t). In each of the subsequent columns (columns 2 through 5), the dependent variable is one of the individual attention comovement measures (i.e., Sync Googlei,t, Sync Analysti,t, Sync Mediai,t, and Sync Edgari,t). We focus our discussion primarily on the Sync A-Scorei,t results in column (1). We find that the explanatory power of the model is 38.4 percent, thus, approximately one-third of the variation in 15 attention comovement is explained by variation in firm-characteristics. 13 We also find that earnings comovement (Sync Earni,t) is strongly related to attention comovement, suggesting that firms with higher comovement in their fundamentals also have higher comovement in investor attention. Remaining explanatory variables can be interpreted as explaining attention comovement in excess of that associated with how well a firm’s fundamentals are related to those of the firm’s industry and market. We find that composite attention comovement is positively associated with the firm’s market value (Mkt Vali,t) and book-to-market ratio (Bk/Mkti,t), indicating that large, value firms receive attention that is more likely to comove with industry and market attention. We find that attention comovement is positively related to membership in the S&P 500 (SP 500i,t), consistent with these firms receiving proportionally more industry and market attention due to their visibility within the industry and market (and despite the fact that members of this index tend to comove with each other regardless of industry membership). Finally, we find that attention comovement is negatively related to institutional holdings (Insti,t), suggesting that less sophisticated investors (e.g., individual investors) are more likely to pay attention to an individual firm when there is higher attention being paid to the firm’s industry and to the market as a whole. The results for the components of the Sync A-Scorei,t variable are reported in columns (2) through (5) and are generally consistent with the coefficients reported in column (1). While only the coefficients on firm size (Mkt Vali,t), institutional ownership (Insti,t), and earnings synchronicity (Sync Earni,t) are significant with the same sign in all five regressions, in no case do we find that a significant coefficient flips signs. In summary, we show that a firm’s attention 13 When we include the lag of Sync A-Scorei,t as an additional independent variable we find that all results are qualitatively similar. The inclusion of Sync A-Scorei,t-1 as an additional independent variable increases the R2 to over 80% 16 comoves more with industry and market attention when the firm is more visible, has less sophisticated ownership, and is viewed by investors to be a value stock. 3.1.3. Attention Comovement and Market Comovement We next examine the association between attention comovement and stock market comovement. Stock return comovement should be, according to asset pricing theory, driven by the underlying fundamentals of the firm. However, prior research has shown that returns tend to comove in excess of what should be explained by fundamental comovement (Barberis et al. 2005). Thus, other behavioral factors that appear to be associated with market comovement are incremental to an explanation based on fundamentals. As discussed earlier, we follow Piotroski and Roulstone (2004) and define the Sync Reti,t and Sync Turni,t variables using the R2 from annual, firm-specific regressions of stock returns and stock turnover on industry and market-level stock returns and stock turnover. We examine whether variation in attention comovement incrementally explains variation in market comovement using the following regressions: Sync Reti,t = §YEAR +§1 ATTN SYNCi,t +§2 ROAi,t +§3 Mkt Vali,t +§4 Bk/Mkti,t (6) +§5 Sales Growthi,t +§6 Insti,t +§7 #Analystsi,t +§8 Std ROAi,t +§9 Abs(Reti,t) +§10 Stk Turni,t +§11 Earn Synci,t +§12 SP 500i,t +§13 Pricei,t +ε Sync Turni,t = λ§YEAR +λ1 ATTN SYNCi,t +λ2 ROAi,t +λ3 Mkt Vali,t +λ4 Bk/Mkti,t +λ5 Sales Growthi,t +λ6 Insti,t +λ7 #Analystsi,t +λ8 Std ROAi,t (7) +λ9 Abs(Reti,t) +λ10 Stk Turni,t +λ11 Earn Synci,t +λ12 SP 500i,t +λ13 Pricei,t +ε where all variables are as defined above and in Appendix A. The models presented in equation (6) and (7) include year fixed effects and statistical significance is assessed using standard errors 17 clustered by firm. In these models, our primary variable of interest is ATTN SYNCi,t, which captures the association between our market-based comovement measures (Sync Reti,t and Sync Turni,t variables) and attention comovement, after controlling for the comovement in firm fundamentals (proxied by earnings comovement) and other firm characteristics associated with stock return and trading volume synchronicity. Panel A of Table 4 presents the results from estimating equation (6), with Sync Reti,t as the dependent variable. In Column (1), we find that the coefficient on Sync A-Scorei,t is equal to 0.1460 and is significant at the 1% level, providing evidence that attention comovement is positively associated with return comovement. In Columns (2) through (5), we include each individual attention synchronicity variable separately. Without exception, we find a positive and significant coefficient on each of the attention synchronicity variables. The coefficients range from a low of 0.1429 on the Sync Googlei,t variable and a high of 0.3796 on the Sync Analysti,t variable. The results provide consistent evidence of a positive relation between returns comovement and measures of attention comovement, even after controlling for comovement in fundamentals. We note that the sign of the coefficients on the control variables are consistent with expectations and/or the prior literature (e.g., Piotroski and Roulstone, 2004). For example, we find a positive coefficient on firm size (Mkt Vali,t), institutional ownership (Insti,t) and earnings synchronicity (Sync Earni,t) as well as a negative coefficient on earnings volatility (Std ROAi,t), consistent with Piotroski and Roulstone (2004). We also find that growth firms (Sales Growthi,t), glamour stocks (Bk/Mkti,t), firms with higher stock prices at the fiscal year end (Pricei,t), firms that are part of the S&P 500 (SP500i,t), and firms with higher returns during the fiscal year (Abs(Reti,t)) are less likely to have synchronous returns. 18 Panel B of Table 4 reports the results from estimating equation (7) with Sync Turni,t as the dependent variable. Similar to the results in Panel A, we find a positive and significant coefficient on Sync A-Scorei,t. In addition, we find a positive and significant coefficient for each of the other attention synchronicity variables presented in columns (2) through (5). The coefficients in columns (2) through (5) range between 0.1428 (Sync Googlei,t) and 0.6165 (Sync Analysti,t). These results suggest that stock turnover synchronicity can be partially explained by the synchronicity of investor attention, after controlling for comovement in fundamentals and for other important firm characteristics. We note that the control variables are relatively consistent in explaining both returns and stock turnover synchronicity. Overall, the results in Table 4 indicate that the comovement of investor attention is associated with the comovement of the firm’s returns and trading volume. Put another way, firms that receive attention even when investors are not searching for information about industry peers and when analysts and the media are not forecasting or writing about industry peers, have returns and trading volume that are less related to the returns and trading volume of their industry or the market. From an economic standpoint, the magnitude of the relation between attention comovement and return/trading comovement is plausible given that a one standard deviation increase in Sync A-Scorei,t is associated with an increase in Sync Reti,t (Sync Turni,t) of 0.1346 (0.1992) standard deviations. 3.2. Attention comovement around important corporate events A stream of studies examines the intuition that information announced by one firm can be informative to investors in related firms, a phenomenon often called information transfer (e.g., Foster 1981; Han, Wild and Ramesh 1989; Ramnath 2002; Thomas and Zhang 2008). These studies show that the earnings announcement for a particular firm can lead to a significant 19 market reaction for related firms. The theory behind intra-industry information transfer is that economic events that drive one firm’s news are often related to economic events at peer firms (e.g., firms in the same industry). An untested underlying assumption in this literature is that investor attention comoves, as the earnings news for a given firm draws investor attention to related firms. We build on the information transfer literature and use the setting of intra-industry earnings news as an alternate way to show the phenomenon of attention comovement. Specifically, in our final set of tests, we extend prior research by investigating whether earnings announcements also trigger investor attention in related (“peer”) firms. We also examine whether the relation between investor attention and a peer firm’s earnings announcement is explained, in part, by the extent to which the firm’s general attention comoves with industry and market attention. 3.2.1. Descriptive Statistics In the analyses above, we employed firm-year level data; for these analyses, we change the unit of observation to the firm-week, allowing us to more precisely focus on investor attention around a corporate announcement. Further, in order to more precisely identify “peer” firms, we identify related firms as those operating in the same four-digit SIC code as a given firm. 14 Table 1, Panel B reports the descriptive statistics for all variables measured at the firmweek level. Here we find that average weekly abnormal Google search (Googlei,w) is 0.004, with a standard deviation of 0.157. The average number of analyst forecast revisions for a firm-week 14 We use four-digit SIC code to identify firms that are most likely to have similar operations. In addition, we use four-digit SIC codes to limit the number of peer firm-weeks for a single earnings announcement. Using four-digit SIC codes, we identify approximately 30% of all firm-week observations to be weeks in which peer firms announce earnings. Making the industry definition broader (e.g., two-digit SIC code) will increase this percentage considerably and reduce the power of our tests because a much higher percentage of firm-weeks become weeks in which peer firms announce earnings. 20 (Analyst Fori,w) is 1.106, with a median of 0 revisions. The average number of media articles (Mediai,w) is 17.82, with a median of 6 articles per firm-week. The average number of EDGAR downloads (Edgari,w), is 90 per firm-week, with a median of 59 downloads. Similar to our calculation of Sync A-Scorei,t, we calculate a composite attention variable, A-Scorei,w, by identifying the principal factor using the four previously defined attention variables. 15 We present the Pearson correlations for our variables in Panel B of Table 2. For the most part, each of the attention variables are positively related to the other attention variables. For example, the correlations between Mediai,w, Analyst Fori,w, and Edgari,w range from 27% to 58%. The Googlei,w variable is positively related to the other measures, but to a lesser degree. The AScorei,w variable is positively related to each of the individual attention variables, except for the Googlei,w variable. 3.2.2. Peer firm investor attention around earnings announcements We first investigate whether the earnings release of an “announcing firm” triggers attention in a peer firm by regressing separately each of the five weekly attention variables – AScorei,w, Googlei,w, Analyst Fori,w, Mediai,w, and Edgari,w – on an indicator variable for the week of the firm’s earnings release (EA) and an indicator for the week of a peer firm’s earnings announcement (Peer EA): ATTNi,w= σFIRM + σ1 EAi,w + σ2 Peer EAi,w + σ3 Mkt Vali,q + σ4 Bk/Mkti,q + σ5 Sales Growthi,q + σ6 ROAi,q + σ7 Insti,q + σ8 Uncertaintyi,q + σ9 Compi,q, + σ10 MOMi,q + ε. Where ATTNi,w is one of the five attention measures and all other variables are as previously defined in the text and Appendix A. In addition to the earnings announcement indicator 15 The results of principal factor analysis (untabulated) reveal that all four attention variables – Googlei,w, Analyst Fori,w, Mediai,w, and Edgari,w – converge to a single significant underlying factor with an Eigenvalue greater than 1.0. 21 (8) variables, we include controls for firm size (Mkt Vali,q ), book-to-market, sales growth, return-onassets, institutional ownership, analyst uncertainty (Uncertaintyi,q), the competitiveness of the firm’s industry (Compi,q ), and recent stock return performance (MOMi,q). Since the level of attention a firm receives is likely to be highly correlated through time, we also include firm fixed effects in the model. We assess statistical significance using standard errors clustered by week. An intuitive way to view equation (8) is that we are regressing the weekly level of attention paid to a firm (say, Coca Cola), on an indicator variable for the week in which Coke announces earnings (EAi,w) and an indicator variable for the week in which a peer firm (say, PepsiCo) announces earnings (Peer EAi,w), along with control variables. A significantly positive coefficient on Peer EAi,w indicates that attention comoves across related firms around important corporate announcements. In equation (8), we include the EAi,w variable as attention for a firm should increase during the week that firm releases its own earnings. We also include control variables for firm characteristics that could be associated with investor attention. Lastly, we delete all firm-week observations in which the firm and another peer firm in the industry both announce earnings. When these two events happen simultaneously, it becomes more difficult to understand whether the increase in attention is related to the firm’s earnings announcement or the peer firm’s earnings announcement. Table 5 presents the results of estimating equation (8). Again, in column (1) we present the results using A-Scorei,w as the dependent variable. In each of the subsequent columns (2) through (5), the dependent variable is one of the individual attention variables. Across all five regressions we find that the coefficient on EAi,w is positive and significant, confirming that investor attention significantly increases during the week of a firm’s earnings announcement. Further, the coefficient on PEER EAi,w is positive and statistically significant for all measures of 22 attention. This suggests that investors’ attention for a given firm increases when a peer firm releases earnings to the public. That is, these results provide additional evidence for the comovement of attention across firms within an industry and provide a source for some of that comovement: firm information releases spark attention both for the disclosing firm and for peer firms in the same industry. The coefficient on EAi,w, captures the increase in investor attention for a particular firm when that firm announces earnings and provides a benchmark against which we can assess the economic significance of the increase in investor attention observed when a peer firm announces earnings. We take the ratio of the coefficient on the PEER EAi,w variable to the coefficient on the EAi,w variable in the same model specification. Higher values of this ratio are consistent with greater levels of investor attention comovement. This ratio is equal to 6.9% when the AScorei,w is the dependent variable and ranges between 2.0 percent for analyst forecasts (column (3)) and 43.2 percent for Google searches (column (2)). We interpret these results as suggesting an economically meaningful relation between peer firm announcements and attention given to a firm. In our final set of tests, we estimate equation (8) separately for two subsamples: firms with low attention comovement (below the Sync A-Scorei,t sample median) and firms with high attention comovement (above the Sync A-Scorei,t sample median). The objective of this test is to investigate whether the positive relation between investor attention and a peer firm’s earnings announcement is conditional on the extent to which the firm’s attention generally comoves with that of firms in the industry. In Table 6 we present results with A-Scorei,w as the dependent variable. For firms with low and high levels of attention comovement, we find a positive and significant coefficient on 23 Peer EAi,w, consistent with the results presented in Table 5. However, we find that the coefficient on Peer EAi,w for the low attention comovement subsample is 0.0834 and that the coefficient on Peer EAi,w for the high attention comovement subsample is 0.1503. 16 This represents an 80% higher level of information transfer for the high attention comovement subsample. A Chow F-test confirms that these coefficients are statistically different from each other at the 1% level. This finding suggests that firms with investor attention that is generally more strongly associated with the amount of attention paid to their industry, experience greater increases in investor attention when a peer firm in that industry discloses news to the public. In other words, firms that receive more (less) firm-specific attention are less (more) likely to receive attention when firms in their industry release news. Our results support the idea that significant firm events can trigger investors to pay attention to other firms that are in the industry and that this relation is stronger for firms with greater industry and market attention comovement. 4. CONCLUSION This paper investigates the extent to which the amount of attention a firm receives from investors and other market participants comoves with the amount of attention paid to their industry and the market as whole. We also examine the capital market impact of this attention comovement. We find that approximately one-fifth of the variation in firm-specific attention is explained by industry- and market-attention. Further, we identify specific firm characteristics that are related to the level of this attention co-movement. We find that attention comovement is positively related to earnings comovement (a proxy for the comovement in firm fundamentals) 16 In untabulated analyses, we confirm that the results are inferentially similar for each of the individual attention variables when examining the differences in the coefficients on the Peer EAi,w variable. 24 and firm visibility. We also show that the comovement in attention is positively associated with the comovement in stock returns and trading volume, suggesting that comovement in stock returns and trading outcomes is partially driven by the actions of investors who view individual firms in the context of categories such as industry. This finding is consistent with “sentiment” explanations for return comovement like those discussed in Barberis et al. (2005). Finally, we document that an important information event (earnings announcements) can increase attention for related firms, once again suggesting an industry component to attention. We document that this effect is more pronounced for firms that are more likely to receive attention at the same time as other firms in the industry and market. Our results suggest that information flows (proxied by our attention measures) help explain comovement in capital market outcomes (i.e., returns and trading volume). This finding is consistent with the arguments in Barberis et al. (2005) that comovement in returns is driven by investors categorizing firms according to similar characteristics, trading subsets of stocks rather than individual stocks, and information diffusion across stocks occurring at different rates for stocks in different categories. We show that when information flows for a stock are focused on the stock and are not explained by industry and market information flows, returns and trading volume for the stock are more idiosyncratic. While we cannot establish a causal relation between attention comovement and return/trading volume comovement, we believe it unlikely that return/trading volume comovement drives attention comovement. Thus our results are suggestive of a causal relation from attention to returns and trading volume. Future research can continue to explore the characteristics and events associated with these forms of comovement as well as the implications of their relation. 25 References Aboody, D., R. Lehavy, and B. Trueman, 2010, “Limited Attention and the Earnings Announcement Returns of Past Stock Market Winners.” Review of Accounting Studies, 15: 317-344 Ball, R. and P. Brown, 1967, “Some Preliminary Findings on the Association between the Earnings of a Firm, its Industry, and the Economy.” Journal of Accounting Research, 5: 55-77 Barberis, N., A. Shleifer, and J. Wurgler, 2005, “Comovement.” Journal of Financial Economics, 75: 283-317 Bushee, B., J. Core, W. Guay, and S. Hamm, 2010, “The Role of the Business Press as an Information Intermediary.” Journal of Accounting Research, 48(1): 1-19. Barron, O., D. Byard, and O. Kim, 2002, “Changes in Analysts’ Information around Earnings Announcements.” The Accounting Review, 77: 821-846. Barron, O., O. Kim, S. Lim, and D. Stevens, 1998, “Using Analysts’ Forecasts to Measure Properties of Analysts’ Information Environment.” The Accounting Review, 73: 421-433. Bhushan, R., 1989, “Firm Characteristics and Analyst Following.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11(2-3): 255-274. Da, Z., J. Engelberg, and P. Gao, 2011, “In Search of Attention.” Journal of Finance, 66(5): 1,461-1,499. Drake, M., N. Guest, and B. Twedt, 2014, “The Media and Mispricing: The Role of the Business Press in the Pricing of Accounting Information.” The Accounting Review, 89(5): 16731701. Drake, M., K. Gee, and J. Thornock, 2014, “March Market Madness: The Impact of Valueirrelevant Events on the Market Pricing of Earnings News,” forthcoming, Contemporary Accounting Research. Drake, M., D. Roulstone, and J. Thornock, 2012, “Investor Information Demand: Evidence from Google Searches around Earnings Announcements.” Journal of Accounting Research, 50(4): 1,001-1,040. Fama, E. and K. French, 1993, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics, 33(1): 3-56. 26 Foster, G., 1981, “Intra-Industry Information Transfers Associated with Earnings Releases.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 3(3): 201-232. Frankel, R., S.P. Kothari, and J. Weber, 2006, “Determinants of the Informativeness of Analyst Research.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 41(1-2): 29-54. Green, T. and B. Hwang, 2009, “Price-Based Return Comovement” Journal of Financial Economics, 93(1):37-50. Grullon, G., S. Underwood, and J. Weston, 2014, “Comovement and Investment Banking Networks.” Journal of Financial Economics, 113(1): 73-89. Han, J., J. Wild, and K. Ramesh, 1989, “Managers’ Earnings Forecasts and Intra-Industry Information Transfers.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11(1): 3-33. Hirshleifer, D. and S. Teoh, 2003, “Limited Attention, Information Disclosure, and Financial Reporting.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 36:337-386. Hirshleifer, D., S. Lim, and S. Teoh, 2009, “Driven to Distraction: Extraneous Events and Underreaction to Earnings News.” Journal of Finance, 64(5): 2,289-2,325. Hou, K., L. Peng, and W. Xiong, 2009, “A Tale of Two Anomalies: The Implications of Investor Attention for Price and Earnings Momentum.” Working paper, The Ohio State University. Kallberg, J. and P. Pasquariello, 2007, Time-Series and Cross-Sectional Excess Comovement in Stock Indexes.” Journal of Empirical Finance, 15(3): 481-502. King, B., 1966, “Market and Industry Factors in Stock Price Behavior.” Journal of Business, 39: 139-190. Kumar, A. and C. Lee, 2006, “Retail Investor Sentiment and Return Comovements.” Journal of Finance, 61(5): 2,451-2,486. Lehavy, R. and R. Sloan, 2008, “Investor Recognition and Stock Returns.” Review of Accounting Studies, 13(2-3): 327-361. Li, J. and J. Yu, 2012, “Investor Attention, Psychological Anchors, and Stock Return Predictability.” Journal of Financial Economics, 101: 401-419. Merton, R., 1987, “A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium with Incomplete Information.” Journal of Finance, 42: 483-510. 27 Morck, R., B. Yeung, and W. Yu, 2000, “The Information Content of Stock Markets: Why Do Emerging Markets have Synchronous Price Movements?” Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1-2): 215-260. Muslu, V., M. Regbello, and Y. Xu, 2014, “Sell-Side Analyst Coverage and Stock Comovement.” Forthcoming, Management Science. Piotroski, J. and D. Roulstone, 2004, “The Influence of Analysts, Institutional Investors, and Insiders on the Incorporation of Market, Industry, and Firm-Specific Information into Stock Prices.” The Accounting Review, 79(4): 1,119-1,151. Ramnath, S., 2002, “Investor and Analyst Reactions to Earnings Announcements of Related Firms: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Accounting Research, 40(5): 1,351-1,376. Teoh, S., Y. Yang, and Y. Zhang, 2009, “R2 and Market Efficiency” Working Paper, University of California-Irvine. Tetlock, P., 2007, “Giving Content to Investor Sentiment: The Role of the Media in the Stock Market.” Journal of Finance, 62: 1,139-1,168. Thomas, J. and F. Zhang, 2008, “Overreaction to Intra-Industry Information Transfers?” Journal of Accounting Research, 46(4): 909-940. 28 Appendix A Variable # Analystsi,t Abs(Reti,t) Analyst Fori,w A-Scorei,w Bk/Mkti,q Bk/Mkti,t Compi,q EAi,w Edgari,w Googlei,w Insti,q Insti,t Mediai,w Mkt Vali,q MOMi,q MVEi,t Peer EAi,w Pricei,t ROAi,q ROAi,t Sales Growthi,q Sales Growthi,t Std ROAi,t Stk Turni,t Sync Analysti,t Sync A-Scorei,t Sync Earni,t Sync Edgari,t Sync Googlei,t Definition equal to the number of analysts following firm i in year t. equal to the buy and hold abnormal monthly return for firm i in fiscal year t. equal to the number of analyst forecasts issued in week w for firm i. a factor analysis using the Googlei,w, Analyst Fori,w, Mediai,w, and Edgari,w variables to identify the common factor and calculate the A-Scorei,t variable for firm i during week w. equal to the book value of equity divided by the market value of equity for firm i in quarter q. equal to the book value of equity divided by the market value of equity for firm i in year t. equal to one minus the Herfindahl Hirschman Index, which is calculated at the annual level. We first divide the firm’s annual sales by the total industry (4-digit SIC code) sales then square the ratio. We then sum the squared ratio by industry. equal to one during the week firm i announces earnings and zero otherwise. equal to the number of searches for firm i's 10-Ks or 10-Qs through the Edgar search platform in week w. equal to the number of google searches for firm i in week w less the median number of google searches in the previous eight weeks for firm i. equal to the percentage of firm i's shares held by institutional investors in quarter q and equal to zero if missing. equal to the percentage of firm i's shares owned by institutions in year t. equal to the number of news articles that mentioned firm i in week w. equal to the market value for firm i calculated at the end of the fiscal quarter q. equal to the buy and hold daily return during quarter q-1 for firm i. equal to the market value of equity for firm i at the end of fiscal year t. equal to one for firm i in week w if a peer firm (i.e., firm in the same four-digit SIC code) announces earnings in week w and zero otherwise. is equal to the stock price for firm i at the end of fiscal year t. equal to net income before extraordinary items in quarter q scaled by total assets in quarter q-4 for firm i. equal to net income for firm i in year t scaled by total assets in year t-1. equal to the sales in quarter q divided by sales in quarter q-4 for firm i. equal to sales in year t divided by sales in year t-1 for firm i. equal to the standard deviation of return on assets between year t-4 and t for firm i. equal to the stock turnover for firm i in year t. calculated similarly to the Sync Googlei,t variable using the number of analyst forecasts issued during week w for firm i. a factor analysis using the Sync Googlei,t, Sync Analysti,t, Sync Mediai,t, and Sync Edgari,t variables to identify the common factor and calculate the Sync A-Scorei,t variable for firm i during year t. equal to the logarithmic transformation, defined as log(R2 / (1 - R2)), of the R2 from a regression of the firm's return on assets on a value-weighted industry index of ROA using quarters t-11 through t. calculated similarly to the Sync Googlei,t variable using the number of searches for 10Ks or 10-Qs during week w for firm i. equal to the logarithmic transformation of the R2, defined as log(R2 / (1 - R2)), using the following model using data over the 52 week period prior to the fiscal year end for firm i in year t: Googlei,w = α + α Ind Googlei,w + Mkt Googlei,w + ε, where Googlei,w is equal to the Google search volume for firm i in week w, Ind Googlei,w is equal to the value weighted Google search volume for industry j (defined as two digit SIC code) in week w, and the Mkt Googlei,w is equal to the value-weighted google search volume 29 Sync Mediai,t Sync Reti,t Sync Turni,t Uncertaintyi,q for all firms with Google search volume in week w. calculated similarly to the Sync Googlei,t variable using the number of media articles written during week w for firm i. calculated similarly to the attention synchronicity variables using returns for firm i during week w. calculated similarly to the attention synchronicity variables using stock turnover for firm i during week w. equal to the average squared analyst forecast error for firm i during quarter q, as presented in Barron, Kim, Lim and Stevens (1998) and Barron, Byard and Kim (2002). Specifically, we compute the variable with the following equation: (1 – (1/N)) * D + SE, where N is the number of analysts following the firm, D is the dispersion of analyst forecasts, and SE is the squared error in the mean forecast. 30 Table 1 Descriptive statistics. Panel A - Attention synchronicity sample descriptive statistics Variable N Mean Std Dev 25th Pctl 50th Pctl 75th Pctl Sync A-Scorei,t 5,663 -0.062 0.903 -0.578 -0.334 0.092 Sync Googlei,t 5,663 0.138 0.342 0.021 0.053 0.121 Sync Analysti,t 5,663 0.265 0.316 0.043 0.147 0.373 Sync Mediai,t 5,663 0.211 0.415 0.032 0.086 0.206 Sync Edgari,t 5,663 0.347 0.392 0.098 0.233 0.454 i,t 5,663 0.099 0.149 0.020 0.052 0.114 Analyst R2i,t 5,663 0.201 0.192 0.042 0.137 0.311 i,t 5,663 0.147 0.184 0.031 0.082 0.186 Edgar R2i,t 5,663 0.252 0.199 0.093 0.208 0.365 Sync Reti,t 5,663 -0.347 1.134 -0.952 -0.211 0.424 Sync Turni,t 5,663 -1.180 1.421 -2.006 -1.002 -0.168 ROAi,t 5,663 0.033 0.120 0.006 0.042 0.088 Mkt Vali,t 5,663 5,773 14,272 384 1,289 3,982 Bk/Mkti,t 5,663 0.662 0.538 0.320 0.545 0.848 Sales Growthi,t 5,663 1.074 0.247 0.957 1.056 1.154 Insti,t 5,663 0.729 0.227 0.600 0.787 0.905 # Analystsi,t 5,663 8.820 6.959 3.000 7.000 13.000 Std ROAi,t 5,663 0.062 0.087 0.015 0.032 0.072 Abs(Reti,t) 5,663 0.362 0.367 0.120 0.259 0.485 Stk Turni,t 5,663 0.029 0.021 0.015 0.023 0.036 Sync Earni,t 5,663 0.256 0.377 0.020 0.102 0.321 SP 500i,t 5,663 0.250 0.433 0.000 0.000 1.000 Pricei,t 5,663 28.016 22.743 10.790 23.110 38.870 2 Google R 2 Media R 31 Panel B - Weekly attention descriptive statistics Variable N Mean Std Dev 25th Pctl 50th Pctl 75th Pctl A-Scorei,w 218,331 -0.002 0.988 -0.737 -0.134 0.616 Googlei,w 218,331 0.004 0.157 -0.016 0.000 0.015 Analyst Fori,w 218,331 1.106 2.048 0.000 0.000 1.000 Mediai,w 218,331 17.815 34.574 2.000 6.000 18.000 Edgari,w 218,331 89.963 100.466 32.000 59.000 107.000 EAi,w 218,331 0.020 0.141 0.000 0.000 0.000 Peer EAi,w 218,331 0.350 0.477 0.000 0.000 1.000 Mkt Vali,q 218,331 7,262 16,910 685 1,900 5,344 Bk/Mkti,q 218,331 0.599 0.461 0.300 0.497 0.776 Sales Growthi,q 218,331 1.087 0.280 0.956 1.060 1.173 ROAi,q 218,331 0.012 0.031 0.003 0.012 0.025 Insti,q 218,331 0.779 0.189 0.680 0.820 0.926 Uncertaintyi,q 218,331 0.132 0.544 0.002 0.010 0.043 Compi,q 218,331 0.767 0.197 0.695 0.821 0.906 MOMi,q 218,331 0.024 0.231 -0.109 0.019 0.139 Panel A includes the descriptive statistics for the attention synchronicity sample. Panel B includes descriptive statistics for the weekly attention sample. All variables are defined in Appendix A. All variables are winsorized at the 1st and 99th percentile. 32 33 34 Table 3 Determinants of attention synchronicity ROAi,t Ln(Mkt Vali,t) Bk/Mkti,t Sales Growthi,t Insti,t Ln(# Analystsi,t) Std ROAi,t Abs(Reti,t) Stk Turni,t Sync Earni,t SP 500i,t Pricei,t Intercept # Observations R2 Sync A-Scorei,t Sync Googlei,t 0.0866 0.6818 0.2417*** 7.4988 0.1282*** 3.6697 -0.0549 -1.6126 -0.6363*** -6.2271 0.1044*** 3.2935 -0.0623 -0.4624 0.0223 0.8278 0.2716 0.2731 0.4174*** 5.0424 0.2609*** 3.8079 -0.0011 -0.7920 -1.7078*** -10.7835 0.0084 0.1797 0.0575*** 3.9172 0.0159 0.9982 0.0082 0.5924 -0.1390*** -2.6245 0.0029 0.2119 0.0267 0.4604 0.0107 0.9545 0.2009 0.4022 0.0841** 2.1902 0.0251 0.9113 -0.0008 -1.0688 -0.2210*** -3.1144 Sync Analysti,t 0.0534 1.2446 0.0488*** 5.4825 0.0386*** 3.6086 -0.0466*** -3.6019 -0.1940*** -6.1230 0.0850*** 7.2955 -0.1049** -2.0457 -0.0096 -0.9771 -0.2097 -0.6475 0.1403*** 5.4797 0.0741*** 3.2271 0.0003 0.7950 -0.1257*** -2.7272 5,663 0.3840 5,663 0.0900 5,663 0.2990 Sync Mediai,t Sync Edgari,t 0.0251 0.3810 0.1075*** 6.0387 0.0486** 2.3729 -0.0051 -0.3108 -0.2613*** -5.4913 -0.0155 -0.9110 -0.0057 -0.0880 0.0034 0.2804 -0.0418 -0.0921 0.1916*** 4.0767 0.0878*** 2.6442 -0.0006 -1.0071 -0.4080*** -4.7211 -0.0044 -0.0828 0.1033*** 8.4188 0.0467*** 3.9175 -0.0020 -0.1145 -0.2437*** -6.0112 0.0336*** 2.7798 0.1184* 1.8060 0.0387*** 3.1789 0.2889 0.7134 0.1953*** 5.5717 0.1145*** 4.3885 -0.0007 -1.3233 -0.3957*** -6.5432 5,663 0.2500 5,663 0.3720 All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are presented below the coefficient estimates. Standard errors are clustered by firm. Year indicator variables are included in the regression but the coefficient outputs are suppressed for brevity. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 35 Table 4 Relation between the synchronicity of attention and the synchronicity of market variables Panel A - Synchronicity of returns on the synchronicity of attention Sync A-Scorei,t Sync Reti,t 0.1460*** 6.5328 Sync Googlei,t Sync Reti,t Sync Reti,t Sync Reti,t 0.1429*** 3.2437 Sync Analysti,t 0.3796*** 6.8216 Sync Mediai,t 0.2049*** 4.3952 Sync Edgari,t ROAi,t Ln(Mkt Vali,t) Bk/Mkti,t Sales Growthi,t Insti,t Ln(# Analystsi,t) Std ROAi,t Abs(Reti,t) Stk Turni,t Sync Earni,t SP 500i,t Pricei,t Intercept # Observations R2 Sync Reti,t 0.0452 0.3059 0.3775*** 17.2605 0.1896*** 5.5211 -0.1949*** -3.2006 0.5037*** 6.0842 0.0189 0.5993 -0.6911*** -3.4743 -0.2040*** -5.5694 0.9124 0.9114 0.2525*** 6.2939 -0.4444*** -7.5517 -0.0022** -2.3140 -3.7930*** -24.6686 0.0567 0.3805 0.4046*** 19.1334 0.2061*** 6.0502 -0.2041*** -3.3407 0.4306*** 5.2521 0.0337 1.0765 -0.7040*** -3.5313 -0.2023*** -5.4439 0.9234 0.9216 0.3015*** 7.1910 -0.4099*** -6.8157 -0.0022** -2.3297 -4.0108*** -27.1770 0.0376 0.2540 0.3943*** 18.6407 0.1937*** 5.7602 -0.1852*** -3.0485 0.4845*** 5.8924 0.0019 0.0602 -0.6604*** -3.2961 -0.1971*** -5.3854 1.0317 1.0426 0.2602*** 6.5587 -0.4345*** -7.4386 -0.0024*** -2.6096 -3.9947*** -27.1395 0.0527 0.3552 0.3908*** 18.0111 0.1984*** 5.7500 -0.2019*** -3.3029 0.4643*** 5.5817 0.0373 1.1832 -0.6991*** -3.4958 -0.2014*** -5.4400 0.9607 0.9530 0.2742*** 6.7669 -0.4243*** -7.1279 -0.0022** -2.3233 -3.9588*** -26.4659 0.2159*** 4.5043 0.0588 0.3971 0.3905*** 17.9893 0.1983*** 5.8101 -0.2025*** -3.3152 0.4634*** 5.6316 0.0269 0.8544 -0.7258*** -3.6392 -0.2091*** -5.6755 0.8897 0.8861 0.2713*** 6.6032 -0.4310*** -7.2146 -0.0022** -2.2908 -3.9570*** -26.5124 5,663 0.4250 5,663 0.4180 5,663 0.4240 5,663 0.4200 5,663 0.4200 36 Panel B - Synchronicity of stock turnover on the synchronicity of attention Sync A-Scorei,t Sync Turni,t 0.2205*** 9.2606 Sync Googlei,t Sync Turni,t Sync Turni,t Sync Turni,t 0.1428*** 2.7807 Sync Analysti,t 0.6165*** 10.9741 Sync Mediai,t 0.2977*** 6.5921 Sync Edgari,t ROAi,t Ln(Mkt Vali,t) Bk/Mkti,t Sales Growthi,t Insti,t Ln(# Analystsi,t) Std ROAi,t Abs(Reti,t) Stk Turni,t Sync Earni,t SP 500i,t Pricei,t Intercept # Observations R2 Sync Turni,t 0.2771* 1.7029 0.3912*** 16.4274 0.0559 1.4256 -0.2606*** -3.5398 0.4176*** 4.3000 -0.0504 -1.2318 -1.1736*** -5.4375 -0.2249*** -4.6430 1.3334 1.1520 0.2062*** 4.6020 -0.1241** -1.9659 0.0007 0.6897 -3.9276*** -23.6071 0.2950* 1.7846 0.4363*** 18.6552 0.0819** 2.0996 -0.2739*** -3.6893 0.2971*** 3.0068 -0.0278 -0.6692 -1.1911*** -5.4760 -0.2215*** -4.4898 1.3646 1.1527 0.2863*** 6.3327 -0.0702 -1.0746 0.0006 0.5496 -4.2727*** -26.2198 0.2633 1.6215 0.4144*** 17.9495 0.0604 1.5758 -0.2440*** -3.2929 0.3969*** 4.1183 -0.0797* -1.9282 -1.1226*** -5.2001 -0.2140*** -4.4122 1.5226 1.3130 0.2118*** 4.8875 -0.1123* -1.7988 0.0003 0.2556 -4.2267*** -26.3604 0.2887* 1.7590 0.4125*** 17.3170 0.0697* 1.7802 -0.2712*** -3.6575 0.3551*** 3.5972 -0.0227 -0.5538 -1.1856*** -5.4563 -0.2209*** -4.5092 1.4058 1.1933 0.2413*** 5.3545 -0.0927 -1.4384 0.0006 0.6433 -4.1827*** -25.5612 0.3163*** 6.3580 0.2976* 1.8162 0.4119*** 17.2094 0.0694* 1.7779 -0.2721*** -3.6796 0.3544*** 3.6042 -0.0379 -0.9259 -1.2248*** -5.5943 -0.2322*** -4.7359 1.3019 1.1185 0.2365*** 5.2555 -0.1028 -1.5956 0.0007 0.6667 -4.1791*** -25.5668 5,663 0.3880 5,663 0.3770 5,663 0.3890 5,663 0.3810 5,663 0.3800 All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are presented below the coefficient estimates. Standard errors are clustered by firm. Year indicator variables are included in the regression but the coefficient outputs are suppressed for brevity. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 37 Table 5 Attention comovement around corporate events EAi,w Peer EAi,w Ln(Mkt Vali,q) Bk/Mkti,q Sales Growthi,q ROAi,q Insti,q Uncertaintyi,q Compi,q MOMi,q Intercept # Observations R2 A-Scorei,w 1.6849*** 85.1948 0.1171*** 5.5146 0.1690*** 7.4287 0.3690*** 16.1936 -0.0226* -1.7693 -0.4146*** -3.3353 -0.0659 -1.5229 0.0136*** 3.4049 -0.2128*** -6.2837 0.0722** 2.4098 -1.3466*** -8.0048 Ln(Googlei,w) 0.0125*** 3.7710 0.0054*** 3.0120 0.0025 1.2335 -0.0008 -0.3808 0.0010 0.5915 0.0127 0.7779 -0.0088* -1.8643 -0.0013* -1.7463 0.0103 1.3433 -0.0038 -1.1602 -0.0329** -2.0137 Ln(Analyst Fori,w) 1.6529*** 149.1949 0.0323*** 3.1441 0.0445*** 3.7464 0.0971*** 7.5402 -0.0075 -0.9127 -0.2454*** -3.2852 0.1648*** 7.2279 0.0088*** 2.7836 0.0249 0.9869 -0.0195 -0.9959 -0.0927 -1.0070 Ln(Mediai,w) 1.5664*** 85.3333 0.1387*** 8.2155 0.2853*** 12.4873 0.2281*** 12.0653 0.0625*** 3.6777 -0.6473*** -4.8491 0.0811** 2.0096 0.0247*** 4.8050 -0.0401 -0.9792 -0.0381 -1.1546 -0.3902** -2.2942 Ln(Edgari,w) 0.3591*** 12.7822 0.0995*** 3.2232 0.0817*** 2.7795 0.4803*** 15.7751 -0.0842*** -4.6991 -0.0619 -0.4391 -0.4019*** -6.5471 -0.0011 -0.2814 -0.4451*** -12.0318 0.2014*** 4.7314 3.8920*** 18.0400 218,331 0.690 218,331 0.068 218,331 0.358 218,331 0.630 218,331 0.613 All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are presented below the coefficient estimates. Standard errors are clustered by week. Firm indicator variables are included in the regression but the coefficient outputs are suppressed for brevity. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 38 Table 6 Attention comovement around corporate events partitioned on attention synchronicity. A-Scorei,w EAi,w Peer EAi,w Ln(Mkt Vali,q) Bk/Mkti,q Sales Growthi,q ROAi,q Insti,q Uncertaintyi,q Compi,q MOMi,q Intercept # Observations R2 Low Synci,t 1.7534*** 95.2568 0.0834*** 4.6049 0.1388*** 7.2844 0.2731*** 14.4710 -0.0231** -2.0740 -0.3910*** -3.8201 -0.0558 -1.4478 0.0073 1.5707 -0.3977*** -8.3793 0.0590** 2.5068 -0.3075* -1.6989 High Synci,t 1.5816*** 60.2263 0.1503*** 6.7030 0.1738*** 5.9617 0.4512*** 16.0645 -0.0228 -1.3825 -0.3434 -1.6287 -0.1525** -2.3782 0.0173*** 3.5440 -0.0084 -0.2021 0.0802** 2.0289 -1.7742*** -6.7978 109,143 0.5680 109,188 0.7190 Difference P-Value -0.172*** <0.001 0.0669*** <0.001 All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are presented below the coefficient estimates. Standard errors are clustered by week. Firm indicator variables are included in the regression but the coefficient outputs are suppressed for brevity. *, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%. 39