120 Business Law Review May 2006 Competition New Developments in Competition Law in Singapore Catherine Tay Swee Kian* Summary With a small and open economy, Singapore has recently joined the international community with a broad standard of similar anti-competitive prohibitions in competition law. This article gives an overview of the new developments in competition law and policy in Singapore. Currently, the new Competition Act is being implemented in a phased approach to facilitate the transition to the new competition rules for businesses in Singapore. Introduction Singapore’s new competition legislation is wide-ranging with punitive powers such as fines and sanctions to combat abuse of power by big businesses. In the second reading of the Competition Bill, the Senior Minister of State for Trade and Industry explained the objective of the Competition law: ‘‘... competition is a key tenet of Singapore’s economic strategy. Market competition spurs firms to be more efficient, innovative, and responsive to consumer needs. Consumers would enjoy more choices, lower prices and better products and services. The opened up sectors of the economy to market competition ... whilst we have rules against anti-competitive behaviours in specific sectors like energy and telecommunications, there is no generic competition law that covers all sectors ... thus recommended that a generic competition law be enacted to create a level playing field for businesses, big and small, to compete on an equal footing... The government accepted ... competition law will help to reinforce our pro-enterprise and pro-competition policies, enhance the efficiency of our markets and strengthen our economic competitiveness.’’ The Competition Act 2004 (the ‘Act’) which was passed by Parliament on 19 October 2004 has been implemented in three phrases. On 1 January 2005, only the provisions on the establishment and incorporation of the Competition Commission of Singapore (the ‘CCS’) became operative. With effect from 1 January 2006, the prohibitions against anti-competitive agreements and abuse of dominance as well as on enforcement and appeal processes under the new Act became operative. The prohibition provisions for mergers and acquisitions will only come into force after 1 January 2007, as these are more complex and technical. The rationale for this phased approach was to prepare businesses regarding the new competition requirements and for the CCS to prepare its operations. The Act has incorporated the international best practices from other competition regimes worldwide (including the United Kingdom, the United States, Australia, Ireland, Canada and India) that are relevant to Singapore economic circumstances although the Act is largely modelled on the United Kingdom and European Community legislations but with a number of significant differences, which are discussed in this paper. In particular, the role of the Competition Commission of Singapore (CCS) is consistent with the objective of its legislation. The legislative driven policy initiative is reflected into the Act itself. This can be seen in the Third Schedule of the Act which allows for exemptions from public policy considerations. The CCS and the law courts have a huge discretion to manage competition rules which are subject to an ever changing social economic environment. The freedom to trade is important as Singapore attracts foreign investments into its small and open economy. In its pursuit of excellence, Singapore’s economic growth is fuelled by competition policies as can be seen in the sectors of the biomedical research, pharmaceuticals and the life sciences, to obtain international competitiveness and the efficient allocation of resources. Another point to note is the institutional relationship which is a new dynamic within Singapore between the CCS and the Competition Appeal Board intertwined with political objectives. The aim of the Act is to create a level playing field for businesses, eg through steps that prevent firms from using their dominant position in markets to thwart competition. But there are certain controversial factors which remain outside its ambit. Previously, Singapore did not have a general competition law regime although she has competition codes administered by regulators for newly liberalised sectors such as energy, telecommunications and the media sectors. Because of the changing technologies and the Free Trade Agreements with the United States and Australia, the competition regulation was introduced. * LL B (Hon) (London), LL M (London), Barrister (England), Advocate and Solicitor (Singapore). The author is a member of the Institutional Review Board / Ethics Committee of the National Healthcare Group Domain Specific Review Board which is tasked to review scientific and ethical aspects of research protocols. She is a member if the Institutional Review Board of SingHealth Polyclinics. She lectures on biomedical ethics and medical law in the Faculty of Dentistry at the National University of Singapore. She has supervised on bioethics and medical law in a special study module in the Faculty of Medicine at the National University of Singapore. Her research interests include business laws, clinical and research ethics, medical and biotechnology laws. She is an author of 28 law books. The author would like to thank Dr Albert Myint Soe, Ph D, (Camb), Barrister (UK), for his valuable comments on a draft of this article. Business Law Review May 2006 121 Competition Scope of Anti-Competition Law The Act applies to every conduct by all undertakings including individuals, corporations and unincorporated bodies and government-linked corporations.1 It will apply to commercial and economic activities carried on by private sector entities, whether owned by the government or not, statutory bodies, local or foreign entities. But there are a number of exclusions from its scope because these undertakings are either currently regulated by the competition codes in the media, energy and telecommunication sectors; or activities subject to pre-existing legal requirements or international obligations; and cases where public policy dictates including the vertical agreements. The exclusions are not permanent as there will be reviews to meet the need for sectoral exclusions taking account of market development. The exclusions made are based on public interest considerations, which are similar to other competition regimes globally. Competition Regulation The Act prohibits three main anti-competitive activities that unduly prevent, restrict or distort competition. These are: 1. anti-competitive agreements, practices and decisions (the section 34 prohibition); 2. abuse of dominant position (the section 47 prohibition); and 3. mergers and acquisitions that substantially lessens competition (the section 54 prohibition). Numerous guidelines covering market definition, intellectual property, transitional arrangements, filing notifications for guidance and decision, enforcement, leniency and the appropriate amount of penalties have been issued by the CCS to guide businesses on how the CCS will interpret the provisions of the Act. These guidelines which appear to have been influenced by the approach taken in the United Kingdom, will ensure greater transparency and clarity to businesses on the competition law regime. To ensure their continued relevance, such guidelines will be reviewed, taking into consideration market changes and the decisions of the Competition Appeal Board and the courts. Anti-Competitive Agreements Since 1 January 2006, section 34 of the Act has prohibited anti-competitive agreements made between undertakings which affect the appreciable prevention, restriction or distortion of competition unless they are exempted in the Third Schedule of the Act such as the vertical agreements or the net economic benefit exclusion or have met the requirements specified in a block exemption order. The CCS has announced its policy on maritime block exemptions. In assessing whether an action is anti-competitive, due consideration will be given to whether it promotes innovation, productivity or longer-term economic efficiency, so as not to inadvertently constrain innovative and enterprising endeavours. The new wide ranging competition law targets prohibited agreements between competing firms on pricefixing, bid-rigging, market-sharing and the restriction of production. The term ‘agreement’ has a wide meaning and includes both legally enforceable and nonenforceable agreements such as gentlemen agreements, whether oral or written.2 Unlike the USA and UK, such blacklisted agreements are not criminal offences but in Singapore, only a financial penalty may be imposed. The section 34 guidelines explain that there are different ways in which prices can be fixed. For instance, it may be fixing the components of a price such as a discount or by fixing the percentage by which prices are to be increased or fixing a range outside which prices are not to move. It is also price-fixing if there is an agreement to adhere to published price lists or not to charge less than any other price in the market. Further, recommendations of a trade association or a professional body in relation to price may be regarded as price-fixing. In certain circumstances, the exchange of information on prices between competitors may lead to price co-ordination and thus diminish competition. Generally, where historical information is exchanged, it is less likely that the exchange could have an appreciable adverse effect on competition.3 Anti-competitive provisions in contracts and agreements are prohibited and void. Both the prohibition and voidness are a matter of competition law and not the law of contract. ‘Voidness’ here is transient, as it only applies when section 34 of the Act applies. On the other hand, the effect of voidness on the other contractual provisions is a matter of contract law.4 There is a leniency programme which is particularly aimed at cartel-busting, with up to 100% immunity from financial penalties subject to providing evidence and on-going cooperation during the investigation. Leniency applies to ‘whistle-blowers’ especially for cartel activities because cartels are secret and usually difficult to detect. Experience has shown in a number of Western competition law regimes that the leniency programmes are usually successful where there is a complete amnesty given to the first conspirator who comes forward to reveal the cartel activities to the Competition authorities. Recently, there was a move by three cinema operators in Singapore to increase ticket prices. Would such conduct be considered ‘price fixing’ under the new 1 See SNUPAT v High Authority [1961] ECR 53; Hofner and Elser v Macrotron GmbH [1991] ECR I-1979; Hydrotherm Geratebau v Compact [1984] ECR 2999; and Viho v Commission [1996] ECR I-5457. 2 See section 34 guidelines of CCS. 3 See US Sherman Act and American Column and Lumber Co v US 257 US 377 (1921) and Maple Flooring Manufacturers’ Association v US 268 US 563 (1925). 4 See the English law position in Passmore v Moreland [1999] 1 CMLR 1129; and Delimitis v Henniger Brau [1991] ECR I-935. 122 Business Law Review May 2006 Competition law? The impact of the new competition law on existing contracts means that businesses and firms now need to look again at their existing contractual agreements to comply with the new Act. However, the businesses were given a one-year window since the law was passed in 1 January 2005 but which took effect on 1 January 2006. Abuse of Dominant Market Position Section 47 of the Act prohibits the abuse of a dominant position but does not prohibit undertakings from having a dominant position.5 The prohibited behavior would include limiting production, tying agreements, price discrimination and predatory pricing towards competitors such as sustained pricing at below average variable cost. But there may be an objective justification defence such as a price promotion or a refusal to supply which may be justified by the poor creditworthiness of the buyer.6 Provided the abuse has an effect within Singapore, the dominant position need not be in Singapore. An indicative market share of 60% or above would be in a dominant position including a position of economic strength or an ability to act independently of the market. However, each case would have to be looked at on its own merit. In practice, it may be difficult to determine whether a particular conduct by a dominant firm is bad or good. Ideally, the economic welfare effect (ie a cost-benefit analysis) and not just the effect on competition should be taken into account. Third Schedule Exclusions to AntiCompetitive Agreements and Abuse of Dominance The following are the exclusions for the sections 34 and 47 prohibitions: 1. services of general economic interest or having the character of a revenue-producing monopoly; 2. activities to avoid conflict with international obligations; 3. activities needed to comply with legal requirements; 4. activities arising from exceptional and compelling reasons of public policy eg national security; 5. goods or services regulated by other sector-specific competition law eg Telecommunications Act 1999 and th0e Info-Communications Development Authority of Singapore Act 1999; 6. specified activities already regulated under various laws: . supply of ordinary letter and postcard services under the Postal Services Act, . supply of piped potable water, . supply of waste water management services, . supply of scheduled bus services under the Public Transport Council Act, . supply of rail services under the rapid Transport Systems Act, . cargo terminal operations under the Maritime and Port Authority of Singapore Act; 7. the clearing and exchanging of articles undertaken by the Automated Clearing House established under the Banking (Clearing House) Regulations; 8. any activity of the Singapore Clearing Houses Association in relation to its activities regarding the Automated Clearing House. Vertical agreements are excluded from section 34 prohibition.7 Agreements with ‘net economic benefit’ which contributes to improving production or distribution or promoting technical or economic progress are exempted also from section 34 prohibition unless specified in a Ministerial order. Such block exemptions may be qualified and conditional. Mergers and Acquisitions At a future date in 2007, section 54 of the Act will prohibit mergers and acquisitions which result in a substantial lessening of competition within any market in Singapore for goods or services unless approved by written law. The section 54 prohibition will not apply to any merger relating to the specified activities stated above under points 6 to 8. The CCS has the power to prohibit mergers. It will provide guidance on the turnover and market shares that will trigger an investigation and will review proposed mergers within a time-frame. The merger test standard is that of a ‘substantial lessening of competition within any market in Singapore’, which is similar to the US and Australian merger test standard. Role of the Competition Commission The functions and duties of the CCS are to maintain and enhance efficient market conduct and promote overall productivity, innovation and competitiveness of markets in Singapore; to eliminate or control practices having adverse effect on competition in Singapore; to act internationally as the national body representative of Singapore and advise the government or other public authority on national needs and policies in relation to competition matters.8 But one cannot ignore the economic reasoning which can help to explain why businesses behave in a certain manner. The CCS will 5 See Hoffman La Roche [1979] ECR 215 on the meaning of ‘abuse’? Also see the Report of Economic Advisory Group for Competition policy), July 2005. 6 See the recent attempts to rely on efficiency justifications for exclusionary conduct which have been unsuccessful British Airways [2003] ECR II-5917 and Michellin II [2003] ECR II4071. 7 See s 8 of Third Schedule of the Act on the meaning of vertical agreement ‘‘... any agreement made between 2 or more undertakings each of which operates at a different level of production or distribution chain ...’’. 8 See s 6(1)of the Act. Business Law Review May 2006 123 Competitiont have regard to the differences in the nature of various markets in Singapore, the economic, industrial and commercial needs of Singapore and maintain the efficient functioning of the markets in Singapore.9 In administering the various prohibitions, the CCS will issue guidelines,10 recommend the making, variation or revocation of a block exemption order, give decisions or guidance, investigate infringements and adjudicate on infringements. The CCS has issued guidelines, after public consultation, on the sections 34 and 47 prohibitions, ‘market definition’, powers of investigation, enforcement, filing notifications for guidance or decision, lenient treatment for undertakings coming forward with information on cartel activity cases, transitional arrangements and appropriate amount of penalty and treatment of intellectual property rights. Undertakings may apply to the CCS for guidance or a decision to indicate whether an agreement is likely to infringe the sections 34 and 47 prohibitions or whether it is likely to be exempted in a block exemption.11 Once the CCS has given guidance or a decision that an agreement has not infringed the sections 34 or 47 prohibitions, the CCS will take no further action unless it has reasonable grounds to believe that there has been a material change of circumstance since giving its decision or guidance or it has reasonable grounds to suspect that the information was incomplete, false or misleading.12 Investigation Powers of Competition Commission If there are reasonable grounds for suspecting infringements, the CCS has certain powers of investigation such as informal enquiries, information notices, witness statements, ‘dawn raids’ or the power to enter premises with or without a warrant.13 The CCS is likely to investigate behaviour where there would be ‘an appreciable adverse effect’. Investigations could be the result of a complaint from a competitor, a public member, the CCS’s own monitoring and surveillance or from overseas competition authorities investigating associated companies overseas. The CCS has wide powers under the Act to request documents or information. Such power to require production of specified documents or information may be given to complainants, suppliers, competitors or customers, besides the infringers and their officers. The term ‘document’ means ‘information recorded in any form’ such as facsimiles, e-mails, letters, customer contacts, board minutes, mobile phones, marketing and strategic plans. But the CCS may require ‘information’ not in a recorded form such as estimates of market shares. The CCS has the powers to conduct searches of business premises. It is a criminal offence if an undertaking fails to comply or co-operate with such powers of investigation. But communications between a legal adviser and his client are considered privileged documents, because the privilege against self-incrimination is recognised. Legally privileged documents must be clearly marked in big bold red ink. There should be sound processes in place to ensure legally privileged documents are clearly labelled. During the investigative process, co-operation is essential as delaying the process is often unwise. It would be wise to give the CCS as much information as possible to justify the business decisions. Early and on-going co-operation to tell ‘your side of the story’ may mean that the competition regulator is more likely to negotiate a settlement should there be an infringement. The CCS cannot disclose confidential information unless there is a gateway such as permission given by the relevant parties or if it is necessary for CCS functions. The CCS has to protect the identity of leniency applicants and complainants. It will participate in international fora but will not be sharing or receiving confidential information. Adjudication by Competition Commission The Act provides several procedural safeguards because the CCS is both the investigator and adjudicator.14 This institutional structure under the Act is similar to the UK competition model. Before deciding that the sections 34 or 47 prohibition is infringed, the CCS shall give written notice to the person so that he has an opportunity to make his representations. A person can appeal a decision of the CCS to the Competition Appeal Board and higher courts.15 If there is an infringement under sections 34 or 47, the CCS may give directions to the infringing parties to end such infringement. Where such infringement is done intentionally or negligently, the CCS can impose a financial penalty of up to 10% of the undertaking’s turnover in Singapore for each year of infringement up to a maximum of 3 years.16 The intention or negligence relates to the facts.17 Intention may be inferred if the consequences of an agreement are reasonably foreseeable.18 But an infringement will be committed negligently where an undertaking ought to have known 9 See s 6(1)of the Act. See s 61 of the Act. These guidelines give conceptual, analytical and procedural approach that the CCS will interpret and give effect to in its enforcement activities; and their application will depend on the facts of each case. 10 11 See s 43 of the Act. See ss 45, 46 and 53 of the Act. 13 See s 62 of the Act. 14 See s 71. Also see Bettercare v DGFT [2002] CAT 6. and Claymore v DGFT [2003] CAT 3. 15 See JJB Sports PLC v Office of Fair Trading [2004] CAT 17 on the civil standard of review that an infringement is duly proved. 16 See s 69(3) of the Act. 17 See paras 4.3 to 4.11 of the CCS’s Guidelines on Enforcement, November 2005. 18 See Napp Pharmaceutical Holdings Ltd v DGFT [2003] Comp AR 13 at para 456 where the CAT gave its guidance on the meaning of ‘intentionally’. 12 124 Business Law Review May 2006 Competition that its agreement would distort competition. Further, even where an undertaking acts under duress, it may still be acting intentionally or negligently. The objectives of the CCS for imposing any financial penalty are to reflect the seriousness of the infringement and to deter undertakings from engaging in anti-competitive practices.19 The CCS adopts the leniency programme for undertakings involved in cartel activity, which is modelled upon the UK competition regime.20 A decision of the Commission as to ‘‘whether the section 34 prohibition, the section 47 prohibition ... has been infringed... is an ‘appealable decision’.’’21 Whether there is an appealable decision is a question of fact depending on the particular circumstances of each case, which is a question to be determined objectively. There is a right of private third party action for damages only after the CCS has made a decision of infringement and after all the appeal processes.22 There is a two year time limit for the taking of such private actions from the time that the CCS made the decision or from the determination of the appeal, whichever is the later.23 The court will be bound in such proceedings by the relevant infringement decisions.24 This is in contrast to the EC and UK approach where a party may bring a claim for damages where there has been no preceding infringement decision. As to who can claim third party actions for damages, it is interesting to note that co-conspirators are excluded. Parties to agreements that infringe the section 34 prohibition have no right of action for relief.25 This is in contrast to the UK and EC competition law.26 ‘Third parties’ in the case of a price-fixing cartel would include direct and indirect purchasers,27 potential purchasers, competitors, non conspirators, purchasers from non conspirators and suppliers. For the issues of causation and quantum, it is likely that the Singapore courts will use the ordinary rules applicable to claims of breach of statutory duty.28 So the loss which can be recovered in an action for damages would be the difference between the losses made and the smaller losses which would have been made in the absence of the infringing conduct. An interesting point to note is whether the Singapore courts would allow the award of punitive or exemplary damages remains to be seen, as section 86(8) of the Act provides that the court may grant the following relief: . relief by way of injunction or declaration, . damages, and . such other relief as the court thinks fit. Compliance Programme Contracts that are affected will be taken care of by the transitional provisions of the Act. Although the law comes into effect on 1 January 2006, businesses get a six-month grace period to ensure their existing contracts comply with the new competition legislation. However, to facilitate the long term agreements, parties who have entered into contracts at least five years before 1 January 2005 may apply to the CCS for a longer transition period and an exemption from the prohibition provisions of the competition law during this period. Businesses would be wise to establish a compliance programme: . to comply with the new competition rules (thereby avoiding litigation costs and rendering future agreements invalid); . to induce a culture of compliance for the whole company / undertaking; . to increase awareness of prohibited behaviour; . to establish effective training programmes for dealing with competition issues; . to have a compliance manual with procedures in place for clearance of certain actions by defining lines of authority; . to formulate policies for internal document retention as a paper trail is important; . to draw up a list of all contracts to be reviewed at multi-department level and review current agreements; . to devise procedures for dealing with any inspections and investigations by the competition regulators; . to have internal policy for whistle-blowers; . to be updated with the latest CCS’s policy and news releases. It is also crucial to monitor overseas developments. Conclusion As a small and open economy, the new competition law can stimulate competitive behavior by opening up a competitive business environment in Singapore thereby ensuring fair competition with a greater innovation, efficiency and enterprise. After all, competition law is meant to enable allocatable economic efficiencies and enhance consumer welfare in the domestic market and not for the case of export cartel. Consumers can 19 See s 69 of the Act. Also see Napp Pharmaceuticals v Office of Fair Trading [2003] Comp AR 13. 20 See Guidelines on Lenient Treatment for Undertakings Coming Forward with Information on Cartel Cases (CCS, November 2005). 21 See s 71(3) of the Act. 22 See s 86 of the Act. 23 See s 86(6) of the Act. 24 See s 86(7) of the Act. 25 See s 86(9) of the Act. 26 See Crehan v Courage [2001] ECR I-6297 where the ECJ held that damages are available even to those parties to an unlawful agreements unless they were ‘significantly responsible’ for the infringement. 27 See Illinois Brick Co v Illinos 431 US 720 (1977) where in the US Federal anti-trust law, the Supreme court stated that claims brought by indirect purchasers (ie those who did not buy directly from the infringer) should generally be refused. This issue has not yet been addressed by the UK or EC courts. 28 See Society of Lloyd’s v John Stewart Clementson (No 2) [1996] QBD at para 12 and Arkin v Borchard Lines (No 4) [2003] EWHC 687. Business Law Review May 2006 125 Competition benefit from lower prices as manufacturers will now have strong incentives to compete with each other for creativity and efficiency. Otherwise, there would be a guaranteed level of prices regardless of quality and the level of innovation. As any regulatory intervention in the market may impose costs, Singapore needs to balance regulatory and business compliance costs against the benefits from effective competition. So instead of catching all forms of anti-competitive activities, Singapore will focus principally on those that have an appreciable adverse effect on competition in Singapore or that do not have any net economic benefit.29 Cartel activities such as price fixing, market arrangements and bid-rigging activities which have an appreciable adverse effect on competition in Singapore are more likely to occupy centre stage in the CCS list of enforcement priorities. The new Act provides the flexibility to apply competition law and policy to suit Singapore’s interest in maintaining an efficient and open economy. However, much will depend on the CCS’s response to the challenges it faces in the future, given that it has the primary control over all competition law liability issues. Perhaps, applying a general effects based standard of reasonableness is a wise step to ensure a more flexible approach in the application of the new competition regime to enhance the competitiveness of Singapore’s economy. For now, it is a new model but a dynamic one. Within a few years, there will be an established Singapore competition law with case laws and further guidelines. If it so requires, Singapore has available to an abundance of case law decided in the United Kingdom,30 the European Union and the United States of America.31 Singapore has joined the international community with a broad standard of similar prohibitions as she has incorporated the best practices from competition regimes globally that are best suited to her particular economic situation. 29 See the Second Reading of the Competition Bill of Parliamentary Debates, Singapore, 19 October 2004. 30 See the recent judgment of the Competition Appeal Tribunal in The Racecourse Association v Office of Fair Trading [2005] CAT 29 in which an important issue of the circumstances in which joint selling might be considered as anti-competitive. 31 See the United States case of National Collegiate Athletic Association v University of Oklahoma 468 US 85 (1984).