Varieties of Welfare Capitalism in Crisis: A Qualitative Comparative Analysis of Labour Market Reforms in 18 Advanced Welfare States Paper presented to the annual conference of the Sheffield Political Economy Research Institute, University of Sheffield, July 1-3. Faraz Vahid Shahidi faraz.vahidshahidi@spi.ox.ac.uk Department of Social Policy and Intervention University of Oxford ABSTRACT Comparative welfare state scholars have long been concerned with explaining the nature and direction of cross-national welfare state developments. This paper contributes the literature on welfare state change by providing an empirical survey of and explanation for labour market reforms enacted across a sample of eighteen advanced welfare states during the period following the economic crisis that began in 2008. Drawing on a set-theoretic multi-method research design, the paper utilizes crisp-set qualitative comparative analysis to systematically test existing theories of welfare state change. The paper finds that the direction of cross-national labour market reforms implemented since the onset of the economic crisis can be explained principally in terms of the variable fiscal capacity of the state. In particular, the results indicate that (i) the presence of fiscal crisis has acted as a necessary (but insufficient) condition for the presence of recommodification; and (ii) the absence of fiscal crisis has acted as a sufficient (but unnecessary) condition for the absence of recommodification. In addition, the findings suggest that mainstream theories of welfare state change do not provide a compelling explanation for the cross-national diversity of contemporary crisis management. I. INTRODUCTION The economic crisis that began in 2008 has provided students and scholars of the welfare state with the opportunity to study the political consequences of severe crisis precisely as they unfold. Advanced political economies have reacted to the recent economic crisis and its associated aftershocks by embarking upon one or another deliberate strategy of crisis management. By crisis management, I mean the variable policy responses that governments formulate in an effort to cope with crisis consequences. Modern welfare states have played a central role in the development and operation of architectures of crisis management. The specific contents of these architectures have varied considerably across space and over time (Farnsworth and Irving, 2011; Pontusson and Raess, 2012; Starke et al., 2013). It is therefore not surprising that contemporary crisis management has manifested itself in an uneven fashion across the landscape of advanced welfare states. Cross-national differences have persisted both in the degree to which countries have been exposed to the crisis, as well as in the responses they have formulated with which to confront it. Thus, despite the international scope of the recent economic crisis, its political consequences have taken a distinctly national form. This paper is concerned with explaining the cross-national variation in contemporary crisis management. It employs qualitative comparative analysis to investigate patterns of recommodification in recent labour market reforms across a sample of eighteen advanced welfare states. The central research questions are as follows. (i) How can we explain patterns of welfare state recommodification in the labour market policy trajectories of advanced welfare states during the aftermath of the recent economic crisis? (ii) What do contemporary patterns of recommodification suggest about the comparative political economy of the welfare state and, in particular, its presumed resilience in the face of present and future challenges. At its core, this paper constitutes an inquiry into the range of factors that have shaped and constrained the observed diversity of contemporary crisis management. In the process of providing an explanation for recent labour market reforms, however, it also offers a preliminary assessment of the extent to which the recent economic crisis has transformed some of the core architectures of advanced welfare states. A sample of eighteen advanced welfare states is included in the paper: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. A number of advanced welfare states are excluded. Luxembourg and Iceland are excluded on the basis of restrictions on the availability of data. Switzerland and Japan have been excluded on the basis that their unique systems of social concertation provide an inadequate foundation for meaningful comparison (Siaroff, 1999). Finally, the United States is excluded because of the presence of significant variation in the direction of welfare state change between individual states. II. EXPLAINING WELFARE STATE CHANGE DURING HARD TIMES Comparative welfare state scholars have long been concerned with explaining the nature and direction of cross-national welfare state developments. The existing literature offers a number of theoretical frameworks with which to attempt to explain welfare state change. According to a first theoretical framework, the welfare state is first and foremost a mechanism of social compensation that is presumed to expand (contract) whenever and wherever there is greater (lesser) need for it (Glatzer and Rueschemeyer, 2005). Advocates of this social compensation hypothesis suggest that socio-economic challenges—be it globalization (Garrett, 1998), deindustrialization (Iversen and Cusack, 2000), or economic crisis (Vis et al., 2011)—create a functional demand for welfare state expansion. Governments are expected to respond to an economic crisis by adjusting the supply of social welfare in order to reflect the objective need for it. Not all welfare states are created equal, however. Rather, the functional need for social compensation is predicted to be greatest in welfare states that are least equipped to cope with the socio-economic consequences of crisis. Accordingly, it is argued that the relationship between an economic crisis and welfare state expansion is moderated by the generosity of existing welfare state measures (Ramesh, 2009). We would therefore expect welfare state expansion to be most likely in small welfare states that lack strong automatic welfare state stabilizers. By contrast, we would expect the functional need for compensation to be the weakest where large automatic stabilizers provide a by and large adequate buffer to the crisis and its consequences. The social compensation hypothesis suffers from a number of theoretical and analytical problems. Chief among these is its functionalist tendency to rely somewhat singularly on impersonal socio-economic forces to explain cross-national patterns of welfare state change (Myles and Quadagno, 2002). The approach lacks a necessary attentiveness to the political and institutional factors that contextualize these forces. Partly in response to the inherent functionalism of the social compensation hypothesis, a second theoretical framework that is sensitive to political conflict has approached the question of welfare state change through the lens of partisan politics (Korpi and Palme, 2003). According to this second approach, the policy objectives of political parties differ systematically according to the perceived interests of their respective constituents. Consequently, even when faced with similar socio-economic circumstances, Left and Right parties are expected to display different preferences vis-à-vis the nature and direction of welfare state reform. Empirically speaking, this partisan politics hypothesis has been particularly successful at explaining the variegated consolidation of modern welfare capitalism during the immediate post-war period (Huber and Stephens, 2001). By contrast, considerable debates have emerged with regards to the salience of partisan politics during the ongoing era of “permanent austerity” (e.g. Hausermann et al., 2013; Kittel and Obinger, 2003). While very little literature has addressed this topic in the specific context of severe economic crisis, the literature that exists has given rise to inconsistent findings: while some observe the persistence of partisan effects during economic downturns (Cusack et al., 2008), others report its diminution (Lipsmeyer, 2011). There are important theoretical reasons to expect partisan politics to retain their significance during periods of economic crisis. While it is true that economic crises affect large portions of the population, they tend to affect the traditional constituencies of left and right parties differently. Thus, the strategies of crisis management they formulate can be expected to differ systematically. An alternative formulation, which we refer to as the constrained partisanship hypothesis, suggests that partisan differences are contingent upon the institutional context in which the crisis unfolds (Starke et al., 2013). More specifically, the salience of partisan politics during a period of economic crisis may depend on the strength of existing welfare state measures. According to this third hypothesis, partisan differences are most likely to appear under conditions where the weakness of automatic welfare state stabilizers demand that governments undertake active forms of crisis management. By contrast, in cases where strong automatic welfare state stabilizers serve as routine buffering mechanisms, passive crisis management may suffice. The result is the depoliticization of crisis management and a concomitant decline in the relevance of partisan politics and any policy differences that it might entail. In other words, the presence (absence) of a partisan effect on crisis management may reflect the absence (presence) of strong automatic welfare state stabilizers. The observation that partisan politics have experienced somewhat of a decline during the ongoing era of permanent austerity has led to the gradual, if partial, displacement of arguments about the “old politics” of the welfare state by those addressing its “new politics” (Pierson, 2001). According to this fourth theoretical framework, the welfare state has become an irreversible and immovable feature of contemporary capitalism. Advocates of this new politics hypothesis advance the argument that the welfare state has generated institutional and political deterrents to retrenchment that make it highly resilient to change. Institutionally speaking, welfare states are said to create increasing returns whose positive feedbacks generate a stability bias in favour of continuity. In addition, the existence of broad welfare state constituencies is said to conspire against an unavoidably unpopular politics of retrenchment. On this basis, those who adhere to the new politics perspective argue that, even in the context of a severe economic crisis, welfare state retrenchment is difficult, if not impossible, to undertake (Kuhnle, 2000; Pierson, 1996). Accordingly, they expect that the radical curtailment of social welfare is unlikely to figure as a central feature of crisis management. Within the context of the emergence of the new politics of the welfare state, a fifth theoretical framework has emphasized the role of institutions in shaping the pathdependent contours of cross-national welfare state change. Institutionalist scholars have brought attention to the fact that, even in the face of a common challenge, welfare states will embark upon different—and often divergent—trajectories of reform (Esping-Andersen, 1996; Hall and Soskice, 2001; Iversen and Wren, 1998; Scharpf and Schmidt, 2000). Proponents of this path dependence hypothesis suggest that welfare states differ systematically in their logic of operation and, consequently, in their responses to a shared set of circumstances. In this sense, an economic crisis is presumed to generate distinct and pathdependent “varieties” or “worlds” of crisis management (Chung and Thewissen, 2011; Iversen, 2007; Lallement, 2011; Wood, 2001). Welfare states are expected to fall back on their established habits and exhibit regime-specific patterns of adjustment whose contents correspond neatly to the logic of pre-existing institutional configurations. Specifically, liberal market economies are expected to rely on market-oriented reforms and a strategy of deregulation. By contrast, non-liberal market economies are expected to reinforce the established principles of the welfare state in order to bolster the advantages that these are thought to confer. In summary, an economic crisis is not only predicted to generate a variegated set of responses, but the ex-post diversity of welfare state responses is explained primarily in terms of the ex-ante diversity of distinct “varieties” and “worlds” of welfare capitalism. Departing considerably from the expectations of the new politics and path dependence hypotheses, a final approach to welfare state change has argued that economic crises can cause the erosion of institutional and ideological constraints and give rise to abrupt and transformative social change. Advocates of this fiscal crisis hypothesis argue that economic crises have the capacity to interrupt and undermine the established principles of the welfare state, revive and reinforce earlier concerns about its long-term viability, and provide the necessary political and economic foundations for radical welfare state retrenchment (Clasen et al., 2012; Vis, 2009; Hay and Wincott, 2013; Streeck, 2011). In other words, economic crises are critical windows of opportunity during which political actors are awarded the necessary capacity to enact reforms that would, under different circumstances, be difficult if not impossible to undertake. Economic crises, so the argument goes, have the potential to fundamentally alter the structural opportunities and constraints that governments perceive themselves to be facing (Bieling, 2012). Significant problem pressures that result from rapidly rising levels of unemployment and declining levels of fiscal stability can generate perceptions—real or imagined—of a fiscal crisis of the welfare state (c.f. O’Connor, 1973). The expectation is that governments will confront such an emergency by embarking upon an agenda of fiscal consolidation whose implications for the welfare state are likely to be dramatic. In summary, a range of theoretical frameworks exists with which to attempt to explain contemporary welfare state change. However, with some notable exceptions, individual frameworks and their corresponding hypotheses tend to highlight one or another determinant of welfare state change to the exclusion of all others. Nevertheless, the complexity of contemporary crisis management is likely to render each of them less than universal. Thus, while an individual framework may prove particularly useful in explaining one or another set of cases, it is unlikely that any of them supplies an adequately dynamic causal formulation with which to tackle broader patterns of cross-national variation. In other words, each theoretical framework is unlikely to provide anything more than a partial explanation for contemporary patterns of recommodification. A central goal of this paper is to use available methodological tools to confront the observed complexity of crisis management with the aim generating a more comprehensive account of its welfare state consequences. The next section of the paper presents qualitative comparative analysis as a method of comparative inquiry that is particularly suited for the analysis of causal complexity across an intermediate-size sample of cases. III. THE STRATEGY OF QUALITATIVE COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS Comparative scholars often face the task of meeting two seemingly contradictory goals: breadth of study and depth of study (Ragin, 1987). On the one hand, the comparativist is interested in undertaking extensive research that is capable of establishing generalizable conclusions across a wide sample of cases. On the other hand, the desire for breadth must be balanced against the demand for intensive research that is capable of attending to the complex and substantive relations that exist between the causal contexts underlying a given case. These seemingly contradictory tendencies have given rise to deep methodological cleavages within the comparative social sciences; namely, between quantitative (i.e. extensive) and qualitative (i.e. intensive) strategies (Brady and Collier, 2004; King et al., 1996). Quantitative strategies in the comparative social sciences are variable-oriented and rely on the application of formal statistical techniques for the study of large samples of data. Despite having the capacity to provide researchers with highly generalizable results, variable-oriented strategies are not well-equipped for tackling the problem of causal complexity. In particular, they employ an additive approach to causation whose assumptions rely on the measurement of independent “net effects”. This approach the substantive relations that exist between causally relevant conditions (Ragin, 2008). Qualitative strategies, on the other hand, are case-oriented and facilitate the in-depth analysis of small-size samples of cases whose complexities are made apparent through the application of more intensive forms of inquiry. Despite offer a more holistic understanding of cases, case-oriented strategies rely on quasi-experimental designs that are limited in their ability to accommodate for causal complexity (Mahoney, 2000). Quasi-experimental research designs involve the systematic comparison of cases with the aim of attributing causation to a single condition (or combination of conditions). These designs are somewhat extreme to the extent that they overlook the possibility that multiple causal recipes can give rise to the same outcome (George and Bennett, 2005). In summary, both variable-oriented and case-oriented strategies are informed by assumptions that undermine their sensitivity to causal complexity. Accordingly, neither set of strategies appears to be particularly appropriate means through which to tackle the present research problem. Rather, an altogether different strategy is required whose epistemological and technical foundations are particularly suited for the study of causal complexity across an intermediate-size sample of cases. Among the methodological tools available to comparative social scientists, qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) represents a powerful instrument for the analysis of causal complexity (Rihoux and Ragin, 2009). As an approach, QCA draws on the extensiveness of variable-oriented strategies and the intensiveness of case-oriented strategies. By drawing on their respective strengths, the method facilitates a shift towards broader and more analytic questions while simultaneously maintaining a holistic understanding of cases. QCA therefore embodies a unique sensitivity to both theoretical generality and case complexity. As a formal technique of analysis, QCA is a configurational comparative method that employs the logic of Boolean algebra and set theory to implement principles of comparison across small- and intermediate-size samples of cases. According to the procedure of crisp-set qualitative comparative analysis (csQCA), the specific variant of QCA employed in this paper, each case is represented configurationally as a combination of causally relevant conditions whose variable presence or absence is said to result either in the occurrence or the non-occurrence of a given outcome of interest, such as recommodification. Cases and their corresponding configurations are systematically compared in order to uncover patterns of similarity and difference between them. Through the application of logical comparison, the method simplifies complex data structures with the overall aim of establishing the conditions of occurrence and non-occurrence of the outcome of interest (i.e. recommodification). Epistemologically speaking, configurational comparative methods rely on a conception of causality that is explicitly sensitive to causal complexity. csQCA and related methods operate through the lens of “multiple conjunctural causation” (Berg-Schlosser et al., 2009). Multiple conjunctural causation implies a number of assumptions. First, it implies that there are multiple distinct causal pathways that can lead to the same outcome. Second, it implies that outcomes are often best explained by a combination of causally relevant conditions, rather than by any single condition alone. Because they are likely to offer meaningful explanation only when they are interpreted in conjunction with one another, the analysis of combinations of causally relevant conditions takes precedence over that of any individual condition. Finally, the concept of multiple conjunctural causation accounts for the possibility of causal asymmetry; that is, it does not assume a priori that the occurrence and the non-occurrence of a given outcome of interest is explained by the same causally relevant conditions. Partly as a result of its sensitivity to causal complexity, QCA and related configurational comparative methods are increasingly viewed as appropriate methodological instruments for comparative welfare state research (Emmenegger et al., 2013). IV. OPERATIONALIZATION AND CALIBRATION Recommodification Recommodification derives its meaning from the corollary concepts of commodification and decommodification. Commodification refers to the condition of labour power under capitalism; namely, as a commodity whose sale in the labour market becomes a necessary pre-requisite for securing the means of subsistence (Room, 2000). Accordingly, decommodification is said to occur when a person can maintain an adequate standard of living without having to rely on the sale of their labour power. Decommodification is therefore used as a term to describe the process whereby the means of subsistence is rendered as a matter of right, rather than as a matter of one’s performance in the labour market (Esping-Andersen, 1990). By contrast, recommodification describes the process whereby state-market relations are reconfigured in such a way as to imply a greater reliance on or heightened exposure to the market as a prerequisite for securing the means of subsistence (Holden, 2003). In other words, one’s ability to secure these means depends to a greater extent upon one’s participation in the labour market. Thus, while decommodification aims to protect citizens from the market, recommodification aims precisely at orienting them towards it. Recommodification has figured as a central feature of recent welfare state transformations and, in particular, the emergence of contemporary “activation” regimes (Peck, 2001). Recommodification is operationalized along three dimensions of labour market policy change. The first dimension of recommodification accounts for labour market policy change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection. The reinforcement of work-related obligations implies a process of recommodification insofar as it strengthens the emphasis on paid employment as a pre-requisite for securing the means of subsistence (Clasen and Clegg, 2007). In the analysis, work-related obligations are said to have been reinforced when (i) mandatory participation in job search activities as a condition for the receipt of unemployment benefits is introduced or intensified; (ii) mandatory participation in active labour market policy schemes as a condition for the receipt of unemployment benefits is introduced or intensified; (iii) the definition of what constitutes a suitable job offer is tightened; or (iv) punitive sanctions resulting from the failure to comply with benefit conditionalities are introduced or intensified. The second dimension of recommodification accounts for labour market policy change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. By reducing the generosity of unemployment protection, one restricts alternatives to paid employment as a pre-requisite for securing the means of subsistence (Pierson, 2001; Van Vliet, 2010). In the analysis, the generosity of unemployment protection is said to have been reduced when (i) the level of unemployment benefits is reduced; (ii) the maximum duration of unemployment benefits is reduced; (iii) access to unemployment benefits is reduced through the tightening of qualifying conditions or the lengthening of the waiting period before benefits can be claimed. The first two dimensions of recommodification account for the variable intensity of recommodification experienced by those who are not engaged in paid employment. A third dimension of recommodification has been included in order to account for the variable intensity of recommodification experienced by those who are engaged in paid employment. This final dimension of recommodification accounts for labour market policy change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. The analysis focuses on changes to the regulatory architectures that govern the parameters of lawful and unlawful dismissals. Accordingly, employment protection is said to have been reduced when (i) the parameters of lawful dismissal is relaxed; or (ii) the punitive consequences associated with the use of unlawful dismissal are relaxed. Notably, employment protection and additional labour market regulations are by and large neglected in existing indices of decommodification (e.g. Esping-Andersen, 1990; Scruggs and Allan, 2006). Nevertheless, they are centrally linked to the experience of commodification and are therefore crucial elements in its reconfiguration vis-à-vis the welfare state (Papadopoulos, 2005). A comprehensive review of labour market reforms enacted across the eighteen advanced welfare states between January 2008 and March 2013 is conducted in order to collect the necessary data on labour market policy change. Temporary labour market reforms are excluded from the analysis on the basis that the aim of the study is to generate insight into the substantive impact of the economic crisis on the long-term trajectories of advanced welfare states. The data were derived from two databases of the European Commission (2013a/2013b) and a database of the International Labour Organization/World Bank (2013). These sources were supplemented with relevant case-based knowledge where such information was available in the existing literature. Table 1 summarizes the results of the comprehensive review of recent labour market reforms across the eighteen advanced welfare states. A more detailed outline of the reforms is provided in Appendix A. The results of the comprehensive review indicate that fourteen of the eighteen cases included in the study enacted at least one measure of recommodification between January 2008 and May 2013. These findings suggest that recommodification may not be as difficult as is often suggested by advocates of the new politics hypothesis (c.f. Pierson, 2001; Kuhnle, 2000). Among the fourteen cases that enacted measures of recommodification in their respective labour market policy architectures, considerable empirical diversity is observed. Cross-national variation is observable both in the relative scale of labour market reforms, as well as in the specific policy instruments they have targeted. A detailed comparison of the labour market reforms reveals that measures belonging to the first dimension of recommodification have been the most common variety of policy change. Work-related obligations in national unemployment protection systems were reinforced in twelve of the eighteen advanced welfare states. They were reinforced through the intensification of existing work-related obligations (e.g. Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, and Portugal); through their extension to additional categories of benefit claimants (e.g. France, Ireland, and New Zealand); through the implementation of new work-related obligations (e.g. Belgium, France, Italy, and Spain); or through the implementation of new punitive sanction measures (e.g. Finland, Ireland, Italy, and the United Kingdom). In addition to work-related obligations, nine of the eighteen cases enacted reforms that reduced the overall generosity of national unemployment protection systems. Generosity was reduced through the reduction of benefit levels (e.g. Belgium, Greece; Ireland, Portugal, Spain, and the United Kingdom); through the reduction of the duration of benefits (e.g. Denmark, France, Ireland, and Portugal); through the abolition of benefit schemes (e.g. Germany); through the tightening of qualifying conditions (e.g. Denmark and Ireland); or through the extension of the waiting period before which benefits can be claimed (e.g. Belgium). Table 1 Overview of Labour Market Reforms, 2008-2013 Change that reinforced the obligation to work Australia Change that reduced the generosity of unemployment protection Change that reduced the strictness of employment protection X Austria Belgium X Canada X Denmark X Finland X France X Germany X X X X X Greece X Ireland X Italy X X X X Netherlands New Zealand X Norway Portugal X X X Spain X X X X X Sweden United Kingdom Sources: European Commission (2013a/2013b); International Labour Organization/World Bank (2013). the obligation to work Australia unemployment protection employment protection X Austria Belgium X Canada X X Finally, six of the eighteen of employment protection by Denmark X cases reduced the strictness X loosening Finland the legal parameters X of lawful individual dismissal (e.g. France, Greece, and France by loosening the legalXparameters of lawful collective X X Greece and Spain); dismissal (e.g. Germany X Greece X Spain); or by reducing the extent of sanctions applied to employers who are found to have transgressed the legal parameters of dismissal (e.g. Italy,XPortugal, and Spain). Ireland X Italy X X X Netherlands In order to derive crisp membership scores, the outcome of interest is calibrated such New Zealand X that each case is described as belonging either to the subset of cases displaying the outcome Norway [1] or to the subset of cases displaying the negation of the outcome [0]. For the purpose of Portugal X X X the present analysis, a distinction is made between cases that display strong Spain X X X evidence of Sweden recommodification and those that display limited or no evidence of recommodification. Unitedevidence Kingdom of recommodification X X Strong is said to be observable when a case tests positively Sources: European Commission (2013a/2013b); International Labour Organization/World Bank (2013). for more than one of the dimensions of recommodification. These cases are assigned a score of [1] for the outcome and are formally operated in the csQCA as the subset of cases that display the presence of recommodification. By contrast, cases that test either positively for only one of the dimensions of recommodification or negatively for all three of them are said to offer limited or no evidence of recommodification. These cases are assigned a score of [0] for the outcome and are formally operated in the csQCA as the subset of cases that display the absence of recommodification. The results of the calibration of recommodification along with the cases that correspond either to its presence or its absence are summarized in Table 2. Table 2 Calibration Results for the Outcome of Interest Cases Recommodification Belgium, Denmark, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, United Kingdom Present [1] Australia, Austria, Canada, Finland, Germany, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden Absent [0] Causally Relevant Conditions A “perspectives approach” is applied to the selection of causally relevant conditions (Amenta and Poulsen, 1994). This approach aims to combine the core propositions of different theoretical hypotheses, such as those outlined above. It has the advantage of facilitating a combinatorial analysis of multiple hypotheses with the aim of deriving a more complex and, by extension, more comprehensive account of the phenomenon under investigation. On the basis of a perspectives approach, a total of five causally relevant conditions are included in the formal csQCA. The raw data corresponding to these five causally relevant conditions is summarized in Table 3. In order to derive crisp membership scores, thresholds are derived for each of the causally relevant conditions according to which the raw data can be recoded into binary form. Whether or not a case meets a defined threshold determines whether it is assigned membership in the subset of cases displaying the condition [1] or in the subset of cases displaying the negation of the condition [0]. The process of calibration is informed by theoretical and substantive criteria (Rihoux and De Meur, 2009). Existing knowledge suggests that labour market policy change during an economic downturn may depend on the partisan composition of government (Cusack et al., 2008; Starke et al., 2013). Accordingly, the first causally relevant condition [RIGHT] accounts for the partisan composition of government. Data on the partisan composition of government were derived from the Comparative Political Data Set (Armingeon et al., 2012). A score of [1] is assigned to countries in which right-leaning parties dominated during key periods of crisis management. A score of [0] is assigned to countries in which left-leaning parties, centrist-parties, or government coalitions involving parties of opposing partisan tendencies dominated during key periods of crisis management. The direction of labour market policy change during an economic downturn may also depend on the fiscal capacity of the state (Bieling, 2012). The current account balance of a national political economy provides a strong indication of the fiscal maneuverability of a country (Claessens et al., 2012). Accordingly, the second causally relevant condition [DEF] accounts for the strength of national current account balances as a proportion of GDP. Data on current account balances were derived from the OECD (2013). A score of [1] is assigned to countries that reported current account deficits in both 2007 and 2008. A score of [0] is assigned to countries that reported a current account surplus in both 2007 and 2008. A third factor that may shape the direction of labour market reforms during an economic downturn is the level of unemployment (Streeck, 2011). Accordingly, the third causally relevant condition [UNEMP] accounts for the change in national levels of unemployment over the course of the economic crisis. Data on unemployment rates were derived from the OECD (2013). Figure 1 shows the percentage change in levels of unemployment between 2007 and 2011 for the eighteen cases. Case-based knowledge suggests that the United Kingdom and Portugal have experienced qualitatively different jobs crises. The United Kingdom has experienced an unexpectedly mild, though far from Table 3 Raw Representation of the Causally Relevant Conditions Partisanship Australia Current Account Balance (% GDP) 2007 2008 Percentage Change in Unemployment, 2007-2011 (%) Variety of Capitalism Automatic Stabilizers -4.5 16 LME 5.6 Left -6.1 Austria Mixed 3.5 4.8 -6 CME 5.4 Belgium Mixed 1.9 -1.3 -4 CME 10.1 Canada Right 0.8 0.3 24 LME 6.7 Denmark Right 1.3 2.6 99 CME 10.5 Finland Mixed 4.0 2.6 13 CME 8.5 France Right -0.9 -1.7 16 SME 6.9 Germany Right 7.4 6.1 -31 LME 7.5 Greece Left -14.3 -14.6 113 SME N/A Ireland Right -5.3 -5.6 209 LME 10.5 Italy Right -2.4 -2.8 38 SME 4.5 Netherlands Right 6.7 4.2 24 CME 10.6 New Zealand Right -8.1 -8.7 78 LME 4.6 Norway Left 12.4 15.9 30 CME 12.9 Portugal Left -10.0 -12.6 60 SME N/A Spain Left -9.9 -9.6 162 SME N/A Sweden Right 9.1 9.0 24 CME 10.6 United Kingdom Right -2.2 -1.0 48 LME 6.6 Sources: Partisanship (Armingeon et al., 2012); Current account balances (OECD, 2013); Unemployment rates (OECD, 2013); Variety of capitalism (Hall and Gingerich, 2009; Schmidt, 2009); Automatic stabilizers (Scruggs, 2004). Figure 2 Automatic Welfare State Stabilizers 15 10 insignificant, increase in unemployment (Clasen et al., 2012; Leschke and Watt, 2010). By 5 contrast, in Portugal, recent labour market reforms have in fact exacerbated an already steep increase in unemployment (Rodrigues and Reis, 2012). The threshold is therefore placed 0 ay No rw de Sw e erl Ire n s an d d lan ark ium nm Fin l Be lg an d an y Ge rm Fra n ce a ad Ca n om gd Au str ia lia d Au str a ala n Ze Ita ly between the United Kingdom (48%) and Portugal (60%). A score of [1] is assigned to Ne th De Kin Un ite d Ne w countries where the increase in unemployment between 2007 and 2011 amounted to 50% or more. A score of [0] was assigned to countries where the increase in unemployment between Source: Scruggs (2004). 2007 and 2011 was less than 50%. Figure 1 Change in Unemployment, 2007-2011 (%) 250 200 150 100 50 0 lan d Ire ain Sp ce Gr ee nm ark nd De ala Ze Ne dK ite w ing do m Po rtu ga l ly ay rw No en ed Ita Un Source: OECD (2013). Sw s Ne the rla nd da na Ca e nc Fra alia str Au lan d Fin um Be lgi tria Au s Ge rm an y -50 A fourth causally relevant condition [LME] is included in order to account for the possibility that labour market policy responses to the economic crisis may vary systematically between differently organized models of welfare capitalism (Lallement, 2011; Iversen, 2007). According to the varieties of capitalism and welfare regimes approaches, when faced with an economic shock, liberal market economies are more likely than nonliberal market economies to rely on a market-oriented strategy of crisis management. A score of [1] is assigned to liberal market economies. A score of [0] is assigned to non-liberal market economies. The distinction between liberal and non-liberal market economies is informed by the empirical analysis of Hall and Gingerich (2009) and Schmidt (2009). Finally, existing knowledge suggests that the presence or absence of automatic welfare state stabilizers may shape the direction of welfare state change during an economic downturn (Ramesh, 2009; Starke et al., 2013). Accordingly, a fifth causally relevant condition [STAB] is included in order to account for the strength of automatic welfare stabilizers. In the analysis that follows, the generosity of unemployment benefits is taken as a proxy for the strength of automatic welfare state stabilizers. Data on the generosity of unemployment benefits were derived from the Comparative Welfare Entitlement Dataset (Scruggs, 2004). Figure 2 lists the generosity scores for the eighteen countries. Case-based knowledge suggests that a significant qualitative distinction can be made between the national unemployment benefit systems of Finland and Germany. While the former is characterized by a comparatively generous and inclusive system of unemployment benefits, the latter is characterized by an exclusive system of unemployment insurance whose generosity has experienced considerable decline over the past decade (Dingeldey, 2011; Picot, 2012). The qualitative threshold is therefore placed between Germany (7.5) and Finland (8.5). A score of [1] is assigned to any country whose unemployment benefit generosity score is 8 or higher. A score of [0] is assigned to countries whose generosity score falls below 8. Figure 2 Automatic Welfare State Stabilizers 15 10 5 ay rw No ed Un ite Ne the Sw rla en nd s d Ire De Be lgi nm lan ark um d Ge Fin rm lan an y e nc Fra m da na Ca Au dK ing do str ia alia Ne w Au Ze str ala Ita ly nd 0 Source: Scruggs (2004). FigureIn1 Change in Unemployment, 2007-2011 (%) the analysis that follows, partisan effects on crisis management are said to be constrained when the case is assigned a score of [1] for the condition [STAB]. In addition, 250 fiscal crisis is said to be present when a case is assigned a score of [1] for either the condition 200 [DEF] or the condition [UNEMP]. By contrast, fiscal crisis is said to be absent when a case is 150 100 assigned a score of [0] for both the condition [DEF] and the condition [UNEMP]. 50 0 d lan Ire Sp ain ce Gr ee ark lan nm d l ga Ze a ing Po rtu do m ly Ita ay en No rw ed Sw nd s rla da na Ca ce Fra n alia str nd Fin la um Be lgi ia str Au rm an y V. TRUTH TABLE ANALYSIS -50 De w Ne dK ite the Ne Au Ge Based on the above calibration of the outcome and the causally relevant conditions, it Source: OECD (2013). Un is possible to generate a configurational representation of the cases and their corresponding membership scores. This is depicted in Table 4. The derived matrix of scores is reformulated into a truth table. The truth table is the fundamental unit of analysis in configurational comparative analysis (Rihoux and De Meur, 2009). It lists all of the logically possible combinations of causally relevant conditions, the cases that correspond to them, and the empirically observed outcomes with which they are associated. Due to limited diversity in the world of actually observed cases of the phenomenon, not all of the logically possible combinations listed in the truth table exist in reality. Table 5 depicts a partial truth table. It is partial because it excludes logical remainders; that is, combinations of causally relevant conditions that are not associated with actually observed cases. Table 4 Configurational Representation of the Cases RIGHT DEF UNEMP Australia 0 Table 4 Configurational Representation of 1the Cases 0 Austria 0 0 0 RIGHT DEF UNEMP Belgium 0 1 0 Australia 0 1 0 Canada 1 0 0 Austria 0 0 0 Denmark 1 0 1 Belgium 0 1 0 Finland 0 0 0 Canada 1 0 0 France 1 1 0 Denmark 1 0 1 Germany 1 0 0 Finland 0 0 0 Greece 0 1 1 France 1 1 0 Ireland 1 1 1 Germany 1 0 0 Italy 1 1 0 Greece 0 1 1 Netherlands 1 0 0 Ireland 1 1 1 New Zealand 1 1 1 Italy 1 1 0 Norway 0 0 0 Netherlands 1 0 0 Portugal 0 1 1 New Zealand 1 1 1 Spain 0 1 1 Norway 0 0 0 Sweden 1 0 0 Portugal 0 1 1 United Kingdom 1 1 0 Spain 0 1 1 Note: [1] denotes presence; [0] denotes absence. Sweden 1 0 0 LME STAB OUTCOME 1 0 0 0 LME 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 STAB 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 OUTCOME 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 0 1 0 0 1 1 1 United Kingdom 1 for the Presence 1 0 1 0 Table 5 Partial Truth Table and Absence of Recommodification Note: [1] denotes presence; [0] denotes absence. RIGHT DEF UNEMP LME STAB OUTCOME Cases Table05 Partial 1Truth Table and 0 for the Presence 1 0 Absence of 0 Recommodification Australia 0 RIGHT 00 01 01 10 11 01 11 DEF0 11 00 10 00 01 00 10 0 UNEMP 00 00 01 00 10 00 00 LME0 10 STAB0 01 10 00 01 10 01 00 00 00 00 11 10 01 0 OUTCOME 01 00 11 00 11 00 10 Austria Cases Belgium Australia Canada Austria Denmark Belgium Finland, Norway Canada France, Italy Denmark Germany Finland, Norway Netherlands, Sweden France, Italy 10 11 01 01 01 01 00 01 00 11 01 01 Greece, Portugal, Spain Germany Ireland Netherlands, Sweden 01 11 11 11 11 10 01 11 00 10 10 11 New Zealand Greece, Portugal, Spain United Kingdom Ireland 1 1 1 1 0 0 New Zealand 1 1 0 1 0 1 United Kingdom 0 1 Truth table analysis proceeds through the process of logical minimization. Broadly speaking, logical minimization refers to the systematic application of Boolean logic with the aim of reducing the complexity of the truth table. The end result of logical minimization is a Boolean solution whose constituent elements reveal minimally relevant causal relations that explain the data within the truth table. The notation and operators involved in the application of Boolean algebra are listed in Box 1. Logical minimization involves the paired comparison of different truth table rows that display the same outcome. The paired comparison of different rows is informed by a simple rule that reflects the system of logic first proposed by Mill (1843). Ragin (1987) summarizes the rule as follows: “if two Boolean expressions differ in only one causal condition, yet produce the same outcome, then the causal condition that distinguishes the two expressions can be considered irrelevant and can be removed to create a simpler, combined expression” (p. 93). Box 1 Boolean Notation and Operators • Upper case letters (e.g. [RIGHT]) represent the [1] value for a given condition. • Lower case letters (e.g. [right]) represent the [0] value for a given condition. • Logical “AND” is represented by the [*] symbol. • Logical “OR” is represented by the [+] symbol. Adapted from Rihoux and De Meur (2009). Depending on the strategy of minimization employed, a single truth table can produce several Boolean solutions of varying complexity (Rihoux and De Meur, 2009; Schneider and Wagemann, 2010). Solutions vary in their complexity based on whether or not they exclude or include logical remainders in the process of paired comparison. If they are excluded, a purely descriptive solution is derived. This descriptive solution does not go much beyond the world of actually observed cases. In order to further reduce the complexity of the truth table, logical remainders can alternatively be included in the process of logical minimization to generate a parsimonious solution. The latter strategy relies on the use of simplifying assumptions. These are simplifying because they allow for a greater number of paired comparisons and, by extension, facilitate the derivation of more parsimonious solutions. However, they are also assumptions because they rely on counterfactual cases that are not observed in the empirical world. Parameters for the use of simplifying assumptions are established on the basis of technical and theoretical criteria (Ragin and Sonnett, 2005). Truth table analysis was conducted for the presence and the absence of recommodification using Tosmana (version 1.3.2). For both the presence and the absence of the outcome, the analysis proceeds in a two-fold manner, beginning with the analysis of necessary conditions and ending with the parsimonious analysis of sufficient conditions. Truth Table Analysis for the Presence of Recommodification The analysis of necessary conditions is concerned with determining whether any condition (or combination of conditions) is necessary for an outcome to occur. In other words, it aims to establish whether the outcome is a subset of a condition (or combination of conditions). The analysis of necessary conditions in configurational comparative methods relies on two measures: consistency and coverage (Bol and Luppi, 2013; Ragin, 2008). Consistency refers to the degree to which a given subset relation is approximated by the data. It is measured as the proportion of cases displaying a given condition (or combination of conditions) among the subset of cases displaying the outcome. Coverage refers to the empirical relevance of a subset relation that has already been determined to be consistent. It is measured as the proportion of cases displaying the outcome among the subset of cases displaying a given condition (or combination of conditions) (Goertz, 2006). Table 6 summarizes the consistency and coverage scores of the causally relevant conditions for the presence of recommodification. The analysis of necessary conditions is conducted using a consistency threshold of 0.900 (Schneider and Wagemann, 2007). Conditions whose consistency scores fall above this threshold are said to be necessary. A test for necessity reveals that none of the individual conditions are individually necessary for recommodification to occur. A test for necessity can also be performed for combinations of conditions. However, such a test is plausible only where there are theoretical arguments to justify it (Schneider and Wagemann, 2007). The fiscal crisis outlined above states that recommodification should occur in the presence of either current account deficits or a significant increase in unemployment. In other words, while the hypothesis holds that fiscal crisis is necessary for the presence of recommodification, there are two causally relevant conditions—[DEF] or [UNEMP]—that individually constitute sufficient but unnecessary conditions for the presence of fiscal crisis. Accordingly, the combination of conditions [DEF + UNEMP] is included in the analysis of necessary conditions. The consistency score for the configuration [DEF + UNEMP] is 1.000, indicating perfect consistency. Furthermore, the combination of conditions reports a somewhat high coverage score of 0.818, revealing that the necessity relation is far from trivial. In other words, fiscal crisis, represented by the combination [DEF + UNEMP], is a necessary condition for the presence of recommodification. A case must display a current account deficit in 2007 and 2008, an increase in unemployment of 50% or more between 2007 and 2011, or both in order for recommodification to occur. UNEMP 0.556 0.833 unemp 0.444 0.333 LME 0.222 0.400 lme 0.778 0.538 STAB 0.333 0.500 stab 0.667 0.500 DEF + UNEMP 1.000 0.818 Table 6 Analysis of Necessary Conditions for the Presence of Recommodification Condition Tested Consistency Coverage Table 4.7 Descriptive Analysis of Sufficient Conditions0.556 for the Presence of Recommodification RIGHT 0.500 right 0.444 Solution Case Coverage 0.500 DEF 0.889 0.800 RIGHT*DEF*unemp*stab + France, Italy, United Kingdom def 0.111 0.125 UNEMP 0.556 0.833 right*DEF*unemp*lme*STAB + Belgium unemp 0.444 0.333 RIGHT*def*UNEMP*lme*STAB + Denmark LME 0.222 0.400 lme 0.778 Greece, Portugal, Spain 0.538 right*DEF*UNEMP*lme*stab + STAB 0.333 0.500 RIGHT*DEF*UNEMP*LME*STAB + Ireland stab 0.667 0.500 DEF + UNEMP 1.000 0.818 Descriptive Analysis Table 74.7 Parsimonious Analysisof ofSufficient Sufficient Conditions Conditions for for the the Presence Presence of of Recommodification Recommodification Solution Solution DEF*lme RIGHT*DEF*unemp*stab + + Belgium, France, right*DEF*unemp*lme*STAB + Case Coverage Greece, Italy, RIGHT*def*UNEMP*lme*STAB + Portugal, Spain right*DEF*UNEMP*lme*stab + Raw Coverage 0.667 Case Coverage UNEMP*STAB + RIGHT*DEF*unemp France, Italy, United Kingdom Belgium France, Italy, United Denmark, Ireland Kingdom Denmark Greece, Portugal, Spain 0.222 0.333 Unique Coverage 0.444 RIGHT*DEF*UNEMP*LME*STAB + Consistency 1.000 0.222 Solution Consistency 1.000 Solution Coverage 1.000 1.000 Ireland 0.111 1.000 Table 7 Parsimonious Analysis of Sufficient Conditions for the Presence of Recommodification The analysis of sufficient conditions with determining the configurations Solution DEF*lme + is concerned UNEMP*STAB + RIGHT*DEF*unemp of conditions that are sufficient for an outcome to occur. The analysis of sufficient conditions Belgium, France, Greece, Italy, Denmark, Ireland Kingdom comparison described above. Table 7 summarizes the results of the parsimonious analysis of Portugal, Spain Italy, United is conducted through the logical reduction of the truth table usingFrance, the process of paired Case Coverage sufficient conditions. The parsimonious solution suggests that there are three causal paths Raw Coverage 0.667 0.222 0.333 that lead to the presence of recommodification. Each causal path is composed Unique Coverage 0.444 0.222 0.111 of a unique Consistency of conditions. However, 1.000 1.000 combination each combination of conditions 1.000 is individually Solution Consistency 1.000 sufficient to ensure the presence of recommodification. The empirical relevance of a solution Solution Coverage 1.000 term is assessed by way of its coverage score (Rihoux and De Meur, 2009). Both raw and unique coverage scores are listed in Table 7. The first term [DEF*lme] in the parsimonious solution combines a current account deficit and non-liberal market arrangements. The second term [UNEMP*STAB] combines a significant increase in unemployment and strong automatic welfare state stabilizers. The third and final term [RIGHT*DEF*unemp] combines a right-leaning government, a current account deficit, and the absence of a significant increase in unemployment. Notably, either [DEF] or [UNEMP] appears in all three of the parsimonious solution terms, confirming the earlier finding that fiscal crisis is a necessary condition for the presence of recommodification. The truth table of the analysis for the presence of recommodification reveals that fiscal crisis—a condition that is sufficiently though not necessarily met by the presence of either [DEF] or [UNEMP]—is a necessary but insufficient condition for the occurrence of recommodification. Fiscal crisis is insufficient insofar as it must operate in combination with the other causally relevant conditions to generate the causal recipes that are sufficient for the presence of recommodification. More specifically, fiscal crisis combines with either (i) the presence of non-liberal market arrangements; (ii) the presence of strong automatic welfare state stabilizers; or (iii) the presence of a right-leaning government and the absence of a significant increase in unemployment in order to create the sufficient conditions for the presence of recommodification. On this basis, [DEF] and [UNEMP] are said to form a pair of SUIN conditions (Mahoney et al., 2009). In other words, they are individual conditions that are sufficient but unnecessary parts of a broader configuration (i.e. fiscal crisis) whose presence is itself insufficient but necessary for the occurrence of recommodification. Truth Table Analysis for the Absence of Recommodification The analysis of necessary conditions for the absence of recommodification proceeds in a similar fashion to that for the presence of recommodification. Table 8 lists the consistency and coverage scores of the causally relevant conditions for the absence of recommodification. All of the causally relevant conditions report consistency scores below the threshold of 0.900. Accordingly, no single condition appears to be individually necessary for the absence of recommodification to occur. Table 9 lists the results of the parsimonious analysis of sufficient conditions for the absence of recommodification. The parsimonious solution indicates that there are three minimally relevant paths that lead to the absence of recommodification. Each of the paths consists of a unique combination of conditions. The first term [def*unemp] in the parsimonious solution combines a current account surplus and the absence of a significant increase in unemployment. The second term [right*unemp*LME] combines a right-leaning government, the absence of a significant increase in unemployment, and liberal market arrangements. The third and final term [UNEMP*LME*stab] combines a significant increase in unemployment, liberal market arrangements, and low levels of automatic welfare state stabilizers. Table 8 Analysis of Necessary Conditions for the Absence of Recommodification Table 8 Analysis for the Absence of Recommodification Condition Testedof Necessary ConditionsConsistency Coverage Condition Consistency Coverage RIGHT Tested 0.556 0.500 RIGHT 0.556 0.500 right 0.444 0.500 right 0.444 0.500 DEF 0.222 0.200 DEF 0.222 0.200 def 0.778 0.875 def 0.778 0.875 UNEMP 0.111 0.167 UNEMP 0.111 0.167 unemp 0.889 0.667 unemp 0.889 0.667 LME 0.333 0.600 LME 0.333 0.600 lme 0.667 0.462 lme 0.667 0.462 STAB 0.333 0.500 STAB 0.333 0.500 stab 0.667 0.500 stab 0.667 0.500 Table 9 Parsimonious Analysis of Sufficient Conditions for the Absence of Recommodification Table 9 Parsimonious Analysis of Sufficient Conditions for the Absence of Recommodification def*unemp + right*unemp*LME + UNEMP*LME*stab Solution def*unemp + right*unemp*LME + UNEMP*LME*stab Solution Austria, Canada, Austria, Germany, Canada, Finland, Case Coverage Australia New Zealand Finland, Germany, Netherlands, Norway, Case Coverage Australia New Zealand Netherlands, Norway, Sweden Sweden Raw Coverage 0.778 0.111 0.111 Raw Coverage 0.778 0.111 0.111 Unique Coverage 0.778 0.111 0.111 Unique Coverage Consistency Consistency Solution Consistency Solution SolutionConsistency Coverage Solution Coverage 0.778 1.000 1.000 0.111 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.111 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 It is noteworthy that the second and third terms in the parsimonious solution account for only a single observed case, respectively. This is reflected in their relatively low coverage scores of 0.111. The low coverage scores indicate that these solution terms are by and large empirically trivial. This is not to say that these terms are theoretically irrelevant. On the contrary, the analysis of atypical or anomalous cases can often generate crucial insights into the causal mechanisms underlying empirical phenomena (Collier et al., 2004). Nevertheless, their overall explanatory relevance to contemporary patterns of recommodification is severely limited, as compared to the first term. Indeed, the first term [def*unemp] is highly empirically relevant. With a coverage score of 0.778, the term covers seven of the nine cases belonging to the subset of cases displaying the absence of recommodification. The combination [def*unemp] represents the absence of fiscal crisis. In other words, the results of the analysis of sufficient conditions demonstrate that the absence of fiscal crisis is a sufficient condition for the absence of recommodification, and that the empirical relevance of this causal path is very high. Finally, the combined truth table analysis for the presence and the absence of recommodification reveals that contemporary patterns of recommodification have unfolded irrespective of (i) the partisan composition of government; (ii) the variety of capitalism; and (iii) the strength of automatic welfare state stabilizers. The results indicate that their explanatory relevance is far from systematic. Thus, it would appear that there is little evidence in favour of theoretical hypotheses whose explanatory underpinnings rely centrally on these conditions. VI. DISCUSSION Revisiting Mainstream Theories of Welfare state Change The empirical regularities unmasked by the configurational analysis of recent labour market reforms suggest that there is a need to revisit mainstream theories of welfare state change and, in particular, the causal leverage they provide during periods of economic crisis. Among the theoretical perspectives that require revisiting, three in particular are addressed in this section of the paper: the social compensation perspective; the path dependence perspective; and the partisan politics perspective. For the purpose of the present discussion, the partisan politics and constrained partisanship hypotheses are addressed simultaneously. Advocates of the social compensation perspective conceive of the welfare state as a mechanism of social compensation that is presumed to expand (contract) whenever and wherever there is a greater (lesser) need for it (Glatzer and Rueschemeyer, 2005). Economic crises are expected to generate increased levels of socio-economic insecurity and, by extension, a functional requirement for welfare state expansion (Ramesh, 2009). The results of this paper have called this perspective and its central claim into question. It is certainly the case that in the immediate aftermath of the recent economic crisis, social protection was temporarily reinforced, albeit to variable extents, by way of labour market reforms aimed at the expansion of short-time work schemes, the strengthening of active labour market policies, the strengthening of unemployment benefit schemes, and their extension to previously excluded groups (Vis et al., 2011). However, this by and large temporary spell of expansionary crisis management has since expired and been displaced by a more austere agenda characterized by a tendency towards less rather greater levels of social protection (Bieling, 2012). In other words, the functional demand for social welfare to which the crisis has given rise has not been met by an increase in the supply of social welfare. This has been the case even where the demand for social welfare has been greatest, such as in Greece and the United Kingdom. This represents somewhat of a break from the economic crises of decades past, the consequences of which triggered structural improvements in levels of social protection (Pontusson and Raess, 2012; Rueda, 2012). Rather than expand the scope of the welfare state, the majority of the governments of advanced political economies have opted to compensate for the most recent crisis by sacrificing established levels protection in favour of fiscal consolidation. The observed inconsistency between the theory and evidence of social compensation raises concerns regarding its functionalist tendency to neglect the political, institutional, and economic conditions that define the parameters according to which governments determine what is or is not a necessary measure of social compensation. Whether or not there is room for such compensatory maneuvering is contingent upon a range of factors, not least of all the political will of government actors, their perceptions of economic and fiscal constraints, and the institutional contexts in which they are situated. A second strand of literature has highlighted the role of institutional path dependence in shaping cross-national welfare state change. Advocates of path dependence argue that welfare states differ systematically in their logic of operation and, consequently, in the responses they are likely to formulate when confronted by a common challenge (EspingAndersen, 1996; Hall and Soskice, 2001; Iversen and Wren, 1998; Scharpf and Schmidt, 2000). During periods of economic crisis, welfare states are therefore expected to fall back on their old habits and exhibit regime-specific patterns of adjustment (Chung and Thewissen, 2011; Iversen, 2007; Lallement, 2011). In other words, advocates of path dependence attempt to explain the cross-national diversity of crisis responses by making reference to the presence of pre-existing differences in cross-national institutional architectures. This paper has provided limited evidence of any such rigid pattern of correspondence between institutional contexts and crisis responses. Indeed, patterns of recommodification have deviated from the predictions of the path dependence literature in some important ways. Countries with similar institutional arrangements, such as Sweden and Denmark, have embarked upon very different strategies of crisis management. Moreover, countries with different institutional arrangements, such as Denmark and Greece, have nevertheless shared similar trajectories of crisis management. More generally, in contrast to the claims of the path dependence literature, the presence and the absence of recommodification is visible across the established “worlds” and “varieties” of welfare capitalism. Neither the presence of recommodification has been confined to liberal market economies, nor its absence confined to their non-liberal counterparts. Taken together, these findings suggest that the ex post diversity of cross-national crisis management cannot be explained strictly or even primarily in terms of the ex ante diversity of cross-national institutional architectures. These findings confirm the conclusions raised by a number of recent comparative surveys of crisis management (Bermeo and Pontusson, 2012; Clasen et al., 2012; Grant and Wilson, 2012; Heyes et al., 2012; Pontusson and Raess, 2012). A third strand of literature has highlighted the role of partisan politics in shaping cross-national welfare state change (Korpi and Palme, 2003). This literature has suggested that strategies crisis management should differ systematically between left and right parties, with the latter being more likely to opt for a market-oriented crisis reaction. However, the findings of this paper suggest that partisan politics provide little causal leverage for explaining cross-national patterns of labour market policy reforms in the aftermath of the recent economic crisis. In other words, the partisan composition of governments explains neither the observed disinclination towards social compensation nor the corollary tendency towards recommodification. This is the case both in countries with weak automatic welfare state stabilizers and in countries where strong automatic welfare state stabilizers are presumed to have depoliticized crisis management (c.f. Starke et al., 2013). In other words, contemporary patterns of recommodification have unfolded, by and large, irrespective of the partisan complexion of ruling parties. It is noteworthy, however, that some instances of crisis management appear to have an important partisan component to them. The results of this paper suggest that this is particularly true for Australia and the United Kingdom, where strong partisan differences have persisted between parties of the left and their counterparts to the right (Starke et al., 2013; Taylor-Gooby and Stoker, 2011). Notably, both countries display weak automatic welfare state stabilizers. Nevertheless, the overall results of the analysis suggest that the recent economic crisis has, for the most part, encouraged a political convergence between parties of varying ideological tendencies (c.f. Bermeo and Pontusson, 2012; Pontusson and Raess, 2012). The existing literature on partisanship and welfare state change provides a number of explanations for such a convergence. On the one hand, Rueda (2012) has pointed to the fact that, contrary to the crises of decades past, the recent economic crisis has primarily affected labour market outsiders whose interests are increasingly neglected by both centreleft and centre-right parties (Rueda, 2007). However, this explanation cannot account for instances of recommodification that have targeted labour market insiders. For example, it fails to explain the recommodification of unemployment benefits in Denmark and the erosion of employment protection legislation in Southern Europe. It would therefore appear that an altogether different explanation is required. Notably, the results of the analysis have highlighted the central importance of economic conditions in shaping contemporary patterns of recommodification. This would suggest that economic constraints associated with economic crises have the capacity to restrict the policy options available to political parties, which in turn results in a political convergence across them. The Fiscal Crisis of the Welfare State The results have demonstrated that economic conditions in general and fiscal crisis in particular have played a particularly powerful role in shaping and, perhaps more appropriately, constraining contemporary patterns of welfare state change. The analysis of recent labour market reforms has revealed that the presence of fiscal crisis is a necessary (but insufficient) condition for the presence of recommodification. It has also revealed that the absence of fiscal crisis is a sufficient (but unnecessary) condition for the absence of recommodification. Together, these results point to the centrality of fiscal concerns as a determinant of welfare state change since the onset of the recent economic crisis. In the immediate aftermath of the economic crisis, the governments of advanced political economies enacted an array of expensive rescue measures with the aim of stabilizing financial markets and stimulating domestic demand. As part of this expansionary phase of crisis management, social programs were temporarily adjusted so as to provide for greater levels of labour market protection (Clasen et al., 2012). Notably, governments have had to mobilize considerable financial resources in order to accomplish these activities (Bieling, 2012). The combined direct and indirect costs of the economic crisis have implied a dramatic increase in public debt. The rapid increase in public indebtedness in turn encouraged governments to promote austere exit strategies through which they now intend to re-establish and maintain the conditions of fiscal stability (Heyes, 2013). If a temporary expansion of labour market protection was the defining feature of earlier crisis responses, then the defining feature of contemporary exit strategies has been a structural decline in labour market protection. If we are correct in assuming that democratic governments are inclined to provide relief against the experience of socio-economic insecurity, the question remains why electoral concerns have not encouraged the governments of advanced welfare states to compensate for the insecurities that have resulted from the recent economic crisis (Pontusson and Raess, 2012). In contrast to the economic crises of decades past, it would appear that the fiscal scope for an expansion of the welfare state was sorely lacking across the landscape of advanced political economies. Indeed, the potential for such expansionary maneuverability was limited regardless of the institutional and partisan context in which crisis management unfolded. In some countries, fiscal pressures have interrupted preexisting policy legacies and facilitated the enactment of path-breaking reforms. In others, they have limited the policy options that both parties of the right and parties of the left have perceived to be available to them, resulting in a political convergence between them. This is not to deny the causal relevance of institutional and partisan conditions to individual cases of crisis management. Indeed, as the above analysis has indicated, fiscal crisis operates neither singularly as a necessary condition for the presence of recommodification, nor universally as a sufficient condition for its absence. Nevertheless, at least since the onset of the recent economic crisis, the explanatory weight of institutional and political factors has diminished considerably while the causal leverage provided by economic conditions in general and fiscal crisis in particular has increased dramatically. It follows that a scholarly preoccupation with institutional arrangements and partisan politics may result in a neglect of the conditions that have proven most decisive during the aftermath of the recent economic crisis. In summary, the paper findings suggest that contemporary patterns of welfare state change can be explained principally in terms of the variable fiscal capacity of the state. Where the fiscal stability of public finances has been more or less maintained, governments have been awarded the sufficient conditions to avoid resorting to measures of recommodification. By contrast, where perceptions of an acute fiscal crisis have dominated, the established principles of the welfare state have eroded. Moreover, their erosion has provided the necessary political and economic conditions for governments to embark upon variable trajectories of recommodification (c.f. Vis, 2009). In countries where the fiscal maneuverability of the state has been constrained, social policy goals have been subordinated to the objective of re-establishing the conditions of fiscal stability (Bieling, 2012; Heyes, 2013). All in all, while the recent economic crisis has generated a functional demand for welfare state expansion, the governments of advanced political economies have thus far proven incapable or unwilling to meet it. These empirical developments raise important theoretical questions regarding the propensity of the capitalist state to sacrifice social welfare in order to promote economic recovery. They demand, in other words, a scholarly return to the problematic relationship between the welfare state and capitalism (Streeck, 2011). Continuity and Change in Contemporary Welfare Capitalism The tensions inherent to the relationship between the welfare state and capitalism have proven less than fatal and not altogether unmanageable (Pierson, 2006). Indeed, early theoretical articulations of an imminent crisis of the welfare state have given way to a rather broad consensus that its architectures display a remarkable degree of institutional and ideological resilience (Castles, 2004; Kuhnle, 2000; Pierson, 2001). According to this consensus and its assumptions about the “new politics” of the welfare state, the crisis has not arrived as predicted because the welfare state has established itself as a permanent and immovable feature of contemporary capitalism. Notably, the recent economic crisis has undermined this consensus and revived earlier concerns about the long-term viability of the welfare state (Hay and Wincott, 2013; Yerkes and van der Veen, 2011). The question today, as it was thirty years ago, is whether the crisis has compromised the institutional and ideological barriers to radical welfare state retrenchment and thereby posed a fundamental challenge to the presumed continuity of contemporary welfare capitalism. To what extent has the recent economic crisis succeeded in transforming some of the core architectures of advanced welfare states? While the results of this paper do not provide a definitive answer to the question, they nevertheless suggest that proponents of the “new politics” perspective have drastically overemphasized the resilience of the welfare state. Since the onset of the economic crisis in 2008, employment and unemployment protection systems have been subject to significant and unexpected levels of change. With some exceptions, labour market reforms have implied the introduction of lower rather than higher standards of social protection. In this sense, modern welfare states have not withstood the test of resilience, at least as it is conceived by advocates of the new politics hypothesis. Of course, the extent of recommodification has varied considerably across countries. In some cases, it has even been more or less absent. Indeed, the political consequences of the economic crisis have manifested themselves unevenly across the landscape of advanced political economies. The persistence of institutional diversity, however, does not negate evidence of the fact that advanced welfare states are converging upon a common political agenda of fiscal consolidation. Nor does it contradict the observation that recommodification has figured as an important empirical feature of this agenda. In summary, contemporary welfare state developments are characterized by both parallel trends and persisting differences (Heyes et al., 2012; Thelen, 2012). These empirical developments are not easily accounted for by institutionalist accounts of path dependence and their claims about the centrality of institutional equilibria (e.g. Ebbinghaus and Manow, 2001; Hall and Thelen, 2009) and institutional complementarities (e.g. Hall and Gingerich, 2009; Rhodes, 2005). In fact, contemporary patterns of recommodification call into question the prevailing notion that cross-national responses to exogenous crises vary systematically according to different “world” and “varieties” of welfare capitalism (c.f. Chung and Thewissen, 2011; Iversen, 2007; Lallement, 2011; Wood, 2001). To this extent, the complexity of contemporary welfare state developments appears to pose a critical challenge against the concept of path dependence and the institutional determinism from which it has been known to suffer (Crouch and Farrell, 2004; Deeg and Jackson, 2007). At its core, the literature on path dependence has been informed by a static comparativism whose methodological and analytical shortcomings have led its advocates to stress the continuity of institutional diversity across different “worlds” and “varieties” of welfare capitalism at the expense of broader historical transformations that they have shared in common (Coates, 2000/2005; Heyes et al., 2012; Howell, 2003; Pontusson, 2005). The varieties of capitalism literature and its proponents among comparative welfare state scholars have relied on cross-sectional snapshots of institutional diversity in order to code countries somewhat strictly into one or another ideal type whose logic they are presumed to observe without interruption. As demonstrated by the recent economic crisis, however, the contours of institutional configurations can be renegotiated, redefined, and reoriented. In contrast to the assumptions of the path dependence literature, the nature and direction of social and political outcomes is not always-already determined by the institutional context in which they unfold. This literature has suffered from a “path dependence” of its own, which has overlooked empirical developments such as those reviewed in this paper (Bruff and Horn, 2012, p. 162). More specifically, its bias in favour of institutional continuity and stability within each “world” or “variety” of welfare capitalism has led to a neglect of actually-existing patterns of change within and across them. As comparativists, we face the challenge of having to attend to both cross-national similarities and cross-national differences (Pontusson, 1995). However, recent scholarship on the impact of the economic crisis has tended to take notice of the former while largely ignoring the latter (e.g. Chung and Thewissen, 2011; Hay and Wincott, 2013; Hemerijck, 2012; Lallement, 2011; Starke et al., 2013). It is true that the crisis has played out differently across advanced political economies, giving rise to unique varieties of crisis management. These varieties nevertheless share some features in common, including an overarching emphasis on fiscal consolidation. The simultaneous presence of parallel trends and persisting differences suggests the need to attend to both continuity and change in contemporary welfare capitalism. After all, while many varieties of crisis management are observable across the landscape of advanced political economies, they are all of a distinctly capitalist nature. VII. CONCLUSION The political consequences of the recent economic crisis have manifested themselves unevenly across the landscape of advanced welfare states. As a result, cross-national variation is clearly observed with respect to the policy responses formulated in the aftermath of its emergence. This paper has attempted to make sense of this cross-national diversity by investigating the political, economic, and institutional conditions that have shaped and constrained it. The existing literature on welfare state change provides a number of theoretical frameworks with which to explain cross-national social policy developments. Drawing on a set-theoretic multi-method research design, the paper has systematically tested these frameworks and their corresponding hypotheses. A crisp-set qualitative comparative analysis of recent labour market reforms was conducted for the purpose of uncovering the conditions under which welfare state recommodification has occurred and not occurred across a sample of eighteen advanced welfare states. The results indicate that economic conditions in general and fiscal crisis in particular have operated as particularly decisive determinants of welfare state change since the onset of the economic crisis in 2008. In particular, the analysis demonstrates that (i) the presence of fiscal crisis is a necessary (but insufficient) condition for the presence of recommodification; and (ii) the absence of fiscal crisis is a sufficient (but unnecessary) condition for the absence of recommodification. Notably, mainstream theories of welfare state change and their corresponding hypotheses do not provide a compelling explanation for the cross-national diversity of contemporary crisis management. The paper has therefore illustrated that the determinants of welfare change operating during one era are not necessarily the same as those operating during another. As a direct result of the crisis and ongoing attempts to arrest it, the fiscal crisis of the welfare state—whether real or imagined—has returned as a core concern across the political landscape of advanced welfare states (Gough, 2010; Hay and Wincott, 2013). In countries where the consequences of the crisis have been most acutely experienced, the established principles of the welfare state have been severely undermined. To the extent that the necessary conditions for recommodification have presented themselves, the economic crisis can be said to have generated a concomitant, if only partial, crisis of the welfare state. In other countries, an immediate sense of fiscal crisis has been more or less absent. Its absence has, in turn, presented governments with sufficient conditions to refrain from embarking upon explicit trajectories of welfare state recommodification. However, broader concerns about the need to re-establish the conditions of fiscal stability have nevertheless given rise to variegated agendas of fiscal consolidation whose consequences for the welfare state are as of yet unclear. While the economic crisis has generated a functional demand for welfare state expansion, the governments of advanced welfare states have thus far proven incapable or unwilling to supply it. Whether the observed disinclination to social compensation will persist into the future or will be displaced by an altogether different agenda remains an empirical question. VIII. BIBLIOGRAPHY Amenta, E. and Poulsen, J.D. (1994). Where to begin? A survey of five approaches to selecting independent variables for qualitative comparative analysis. Sociological Methods and Research, 23(1), 22-53. Armingeon, K., Weisstanner, D., Engler, S., Potolidis, P., and Gerber, M. (2012). Comparative political data set: 1960-2010. Berg-Schlosser, D., De Meur, G., Rihoux, B., and Ragin, C.C. (2009). Qualitative comparative analysis (QCA) as an approach. In: Rihoux, B. and Ragin, C.C. (eds.) Configurational comparative methods: Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and related techniques. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Bermeo, N. and Pontusson, J. (eds.) (2012). Coping with crisis: Government reactions to the Great Recession. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Bieling, H-J. (2012). EU facing the crisis: Social and employment policies in times of tight budgets. Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 18(3), 255-271. Brady, H.E. and Collier, D. (eds.) (2004). Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared standards. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers. Bruff, I. and Horn, L. (2012). Varieties of capitalism in crisis? Competition and Change, 16(3), p. 161-168. Castles, F.G. (2004). The future of the welfare state: Crisis myths and crisis realities. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Chung, H. and Thewissen, S. (2011). Falling back on old habits? A comparison of social and unemployment crisis reactive policy strategies in Germany, the UK and Sweden. Social Policy & Administration, 45(4), p. 354-370. Claessens, S., Dell’Ariccia, G., Igan, D., and Laeven, L. (2010). Cross-country experiences and policy implications from the global financial crisis. Economic Policy, 25(62), 267-293. Clasen, J. and Clegg, D. (2007). Levels and levers of conditionality: Measuring change within welfare states. In: Clasen, J. and Siegel, N. (eds.) Investigating welfare state change: The dependent variable problem in comparative analysis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Clasen, J., Clegg, D., and Kvist, J. (2012). European labour market policies in (the) crisis. ETUI working paper No. 2012.12. Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Clasen, J. and Siegel, N. (eds.) (2007). Investigating welfare state change: The dependent variable problem in comparative analysis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Coates, D. (ed.) (2000). Models of capitalism: Growth and stagnation in the modern era. Cambridge: Polity Press. Coates, D. (ed.) (2005). Varieties of capitalism, varieties of approaches. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Collier, D., Mahoney, J., and Seawright, J. (2004). Claiming too much: Warnings about selection bias. In: Brady, H.E. and Collier, D. (eds.) Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared standards. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers. Crouch, C. and Farrell, H. (2004). Breaking the path of institutional development? Alternatives to the new determinism. Rationality and Society, 16(1), 5-43. Cusack, T.R., Iversen, T. and Rehm, P. (2008). Economic shocks, inequality, and popular support for redistribution. In: Beramendi, P. and Anderson, C.J. (eds.) Democracy, inequality, and representation. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Deeg, R. and Jackson, G. (2007). Towards a more dynamic theory of capitalist variety. SocioEconomic Review, 5, 149-179. Dingeldey, I. (2007). Between workfare and enablement: The different paths to transformation of the welfare state: A comparative analysis of activating labour market policies. European Journal of Political Research, 46(6), 823-851. Ebbinghaus, B. and Manow, P. (eds.) (2001). Comparing welfare capitalism: Social policy and political economy in Europe, Japan, and the USA. London: Routledge. Emmenegger, P., Kvist, J., and Skaaning, S-E. (2013). Making the most of configurational comparative analysis: An assessment of QCA applications in comparative welfarestate research. Political Research Quarterly, 66(1), 185-190. Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press. Esping-Andersen, G. (ed.) (1996). Welfare states in transition: National adaptations in global economies. London: Sage Publications. Farnsworth, K. and Irving, Z. (eds.) (2011). Social policy in challenging times: Economic crisis and welfare systems. Bristol: The Policy Press. Garrett, G. (1998). Partisan politics in the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. George, A.L. and Bennett, A. (2005). Case studies and theory development in the social sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Glatzer, M. and Rueschemeyer, D. (2005). Globalization and the future of the welfare state. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Grant, W. and Wilson, G.K. (eds.) (2012). The consequences of the global financial crisis: The rhetoric of reform and regulation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hall, P. and Gingerich, D.W. (2009). Varieties of capitalism and institutional complementarities in the political economy: An empirical analysis. British Journal of Political Science, 39(3), p. 449-482. Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (eds.) (2001). Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage. New York: Oxford University Press. Hall, P. and Thelen, K. (2009). Institutional change in varieties of capitalism. Socio-Economic Review, 7(1), 7-34. Hancké, B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (eds.) (2007). Beyond varieties of capitalism: Conflict, contradictions, and complementarities in the European economy. Hausermann, S., Picot, G., and Geering, D. (2013). Rethinking party politics and the welfare state—Recent advances in the literature. British Journal of Political Science, 43(1), 221240. Hay, C. and Wincott, D. (2013). The political economy of European welfare capitalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Hemerijck, A. (2012). Stress-testing the new welfare state. In: Bonoli, G. and Natali, D. (eds.) The politics of the new welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Heyes, J. (2013). Flexicurity in crisis: European labour market policies in a time of austerity. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 19(1), 71-86. Heyes, J., Lewis, P. and Clark, I. (2012). Varieties of capitalism, neoliberalism, and the economic crisis of 2008-? Industrial Relations Journal, 43(3), 222-241. Holden, C. (2003). Decommodification and the workfare state. Political Studies Review, 1, 303316. Howell, C. (2003). Varieties of capitalism: And then there was one? Comparative Politics, 36(1), p. 103-124. Huber, E. and Stephens, J.D. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. International Labour Organization/World Bank. (2013). Inventory of policy responses to the global financial and economic crisis of 2008. Accessed on January 15, 2013. Iversen, T. (2007). Economic shocks and varieties of government responses. In: Hancké, B., Rhodes, M. and Thatcher, M. (eds.) Beyond varieties of capitalism: Conflict, contradictions, and complementarities in the European economy. Iversen, T. and Cusack, T.R. (2000). The causes of welfare state expansion: Deindustrialization or globalization? World Politics, 52(3), 313-349. Iversen, T. and Wren, A. (1988). Equality, employment, and budgetary restraint: The trilemma of the service economy. World Politics, 50(4), p. 507-546. King, G., Keohane, R.O., and Verba, S. (1994). Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Kittel, B. and Obinger, H. (2003). Political parties, institutions, and the dynamics of social expenditure in times of austerity. Journal of European Public Policy, 10(1), p. 20-45. Korpi, W. and Palme, J. (2003). New politics and class politics in the context of austerity and globalization: Welfare state regress in 18 countries, 1975-1995. American Political Science Review, 97, p. 425-446. Kuhnle, S. (ed.) (2000). Survival of the European welfare state. London: Routledge. Lallement, M. (2011). Europe and the economic crisis: forms of labour market adjustment and varieties of capitalism. Work, Employment and Society, 25(4), 627-641. Leschke, J. and Watt, A. (2010). How do institutions affect the labour market adjustment to the economic crisis in different EU countries? ETUI working paper No. 2010.04. Brussels: European Trade Union Institute. Lipsmeyer, C.S. (2011). Booms and busts: How parliamentary governments and economic context influence welfare policy. International Studies Quarterly, 55(4), p. 959-980. Mahoney, J. (2000). Strategies of causal inference in small-N analysis. Sociological Methods & Research, 28(4), 387-424. Myles, J. and Quadagno, J. (2002). Political theories of the welfare state. Social Service Review, 76(1), 34-57. O’Connor, J. (1973). The fiscal crisis of the state. New York: St. Martin’s Press. OECD. (2013). Stat extracts. Accessed January 15, 2013. Papadopoulos, T. (2006). Support for the unemployed in a familistic welfare regime. In: Petmesidou, M. and Mossialos, E. (eds.) Social policy developments in Greece. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing Limited. Peck, J. (2001). Workfare states. New York: The Guilford Press. Pierson, C. (2006). Beyond the welfare state? The new political economy of welfare. Cambridge: Polity Press. Pierson, P. (1996). The new politics of the welfare state. World Politics, 48(2), p. 143-179. Pierson, P. (ed.) (2001). The new politics of the welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Pontusson, J. (1995). Explaining the decline of European social democracy. World Politics, 47(4), 495-533. Pontusson, J. (2005). Varieties and commonalities of capitalism. In: Coates, D. (ed.) Varieties of capitalism, varieties of approaches. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Pontusson, J. and Raess, D. (2012). How (and why) is this time different? The politics of economic crisis in Western Europe and the United States. Annual Review of Political Science, 15, p. 13-33. Ragin, C.C. (1987). The comparative method: Moving beyond qualitative and quantitative strategies. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Ragin, C.C. (2008). Redesigning social inquiry: Fuzzy sets and beyond. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Ramesh, M. (2009). Economic crisis and its social impacts: Lessons from the 1997 Asian Economic Crisis. Global Social Policy, 9(supplement), p. 79-99. Rhodes, M. (2005). ‘Varieties of capitalism’ and the political economy of European welfare states. New Political Economy, 10(3), 363-370. Rihoux, B. and De Meur, G. (2009). Crisp-set qualitative comparative analysis (csQCA). In: Rihoux, B. and Ragin, C.C. (eds.) Configurational comparative methods: Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and related techniques. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Rihoux, B. and Ragin, C.C. (eds.) (2009). Configurational comparative methods: Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and related techniques. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Rodrigues, J. and Reis, J. (2012). The asymmetries of European integration and the crisis of capitalism in Portugal. Competition and Change, 16(3), 188-205. Room, G. (2000). Commodification and decommodification: A developmental critique. Policy & Politics, 28(3), 331-351. Rueda, D. (2007). Social democracy inside out: Partisanship and labor market policy in advanced industrialized democracies. Oxford: Oxford University press. Rueda, D. (2012). Dualization and crisis. Swiss Political Science Review, 18(4), 523-530. Scharpf, F.W. and Schmidt, V.A. (2000). Welfare and work in the open economy: From vulnerabilities to competitiveness. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Schmidt, V.A. (2009). Putting the political back into political economy by bringing the state back in yet again. World Politics, 61(3), 516-546. Scruggs, L. (2004). Welfare state entitlements data set: A comparative institutional analysis of eighteen welfare states. Scruggs, L. and Allan, J. (2006). Welfare-state decommodification in 18 OECD countries: A replication and revision. Journal of European Social Policy, 16(1), 55-72. Siaroff, A. (1999). Corporatism in 24 industrial democracies: Meaning and measurement. European Journal of Political Research, 36(2), 175-205. Starke, P., Kaasch, A., and van Hooren, F. (2013). The welfare state as crisis manager: Explaining the diversity of policy responses to economic crisis. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Streeck, W. (2011). The crises of democratic capitalism. New Left Review, 71, 5-29. Taylor-Gooby, P. and Stoker, G. (2011). The coalition programme: A new vision for Britain or politics as usual? The Political Quarterly, 82(1), 4-15. Thelen, K. (2012). Varieties of capitalism: Trajectories of liberalization and the new politics of social solidarity. Annual Review of Political Science, 15, 137-159. van Vliet, O. (2010). Divergence within convergence: Europeanization of social and labour market policies. Journal of European Integration, 32(3), 269-290. Vis, B. (2009). The importance of socio-economic and political losses and gains in welfare state reform. Journal of European Social Policy, 19(5), 395-407. Vis, B., van Kersbergen, K. and Hylands, T. (2011). To what extent did the financial crisis intensify the pressure to reform the welfare state? Social Policy & Administration, 45(4), p. 338-353. Wood, S. (2001). Labour market regimes under threat? Sources of continuity in Germany, Britain, and Sweden. In: Pierson, P. (ed.) The new politics of the welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press. APPENDIX A: DETAILED OVERVIEW OF LABOUR MARKET REFORMS Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection • Job search requirements now apply immediately upon the receipt of unemployment benefits rather than after three months. • The geographical scope of job search requirements has been extended from 25km to 60km. Australia Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. Austria • Belgium • The right to limit job search according to the recipient’s previous employment now ends after 3 months for youth and 5 months for others rather than after 6 months. Personal contracts with public employment services are now mandatory rather than voluntary. • Benefit levels after 15 months of unemployment have been reduced by 12% for a co-habiting person with dependents, 17.5% for a person living alone, and 41.5% for a co-habiting person with no dependents. • The waiting period for youth to receive unemployment benefits has increased from nine months to one year. Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection Canada • The right to limit job search according to the recipient’s previous wage has been abolished. • A new measure dictates that job search should take place up to 100km away from the recipient’s place of residence, whereas previously the recipient could limit job search to the immediate area in which they lived. • Denmark Mandatory participation in active labour market policy programs for those under the age of 30 now begins after 3 months rather than after 6 months. • New sanctions dictate that unemployment benefits not be paid for 15 days if the recipient fails to attend a scheduled appointment with the public employment services. • The timetable for the development of individualized job search plans has been tightened. Finland Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. • The maximum duration unemployment insurance has reduced from 4 years to 2 years. of been • Qualifying conditions for regaining the right to unemployment insurance have increased from 26 weeks of previous employment to 52 weeks. Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection • France • Registration with the public employment services is now compulsory for recipients of social assistance, whereas previously it had been voluntary. Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. • The maximum duration of unemployment insurance is now equal to the duration of one's contributions. This has resulted in a reduction in benefit duration for those with moderate to high contribution records. • A transitional allowance awarded to the unemployed moving from the first to the second tier of the benefit system has been abolished. Job search requirements now apply to all working-age members of the recipient’s household. Germany Greece • All unemployment benefits have been reduced by 22%. Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. • The probationary period during which employees can be lawfully dismissed without any compensation has increased from 1 to 2 months for blue-collar workers, and from 3 to 4 months for those in management. • The notice period for lawful dismissal has been reduced; for example, from 60 days to 30 days for employees who have worked for one year. • The threshold for collective dismissals has been relaxed from 4 to 6 employees for companies with 150 or fewer employees, and from 2-3% of employees to 5% of employees for companies with more than 150 employees. Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection Ireland • New sanctions dictate that benefit cuts can be applied if the recipient refuses a work or training offer. • A new measure has established job search requirements for unemployed youth in receipt of unemployment benefits. Youth you fail to comply with the new measure face a 51% benefit cut. • New sanctions dictate the unemployment benefits may now be terminated on the grounds of a refusal to accept a job offer. Italy • Access to unemployment benefits is now conditional upon the recipient declaring immediate readiness to work or participate in training. Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. • The duration of unemployment insurance has been reduced from 15 weeks and 12 weeks (depending on one’s contributions) to 12 weeks and 9 weeks, respectively. • Qualifying conditions for unemployment insurance have doubled, from 52 weeks of contributions to 104 weeks. • The generosity of unemployment benefits has also been reduced by 8% (from €204 to €188). Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. • The parameters of lawful dismissal for economic and disciplinary reasons have been eased. • Employees found to have been unlawfully dismissed will no longer be entitled to reinstatement. • The repayment of foregone wages after unlawful dismissal has now been capped at 12 months. ! ! Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. Netherlands • New Zealand The unemployment benefit system has been restructured. As a result of this restructuring, new categories of benefit recipients now face job search requirements, despite previously having been exempt from them. Norway Portugal A new measure dictates that benefit recipients must accept a job offer if the wage is equivalent to 10% more than their unemployment benefit level. Moreover, after the first year of unemployment, the benefit recipient must accept a job offer even if the wage is equivalent to their benefit level. • The minimum duration of unemployment benefits has been cut from nine months to five months, affecting those with leaner contribution records. The level of unemployment benefits is now reduced by 10% after 180 days of receipt. • The time awarded to employees to launch an unfair dismissal claim has been reduced from 1 year to 2 months. Change that reinforces the obligation to work as a condition of unemployment protection • Spain The receipt of extraordinary unemployment benefits for recipients whose entitlement to ordinary unemployment benefits has expired is now conditional upon participation in mandatory retraining programs. Change that reduces the strictness of employment protection. Change that reduces the generosity of unemployment protection. The replacement rate of unemployment benefits is now reduced from 70% to 50% rather than to 60% after 6 months of benefit receipt. • New legislation has promoted the use of contracts with reduced levels of severance pay in the case of unfair dismissal. Severance pay in case of dismissal is 33 days per year of service as opposed to 45 days. • The notice period for lawful dismissal has been reduced from 30 days to 15. • A new definition of collective dismissal has been adopted in order to allow collective dismissals for economic reasons. New legislation has legalized collective dismissals in the public sector on economic, technical, or organizational grounds. Sweden United Kingdom New sanctions dictate that unemployment benefits can be withdrawn for a period of 1 to 2 weeks if the benefit recipient fails to attend a scheduled appointment with the job centre. A re-indexation of cash benefits has resulted in a 1.5% decrease in the real value of unemployment benefits. APPENDIX B: SIMPLIFYING ASSUMPTIONS (PRESENCE OF RECOMMODIFICATION) (1) right*def*UNEMP*lme*STAB + (2) right*def*UNEMP*LME*STAB + (3) right*DEF*unemp*lme*stab + (4) right* DEF*UNEMP*lme*STAB + (5) right*DEF*UNEMP*LME*STAB + (6) RIGHT*def*UNEMP*LME*STAB + (7) RIGHT*DEF*unemp*lme*STAB + (8) RIGHT*DEF*unemp*LME*STAB + (9) RIGHT*DEF*UNEMP*lme*stab + (10) RIGHT*DEF*UNEMP*lme*STAB APPENDIX C: SIMPLIFYING ASSUMPTIONS (ABSENCE OF RECOMMODIFICATION) (1) right*def*unemp*LME*stab + (2) right*def*unemp*LME*STAB + (3) right*def*UNEMP*LME*stab + (4) right*DEF*unemp*LME*STAB (5) right*IMBAL*UNEMP*LME*stab + (6) RIGHT*imbal*unemp*LME*STAB + (7) RIGHT*imbal*UNEMP*LME*stab